메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 33, Issue 2, 2010, Pages 557-606

Antitrust in an era of market failure

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 78049275491     PISSN: 01934872     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (20)

References (333)
  • 1
    • 78049313629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cognizant of this restorative process, the law seeks to facilitate entry and to avoid mistaken findings that might insulate undesirable behavior from free-market forces. Obeisance toward the curative powers of the market has led U.S. law to adopt an agnostic approach to economic conduct of indeterminate long-run effect
    • Cognizant of this restorative process, the law seeks to facilitate entry and to avoid mistaken findings that might insulate undesirable behavior from free-market forces. Obeisance toward the curative powers of the market has led U.S. law to adopt an agnostic approach to economic conduct of indeterminate long-run effect.
  • 2
    • 59149085479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • China's competition policy reforms: The anti-monopoly law and beyond
    • 231 (explaining the myriad benefits competition policy has bestowed upon Western economies)
    • See Bruce M. Owen et al., China's Competition Policy Reforms: The Anti-Monopoly Law and Beyond, 75 ANTITRUST L.J. 231, 231 (2008) (explaining the myriad benefits competition policy has bestowed upon Western economies).
    • (2008) Antitrust L.J. , vol.75 , pp. 231
    • Owen, B.M.1
  • 3
    • 0012072108 scopus 로고
    • Recent developments in economics that challenge chicago school views
    • 646
    • See Jonathan B. Baker, Recent Developments in Economics that Challenge Chicago School Views, 58 ANTITRUST L.J. 645, 646 (1989);
    • (1989) Antitrust L.J. , vol.58 , pp. 645
    • Baker, J.B.1
  • 4
    • 13444276477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Post-chicago antitrust: A review and critique
    • 258
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, Post-Chicago Antitrust: A Review and Critique, 2001 COLUM. Bus. L. REV. 257, 258;
    • Colum. Bus. L. Rev. , vol.2001 , pp. 257
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 5
    • 0000156633 scopus 로고
    • The chicago school of antitrust analysis
    • Richard A. Posner, The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 925 (1979).
    • (1979) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.127 , pp. 925
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 6
    • 78049292286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ltd. V. Empagran and the extraterritorial limits of united states antitrust jurisdiction: Where comity and deterrence collide
    • 268 (noting that the "United States has what is considered the world's most advanced and extensive antitrust regime" (footnote omitted))
    • See Siddharth Fernandes, F. Hoffmann-LaRoche, Ltd. v. Empagran and the Extraterritorial Limits of United States Antitrust Jurisdiction: Where Comity and Deterrence Collide, 20 CONN. J. INT'L L. 267, 268 (2005) (noting that the "United States has what is considered the world's most advanced and extensive antitrust regime" (footnote omitted));
    • (2005) Conn. J. Int'l L. , vol.20 , pp. 267
    • Fernandes, S.1    Hoffmann-LaRoche, F.2
  • 7
    • 78049244454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tweaking antitrust's business model
    • 53-54 (reviewing HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE ANTITRUST ENTERPRISE: PRINCIPLE AND EXECUTION (2005))
    • Thomas A. Lambert, Tweaking Antitrust's Business Model, 85 TEX. L. REV. 153, 153-54 (2006) (reviewing HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE ANTITRUST ENTERPRISE: PRINCIPLE AND EXECUTION (2005)).
    • (2006) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.85 , pp. 1531
    • Lambert, T.A.1
  • 8
    • 78049285327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why mcrosoft was wrong
    • Sept. 26, ("U.S. and EU antitrust laws agree on most things, not least the objective of benefiting consumers."); Mario Monti, Comm'r for Competition: European Comm'n, Comments and Concluding Remarks, Conference on Professional Regulation 16 (Oct. 28, 2003), (referring to the goal of making "the EU the most competitive and dynamic economy in the world by 2010")
    • See Neelie Kroes, Why Mcrosoft Was Wrong, WALL ST. J. EUR., Sept. 26, 2007, at 13 ("U.S. and EU antitrust laws agree on most things, not least the objective of benefiting consumers."); Mario Monti, Comm'r for Competition: European Comm'n, Comments and Concluding Remarks, Conference on Professional Regulation 16 (Oct. 28, 2003), available at http://ec.europa.eu/ comm/competition/speeches/text/ sp2003-028-en.pdf (referring to the goal of making "the EU the most competitive and dynamic economy in the world by 2010").
    • (2007) Wall St. J. Eur. , pp. 13
    • Kroes, N.1
  • 9
    • 78049312723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Transatlantic antitrust: Convergence or divergence
    • 5
    • See Deborah A. Garza, Transatlantic Antitrust: Convergence or Divergence, 16 ANTITRUST 5, 5 (2001);
    • (2001) Antitrust , vol.16 , pp. 5
    • Garza, D.A.1
  • 10
    • 21644488588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A world of uncertainty: Economics and the globalization of antitrust
    • 403
    • Ken Heyer, A World of Uncertainty: Economics and the Globalization of Antitrust, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 375, 403 (2005);
    • (2005) Antitrust L.J. , vol.72 , pp. 375
    • Heyer, K.1
  • 11
    • 72749105271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The future of global competition governance: Lessons from the transatlantic
    • 821-25
    • Charles W. Smitherman III, The Future of Global Competition Governance: Lessons from the Transatlantic, 19 AM. U. INT'L L. REV. 769, 821-25 (2004).
    • (2004) Am. U. Int'l L. Rev. , vol.19 , pp. 769
    • Smitherman III, C.W.1
  • 12
    • 77649161285 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (comparing and contrasting the role of economic analysis in U.S. and EC competition law)
    • See, e.g., GIORGIO MONTI, EC COMPETITION LAW 73-82 (2007) (comparing and contrasting the role of economic analysis in U.S. and EC competition law).
    • (2007) EC Competition Law , pp. 73-82
    • Monti, G.1
  • 14
    • 78049232320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • infra Part ILB
    • See infra Part ILB;
  • 16
    • 77951547203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Revitalizing section 5 of the FTC Act using consumer choice analysis
    • Feb.
    • See, e.g., Robert H. Lande, Revitalizing Section 5 of the FTC Act Using 'Consumer Choice'Analysis, ANTITRUST SOURCE, Feb. 2009;
    • (2009) Antitrust Source
    • Lande, R.H.1
  • 17
    • 78049244915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A suggestion for the revival of section
    • Feb.
    • Thomas B. Leary, A Suggestion for the Revival of Section 5, ANTITRUST SOURCE, Feb. 2009.
    • (2009) Antitrust Source , vol.5
    • Leary, T.B.1
  • 18
    • 78049233742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EU actions suggest tougher antitrust enforcement
    • DoJ, June 1
    • See DoJ, EU Actions Suggest Tougher Antitrust Enforcement, TELECOMM. REP., June 1, 2009, at 43.
    • (2009) Telecomm. Rep. , pp. 43
  • 19
    • 78049257341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interview with J. Thomas Rosch, Commissioner, Federal trade commission
    • 41 ("A ... possibility is that the agencies will be taking a closer look to see whether or not the merger will result in a post transaction firm that is too big to fail....")
    • See Mark D. Whitener, Interview with J. Thomas Rosch, Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission, 23 ANTITRUST 32, 41 (2009) ("A ... possibility is that the agencies will be taking a closer look to see whether or not the merger will result in a post transaction firm that is too big to fail....");
    • (2009) Antitrust , vol.23 , pp. 32
    • Whitener, M.D.1
  • 20
    • 78049253956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust enforcer vows tough stance
    • May 12, (noting Christine Varney's question of whether antitrust has failed if companies get too big to fail and observation that "[c]onsumers have been waiting for the markets to correct themselves, but the financial crisis has shown they haven't")
    • see also Jim Puzzanghera, Antitrust Enforcer Vows Tough Stance, L.A. TIMES, May 12, 2009, at B1 (noting Christine Varney's question of whether antitrust has failed if companies get too big to fail and observation that "[c]onsumers have been waiting for the markets to correct themselves, but the financial crisis has shown they haven't").
    • (2009) L.A. Times
    • Puzzanghera, J.1
  • 21
    • 78049281374 scopus 로고
    • 903 F.2d 659, 668-69 9th Cir.
    • See, e.g., United States v. Syufy Enters., 903 F.2d 659, 668-69 (9th Cir. 1990).
    • (1990) United States V. Syufy Enters.
  • 23
    • 78049273697 scopus 로고
    • "Congress designed the Sherman Act as a 'consumer welfare prescription.'" quoting 442 U.S. 330, 343
    • ("Congress designed the Sherman Act as a 'consumer welfare prescription.'" (quoting Reiter v. Sonotone Corp., 442 U.S. 330, 343 (1979));
    • (1979) Reiter V. Sonotone Corp.
  • 25
    • 0041647697 scopus 로고
    • The economic goals of antitrust: Efficiency, consumer welfare, and technological progress
    • 1025-27
    • Joseph F. Brodley, The Economic Goals of Antitrust: Efficiency, Consumer Welfare, and Technological Progress, 62 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1020, 1025-27 (1987);
    • (1987) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.62 , pp. 1020
    • Brodley, J.F.1
  • 26
    • 33748440954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Conglomerate mergers and range effects: It's a long way from chicago to brussels
    • 533-34
    • William J. Kolasky, Conglomerate Mergers and Range Effects: It's a Long Way from Chicago to Brussels, 10 GEO. MASON L. REV. 533, 533-34 (2002);
    • (2002) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.10 , pp. 533
    • Kolasky, W.J.1
  • 27
    • 0043150518 scopus 로고
    • Commentary: Implications of professor scherer's research for the future of antitrust
    • 258 ("[T]he dominant paradigm today is that the only goal of the existing antitrust laws is to increase economic efficiency)
    • Robert H. Lande, Commentary: Implications of Professor Scherer's Research for the Future of Antitrust, 29 Washburn L.J. 256, 258 (1990) ("[T]he dominant paradigm today is that the only goal of the existing antitrust laws is to increase economic efficiency");
    • (1990) Washburn L.J. , vol.29 , pp. 256
    • Lande, R.H.1
  • 28
    • 0035579661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GTE sylvania and the empirical foundations of antitrust
    • 900 (interpreting GTE Sylvania as a ringing endorsement of the economic approach to antitrust")
    • Timothy J. Muris, GTE Sylvania and the Empirical Foundations of Antitrust, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 899, 900 (2001) (interpreting GTE Sylvania as "a ringing endorsement of the economic approach to antitrust").
    • (2001) Antitrust L.J. , vol.68 , pp. 899
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 29
    • 58749087252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The fundamental goal of antitrust: Protecting consumers, not increasing efficiency
    • But see John B. Kirkwood & Robert H. Lande, The Fundamental Goal of Antitrust: Protecting Consumers, Not Increasing Efficiency, 84 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 191 (2008).
    • (2008) Notre Dame L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 191
    • Kirkwood, J.B.1    Lande, R.H.2
  • 30
    • 78049236974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Synthetic competition
    • (observing the vast range of ends to which antitrust laws have historically been applied, noting that the "varied goals endorsed by the Supreme Court were... divisive and contradictory," and observing that the Supreme Court's decision in GTE Sylvania largely ended the confusion... [and] made the maximization of consumer welfare, or allocative efficiency, the chief consideration when applying the antitrust laws)
    • See Douglas H. Ginsburg, Synthetic Competition, 16 MEDIA L. & POL'Y 1, 7-10 (2006) (observing the vast range of ends to which antitrust laws have historically been applied, noting that the "varied goals endorsed by the Supreme Court were... divisive and contradictory," and observing that the Supreme Court's decision in GTE Sylvania "largely ended the confusion... [and] made the maximization of consumer welfare, or allocative efficiency, the chief consideration when applying the antitrust laws").
    • (2006) Media L. & Pol'y 1 , vol.16 , pp. 7-10
    • Ginsburg, D.H.1
  • 31
    • 0005121542 scopus 로고
    • Legislative intent and the policy of the sherman act
    • 10
    • It would, as Judge Robert Bork characterized it, be like "playing tennis with the net down." Robert H. Bork, Legislative Intent and the Policy of the Sherman Act, 9 J.L. & ECON. 7, 10 (1966).
    • (1966) J.L. & Econ. , vol.9 , pp. 7
    • Bork, R.H.1
  • 32
    • 78049277870 scopus 로고
    • The end of history and the new world order: The triumph of capitalism and the competition between liberalism and democracy
    • 283
    • See Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, The End of History and the New World Order: The Triumph of Capitalism and the Competition Between Liberalism and Democracy, 25 CORNELL INT'L L.J. 277, 283 (1992).
    • (1992) Cornell Int'l L.J. , vol.25 , pp. 277
    • Macey, J.R.1    Miller, G.P.2
  • 33
    • 78049232799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Essential facilities and trinko: Should antitrust and regulation be combined?
    • 147
    • See Timothy J. Brennan, Essential Facilities and Trinko: Should Antitrust and Regulation Be Combined?, 61 FED. COMM. L.J. 133, 147 (2008);
    • (2008) Fed. Comm. L.J. , vol.61 , pp. 133
    • Brennan, T.J.1
  • 34
    • 0041869241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The report of the attorney general's national committee to study the antitrust laws: A retrospective
    • 1870 ("American antitrust rests heavily on what in the end is an act of faith, faith that markets work and are in large part self-correcting.")
    • Thomas E. Kauper, The Report of the Attorney General's National Committee to Study the Antitrust Laws: A Retrospective, 100 MICH. L. REV. 1867, 1870 (2002) ("American antitrust rests heavily on what in the end is an act of faith, faith that markets work and are in large part self-correcting.").
    • (2002) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.100 , pp. 1867
    • Kauper, T.E.1
  • 35
    • 84934453628 scopus 로고
    • The limits of antitrust
    • 18 ("When a business rival brings suit, it is often safe to infer that the arrangement is beneficial to consumers.")
    • See Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 18 (1984) ("When a business rival brings suit, it is often safe to infer that the arrangement is beneficial to consumers.").
    • (1984) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.63 , pp. 1
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 36
    • 78049299582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Before proceeding further, a word on interpretation is needed. Specificity is the key to reasoned debate about the crisis. Sweeping references to "the market," "deregulation," "capitalism," "Chicago," and other broad terms are not likely to yield meaningful conclusions. Deregulation of industry segments that do not display natural monopoly characteristics is distinct from deregulation of banking activities predisposed to excessive leverage. "The market" performs a different role in antitrust analysis than it does when uncritically used to support wholesale deregulation. Each industry and every market must be subject to particularized analysis-conclusions about the perceived failure of capitalism in one context may have legitimate normative consequences in one setting and yet none in another.
  • 37
    • 0005121542 scopus 로고
    • Legislative intent and the policy of the sherman act
    • 7
    • See Robert H. Bork, Legislative Intent and the Policy of the Sherman Act, 9 J.L. & ECON. 7, 7 (1966);
    • (1966) J.L. & Econ. , vol.9 , pp. 7
    • Bork, R.H.1
  • 38
    • 0012041640 scopus 로고
    • An essay on the normative foundations of antitrust economics
    • 226-27
    • Michael S. Jacobs, An Essay on the Normative Foundations of Antitrust Economics, 74 N.C. L. REV. 219, 226-27 (1995).
    • (1995) N.C. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 219
    • Jacobs, M.S.1
  • 39
    • 78049240391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There is an important distinction between short-run static efficiency, in which a market displays allocative efficiency with zero deadweight loss, and long-run dynamic efficiency, in which markets may be subject to ephemeral bouts of monopoly that fuel ongoing innovation. In some information markets, often referred to collectively as the "new economy," there is a tension between static and dynamic efficiency, with the latter goal being by far the more important.
  • 40
    • 62649095230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interoperability between antitrust and intellectual property
    • 860 It is for this reason that society bestows certain inventors and artists with limited exclusivity under the intellectual property laws. The key point to remember is that although efficiency is indeed the goal of contemporary antitrust policy, the particular form of efficiency mandated by theory differs depending on the particular market.
    • See Thomas O. Barnett, Interoperability Between Antitrust and Intellectual Property, 14 GEO. MASON L. REV. 859, 860 (2007). It is for this reason that society bestows certain inventors and artists with limited exclusivity under the intellectual property laws. The key point to remember is that although efficiency is indeed the goal of contemporary antitrust policy, the particular form of efficiency mandated by theory differs depending on the particular market.
    • (2007) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.14 , pp. 859
    • Barnett, T.O.1
  • 42
    • 0033434233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Liberty and antitrust in the formative era
    • 4-5
    • See, e.g., Alan J. Meese, Liberty and Antitrust in the Formative Era, 79 B.U. L. REV. 1, 4-5 (1999).
    • (1999) B.U. L. Rev. , vol.79 , pp. 1
    • Meese, A.J.1
  • 43
    • 0036926038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What is harm to competition? Exclusionary practices and anticompetitive effect
    • 379
    • See Eleanor M. Fox, What Is Harm to Competition? Exclusionary Practices and Anticompetitive Effect, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 371, 379 (2002).
    • (2002) Antitrust L.J. , vol.70 , pp. 371
    • Fox, E.M.1
  • 45
    • 78049258307 scopus 로고
    • 26 Stat. 209 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7 (2006))
    • Sherman Act, ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209 (1890) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7 (2006)).
    • (1890) Sherman Act, Ch. , pp. 647
  • 47
    • 84926229709 scopus 로고
    • Price-fixing agreements under the sherman anti-trust law
    • Notably, Senator Sherman commented on a related draft that the act does not announce a new principle of law, but applies old and well recognized principles of the common law. 306 n.29
    • Notably, Senator Sherman commented on a related draft that the act "does not announce a new principle of law, but applies old and well recognized principles of the common law." John C. Peppin, Price-Fixing Agreements Under the Sherman Anti-Trust Law, 28 CAL. L. REV. 297, 306 n.29 (1940)
    • (1940) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.28 , pp. 297
    • Peppin, J.C.1
  • 48
    • 0346253338 scopus 로고
    • (quoting 21 CONG. REC. 2456 (1890)).
    • (1890) Cong. Rec. , vol.21 , pp. 2456
  • 49
    • 85052893127 scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court has explicitly recognized this, noting that the "vagueness of [the Sherman Act's] language" left it to the courts to give "content to the statute. 310 U.S. 469
    • The Supreme Court has explicitly recognized this, noting that the "vagueness of [the Sherman Act's] language" left it to the courts to give "content to the statute." Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, 310 U.S. 469, 489 (1940).
    • (1940) Apex Hosiery Co. V. Leader , pp. 489
  • 50
    • 77950642802 scopus 로고
    • F.2d 416, 428-29 2d Cir. (describing the "helplessness of the individual" before "great aggregations of capital" as an object of concern for antitrust)
    • See United States v. Aluminum Co. of America (Alcoa), 148 F.2d 416, 428-29 (2d Cir. 1945) (describing the "helplessness of the individual" before "great aggregations of capital" as an object of concern for antitrust).
    • (1945) United States V. Aluminum Co. of America (Alcoa) , pp. 148
  • 51
    • 0345335559 scopus 로고
    • Toward a three-dimensional antitrust policy
    • 422-23
    • See Harlan M. Blake & William K. Jones, Toward a Three-Dimensional Antitrust Policy, 65 COLUM. L. REV. 422, 422-23 (1965);
    • (1965) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.65 , pp. 422
    • Blake, H.M.1    Jones, W.K.2
  • 52
    • 0002349749 scopus 로고
    • The politica content of antitrust
    • 1053-57
    • see also Robert Pitofsky, The Politica Content of Antitrust, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 1051, 1053-57 (1979).
    • (1979) U. PA. L. Rev. , vol.127 , pp. 1051
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 53
    • 78049312275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rules versus standards in antitrust adjudication
    • 102-03 (noting that "[a]ntitrust opposition to mergers, collaborative restraints of trade, and exclusionary practices reached its zenith under the Warren Court's rule-based approach which restricted concentrations of industrial power and favored non-economic values and small business interests")
    • See Daniel A. Crane, Rules Versus Standards in Antitrust Adjudication, 64 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 49, 102-03 (2007) (noting that "[a]ntitrust opposition to mergers, collaborative restraints of trade, and exclusionary practices reached its zenith under the Warren Court's rule-based approach which restricted concentrations of industrial power and favored non-economic values and small business interests");
    • (2007) Wash. & Lee L. Rev. , vol.64 , pp. 49
    • Crane, D.A.1
  • 54
    • 70349205162 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The shifting sands of antitrust policy: Where it has been, where it is now, where it will be in its third century
    • 245
    • Robert A. Skitol, The Shifting Sands of Antitrust Policy: Where It Has Been, Where It Is Now, Where It Will Be in its Third Century, 9 CORNELL J.L. PUB. POL'Y 239, 245 (1999).
    • (1999) Cornell J.L. Pub. Pol'y , vol.9 , pp. 239
    • Skitol, R.A.1
  • 55
    • 78049237724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 428-29
    • Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 428-29.
  • 56
    • 78049291372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id
    • See id.
  • 58
    • 78049306558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 61
    • 78049254431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 62
    • 84874841334 scopus 로고
    • 394 U.S. 495, 503 (holding that tieins "generally serve no legitimate business purpose that cannot be achieved in some less restrictive way")
    • See Fortner Enters, v. U.S. Steel Corp., 394 U.S. 495, 503 (1969) (holding that tieins "generally serve no legitimate business purpose that cannot be achieved in some less restrictive way").
    • (1969) Fortner Enters, V. U.S. Steel Corp.
  • 64
    • 31344439723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why do firms bundle and tie? Evidence from competitive markets and implications for tying law
    • 38-39
    • See David S. Evans & Michael Salinger, Why Do Firms Bundle and Tie? Evidence from Competitive Markets and Implications for Tying Law, 22 YALE J. ON REG. 37, 38-39 (2005).
    • (2005) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.22 , pp. 37
    • Evans, D.S.1    Salinger, M.2
  • 68
    • 78049280984 scopus 로고
    • 390 U.S. 145, 153
    • See Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145, 153 (1968).
    • (1968) Albrecht V. Herald Co.
  • 69
    • 39049161358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From post-chicago antitrust to resource-advantage competition
    • 126-27
    • See Christopher M. Grengs, Verizon v. Tririko: From Post-Chicago Antitrust to Resource-Advantage Competition, 2 J.L. ECON. & POL'Y 105, 126-27 (2006);
    • (2006) J.L. Econ. & Pol'y , vol.2 , pp. 105
    • Grengs, C.M.1    Tririko, V.V.2
  • 70
    • 70350458216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Improving the economic foundations of competition policy
    • 9-10
    • Timothy J. Muris, Improving the Economic Foundations of Competition Policy, 12 GEO. MASON L. REV. 1, 9-10 (2003).
    • (2003) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.12 , pp. 1
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 71
    • 78049275375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Muris, supra note 43
    • Muris, supra note 43.
  • 73
    • 78049272787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The market as instrument: A response to professor harrison
    • 1721-23
    • See Shubha Ghosh, The Market as Instrument: A Response to Professor Harrison, 52 SMU L. REV. 1717, 1721-23 (1999);
    • (1999) Smu L. Rev. , vol.52 , pp. 1717
    • Ghosh, S.1
  • 74
    • 0039027645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust policy: A century of economic and legal thinking
    • 52
    • William E. Kovacic & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal Thinking, 14 J. ECON. PERSP. 43, 52 (2000).
    • (2000) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.14 , pp. 43
    • Kovacic, W.E.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 76
    • 78049234172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 77
    • 0012072114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The language of law and the language of business
    • 297 (describing the rise of the Structure-ConductPerformance paradigm in antitrust enforcement)
    • See Spencer Weber Waller, The Language of Law and the Language of Business, 52 CASE W. RES. L. REV. 283, 297 (2001) (describing the rise of the Structure-ConductPerformance paradigm in antitrust enforcement).
    • (2001) Case W. Res. L. Rev. , vol.52 , pp. 283
    • Waller, S.W.1
  • 80
    • 54849441715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The class action fairness act in perspective: The old and the new in federal jurisdiction reform
    • 1916-17
    • See Edward A. Purcell Jr., The Class Action Fairness Act in Perspective: The Old and the New in Federal Jurisdiction Reform, 156 U. PA. L. REV. 1823, 1916-17 (2007)
    • (2007) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.156 , pp. 1823
    • Purcell Jr., E.A.1
  • 81
    • 78049284838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ("Milton Friedman attributed the recent dominance of the 'Chicago school' to the economic crises of the 1970s and early 1980s and to the subsequent collapse of Communism and the Soviet Union. It wasn't my talking that caused people to embrace these ideas, just as the rooster doesn't make the sun rise, [Friedman] explained. 'Collectivism was an impossible way to run an economy. What has brought about the change is reality, fact-and what Marx called the inevitable forces of history.'" (citations omitted));
  • 83
    • 78049307520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner, supra note 3, at 925-33
    • See Posner, supra note 3, at 925-33.
  • 84
    • 78049283320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 35, at 261
    • See POSNER, supra note 35, at 261;
  • 85
    • 78049231836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bork, supra note 16, at 9
    • Bork, supra note 16, at 9;
  • 86
    • 0039202359 scopus 로고
    • The crisis in antitrust
    • 375-76
    • Robert H. Bork & Ward S. Bowman, Jr., The Crisis in Antitrust, 65 COLUM. L. REV. 363, 375-76 (1965).
    • (1965) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.65 , pp. 363
    • Bork, R.H.1    Bowman Jr., W.S.2
  • 87
    • 78049302580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner, supra note 3, at 926-28
    • See Posner, supra note 3, at 926-28.
  • 89
    • 70349096585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Intellectual DNA of modern U.S. Competition law for dominant firm conduct: The Chicago/Harvard double helix
    • The latter occupies a distinct position, and assumed a role of transformational importance in causing U.S. antitrust law to evolve beyond the Warren Court jurisprudence
    • At this juncture, it is crucial to draw a distinction between the "Chicago School" -broadly defined, but referring in particular to macroeconomic policy-and the approach to competition policy dictated by both that School and the post-Chicago literature. See William E. Kovacic, The Intellectual DNA of Modern U.S. Competition Law for Dominant Firm Conduct: The Chicago/Harvard Double Helix, 2007 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1, 21-29. The latter occupies a distinct position, and assumed a role of transformational importance in causing U.S. antitrust law to evolve beyond the Warren Court jurisprudence.
    • (2007) Colum. Bus. L. Rev. , vol.1 , pp. 21-29
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 90
    • 65349191996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Should the government prosecute monopolies?
    • 506-07
    • See, e.g., Maurice E. Stucke, Should the Government Prosecute Monopolies?, 2009 U. III. L. REV. 497, 506-07.
    • U. III. L. Rev. , vol.2009 , pp. 497
    • Stucke, M.E.1
  • 91
    • 0042648955 scopus 로고
    • Workable antitrust policy
    • (discussing the Workable Antitrust Policy School, which advocates a "profoundly skeptical program" that would consist of "little other than prosecuting plain vanilla cartels and mergers to monopoly")
    • See Frank H. Easterbrook, Workable Antitrust Policy, 84 MICH. L. REV. 1696, 1701 (1986) (discussing the Workable Antitrust Policy School, which advocates a "profoundly skeptical program" that would consist of "little other than prosecuting plain vanilla cartels and mergers to monopoly").
    • (1986) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 1696
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 92
    • 78049314107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 35, at 251
    • POSNER, supra note 35, at 251;
  • 93
    • 70349216141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keynote address: Vertical restrictions and fragile monopoly
    • 500 ("[E]ven the early versions of Chicago school thinking recognized that there could be cases in which single-firm abuses would give rise to a serious antitrust concern.")
    • see also Richard A. Posner, Keynote Address: Vertical Restrictions and "Fragile" Monopoly, 50 ANTITRUST BULL. 499, 500 (2005) ("[E]ven the early versions of Chicago school thinking recognized that there could be cases in which single-firm abuses would give rise to a serious antitrust concern.").
    • (2005) Antitrust Bull. , vol.50 , pp. 499
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 94
    • 78049293737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bork, supra note 16 (explaining these points in detail)
    • See Bork, supra note 16 (explaining these points in detail);
  • 95
    • 78049243964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner, supra note 3, at 925-33 (same)
    • Posner, supra note 3, at 925-33 (same).
  • 96
    • 78049232318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jacobs, supra note 21, at 240-50
    • See Jacobs, supra note 21, at 240-50.
  • 98
    • 78049268501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, supra note 3, at 278
    • See Hovenkamp, supra note 3, at 278;
  • 100
    • 21844490185 scopus 로고
    • Post-chicago economics: Economists, lawyers, judges, and enforcement officials in a less determinate theoretical world
    • 672
    • Lawrence A. Sullivan, Post-Chicago Economics: Economists, Lawyers, Judges, and Enforcement Officials in a Less Determinate Theoretical World, 63 ANTITRUST L.J. 669, 672 (1995).
    • (1995) Antitrust L.J. , vol.63 , pp. 669
    • Sullivan, L.A.1
  • 101
    • 78049280653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, supra note 3, at 258, 279
    • See Hovenkamp, supra note 3, at 258, 279;
  • 102
    • 0035730228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tying law and policy: A decision-theoretic approach
    • 497 ("[T]he post-Chicago literature arose in response to the Chicago School's implication that tying should be legal per se. The post-Chicago models indicate that tying can be anticompetitive, not that it must be anticompetitive or that it is likely to be anticompetitive. Indeed, the models cannot tell us even that anticompetitive tying is more than a remote possibility.")
    • Keith N. Hylton & Michael Salinger, Tying Law and Policy: A Decision-Theoretic Approach, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 469, 497 ("[T]he post-Chicago literature arose in response to the Chicago School's implication that tying should be legal per se. The post-Chicago models indicate that tying can be anticompetitive, not that it must be anticompetitive or that it is likely to be anticompetitive. Indeed, the models cannot tell us even that anticompetitive tying is more than a remote possibility.").
    • Antitrust L.J. , vol.69 , pp. 469
    • Hylton, K.N.1    Salinger, M.2
  • 103
    • 78049239040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jacobs, supra note 21, at 219
    • See Jacobs, supra note 21, at 219.
  • 104
    • 78049259594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 35, at viii (characterizing the pre-Chicago School body of antitrust doctrine as an "intellectual disgrace")
    • See POSNER, supra note 35, at viii (characterizing the pre-Chicago School body of antitrust doctrine as an "intellectual disgrace").
  • 105
    • 78049253955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BORK, supra note 61, at 4
    • See BORK, supra note 61, at 4
  • 107
    • 78049315833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting BORK, supra note 61, at 66)
    • (quoting BORK, supra note 61, at 66);
  • 110
    • 78049308944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (overruling its 1911 Dr. Miles decision, which had held that vertical minimum price fixing is illegal per se)
    • (overruling its 1911 Dr. Miles decision, which had held that vertical minimum price fixing is illegal per se);
  • 111
    • 76649118378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 547 U.S. 28 (overruling presumption that patents confer market power for the purposes of the antitrust laws)
    • Tool Works, Inc. v. Indep. Ink, 547 U.S. 28 (2006) (overruling presumption that patents confer market power for the purposes of the antitrust laws);
    • (2006) Tool Works, Inc. V. Indep. Ink
  • 112
    • 31144458231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 522 U.S. 3 (overruling its 1968 Albrecht decision, which had held that vertical maximum price fixing was a per se antitrust violation)
    • State Oil Co. v. Kahn, 522 U.S. 3 (1997) (overruling its 1968 Albrecht decision, which had held that vertical maximum price fixing was a per se antitrust violation);
    • (1997) State Oil Co. V. Kahn
  • 113
    • 76649087907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 509 U.S. 209 (1993) (requiring that an antitrust plaintiff who alleges predatory pricing establish a dangerous probability of recoupment)
    • Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993) (requiring that an antitrust plaintiff who alleges predatory pricing establish a dangerous probability of recoupment);
    • Brooke Group Ltd. V. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp.
  • 114
    • 77952265193 scopus 로고
    • 433 U.S. (advocating the abandonment of per se rules that are inconsistent with prevailing economic theory and analyzing vertically-imposed nonprice constraints under the rule of reason)
    • Cont'l T. V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977) (advocating the abandonment of per se rules that are inconsistent with prevailing economic theory and analyzing vertically-imposed nonprice constraints under the rule of reason).
    • (1977) Cont'l T. V., Inc. V. GTE Sylvania Inc. , pp. 36
  • 115
    • 78049277904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 509 U.S. at 223
    • See Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 223.
    • Brooke Group
  • 116
    • 78049306095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weyerhaeuser's implications for future antitrust disputes
    • 352-53
    • See Nickolai G. Levin, Weyerhaeuser's Implications for Future Antitrust Disputes, 4 N.Y.U. J.L. &BUS. 343, 352-53 (2007).
    • (2007) N.Y.U. J.L. &Bus. , vol.4 , pp. 343
    • Levin, N.G.1
  • 117
    • 78049232798 scopus 로고
    • 51 F.3d 1421, 1433, 1444 n.15 9th Cir.
    • See Rebel Oil Co. v. Atl. Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1433, 1444 n.15 (9th Cir. 1995);
    • (1995) Rebel Oil Co. V. Atl. Richfield Co.
  • 119
    • 78049240553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, it is not possible to delineate politics and economics into two distinct and mutually exclusive disciplines. The teachings of each influence the other. Nevertheless, they are not coterminous. Fundamentally, price theory provides the policymaker with a means by which to ascertain the economic consequences, both positive and negative, of a particular course of action. That theory does not dictate a single right approach, however. Society can, and often does, pursue policies that are inconsistent with aggregate welfare. One need only think of minimum wage laws. Economics teaches that such laws will prevent certain labor markets from clearing at optimal levels, with ensuing deadweight loss. This loss takes the form of jobs that would have existed, but for the government policy. While those who receive jobs gain from these laws, economics predicts on the whole that workers are made worse off. Mindful of this theory, society nevertheless concludes that certain political factors-the belief that an individual's effort has to be worth at least a certain amount, the concern that employers may force wages to suboptimal levels due to the homogeneity of the workforce, and others-are of sufficient value that the laws are nonetheless justified. The case is no different with antitrust economics, which approximate the impact of challenged business conduct on allocative efficiency. An electorate can choose to adopt this measure of efficiency as its sole normative metric, or it can elect to take such efficiency into account as a relevant factor amongst several.
  • 120
    • 76649143667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The most dramatic example is the Supreme Court's decision in Trinko. There, the Court opined that [t]he opportunity to charge monopoly prices-at least for a short period-is what attracts 'business acumen' in the first place; it induces risk taking that produces innovation and economic growth. LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407
    • The most dramatic example is the Supreme Court's decision in Trinko. There, the Court opined that "[t]he opportunity to charge monopoly prices-at least for a short period-is what attracts 'business acumen' in the first place; it induces risk taking that produces innovation and economic growth." Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004).
    • (2004) Verizon Commc'ns Inc. V. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko
  • 121
    • 78049268999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The future of the net-comments on lawrence lessig's code and other laws of cyberspace and the future of ideas
    • 293
    • See Reed Hundt, The Future of the Net-Comments on Lawrence Lessig's Code and Other Laws of Cyberspace and The Future of Ideas, 68 BROOK. L. REV. 289, 293 (2002).
    • (2002) Brook. L. Rev. , vol.68 , pp. 289
    • Hundt, R.1
  • 122
    • 0345984391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The economics of improvement in intellectual property law
    • 994-95
    • See Mark A. Lemley, The Economics of Improvement in Intellectual Property Law, 75 TEX. L. REV. 989, 994-95 (1997);
    • (1997) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 989
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 123
    • 0035579072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust in the new economy
    • 930
    • Richard A. Posner, Antitrust in the New Economy, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 925, 930 (2001).
    • (2001) Antitrust L.J. , vol.68 , pp. 925
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 124
    • 78049291830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barnett, supra note 21, at 865
    • See Barnett, supra note 21, at 865.
  • 125
    • 78049256815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id
    • See id.
  • 126
    • 78049319388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407
    • See Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407.
  • 128
    • 78049262502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How obama could prevent firms from becoming too big to fail
    • Apr. 26 32
    • Illustratively, Albert Foer, president of the American Antitrust Institute, has opined that the crisis will cause the public mood to shift "from worship of big corporations to skepticism of the role they play." David R. Francis, How Obama could prevent firms from becoming 'too big to fail', CHRISTIAN SCI. MONITOR, Apr. 26 2009, at 32.
    • (2009) Christian Sci. Monitor
    • Francis, D.R.1
  • 129
    • 78049312274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 11
    • See supra note 11.
  • 130
    • 78049297480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • infra Part II.B
    • See infra Part II.B.
  • 131
    • 78049302579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 453 F.3d 1244 1258 10th Cir.
    • Tal v. Hogan, 453 F.3d 1244 1258 (10th Cir. 2006).
    • (2006) Tal V. Hogan
  • 132
    • 78049266779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an example of a position that would not be appropriate in current market conditions
    • For an example of a position that would not be appropriate in current market conditions,
  • 133
    • 78049239950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, GE-Honeywell: The U.S. Decision, Remarks Before the Antitrust Law Section, State Bar of Georgia 8 Nov. 29, (opining that the capital requirements for entry into a market should not be construed as an entry barrier because "[c]apital markets generally work very efficiently and there is no obvious reason... why [an incumbent's] cost of capital for a particular project should be any lower than that of its rivals")
    • see Deborah Platt Majoras, Deputy Ass't Att'y Gen., Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, GE-Honeywell: The U.S. Decision, Remarks Before the Antitrust Law Section, State Bar of Georgia 8 (Nov. 29, 2001) (opining that the capital requirements for entry into a market should not be construed as an entry barrier because "[c]apital markets generally work very efficiently and there is no obvious reason... why [an incumbent's] cost of capital for a particular project should be any lower than that of its rivals").
    • (2001) Deputy Ass't Att'y Gen.
    • Majoras, D.P.1
  • 134
    • 78049260991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT (2008) [hereinafter COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY]
    • U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT (2008) [hereinafter COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY].
  • 135
    • 70449723350 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Administration plans to strengthen antitrust rules
    • May 11, Al. One questioning the existence of this controversy need merely read the FTC's reaction to the report
    • See Stephen Labaton, Administration Plans to Strengthen Antitrust Rules, N.Y. TIMES, May 11, 2009, at Al. One questioning the existence of this controversy need merely read the FTC's reaction to the report.
    • (2009) N.Y. Times
    • Labaton, S.1
  • 136
    • 70349214510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm., FTC Commissioners React to Department of Justice Report, Sept. 8
    • See Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm., FTC Commissioners React to Department of Justice Report, "Competition and Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act" (Sept. 8, 2008), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2008/09/section2.shtm.
    • (2008) Competition and Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct under Section 2 of the Sherman Act
  • 137
    • 78049281897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Puzzanghera, supra note 12.
    • See Puzzanghera, supra note 12.
  • 138
    • 78049314106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This Part is intentionally concise because an exhaustive treatment of Chicago's influence on macroeconomic and regulatory policy would demand a book in itself. The purpose here is to provide the reader with sufficient knowledge about the School's broader role in the deregulatory movement that swept across some Western economies from the 1980s on
    • This Part is intentionally concise because an exhaustive treatment of Chicago's influence on macroeconomic and regulatory policy would demand a book in itself. The purpose here is to provide the reader with sufficient knowledge about the School's broader role in the deregulatory movement that swept across some Western economies from the 1980s on.
  • 139
    • 78049258306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kovacic, supra note 55, at 25 n.71 (quoting various authorities for the proposition that Ronald Regan's acceptance of Chicago School theories informed the deregulatory movement in the 1980s)
    • See Kovacic, supra note 55, at 25 n.71 (quoting various authorities for the proposition that Ronald Regan's acceptance of Chicago School theories informed the deregulatory movement in the 1980s).
  • 140
    • 78049256343 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An exception to the Chicago School's free-market approach lay in its promotion of government-controlled monetary policy. Milton Friedman's revolutionary work on monetarism, which rejected the prevailing Keynesian and post-Keynesian theories of the day to focus on money supply, grew in influence throughout the 1970s. The body of thought, perhaps best summarized by the conclusion that "inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon," typically regarded markets as inherently stable. As a result, monetarist thought concludes that governments need merely control the money supply and need not employ the fiscal policies associated with Keynes. Alan Greenspan, Chairman of the Federal Reserve from 1987 to 2006, largely adhered to monetarist policy.
  • 141
    • 0346333562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unnatural competition?: Applying the new antitrust learning to foster competition in the local exchange
    • 1485-86 (observing that "[t]he impact of the Chicago School on regulatory policy is less obvious than on antitrust policy, but is almost certainly reflected in the massive wave of deregulation and unbundling that has swept through regulated industries in the past two decades")
    • See Ashutosh Bhagwat, Unnatural Competition?: Applying the New Antitrust Learning to Foster Competition in the Local Exchange, 50 HASTINGS L.J. 1479, 1485-86 (1999) (observing that "[t]he impact of the Chicago School on regulatory policy is less obvious than on antitrust policy, but is almost certainly reflected in the massive wave of deregulation and unbundling that has swept through regulated industries in the past two decades").
    • (1999) Hastings L.J. , vol.50 , pp. 1479
    • Bhagwat, A.1
  • 143
    • 78049252332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The effects of deregulation on competition: The experience of the united states
    • S12
    • See Richard A. Posner, The Effects of Deregulation on Competition: The Experience of the United States, 23 FORDHAM INT'L L.J. S7, S12 (2000);
    • (2000) Fordham Int'l L.J. , vol.23
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 144
    • 0000048140 scopus 로고
    • Natural monopoly and its regulation
    • 548
    • Richard A. Posner, Natural Monopoly and Its Regulation, 21 STAN. L. REV. 548, 548 (1969).
    • (1969) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.21 , pp. 548
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 146
    • 0039818696 scopus 로고
    • Local broadband networks: A new regulatory philosophy
    • 114
    • See James Walter Grudus, Local Broadband Networks: A New Regulatory Philosophy, 10 YALE J. ON REG. 89, 114 (1993);
    • (1993) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.10 , pp. 89
    • Grudus, J.W.1
  • 148
    • 78049278340 scopus 로고
    • A price-level (incentive) regulation proposal for oil pipelines
    • 417 (noting that "the failure of traditional cost-of-service regulation to achieve its primary objective-the replication of competitive results in terms of return levels, resource utilization, and efficiencies-is dramatic and well documented")
    • Win Whittaker, A Price-Level (Incentive) Regulation Proposal for Oil Pipelines, 46 OKLA. L. REV. 415, 417 (1993) (noting that "the failure of traditional cost-of-service regulation to achieve its primary objective-the replication of competitive results in terms of return levels, resource utilization, and efficiencies-is dramatic and well documented");
    • (1993) Okla. L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 415
    • Whittaker, W.1
  • 149
    • 84937179463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The takings clause and improvident regulatory bargains
    • 825
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The Takings Clause and Improvident Regulatory Bargains, 108 YALE L.J. 801, 825 (1999)
    • (1999) Yale L.J. , vol.108 , pp. 801
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 151
    • 78049320309 scopus 로고
    • Policy and rules concerning rates for dominant carriers
    • 2878 F.C.C
    • See In re Policy and Rules Concerning Rates for Dominant Carriers, 4 F.C.C.R. 2873, 2878 (F.C.C. 1989).
    • (1989) F.C.C.R. , vol.4 , pp. 2873
  • 152
    • 26044475279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deregulatory takings and breach of regulatory contract: A comment
    • What little incentive such a regulated entity may have to limit costs emanates from the phenomenon of regulatory lag. See 1001
    • What little incentive such a regulated entity may have to limit costs emanates from the phenomenon of regulatory lag. See Stephen F. Williams, Deregulatory Takings and Breach of Regulatory Contract: A Comment, 71 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1000, 1001 (1996).
    • (1996) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 1000
    • Williams, S.F.1
  • 153
    • 0001403985 scopus 로고
    • Current issues in telecommunications regulation: Pricing
    • 227 n.87, 240
    • See Alfred E. Kahn & William B. Shew, Current Issues in Telecommunications Regulation: Pricing, 4 YALE J. ON REG. 191, 227 n.87, 240 (1987);
    • (1987) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.4 , pp. 191
    • Kahn, A.E.1    Shew, W.B.2
  • 154
    • 33749607141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cap-sized: How the promise of the price cap voyage to competition was lost in a sea of good intentions
    • 360-61
    • Gregory J. Vogt, Cap-Sized: How the Promise of the Price Cap Voyage to Competition Was Lost in a Sea of Good Intentions, 51 FED. COMM. L.J. 349, 360-61 (1999).
    • (1999) Fed. Comm. L.J. , vol.51 , pp. 349
    • Vogt, G.J.1
  • 155
    • 0001621862 scopus 로고
    • Effects of the change from rate-ofreturn to price-cap regulation
    • 193
    • See Ronald R. Braeutigam & John C. Panzar, Effects of the Change from Rate-OfReturn to Price-Cap Regulation, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 191, 193 (1993).
    • (1993) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 191
    • Braeutigam, R.R.1    Panzar, J.C.2
  • 156
    • 0033420578 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Setting the x factor in price-cap regulation plans
    • 5-6
    • See Jeffrey I. Bernstein & David E.M. Sappington, Setting the X Factor in Price-Cap Regulation Plans, 16 J. REG. ECON. 5, 5-6 (1999).
    • (1999) J. Reg. Econ. , vol.16 , pp. 5
    • Bernstein, J.I.1    Sappington, D.E.M.2
  • 157
    • 78049251833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The nature of the public utility: Infrastructure, the market, and the law
    • (reviewing JOSÉ A. GÓMEZ-IBÁÑEZ, REGULATING INFRASTRUCTURE: MONOPOLY, CONTRACTS, AND DISCRETION (2003))
    • See Jim Chen, The Nature of the Public Utility: Infrastructure, the Market, and the Law, 98 Nw. U. L. REV. 1617, 1672 (2004) (reviewing JOSÉ A. GÓMEZ-IBÁÑEZ, REGULATING INFRASTRUCTURE: MONOPOLY, CONTRACTS, AND DISCRETION (2003)).
    • (2004) 98 Nw. U. L. REV. , vol.1617 , pp. 1672
    • Chen, J.1
  • 159
    • 33750030004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Costs and consequences of federal telecommunications regulations
    • 42-43
    • See Jerry Eilig, Costs and Consequences of Federal Telecommunications Regulations, 58 FED. COMM. L.J. 37, 42-43 (2006);
    • (2006) Fed. Comm. L.J. , vol.58 , pp. 37
    • Eilig, J.1
  • 160
    • 27844473775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The concurrent application of competition law and regulation: The case of margin squeeze abuses in the telecommunications sector
    • Damien Geradin & Robert O'Donoghue, The Concurrent Application of Competition Law and Regulation: The Case of Margin Squeeze Abuses in the Telecommunications Sector, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 355, 377 (2005).
    • (2005) 1 J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.355 , pp. 377
    • Geradin, D.1    O'Donoghue, R.2
  • 161
    • 78049287234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vogt, supra note 97, at 360-61
    • See Vogt, supra note 97, at 360-61.
  • 162
    • 70350393443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adjusting regulation to competition: Toward a new model for U.S. telecommunications policy
    • 80
    • Howard A. Shelanski, Adjusting Regulation to Competition: Toward a New Model for U.S. Telecommunications Policy, 24 YALE J. ON REG. 55, 80 (2007).
    • (2007) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.24 , pp. 55
    • Shelanski, H.A.1
  • 163
    • 78049320800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 22, at 89
    • See CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 22, at 89.
  • 164
    • 36248998439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market definition: Use and abuse
    • See Dennis W. Carlton, Market Definition: Use and Abuse, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 1, 7 (2007);
    • (2007) 3 Competition Pol'y Int'l , vol.1 , pp. 7
    • Carlton, D.W.1
  • 165
    • 0032363324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Testing static oligopoly models: Conduct and cost in the sugar industry, 1890-1914
    • 355
    • David Genesove & Wallace P. Mullin, Testing Static Oligopoly Models: Conduct and Cost in the Sugar Industry, 1890-1914, 29 RAND. J. ECON. 355, 355 (1998).
    • (1998) Rand. J. Econ. , vol.29 , pp. 355
    • Genesove, D.1    Mullin, W.P.2
  • 166
    • 78049306094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • F.3d 1109, 10th Cir.
    • See, e.g., United States v. AMR Corp., 335 F.3d 1109, 1116 (10th Cir. 2003);
    • (2003) United States V. AMR Corp. , vol.335 , pp. 1116
  • 168
    • 33748440349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition policy in the new economy
    • See Lawrence H. Summers, Competition Policy in the New Economy, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 353, 355-56 (2001).
    • (2001) 69 Antitrust L.J. , vol.353 , pp. 355-356
    • Summers, L.H.1
  • 169
    • 78049312722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • More controversially, the Chicago School also alleged the existence of a phenomenon it labeled regulatory capture, which described regulators' tendency to become influenced by, and ultimately serve the interests of, those they sought to constrain
    • More controversially, the Chicago School also alleged the existence of a phenomenon it labeled "regulatory capture," which described regulators' tendency to become influenced by, and ultimately serve the interests of, those they sought to constrain.
  • 170
    • 0001618495 scopus 로고
    • A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence
    • See Gary S. Becker, A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence, 98 Q. J. ECON. 371 (1983);
    • (1983) Q. J. Econ. , vol.98 , pp. 371
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 171
    • 0000420789 scopus 로고
    • Toward a More General Theory of Regulation
    • Sam Peltzman, Toward a More General Theory of Regulation, 19 J.L. & ECON. 211 (1976);
    • (1976) 19 J.L. & ECON. , vol.211
    • Peltzman, S.1
  • 173
    • 0001849038 scopus 로고
    • Why regulate utilities?
    • See Harold Demsetz, Why Regulate Utilities?, 11 J.L. & ECON. 55 (1968);
    • (1968) 11 J.L. & ECON. , vol.55
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 174
    • 0002369647 scopus 로고
    • Taxation by regulation
    • Observing that "many regulated industries are not monopolistic in structure
    • Richard A. Posner, Taxation by Regulation, 2 BELL J. ECON. & MGMT. Sci. 22, 38 (1971) (observing that "many regulated industries are not monopolistic in structure");
    • (1971) 2 BELL J. ECON. & MGMT. Sci. , vol.22 , pp. 38
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 175
    • 0002734011 scopus 로고
    • The economics of information
    • George J. Stigler, The Economics of Information, 69 J. POL. ECON. 213 (1961);
    • (1961) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.69 , pp. 213
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 176
    • 0001650452 scopus 로고
    • Public regulation of the securities markets
    • George J. Stigler, Public Regulation of the Securities Markets, 19 Bus. LAW. 721, 721 (1964);
    • (1964) 19 Bus. LAW. , vol.721 , pp. 721
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 177
    • 0001810299 scopus 로고
    • What can regulators regulate? The case of electricity
    • George J. Stigler & Clair Friedland, What Can Regulators Regulate? The Case of Electricity, 5 J.L. &ECON. 1 (1962).
    • (1962) 5 J.L. &ECON. , vol.1
    • Stigler, G.J.1    Friedland, C.2
  • 178
    • 78049281896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PIERCE & GELLHORN, supra note 92, at 343-44; Hovenkamp, supra note 95, at 825
    • See PIERCE & GELLHORN, supra note 92, at 343-44; Hovenkamp, supra note 95, at 825.
  • 179
    • 78049306091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Will access regulation work?
    • 38
    • See Gerald R. Faulhaber, Will Access Regulation Work?, 61 FED. COMM. L.J. 37, 38 (2008).
    • (2008) Fed. Comm. L.J. , vol.61 , pp. 37
    • Faulhaber, G.R.1
  • 180
    • 78049264369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PIERCE & GELLHORN, supra note 92, at 343-78
    • See PIERCE & GELLHORN, supra note 92, at 343-78;
  • 181
    • 78049242478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posting of Gary Becker to The Becker-Posner Blog, Apr. 28, 19:37 EDT
    • Posting of Gary Becker to The Becker-Posner Blog, Greater Regulation of Financial Markets?, http://www.becker-posner-blog.com/ (Apr. 28, 2008, 19:37 EDT).
    • (2008) Greater Regulation of Financial Markets
  • 182
    • 78049302108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The results were largely satisfactory, even if all were not convinced. Even before the onset of the current crisis, which itself strongly suggests that unbridled deregulation can produce far from desirable results, some were skeptical of the curative powers of deregulation
    • The results were largely satisfactory, even if all were not convinced. Even before the onset of the current crisis, which itself strongly suggests that unbridled deregulation can produce far from desirable results, some were skeptical of the curative powers of deregulation.
  • 183
    • 0040239393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The folklore of deregulation (with apologies to thurman arnold)
    • See, e.g., Richard D. Cudahy, The Folklore of Deregulation (with Apologies to Thurman Arnold), 15 YALE J. ON REG. 427 (1998).
    • (1998) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.15 , pp. 427
    • Cudahy, R.D.1
  • 185
    • 78049271826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commissioner, Fed. Trade Comm'n, Remarks to the New York Bar Association Annual Dinner: Implications of the Financial Meltdown for the FTC 2 Jan. 29
    • J. Thomas Rosch, Commissioner, Fed. Trade Comm'n, Remarks to the New York Bar Association Annual Dinner: Implications of the Financial Meltdown for the FTC 2 (Jan. 29, 2009), available at www2.ftc.gov/speeches/rosch/ 090129financialcrisisnybarspeech.pdf.
    • (2009)
    • Thomas Rosch, J.1
  • 186
    • 78049235139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PITOFSKY, supra note 62, at 7 (discussing various economists' growing "unease" with Chicago School analysis)
    • See PITOFSKY, supra note 62, at 7 (discussing various economists' growing "unease" with Chicago School analysis).
  • 187
    • 62949096642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Greenspan concedes error on regulation
    • Oct. 24, For a consideration of the normative conclusions to be drawn from the recession, see infra Part II.B
    • Edmund L. Andrews, Greenspan Concedes Error on Regulation, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 24, 2008, at B1. 118. For a consideration of the normative conclusions to be drawn from the recession, see infra Part II.B.
    • (2008) N.Y. Times , vol.B1 , pp. 118
    • Andrews, E.L.1
  • 188
    • 78049236973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114 at vii
    • See POSNER, supra note 114 at vii.
  • 189
    • 78049265844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 31-34 (noting the vast increase in consumer debt and further observing that "in the years leading up to the current depression, the personal savings rate of Americans had plummeted")
    • See id. at 31-34 (noting the vast increase in consumer debt and further observing that "in the years leading up to the current depression, the personal savings rate of Americans had plummeted").
  • 190
    • 78049296993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at vii-xi
    • See id. at vii-xi.
  • 191
    • 78049311284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 66-68
    • See id. at 66-68.
  • 192
    • 78049300040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 68
    • See id. at 68.
  • 193
    • 78049239488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 209
    • See id. at 209.
  • 194
    • 78049260990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 133, 274 (characterizing the decision "to allow Lehman Brothers to slip into bankruptcy ... as the single biggest blunder to date in the response to the gathering storm")
    • See id. at 133, 274 (characterizing the decision "to allow Lehman Brothers to slip into bankruptcy ... as the single biggest blunder to date in the response to the gathering storm").
  • 195
    • 78049241992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What next?
    • Sept. 20, surveying the week's events, opining that "[i]t is no hyperbole to say that for an inkling of what is at stake, you have only to study the 1930s, and concluding that it had been a black week
    • See What Next?, ECONOMIST, Sept. 20, 2008, at 19-20 (surveying the week's events, opining that "[i]t is no hyperbole to say that for an inkling of what is at stake, you have only to study the 1930s," and concluding that it had been "a black week").
    • (2008) Economist , pp. 19-20
    • Andrews, E.L.1
  • 197
    • 78049310338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114 at 274
    • See POSNER, supra note 114 at 274;
  • 198
    • 62149149103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Accelerating downhill
    • Jan. 17
    • Accelerating Downhill, ECONOMIST, Jan. 17, 2009, at 13-14 129.
    • (2009) Economist , vol.129 , pp. 13-14
  • 199
    • 78049241040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114 at viii
    • See POSNER, supra note 114 at viii.
  • 200
    • 78049262936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I want your money
    • Sept. 27
    • See I Want Your Money, ECONOMIST, Sept. 27, 2008, at 17.
    • (2008) Economist , pp. 17
  • 201
    • 78049295602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • All you need is cash
    • Nov. 22
    • See All You Need Is Cash, ECONOMIST, Nov. 22, 2008, at 17.
    • (2008) Economist , pp. 17
  • 202
    • 73649098493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • World on the edge
    • Oct. 4
    • See World on the Edge, ECONOMIST, Oct. 4, 2008, at 11-12.
    • (2008) Economist , pp. 11-12
  • 203
    • 78049287233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114 at 275
    • See POSNER, supra note 114 at 275.
  • 204
    • 78049245394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The end of the affdr
    • Nov. 22
    • See The End of the Affdr, ECONOMIST, Nov. 22, 2008, at 39-40;
    • (2008) Economist , pp. 39-40
  • 205
    • 78049258304 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When the golden eggs run out
    • Dec. 6
    • When the Golden Eggs Run Out, ECONOMIST, Dec. 6, 2008, at 95-97.
    • (2008) Economist , pp. 95-97
  • 206
    • 84864222734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It's official: Recession since Dec'07
    • Dec. 1
    • See Chris Isidore, It's Official: Recession Since Dec'07, CNN MONEY.COM, Dec. 1, 2008, http://money.cnn.com/2008/12/01/news/economy/recession/index.htm.
    • (2008) CNN Money.com
    • Isidore, C.1
  • 207
    • 78049295148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where have all your savings gone?
    • Dec. 6
    • See Where Have All Your Savings Gone?, ECONOMIST, Dec. 6, 2008, at 13.
    • (2008) Economist , pp. 13
  • 208
    • 77649129007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Banks need more capital
    • Dec. 18
    • See Alan Greenspan, Banks Need More Capital, ECONOMIST, Dec. 18, 2008, at 122.
    • (2008) Economist , vol.122
    • Greenspan, A.1
  • 209
    • 78049271318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decoupling 2.0
    • May 23
    • See Decoupling 2.0, ECONOMIST, May 23, 2009, at 14
    • (2009) Economist , pp. 14
  • 210
    • 78049275807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iceland's government collapses
    • Jan. 27
    • See Judy Dempsey, Iceland's Government Collapses, N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 27, 2009, at A8;
    • (2009) N.Y. Times , vol.A8
    • Dempsey, J.1
  • 211
    • 78049320307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iceland is all but officially bankrupt
    • Oct. 9
    • Eric Pf anner, Iceland Is All But Officially Bankrupt, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 9, 2008, at B1.
    • (2008) N.Y. Times , vol.B1
    • Anner, E.P.1
  • 212
    • 78049272284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-343, 122 Stat. 3765
    • Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-343, 122 Stat. 3765.
  • 213
    • 78049269478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In fact, it was a solvency problem See POSNER, supra note 114 at 64-74
    • In fact, it was a solvency problem See POSNER, supra note 114 at 64-74
  • 214
    • 78049309895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, Pub. L. No. 111-5, 123 Stat. 115
    • American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, Pub. L. No. 111-5, 123 Stat. 115.
  • 215
    • 78049260069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recovery.gov, last visited Mar. 27
    • Recovery.gov, The Act, http://www.recovery.gov/About/Pages/The-Act.aspx (last visited Mar. 27, 2010).
    • (2010)
  • 216
    • 78049273252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Commerce, Jan. 29, reporting that GDP rose at an annual rate of 5.4% in the fourth quarter of 2009
    • See Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Commerce, Bureau of Econ. Analysis, Gross Domestic Product: Fourth Quarter 2009 (Jan. 29, 2010), available at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/gdp/gdpnewsrelease.htm (reporting that GDP rose at an annual rate of 5.4% in the fourth quarter of 2009);
    • (2010) Bureau of Econ. Analysis, Gross Domestic Product: Fourth Quarter 2009
  • 217
    • 78049302577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is the economy starting to recover? Or just less bad?
    • Mar. 26
    • see also Justin Fox, Is the Economy Starting to Recover? Or Just Less Bad?, TIME.COM, Mar. 26, 2009, http://www.time.com/time/business/article/0,8599, 188768400.html;
    • (2009) Time.com
    • Fox, J.1
  • 218
    • 78049294679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • World stocks rally on hopes for economic recovery
    • May 19
    • Carlo Piovano, World Stocks Rally on Hopes for Economic Recovery, ABCNEWS, May 19, 2009, http://abcnews.go.com/Business/wireStory?id=7620953.
    • (2009) Abcnews
    • Piovano, C.1
  • 219
    • 78049239949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federd reserve leaders see economic progress
    • May 21
    • See Annys Shin, Federd Reserve Leaders See Economic Progress, WASH. POST, May 21, 2009, at A15.
    • (2009) Wash. Post , vol.A15
    • Shin, A.1
  • 220
    • 78049274186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unemployment rate stays at 9.7%; 36k jobs lost
    • Mar. 5
    • See Patrice Hill Unemployment Rate Stays at 9.7%; 36K Jobs Lost, WASH. TIMES, Mar. 5, 2010, available at http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2010/mar/ 05/unemployment-held-steady-97-percent-february/.
    • (2010) Wash. Times
    • Hill, P.1
  • 221
    • 78049253517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • May 20, 2009, 9:59 EDT
    • Richard A. Posner, http://www.theatlantic.com/richard-a-posner (May 20, 2009, 9:59 EDT).
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 222
    • 78049305642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 223
    • 78049236038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114 at 273
    • see also POSNER, supra note 114 at 273.
  • 224
    • 78049272283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner, supra note 147
    • Posner, supra note 147.
  • 225
    • 78049278817 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although this Part seeks to provide a reasonably detailed explanation of how and why the economic crisis occurred, such that the reader can properly interpret the consequences of the global recession for macroeconomic and, more importantly for this Article, antitrust policy, a full and authoritative treatment of the subject would require space far in excess of what is feasible for an article. Readers who seek a more detailed treatment of the crisis should look to any of a number of excellent books.
  • 226
    • 78049303540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114
    • See, e.g., POSNER, supra note 114;
  • 229
    • 78049269477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Notably, some weaknesses are already being resolved. For example, the market for credit-default swaps has transformed itself in the short time since the onset of the crisis
    • Notably, some weaknesses are already being resolved. For example, the market for credit-default swaps has transformed itself in the short time since the onset of the crisis.
  • 230
    • 78049283318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Puzzanghera, supra note 12. 153. Id.
    • Puzzanghera, supra note 12. 153. Id.
  • 231
    • 78049318911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 232
    • 78049272785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brennan, supra note 18, at 147
    • See, e.g., Brennan, supra note 18, at 147;
  • 233
    • 0442313640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The monopolization offense
    • 1049
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The Monopolization Offense, 61 OHIO ST. L.J. 1035, 1049 (2000);
    • (2000) Ohio St. L.J. , vol.61 , pp. 1035
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 234
    • 78049276296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kauper, supra note 18, at 1870
    • Kauper, supra note 18, at 1870.
  • 235
    • 0004199595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FED. TRADE COMM'N & U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, §§3.0-3.4
    • See FED. TRADE COMM'N & U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES §§3.0-3.4 (1997).
    • (1997) Horizontal Merger Guidelines
  • 236
    • 78049285788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • F.3d 883, 9th Cir. One of the challenges of interpreting and enforcing the amorphous prohibitions of §§1 and 2 of the Sherman Act is ensuring that the antitrust laws do not punish economic behavior that benefits consumers and will not cause long-run injury to the competitive process
    • See Cascade Health Solutions v. PeaceHealth, 515 F.3d 883, 902-03 (9th Cir. 2008) ("One of the challenges of interpreting and enforcing the amorphous prohibitions of §§1 and 2 of the Sherman Act is ensuring that the antitrust laws do not punish economic behavior that benefits consumers and will not cause long-run injury to the competitive process.").
    • (2008) Cascade Health Solutions V. PeaceHealth , vol.515 , pp. 902-903
  • 238
    • 46049113694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The chicago school and exclusionary conduct
    • noting that "antitrust law and bankruptcy law go hand in hand
    • See Frank H. Easterbrook, The Chicago School and Exclusionary Conduct, 31 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 439, 440 (2008) (noting that "[antitrust law and bankruptcy law go hand in hand").
    • (2008) 31 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y , vol.439 , pp. 440
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 242
    • 84875128652 scopus 로고
    • Market power in antitrust cases
    • 959, The only exception relates to per se illegal conduct, such as naked price-fixing and market allocation
    • see also William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, Market Power in Antitrust Cases, 94 HARV. L. REV. 937, 959 (1981). The only exception relates to per se illegal conduct, such as naked price-fixing and market allocation.
    • (1981) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 937
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 243
    • 78049319841 scopus 로고
    • F.T.C. 669
    • In re Borden, Inc., 92 F.T.C. 669, 795 (1978).
    • (1978) In Re Borden, Inc. , vol.92 , pp. 795
  • 244
    • 78049231382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114 at 5-7
    • See POSNER, supra note 114 at 5-7.
  • 246
    • 78049256342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114 at 7-8
    • See POSNER, supra note 114 at 7-8.
  • 247
    • 78049232797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 248
    • 79959186974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The anatomy of the GE-honeywell disaster
    • July 8, quoting Treasury Secretary Paul O'Neill as denouncing the European Commission's veto of the GE-Honeywell merger for being "off the wall
    • See Michael Elliott, The Anatomy of the GE-Honeywell Disaster, TIME.COM, July 8, 2001, http://www.time.com/time/business/article/0,8599,166732-2,00.html (quoting Treasury Secretary Paul O'Neill as denouncing the European Commission's veto of the GE-Honeywell merger for being "off the wall");
    • (2001) Time.Com
    • Elliott, M.1
  • 249
    • 78049304711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Assistant Att'y. Gen. for Antitrust, Dep't of Justice, Sept. 17, criticizing a decision of the Court of First Instance of the European Communities, which affirmed a decision of the EC, because "rather than helping consumers, [it] may have the unfortunate consequence of harming consumers by chilling innovation and discouraging competition
    • Press Release, Thomas O. Barnett, Assistant Att'y. Gen. for Antitrust, Dep't of Justice, Statement on European Microsoft Decision (Sept. 17, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/press-releases/2007/226070.htm (criticizing a decision of the Court of First Instance of the European Communities, which affirmed a decision of the EC, because "rather than helping consumers, [it] may have the unfortunate consequence of harming consumers by chilling innovation and discouraging competition").
    • (2007) Statement on European Microsoft Decision
    • Barnett, T.O.1
  • 250
    • 78049241039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 35
    • See POSNER, supra note 35, at 9-32.
  • 252
    • 78049288578 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • generdly id. at 1
    • See generdly id. at 1;
  • 253
    • 78049258303 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 35
    • POSNER, supra note 35, at 136-40.
  • 254
    • 34548134852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collusive duopoly: The economic effects of the aloha and hawdian airlines' agreement to reduce capacity
    • In some circumstances, however, cartels will not have long-run anticompetitive effect, as the increase in price to supracompetitive levels will spur rapid entry 436
    • In some circumstances, however, cartels will not have long-run anticompetitive effect, as the increase in price to supracompetitive levels will spur rapid entry. See Roger D. Blair, James Mak & Carl Bonham, Collusive Duopoly: The Economic Effects of the Aloha and Hawdian Airlines' Agreement to Reduce Capacity, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 409, 436 (2007).
    • (2007) ANTITRUST L.J. , vol.74 , pp. 409
    • Blair, R.D.1    Mak, J.2    Bonham, C.3
  • 255
    • 78049244449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 35, at 136-40
    • See POSNER, supra note 35, at 136-40.
  • 256
    • 78049242477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Whitener, supra note 12; Puzzanghera, supra note 12
    • See Whitener, supra note 12; Puzzanghera, supra note 12.
  • 257
    • 77956840911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lessons from the great depression
    • 9
    • See John D. Harkrider, Lessons from the Great Depression, 23 ANTITRUST 6, 9 (2009).
    • (2009) Antitrust , vol.23 , pp. 6
    • Harkrider, J.D.1
  • 258
    • 78049316326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id.
    • See id.
  • 259
    • 54149119881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Evaluating market power with two-sided demand and preemptive offers to dissipate monopoly rent: Lessons for high-technology industries from the antitrust division's approvd of the xm-sirius satellite radio merger
    • One need merely observe the debate leading up to the XM-Sirius merger, which largely divided along party lines. For a discussion of the economics applicable to that merger
    • One need merely observe the debate leading up to the XM-Sirius merger, which largely divided along party lines. For a discussion of the economics applicable to that merger, see J. Gregory Sidak & Hal J. Singer, Evaluating Market Power with Two-Sided Demand and Preemptive Offers to Dissipate Monopoly Rent: Lessons for High-Technology Industries from the Antitrust Division's Approvd of the XM-Sirius Satellite Radio Merger, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 697 (2008).
    • (2008) 4 J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.697
    • Gregory Sidak, J.1    Singer, H.J.2
  • 260
    • 78049307517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 346 Days: With less than a year left in the Bush administration's tenure, some see an urgency to push through mergers in a pro-business climate
    • Democratic administrations are likely to be significantly tougher on merger enforcement than their Republican counterparts are. See Feb. 8
    • Democratic administrations are likely to be significantly tougher on merger enforcement than their Republican counterparts are. See Julie Johnsson et al., 346 Days: With less than a year left in the Bush administration's tenure, some see an urgency to push through mergers in a pro-business climate, CHI. TRIB., Feb. 8, 2008, at 1.
    • (2008) Chi. Trib. , vol.1
    • Johnsson, J.1
  • 261
    • 0001652957 scopus 로고
    • Economies as an antitrust defense: The welfare tradeoffs
    • Aggregate-welfare models place as much relevance on producer-side cost savings as they do on merger-specific consumers' benefits. Oliver Williamson famously demonstrated that output-restricting mergers, which increase prices for consumers, may be socially desirable if even a relatively small productive efficiency gain is achieved
    • Aggregate-welfare models place as much relevance on producer-side cost savings as they do on merger-specific consumers' benefits. Oliver Williamson famously demonstrated that output-restricting mergers, which increase prices for consumers, may be socially desirable if even a relatively small productive efficiency gain is achieved. See Oliver E. Williamson, Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Tradeoffs, 58 AM. ECON. REV. 18 (1968).
    • (1968) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.58 , pp. 18
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 262
    • 78049289057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At present, so-called Williamson mergers are not allowed in the United States. Debate on whether this prohibition is appropriate continues
    • At present, so-called "Williamson mergers" are not allowed in the United States. Debate on whether this prohibition is appropriate continues.
  • 263
    • 78049297477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reformulating antitrust rules to safeguard societa wealth
    • making the case for an aggregate-welfare approach to antitrust policy
    • See Alan Devlin & Bruno Peixoto, Reformulating Antitrust Rules to Safeguard Societa Wealth, 13 STAN. J.L. BUS. & FIN. 225, 231-32 (2007) (making the case for an aggregate-welfare approach to antitrust policy).
    • (2007) 13 STAN. J.L. BUS. & FIN. , vol.225 , pp. 231-232
    • Devlin, A.1    Peixoto, B.2
  • 264
    • 84878832081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The classic example is F. Supp.D.D.C
    • The classic example is FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066 (D.D.C. 1997).
    • (1997) FTC V. Staples, Inc. , vol.970 , pp. 1066
  • 265
    • 78049239485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 35, at 157-58 (explaining the econometric techniques employed in the case and concluding that "[e]conomic analysis of mergers had come of age"). These empirical tools have also been employed in consummated mergers to prove actual anticompetitive effects
    • See POSNER, supra note 35, at 157-58 (explaining the econometric techniques employed in the case and concluding that "[e]conomic analysis of mergers had come of age"). These empirical tools have also been employed in consummated mergers to prove actual anticompetitive effects.
  • 266
    • 78049255358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Evanston Nw. Healthcare Corp., F.T.C. No. 9315 (Aug. 6, 2007)
    • See In re Evanston Nw. Healthcare Corp., F.T.C. No. 9315 (Aug. 6, 2007).
  • 267
    • 78049311282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 18(2006)
    • See 15 U.S.C. § 18(2006).
  • 268
    • 78049260989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The feasibility, likelihood, and effect of post-merger entry arguably play the most important role in the merger assessment process after market definition
    • The feasibility, likelihood, and effect of post-merger entry arguably play the most important role in the merger assessment process after market definition.
  • 269
    • 0004199595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FED. TRADE COMM'N & U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, §§ 3.0-3.4
    • See FED. TRADE COMM'N & U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES §§ 3.0-3.4 (1997).
    • (1997) Horizontal Merger Guidelines
  • 270
    • 78049309894 scopus 로고
    • Indeed, U.S. courts have previously chastised the enforcement agencies for seeking to enjoin combinations when post-merger entry is likely. Perhaps the most important case under this heading is F.2d 9th Cir.
    • Indeed, U.S. courts have previously chastised the enforcement agencies for seeking to enjoin combinations when post-merger entry is likely. Perhaps the most important case under this heading is United States v. Syufy Enters., 903 F.2d 659 (9th Cir. 1990).
    • (1990) United States V. Syufy Enters. , vol.903 , pp. 659
  • 271
    • 78049252331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decoupling 2.0, supra note 138, at 14
    • See Decoupling 2.0, supra note 138, at 14;
  • 272
    • 78049280982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economists: Recession to end in 2009
    • May 27
    • Economists: Recession to End in 2009, CNN MONEY, May 27, 2009, http://money.cnn.com/2009/05/27/news/economy/NABE-recovery-outlook/index.htm
    • (2009) Cnn Money
  • 273
    • 78049241038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 35, at 115
    • See POSNER, supra note 35, at 115.
  • 274
    • 78049257340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, the U.S. Justice Department approved a controversial merger between General Electric and Honeywell that was subsequently blocked by the European Commission. The Commission was concerned, in part, by GE's large capital reserves, which GE-Honeywell would be able to use to fund its activities in various markets. GE-Honeywell's competitors, by contrast, would not have access to such funds. The Justice Department rejected this contention, reasoning that "[c]apital markets generally work very efficiently and there is no obvious reason, absent some clearly defined market imperfection, why GE's cost of capital for a particular project should be any lower than that of its rivals." Majoras, supra note 84, at 8. Such a conclusion might lie on shakier foundation were it reached in the present, credit-deprived economy.
  • 276
    • 78049305641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Evanston Nw. Healthcare Corp., F.T.C. No. 9315, 2007 WL 2286195 (Aug. 6, 2007) (noting that, in a consummated merger, "our analysis is a retrospective inquiry based on empirical evidence" of competitive effects)
    • See, e.g., Evanston Nw. Healthcare Corp., F.T.C. No. 9315, 2007 WL 2286195 (Aug. 6, 2007) (noting that, in a consummated merger, "our analysis is a retrospective inquiry based on empirical evidence" of competitive effects).
  • 278
    • 78049259161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 9
    • Id. at 9.
  • 280
    • 0042695957 scopus 로고
    • Competition and the electric utility industry: An evduation
    • 67-68
    • Douglas Gegax & Kenneth Nowotny, Competition and the Electric Utility Industry: An Evduation, 10 YALE J. ON REG. 63, 67-68 (1993).
    • (1993) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.10 , pp. 63
    • Gegax, D.1    Nowotny, K.2
  • 281
    • 34547112568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Prohibition of the Proposed Springer-Prosiebensat.l Merger: How much Economics in German Merger Control?
    • See, e.g., Oliver Budzinski & Katharina Wacker, The Prohibition of the Proposed Springer-Prosiebensat.l Merger: How much Economics in German Merger Control? 3 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 281, 286 (2007).
    • (2007) 3 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. , vol.281 , pp. 286
    • Budzinski, O.1    Wacker, K.2
  • 283
    • 78049303995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DAVIES &GREEN, supra note 186, at 16-17
    • See DAVIES &GREEN, supra note 186, at 16-17.
  • 284
    • 78049284348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Whitener, supra note 12; Puzzanghera, supra note 12
    • See Whitener, supra note 12; Puzzanghera, supra note 12.
  • 285
    • 78049244912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114 at ix. 194. As the Seventh Circuit classically explained, [n]o court has yet said that the accumulation and use of great power is unlawful per se
    • See POSNER, supra note 114 at ix. 194. As the Seventh Circuit classically explained, "[n]o court has yet said that the accumulation and use of great power is unlawful per se.
  • 287
    • 78049285322 scopus 로고
    • F.2d 263, 2d Cir. (distinguishing mere size from market power)
    • accord Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 274 (2d Cir. 1979) (distinguishing mere size from market power);
    • (1979) Accord Berkey Photo, Inc. V. Eastman Kodak Co. , vol.603 , pp. 274
  • 289
    • 78049291829 scopus 로고
    • F.2d 9th Cir. Mere size, nor continued exercise of lawful powers by even a monopolist, is not illegal
    • aff'd, 401 F.2d 182 (9th Cir. 1968) ("Mere size, nor continued exercise of lawful powers by even a monopolist, is not illegal....").
    • (1968) Aff'd , vol.401 , pp. 182
  • 291
    • 50349084850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abolishing the Price Squeeze as a Theory of Antitrust Liability
    • Alcoa, the landmark case that stood for the proposition that a company can violate the antitrust laws by monopolizing a market on the sole basis of efficiency, has been characterized as discredited, "defunct," and "no longer the law." quoting POSNER, supra note 35, at 103, 196, 250, 263
    • Alcoa, the landmark case that stood for the proposition that a company can violate the antitrust laws by monopolizing a market on the sole basis of efficiency, has been characterized as "discredited," "defunct," and "no longer the law." J. Gregory Sidak, Abolishing the Price Squeeze as a Theory of Antitrust Liability, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 279, 304 (2008) (quoting POSNER, supra note 35, at 103, 196, 250, 263).
    • (2008) 4 J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.279 , pp. 304
    • Gregory Sidak, J.1
  • 292
    • 78049255357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kolasky, supra note 14 at 533
    • See Kolasky, supra note 14 at 533.
  • 293
    • 78049262499 scopus 로고
    • Government enforcement policy of section 7 of the clayton act: Carte blanche for conglomerate mergers?
    • See generlly Joseph P. Bauer, Government Enforcement Policy of Section 7 of the Clayton Act: Carte Blanche for Conglomerate Mergers?, 71 CAL. L. REV. 348 (1983).
    • (1983) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 348
    • Bauer, J.P.1
  • 294
    • 78049315830 scopus 로고
    • Efficiency considerations in merger enforcement
    • n.101
    • See Alan A. Fisher & Robert H. Lande, Efficiency Considerations in Merger Enforcement, 71 CAL. L. REV. 1580, 1603 n.101 (1983);
    • (1983) 71 CAL. L. REV. , vol.1580 , pp. 1603
    • Fisher, A.A.1    Lande, R.H.2
  • 295
    • 5244250385 scopus 로고
    • Conglomerate mergers and section 7 of the clayton act
    • Donald F. Turner, Conglomerate Mergers and Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 78 HARV. L. REV. 1313, 1321-22 (1965).
    • (1965) 78 HARV. L. REV. , vol.1313 , pp. 1321-1322
    • Turner, D.F.1
  • 296
    • 78049248466 scopus 로고
    • Conglomerate mergers, allocative efficiency, and section 7 of the clayton act
    • See Edmund H. Mantell, Conglomerate Mergers, Allocative Efficiency, and Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 56 TEX. L. REV. 207, 208 (1978).
    • (1978) 56 TEX. L. REV. , vol.207 , pp. 208
    • Mantell, E.H.1
  • 297
    • 31844434765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A critique of professor church's report on the impact of vertical and conglomerate mergers on competition
    • Compare James Cooper, Luke Froeb, Daniel O'Brien & Michael Vita, A Critique of Professor Church's Report on the Impact of Vertical and Conglomerate Mergers on Competition, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 785 (2005),
    • (2005) 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. , vol.785
    • Cooper, J.1    Froeb, L.2    O'Brien, D.3    Vita, M.4
  • 298
    • 31844443590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The church report's analysis of verticd and conglomerate mergers: A reply to cooper, froeb, o'brien, and vita
    • with Jeffrey Church, The Church Report's Analysis of Verticd and Conglomerate Mergers: A Reply to Cooper, Froeb, O'Brien, and Vita, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 797 (2005).
    • (2005) 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. , vol.797
    • Church, J.1
  • 299
    • 78049273693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BORK, supra note 61, at 257; POSNER, supra note 35, at 131 n.30
    • See BORK, supra note 61, at 257; POSNER, supra note 35, at 131 n.30;
  • 300
    • 78049252762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent development, bridging the divide? the european court of first instance judgment in GE/honeywell
    • George Stephanov Georgiev, Recent Development, Bridging the Divide? The European Court of First Instance Judgment in GE/Honeywell, 31 YALE J. INT'L L. 518, 519 (2006).
    • (2006) 31 YALE J. INT'L L. , vol.518 , pp. 519
    • Georgiev, G.S.1
  • 301
    • 78049285787 scopus 로고
    • Conglomerate mergers and the antitrust laws
    • This includes the Warren Court era in the United States where antitrust largely reflected populist principles. For a contemporaneous articulation of the view at that time
    • This includes the Warren Court era in the United States where antitrust largely reflected populist principles. For a contemporaneous articulation of the view at that time, see Harlan M. Blake, Conglomerate Mergers and the Antitrust Laws, 73 COLUM. L. REV. 555, 586 (1973).
    • (1973) 73 COLUM. L. REV. , vol.555 , pp. 586
    • Blake, H.M.1
  • 302
    • 78049320306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nature vs. Nurture and Reaching the Age of Reason: The U.S.IE.U. Treatment of Transatlantic Mergers
    • See Ilene Knable Gotts et al., Nature vs. Nurture and Reaching the Age of Reason: The U.S.IE.U. Treatment of Transatlantic Mergers, 61 N.Y.U. ANN. SURV. AM. L. 453, 473-74 (2005).
    • (2005) 61 N.Y.U. ANN. SURV. AM. L. , vol.453 , pp. 473-474
    • Gotts, I.K.1
  • 304
    • 78049253516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jacobs, supra note 21, at 228; Herbert J. Hovenkamp, The Neal Report and the Crisis in Antitrust March
    • See Jacobs, supra note 21, at 228; Herbert J. Hovenkamp, The Neal Report and the Crisis in Antitrust (March 2009) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1348707.
    • (2009)
  • 306
    • 78049303054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • F.2d at
    • Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 430-32.
    • Alcoa , vol.148 , pp. 430-432
  • 307
    • 78049274874 scopus 로고
    • F.2d 659, 9th Cir. (citations omitted)
    • United States v. Syufy Enters., 903 F.2d 659, 668 (9th Cir. 1990) (citations omitted).
    • (1990) United States V. Syufy Enters. , vol.903 , pp. 668
  • 308
    • 84979188687 scopus 로고
    • The nature of the firm
    • (explaining that firms exist and grow in response to the transaction cost-savings made possible by internal production and coordination)
    • See Ronald H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 ECONOMICA 386, 388 (1937) (explaining that firms exist and grow in response to the transaction cost-savings made possible by internal production and coordination).
    • (1937) 4 ECONOMICA , vol.386 , pp. 388
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 309
    • 78049292283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 210. POSNER, supra note 35, at viii
    • 210. POSNER, supra note 35, at viii.
  • 310
    • 78049308943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 7366, 48 Stat. 162 (1933) (repealed 1999) (separating investment and commercial-banking activities)
    • Pub. L. No. 73-66, 48 Stat. 162 (1933) (repealed 1999) (separating investment and commercial-banking activities).
  • 311
    • 78049239948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decision theory is the branch of economics concerned with decision making under conditions of uncertainty. Uncertainty is to be distinguished from risk, which is quantifiable
    • Decision theory is the branch of economics concerned with decision making under conditions of uncertainty. Uncertainty is to be distinguished from risk, which is quantifiable.
  • 312
    • 78049280981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 35, at 60
    • See POSNER, supra note 35, at 60.
  • 313
    • 78049286284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Type I errors involve erroneous conclusions of anticompetitive conduct
    • Type I errors involve erroneous conclusions of anticompetitive conduct.
  • 314
    • 78049314619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Type II errors involve mistaken determinations that conduct is procompetitive
    • Type II errors involve mistaken determinations that conduct is procompetitive.
  • 315
    • 84934453628 scopus 로고
    • The limits of antitrust
    • See Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 3 (1984).
    • (1984) 63 TEX. L. REV. , vol.1 , pp. 3
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 316
    • 78049288577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY, supra note 85, at ix
    • COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY, supra note 85, at ix.
  • 317
    • 78049238194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Dep't of Justice, Justice Department Withdraws Report on Antitrust Monopoly Law: Antitrust Divisions to Apply More Rigorous Standard With Focus on the Impact of Exclusionary Conduct on Consumers (May 11, 2009), Commissioner Rosch has expressed a similar sentiment
    • Press Release, Dep't of Justice, Justice Department Withdraws Report on Antitrust Monopoly Law: Antitrust Divisions to Apply More Rigorous Standard With Focus on the Impact of Exclusionary Conduct on Consumers (May 11, 2009), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/press-releases/2009/245710.htm. Commissioner Rosch has expressed a similar sentiment.
  • 318
    • 78049288169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Whitener, supra note 12, at 40-41
    • See Whitener, supra note 12, at 40-41.
  • 319
    • 78049263909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114 at 82-85
    • See POSNER, supra note 114 at 82-85.
  • 320
    • 78049253029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Whitener, supra note 12, at 40-41
    • See Whitener, supra note 12, at 40-41.
  • 322
    • 0348246071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A behaviord approach to law and economics
    • Compare Christine Jolis, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, A Behaviord Approach to Law and Economics, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1471 (1998),
    • (1998) 50 STAN. L. REV. , vol.1471
    • Jolis, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Thaler, R.3
  • 323
    • 0347487318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rationd choice, behaviord economics, and the law
    • with Richard A. Posner, Rationd Choice, Behaviord Economics, and the Law, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1551 (1998).
    • (1998) 50 STAN. L. REV. , vol.1551
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 324
    • 78049276295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rationdity of preference construction (and the irrationdity of rational choice)
    • See Claire A. Hill, The Rationdity of Preference Construction (and the Irrationdity of Rational Choice), 9 MINN. J.L. Sci. &TECH. 689, 701-02 (2008).
    • (2008) 9 MINN. J.L. Sci. &TECH. , vol.689 , pp. 701-702
    • Hill, C.A.1
  • 325
    • 66749125340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Organizationd irrationality and corporate human rights violations
    • POSNER, supra note 35, at ix. But see Note
    • See POSNER, supra note 35, at ix. But see Note, Organizationd Irrationality and Corporate Human Rights Violations, 122 HARV. L. REV. 1931, 1932-33 (2009).
    • (2009) 122 HARV. L. REV. , vol.1931 , pp. 1932-1933
  • 326
    • 78049250374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 114 at 79
    • See POSNER, supra note 114 at 79.
  • 328
    • 70349095085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral economists at the gate: Antitrust in the twenty-first century
    • For an exception, see advocating the use of behavioral economics in market analysis
    • For an exception, see Maurice E. Stucke, Behavioral Economists at the Gate: Antitrust in the Twenty-First Century, 38 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 513, 525 (2006) (advocating the use of behavioral economics in market analysis).
    • (2006) 38 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. , vol.513 , pp. 525
    • Stucke, M.E.1
  • 329
    • 77649129007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic focus: Banks need more capital
    • Dec. 20
    • Alan Greenspan, Economic Focus: Banks Need More Capital, ECONOMIST, Dec. 20, 2008, at 122.
    • (2008) ECONOMIST , pp. 122
    • Greenspan, A.1
  • 330
    • 78049252763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. 229
    • See id. 229.
  • 331
    • 78049266293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Kolasky, supra note 14, at 537 ("In the U.S., we have very little confidence in the ability of regulators to make these judgments, which would necessarily involve predictions far out into the future. U.S. antitrust agencies believe, in the immortal words of my favorite golfer, Tin Cup McAvoy, that they need to 'be humble.' The agencies also have more confidence in the self-correcting nature of markets. This confidence is especially strong when the markets are populated by strong rivals and strong buyers, who will usually find ways to protect themselves from an aspiring monopolist. This strong belief in markets and humility in their predictive abilities lead U.S. authorities to be skeptical of claims by rivals that a merger will lead to their ultimate demise and to demand strong empirical proof before we will accept such claims." (footnotes omitted)).
  • 332
    • 73649129921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lessons from a Crisis
    • Oct. 4
    • See Lessons from a Crisis, ECONOMIST, Oct. 4 2008, at 55.
    • (2008) ECONOMIST , pp. 55
  • 333
    • 78049308469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.