메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 1, Issue 4, 2005, Pages 785-795

A critique of professor church's report on the impact of vertical and conglomerate mergers on competition

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 31844434765     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: 17446422     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhi025     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (4)

References (56)
  • 2
    • 33745613137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Report by EAGCP
    • Report by EAGCP, An Economic Approach to Article 82 (2005), http://europa.eu.int/comm/ competition/publications/studies/ eagcp_july_21_05.pdf.
    • (2005) An Economic Approach to Article 82
  • 3
    • 84858542556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Member of the European Commission in Charge of Competition Policy, Speech at Fordham Corporate Law Institute: (23 September)
    • Nellie Kroes, Member of the European Commission in Charge of Competition Policy, Speech at Fordham Corporate Law Institute: Preliminary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82 (23 September 2005), http://europa.eu.int/ rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/ 05/537.
    • (2005) Preliminary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82
    • Kroes, N.1
  • 4
    • 0004217626 scopus 로고
    • In this manner, Professor Church's report resembles (MIT Press)
    • In this manner, Professor Church's report resembles Jean Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization (MIT Press 1988).
    • (1988) The Theory of Industrial Organization
    • Tirole, J.1
  • 6
    • 31844432030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Strategic complements and substitutes are the "normal" cases for Bertrand and Cournot competition, respectively.
  • 7
    • 84959817179 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration and Market Foreclosure
    • The reviewed literature started with
    • The reviewed literature started with Michael A. Salinger, Vertical Integration and Market Foreclosure, 103 Q. J. Econ. 345 (1988),
    • (1988) Q. J. Econ. , vol.103 , pp. 345
    • Salinger, M.A.1
  • 8
    • 0030304038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration, Foreclosure, and Profits in the Presence of Double Marginalization
    • and includes
    • and includes Gerard Gaudet & Ngo Van Long, Vertical Integration, Foreclosure, and Profits in the Presence of Double Marginalization, 5 J. Econ. & Mgmt. Strategy 409 (1996);
    • (1996) J. Econ. & Mgmt. Strategy , vol.5 , pp. 409
    • Gaudet, G.1    Van Long, N.2
  • 9
    • 0000970379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical Market Participation
    • Alexander Schrader & Stephen Martin, Vertical Market Participation, 13 Rev. Indus. Org. 321 (1998);
    • (1998) Rev. Indus. Org. , vol.13 , pp. 321
    • Schrader, A.1    Martin, S.2
  • 10
    • 31844452310 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competitive Vertical Foreclosure
    • Richard S. Higgins, Competitive Vertical Foreclosure, 20 Managerial & Decision Econ. 229 (1999);
    • (1999) Managerial & Decision Econ. , vol.20 , pp. 229
    • Higgins, R.S.1
  • 11
    • 0034385704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical Foreclosure, Technological Choice, and Entry on the Intermediate Market
    • and Eric Avenel & Corinne Barlet, Vertical Foreclosure, Technological Choice, and Entry on the Intermediate Market, 9 J. Econ. & Mgmt. Strategy 211 (2000).
    • (2000) J. Econ. & Mgmt. Strategy , vol.9 , pp. 211
    • Avenel, E.1    Barlet, C.2
  • 15
    • 84959817179 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration and Market Foreclosure
    • The reviewed literature started with
    • Salinger, supra note 7.
    • (1988) Q. J. Econ. , vol.103 , pp. 345
    • Salinger, M.A.1
  • 16
    • 31844444803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Impact of Vertical and Conglomerate Mergers
    • Church, supra note 1, at viii.
    • (2004)
    • Church, J.1
  • 17
    • 84959817179 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration and Market Foreclosure
    • The price rivals pay for the input may rise or fall, e.g. If it falls, the effective input price paid by all downstream firms falls, and welfare necessarily rises. If the price charged rivals rises but not by much, welfare will still rise. Only if the price charged rivals rises by enough to offset the elimination of the double markup will welfare fall. The reviewed literature started with
    • The price rivals pay for the input may rise or fall, e.g. Salinger, supra note 7. If it falls, the effective input price paid by all downstream firms falls, and welfare necessarily rises. If the price charged rivals rises but not by much, welfare will still rise. Only if the price charged rivals rises by enough to offset the elimination of the double markup will welfare fall.
    • (1988) Q. J. Econ. , vol.103 , pp. 345
    • Salinger, M.A.1
  • 20
    • 84959817179 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration and Market Foreclosure
    • This discussion is somewhat out of place, as the model is about entry deterrence, whereas the other literature is static and ignores entry, e.g. The reviewed literature started with
    • This discussion is somewhat out of place, as the model is about entry deterrence, whereas the other literature is static and ignores entry, e.g. Salinger, supra note 7
    • (1988) Q. J. Econ. , vol.103 , pp. 345
    • Salinger, M.A.1
  • 22
    • 0002116896 scopus 로고
    • Comment: Is There New Thinking on Vertical Mergers?
    • David Reiffen & Michael G. Vita, Comment: Is There New Thinking on Vertical Mergers?, 63 Antitrust L. J. 917 (1995). Professor Church does not classify models by whether they are static or dynamic, although we believe that the distinction is important. The argument that prices will rise because competition is "softened" is very different from the argument that prices will rise because entry will be deterred. Further, in models of entry deterrence, the possibility of harm necessarily is more speculative than in static models, and for that reason should be given less weight against known benefits. In the analysis of horizontal mergers, for example, likely short-run losses from either unilateral or coordinated effects are given more weight than future benefits, simply because the benefits are less certain and occur further in the future.
    • (1995) Antitrust L. J. , vol.63 , pp. 917
    • Reiffen, D.1    Vita, M.G.2
  • 23
    • 31844450373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although vertical integration reduces consumer welfare under these assumptions, it may or may not reduce total welfare, depending on the nature of upstream scale economies.
  • 26
    • 0034553038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical Foreclosure with the Choice of Input Specifications
    • Jay Choi & Sang-Seung Yi, Vertical Foreclosure with the Choice of Input Specifications, 31 RAND J. Econ. 717 (2000).
    • (2000) Rand J. Econ. , vol.31 , pp. 717
    • Choi, J.1    Yi, S.-S.2
  • 27
    • 0038695617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Vertical Mergers and Their Competitive Effects
    • Yongmin Chen, On Vertical Mergers and Their Competitive Effects, 32 RAND J. ECON. 667 (2001).
    • (2001) Rand J. Econ. , vol.32 , pp. 667
    • Chen, Y.1
  • 31
    • 24644465518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of Inference
    • There is a significant literature on two-stage game models of vertical control in which upstream and downstream firms can write non-linear contracts. The results in this literature depend in subtle ways on the details of the oligopoly game, such as whether downstream decision variables are strategic substitutes or complements and whether firms observe their rivals' contracts. For more on these issues, see and the references cited therein
    • There is a significant literature on two-stage game models of vertical control in which upstream and downstream firms can write non-linear contracts. The results in this literature depend in subtle ways on the details of the oligopoly game, such as whether downstream decision variables are strategic substitutes or complements and whether firms observe their rivals' contracts. For more on these issues, see James Cooper, Luke Froeb, Dan O'Brien & Michael Vita, Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of Inference, 23 Int'l J. Indus. Org. 639 (2005), and the references cited therein.
    • (2005) Int'l J. Indus. Org. , vol.23 , pp. 639
    • Cooper, J.1    Froeb, L.2    O'Brien, D.3    Vita, M.4
  • 33
    • 31844440237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In the main body of the report, Professor Church provides a more careful definition of "market power": "The concern here is not with market power as conventionally defined by economists - the ability to raise price above marginal cost - but with antitrust market power. Antitrust market power is significant and durable, where significant means prices exceed average cost and durable means that these prices can be sustained in the long run."
  • 34
    • 31844438256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 9.
  • 35
    • 31844449652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Professor Church focuses on average cost instead of marginal cost, but both the marginal and average cost margins of the downstream firm can rise when successive monopolists merge, even though market power clearly does not increase in this case. The accepted legal definition of "market power" - "the ability to raise prices above those that would be charged in a competitive market"-does not appear to have any grounding in a reduction of welfare, but rather focuses on a departure of price from marginal cost.
  • 36
    • 31844432998 scopus 로고
    • NCAA v. Board of Regents
    • n.38
    • NCAA v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85, 198 n.38 (1984).
    • (1984) U.S. , vol.468 , Issue.85 , pp. 198
  • 37
    • 84858537275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Similarly the FTC and DOJ define "market power" in the Horizontal Merger Guidelines as "the ability profitably to maintain prices above competitive levels for a significant period of time"
    • §
    • Similarly the FTC and DOJ define "market power" in the Horizontal Merger Guidelines as "the ability profitably to maintain prices above competitive levels for a significant period of time." U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines §0.1
    • U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines
  • 38
    • 27844587041 scopus 로고
    • Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc
    • see also ("Market power is the power 'to force a purchaser to do something that he would not do in a competitive market.' It has been described as 'the ability of a single seller to raise price and restrict output.'") (quoting Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 4)
    • see also Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 464 (1992) ("Market power is the power 'to force a purchaser to do something that he would not do in a competitive market.' It has been described as 'the ability of a single seller to raise price and restrict output.'")
    • (1992) U.S. , vol.504 , Issue.451 , pp. 464
  • 39
    • 0346253189 scopus 로고
    • Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 4 v. Hyde
    • (quoting)
    • (quoting Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 4 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 14 (1984);
    • (1984) U.S. , vol.466 , Issue.2 , pp. 14
  • 40
    • 31844450094 scopus 로고
    • Fortner Enterprises, Inc. v. U.S. Steel Corp
    • Fortner Enterprises, Inc. v. U.S. Steel Corp., 394 U.S. 495, 503 (1969)).
    • (1969) U.S. , vol.394 , Issue.495 , pp. 503
  • 41
    • 31844443666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Some, however, have argued that a focus on own-price elasticity departs from a proper reading of courts' interpretations of market power, which typically means the ability to affect market-wide price, not merely one's own price.
  • 42
    • 0040380193 scopus 로고
    • Market Power in Antitrust: Economic Analysis After Kodak
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Benjamin Klein, Market Power in Antitrust: Economic Analysis After Kodak, 3 S. Ct. Econ. Rev. 43, 71-85 (1993).
    • (1993) S. Ct. Econ. Rev. , vol.3 , Issue.43 , pp. 71-85
    • Klein, B.1
  • 43
    • 31844457086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, a reasonable reading of Professor Church's definition could lead to an antitrust challenge of a vertical merger that creates a competitive advantage for the merging parties due to the elimination of the double markup problem and other vertical externalities.
  • 44
    • 31844437503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is true as long as consumers prefer one-stop shopping.
  • 45
    • 31844456253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If consumers have different preferences for one-stop shopping and firms cannot price discriminate, some consumers may benefit and some may lose. The net effect on consumers will be ambiguous.
  • 49
    • 31844444803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the main body of the report, Professor Church also notes: "Unfortunately, it does not appear to be possible to provide such a mapping [between key variables that can be observed and implications] for vertical mergers."
    • Id. In the main body of the report, Professor Church also notes: "Unfortunately, it does not appear to be possible to provide such a mapping [between key variables that can be observed and implications] for vertical mergers."
    • (2004) Impact of Vertical and Conglomerate Mergers
    • Church, J.1
  • 51
    • 24644465518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of Inference
    • This is quite consistent with the view we articulate in that the theory in this area is too sensitive and relies on too many variables that are hard to observe to provide a practical basis for policy. There is a significant literature on two-stage game models of vertical control in which upstream and downstream firms can write non-linear contracts. The results in this literature depend in subtle ways on the details of the oligopoly game, such as whether downstream decision variables are strategic substitutes or complements and whether firms observe their rivals' contracts. For more on these issues, see and the references cited therein
    • This is quite consistent with the view we articulate in Cooper, Froeb, O'Brien & Vita (2005), supra note 25, that the theory in this area is too sensitive and relies on too many variables that are hard to observe to provide a practical basis for policy.
    • (2005) Int'l J. Indus. Org. , vol.23 , pp. 639
    • Cooper, J.1    Froeb, L.2    O'Brien, D.3    Vita, M.4
  • 55
    • 84858546306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example (AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Related Publication 05-27)
    • For example, Timothy J. Brennan, Saving Section 2: Reframing Monopolization Law (AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Related Publication 05-27, 2005), http://www.aei.brookings.org/admin/ authorpdfs/page.php?id=1202.
    • (2005) Saving Section 2: Reframing Monopolization Law
    • Brennan, T.J.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.