메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 39, Issue 3, 2009, Pages 517-537

Perceiving credible commitments: How independent regulators shape elite perceptions of regulatory quality

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 67749133403     PISSN: 00071234     EISSN: 14692112     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0007123409000623     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (41)

References (94)
  • 1
    • 1542290590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Piet Rietveld and Uma Subramanian, 'The Institutional Determinants of Bilateral Trade Patterns'
    • Henri L. F. de Groot, Gert-Jan Linders, Piet Rietveld and Uma Subramanian, 'The Institutional Determinants of Bilateral Trade Patterns', Kyklos, 57 (2004), 103-23.
    • (2004) Kyklos , vol.57 , pp. 103-123
    • Henri, L.1    de Groot, F.2    Jan Linders, G.3
  • 2
    • 0037654913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Growth without Governance
    • Daniel Kaufmann and Aart Kraay, 'Growth without Governance', Economía, 3 (2002), 169-229.
    • (2002) Economía , vol.3 , pp. 169-229
    • Kaufmann, D.1    Kraay, A.2
  • 3
    • 0036843789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Global Foreign Direct Investment Flows: The Role of Governance Infrastructure
    • Steven Globerman and Daniel Shapiro, 'Global Foreign Direct Investment Flows: The Role of Governance Infrastructure', World Development, 30 (2002), 1899-920.
    • (2002) World Development , vol.30 , pp. 1899-1920
    • Globerman, S.1    Shapiro, D.2
  • 5
    • 0001890195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Worker than Others?
    • Robert E. Hall and Charles I. Jones, 'Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Worker than Others?' Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114 (1999), 83-116;
    • (1999) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.114 , pp. 83-116
    • Hall, R.E.1    Jones, C.I.2
  • 6
    • 0034439031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutions for High-Quality Growth: What They Are and How To Acquire Them
    • Dani Rodrik, 'Institutions for High-Quality Growth: What They Are and How To Acquire Them', Studies in Comparative International Development, 35 (2000), 3-31;
    • (2000) Studies in Comparative International Development , vol.35 , pp. 3-31
    • Rodrik, D.1
  • 10
    • 84984517112 scopus 로고
    • Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures
    • Philip Keefer and Stephen Knack, 'Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures', Economics and Politics, 7 (1995), 207-27;
    • (1995) Economics and Politics , vol.7 , pp. 207-227
    • Keefer, P.1    Knack, S.2
  • 12
    • 0001301322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contract-Intensive Money: Contract Enforcement, Property Rights and Economic Performance
    • Christopher Clague, Philip Keefer, Stephen Knack and Mancur Olson, 'Contract-Intensive Money: Contract Enforcement, Property Rights and Economic Performance', Journal of Economic Growth, 4 (1999), 185-210;
    • (1999) Journal of Economic Growth , vol.4 , pp. 185-210
    • Clague, C.1    Keefer, P.2    Knack, S.3    Olson, M.4
  • 14
    • 0000643498 scopus 로고
    • Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans
    • 473-91, p
    • Finn Kydland and Edward Prescott, 'Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans', Journal of Political Economy, 85 (1977), 473-91, p. 487.
    • (1977) Journal of Political Economy , vol.85 , pp. 487
    • Kydland, F.1    Prescott, E.2
  • 15
    • 67749099808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kydland and Prescott, 'Rules Rather than Discretion', p. 487.
    • Kydland and Prescott, 'Rules Rather than Discretion', p. 487.
  • 16
    • 0017001516 scopus 로고
    • Regulation and Administered Contracts
    • For example
    • For example, Victor Goldberg, 'Regulation and Administered Contracts', Bell Journal of Economics, 7 (1976), 426-52;
    • (1976) Bell Journal of Economics , vol.7 , pp. 426-452
    • Goldberg, V.1
  • 17
    • 21844518521 scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Foundations of Regulatory Commitment: A Comparative Analysis of Telecommunications Regulation
    • Brian Levy and Pablo T. Spiller, 'The Institutional Foundations of Regulatory Commitment: A Comparative Analysis of Telecommunications Regulation', Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 10 (1994), 201-45;
    • (1994) Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization , vol.10 , pp. 201-245
    • Levy, B.1    Spiller, P.T.2
  • 19
    • 0032393929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political Institutions and Electric Utility Investment: A Cross-Nation Analysis
    • Mario Bergara, Witold Henisz and Pablo T. Spiller, 'Political Institutions and Electric Utility Investment: A Cross-Nation Analysis', California Management Review, 40 (1998), 18-35;
    • (1998) California Management Review , vol.40 , pp. 18-35
    • Bergara, M.1    Henisz, W.2    Spiller, P.T.3
  • 21
    • 0032812674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulatory Governance: Criteria for Assessing the Performance of Regulatory Systems - an Application to Infrastructure Industries in the Developing Countries of Asia
    • Jon Stern and Stuart Holder, 'Regulatory Governance: Criteria for Assessing the Performance of Regulatory Systems - an Application to Infrastructure Industries in the Developing Countries of Asia', Utilities Policy, 8 (1999), 33-50;
    • (1999) Utilities Policy , vol.8 , pp. 33-50
    • Stern, J.1    Holder, S.2
  • 22
    • 0034600599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Developments in Best-Practice Regulation: Principles, Processes, Performance
    • Sanford Berg, 'Developments in Best-Practice Regulation: Principles, Processes, Performance', Electricity Journal, 13 (2000), 11-18.
    • (2000) Electricity Journal , vol.13 , pp. 11-18
    • Berg, S.1
  • 23
    • 7444244948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Getting to Grips with Quality in the Diffusion of Regulatory Impact Assessment in Europe
    • 271-6, p
    • Claudio M. Radaelli, 'Getting to Grips with Quality in the Diffusion of Regulatory Impact Assessment in Europe', Public Money & Management, 24 (2004), 271-6, p. 271.
    • (2004) Public Money & Management , vol.24 , pp. 271
    • Radaelli, C.M.1
  • 24
    • 67749142276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kydland and Prescott, 'Rules Rather than Discretion'.
    • Kydland and Prescott, 'Rules Rather than Discretion'.
  • 26
    • 84974486152 scopus 로고
    • Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England
    • See
    • See Douglass North and Barry Weingast, 'Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England', Journal of Economic History, 49 (1989), 803-32;
    • (1989) Journal of Economic History , vol.49 , pp. 803-832
    • North, D.1    Weingast, B.2
  • 27
    • 0036245740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Credible Commitment in Early Modern Europe: North and Weingast Revisited
    • David Stasavage, 'Credible Commitment in Early Modern Europe: North and Weingast Revisited', Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 18 (2002), 155-86.
    • (2002) Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization , vol.18 , pp. 155-186
    • Stasavage, D.1
  • 28
    • 67749118345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Persson and Tabellini, Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy, p. 298.
    • Persson and Tabellini, Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy, p. 298.
  • 31
    • 2542590102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Delegating an executive task to a cabinet department in the United Kingdom, for example, gives the minister a veto over policy choice, but locating the authority with an independent regulator such as the Water Services Regulation Authority (Ofwat) removes the incumbent government's policy veto. The creation of such independent regulators is a form of delegation, which, for example, Aghion et al. have operationalized as an increase in the 'share of votes that can block a leader ex post when he tries to implement legislation, Phillipe Aghion, Alberto Alesina and Francesco Trebbi, Endogenous Political Institutions, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119 2004, 565-611, p. 566, In the case of a truly independent regulator, that share of votes for a given action being regulated is driven to infinity
    • Delegating an executive task to a cabinet department in the United Kingdom, for example, gives the minister a veto over policy choice, but locating the authority with an independent regulator such as the Water Services Regulation Authority (Ofwat) removes the incumbent government's policy veto. The creation of such independent regulators is a form of delegation, which, for example, Aghion et al. have operationalized as an increase in the 'share of votes that can block a leader ex post when he tries to implement legislation' (Phillipe Aghion, Alberto Alesina and Francesco Trebbi, 'Endogenous Political Institutions', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119 (2004), 565-611, p. 566). In the case of a truly independent regulator, that share of votes for a given action being regulated is driven to infinity.
  • 32
    • 0036312709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Our approach runs parallel to recent political science literature on regulatory trust, which argues that declining trust in public institutions from scandals and strategic blame shifting by politicians has led, among other things, to more regulation of regulators by other governmental authorities (see generally: Michael Moran, Understanding the Regulatory State, British Journal of Political Science, 32 2002, 391-413;
    • Our approach runs parallel to recent political science literature on regulatory trust, which argues that declining trust in public institutions from scandals and strategic blame shifting by politicians has led, among other things, to more regulation of regulators by other governmental authorities (see generally: Michael Moran, 'Understanding the Regulatory State', British Journal of Political Science, 32 (2002), 391-413;
  • 33
    • 0035995609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Risk Game and the Blame Game
    • Christopher Hood, 'The Risk Game and the Blame Game', Government and Opposition, 37 (2002), 15-37;
    • (2002) Government and Opposition , vol.37 , pp. 15-37
    • Hood, C.1
  • 34
    • 67749114668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Christopher Hood, Colin Scott, Oliver James, George Jones and Tony Travers, Regulation Inside Government: Waste-watchers, Quality Police, and Sleaze Busters (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999)).
    • Christopher Hood, Colin Scott, Oliver James, George Jones and Tony Travers, Regulation Inside Government: Waste-watchers, Quality Police, and Sleaze Busters (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999)).
  • 35
    • 85016721127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Generally, the primary target of monetary policy is the inflation rate; this literature shows that even a politician who accepts higher inflation rates has the incentive to delegate to a conservative (inflation intolerant) central banker because of the unforeseen contingency of economic shocks. However, delegation to a central bank is generally not optimal when the bank is completely independent, but rather when there is an 'escape clause' the politician can use under extreme conditions to reject the banker's policy choice (Susanne Lohmann, 'Optimal Commitment in Monetary Policy: Credibility versus Flexibility', American Economic Review, 82 (1992), 273-86).
    • Generally, the primary target of monetary policy is the inflation rate; this literature shows that even a politician who accepts higher inflation rates has the incentive to delegate to a conservative (inflation intolerant) central banker because of the unforeseen contingency of economic shocks. However, delegation to a central bank is generally not optimal when the bank is completely independent, but rather when there is an 'escape clause' the politician can use under extreme conditions to reject the banker's policy choice (Susanne Lohmann, 'Optimal Commitment in Monetary Policy: Credibility versus Flexibility', American Economic Review, 82 (1992), 273-86).
  • 36
    • 67749104695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Kydland and Prescott, 'Rules Rather than Discretion';
    • See also Kydland and Prescott, 'Rules Rather than Discretion';
  • 37
    • 49049128000 scopus 로고
    • Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy
    • Robert Barro and David Gordon, 'Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy', Journal of Monetary Economics, 12 (1983), 101-20;
    • (1983) Journal of Monetary Economics , vol.12 , pp. 101-120
    • Barro, R.1    Gordon, D.2
  • 38
    • 84947586303 scopus 로고
    • The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target
    • Kenneth Rogoff, 'The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100 (1985), 1169-89;
    • (1985) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.100 , pp. 1169-1189
    • Rogoff, K.1
  • 39
    • 0141574246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Limits of Delegation: Veto Players, Central Bank Independence, and the Credibility of Monetary Policy
    • Philip Keefer and David Stasavage, 'The Limits of Delegation: Veto Players, Central Bank Independence, and the Credibility of Monetary Policy', American Political Science Review, 97 (2003), 407-23.
    • (2003) American Political Science Review , vol.97 , pp. 407-423
    • Keefer, P.1    Stasavage, D.2
  • 40
    • 66049117352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth
    • See, Philippe Aghion and Stephen Durlauf, eds, Amsterdam: North Holland
    • See Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson, 'Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth', in Philippe Aghion and Stephen Durlauf, eds, Handbook of Economic Growth (Amsterdam: North Holland, 2005), pp. 385-472.
    • (2005) Handbook of Economic Growth , pp. 385-472
    • Acemoglu, D.1    Johnson, S.2    Robinson, J.A.3
  • 44
    • 0002965561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism as a Commitment to Preserving Market Incentives
    • Yingyi Qian and Barry R. Weingast, 'Federalism as a Commitment to Preserving Market Incentives', Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11 (1997), 83-92.
    • (1997) Journal of Economic Perspectives , vol.11 , pp. 83-92
    • Qian, Y.1    Weingast, B.R.2
  • 45
    • 0001913043 scopus 로고
    • The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules
    • Cf. George Priest, 'The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules', Journal of Legal Studies, 6 (1977), 65-82;
    • (1977) Journal of Legal Studies , vol.6 , pp. 65-82
    • George Priest, C.1
  • 46
    • 0002401339 scopus 로고
    • Why is the Common Law Efficient?
    • Paul Rubin, 'Why is the Common Law Efficient?' Journal of Legal Studies, 7 (1977), 51-63;
    • (1977) Journal of Legal Studies , vol.7 , pp. 51-63
    • Rubin, P.1
  • 47
    • 0001628664 scopus 로고
    • Can Litigation Improve the Law without the Help of Judges?
    • Robert Cooter and Lewis Kornhauser, 'Can Litigation Improve the Law without the Help of Judges?' Journal of Legal Studies, 9 (1980), 139-63.
    • (1980) Journal of Legal Studies , vol.9 , pp. 139-163
    • Cooter, R.1    Kornhauser, L.2
  • 48
    • 67749084607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consider the case of Hungarian telecommunications. The government's divestiture of a majority interest in Matáv, the national telecommunications monopoly, was completed in 1995 (David M. Eisenberg, Linking Privatisation and Regulatory Reform (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1998, p. 2, http://www.ebrd.com/country/sector/ law/telecoms/about/private.pdf (accessed 6 May 2007, In 1993-98, the Telecommunications General Inspectorate served as the regulator of the telecommunications industry, but was directly controlled by the Ministry of Transport. During this period, a formal complaint was made by local telephone operators and mobile service providers alleging that Matav unfairly influenced the Minister for Transport to gain permission to control the interconnection charges levied against other providers for each transmission originating on Matav's network Eisenberg, Linking Privatisation and Regulatory Reform, p. 3, Eisenberg wr
    • Consider the case of Hungarian telecommunications. The government's divestiture of a majority interest in Matáv - the national telecommunications monopoly - was completed in 1995 (David M. Eisenberg, Linking Privatisation and Regulatory Reform (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1998), p. 2, http://www.ebrd.com/country/sector/ law/telecoms/about/private.pdf (accessed 6 May 2007)). In 1993-98, the Telecommunications General Inspectorate served as the regulator of the telecommunications industry, but was directly controlled by the Ministry of Transport. During this period, a formal complaint was made by local telephone operators and mobile service providers alleging that Matav unfairly influenced the Minister for Transport to gain permission to control the interconnection charges levied against other providers for each transmission originating on Matav's network (Eisenberg, Linking Privatisation and Regulatory Reform, p. 3). Eisenberg writes that such charges 'imposed by the dominant telecoms operator are regularly contested by competing operators. The situation in Hungary is therefore unexceptional' (Eisenberg, Linking Privatisation and Regulatory Reform, p. 3). In the Electronic Communications Act of 2003, an independent regulator - the National Communications Authority - was created. The Authority 'is an independent central budgetary entity with its own budget and uses its own revenues to cover the costs incurred in relation with the performance of its duties' (National Communications Authority, 'About Us', 2007, http://www.nhh.hu/index.php?id5 hir&cid5891&mid5599 (accessed 6 May 2007)).
  • 50
    • 67749111868 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kydland and Prescott, 'Rules Rather than Discretion'.
    • Kydland and Prescott, 'Rules Rather than Discretion'.
  • 51
    • 25444521770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Electoral Rules and Constitutional Structures as Constraints on Corruption
    • Jana Kunicová and Susan Rose-Ackerman, 'Electoral Rules and Constitutional Structures as Constraints on Corruption', British Journal of Political Science, 35 (2005), 573-606.
    • (2005) British Journal of Political Science , vol.35 , pp. 573-606
    • Kunicová, J.1    Rose-Ackerman, S.2
  • 53
    • 67749131135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keefer and Stasavage, 'The Limits of Delegation';
    • Keefer and Stasavage, 'The Limits of Delegation';
  • 54
    • 84976104285 scopus 로고
    • Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism
    • George Tsebelis, 'Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism', British Journal of Political Science, 25 (1995), 289-325;
    • (1995) British Journal of Political Science , vol.25 , pp. 289-325
    • Tsebelis, G.1
  • 55
    • 0004338586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J, Princeton University Press
    • George Tsebelis, Veto Players (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
    • (2002) Veto Players
    • Tsebelis, G.1
  • 57
    • 67749114667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shugart and Carey, Presidents and Assemblies, p. 140.
    • Shugart and Carey, Presidents and Assemblies, p. 140.
  • 58
    • 0010589784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Determinants of Economic Policy Outcomes
    • For example, Stephan Haggard and Mathew D. McCubbins, eds, New York: Cambridge University Press
    • For example, Gary W. Cox and Mathew D. McCubbins, 'The Institutional Determinants of Economic Policy Outcomes', in Stephan Haggard and Mathew D. McCubbins, eds, Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001).
    • (2001) Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy
    • Cox, G.W.1    McCubbins, M.D.2
  • 59
    • 67749135772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism as a Commitment to Preserving Market Incentives
    • For example
    • For example, Qian and Weingast, 'Federalism as a Commitment to Preserving Market Incentives'.
  • 62
    • 0000979996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation
    • Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson, 'The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation', American Economic Review, 91 (2001), 1369-401;
    • (2001) American Economic Review , vol.91 , pp. 1369-1401
    • Acemoglu, D.1    Johnson, S.2    Robinson, J.A.3
  • 65
    • 67749145672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cooter and Kornhauser, 'Can Litigation Improve the Law without the Help of Judges?'
    • Cooter and Kornhauser, 'Can Litigation Improve the Law without the Help of Judges?'
  • 66
    • 67749113675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These data are available at http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/pubs/ govmatters5.html. See Daniel Kaufmann, Aart Kraay and Massimo Mastruzzi, 'Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for 1996-2002', Technical Report of the World Bank, 2004, for full details.
    • These data are available at http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/pubs/ govmatters5.html. See Daniel Kaufmann, Aart Kraay and Massimo Mastruzzi, 'Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for 1996-2002', Technical Report of the World Bank, 2004, for full details.
  • 72
    • 67749139997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Levy and Spiller, 'A Framework for Resolving the Regulatory Problem';
    • Levy and Spiller, 'A Framework for Resolving the Regulatory Problem';
  • 75
    • 84928372050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paul de Bijl and Martin Peitz, Regulation and Entry into Telecommunications Markets (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002).
    • Paul de Bijl and Martin Peitz, Regulation and Entry into Telecommunications Markets (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002).
  • 76
    • 0042108430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • European Telecommunications Markets on the Verge of Full Liberalization
    • 113-26, p
    • Leonard Waverman and Esen Sirel, 'European Telecommunications Markets on the Verge of Full Liberalization', Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11 (1997), 113-26, p. 118.
    • (1997) Journal of Economic Perspectives , vol.11 , pp. 118
    • Waverman, L.1    Sirel, E.2
  • 77
    • 67749097969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A search of Lexis-Nexis during the period of our dataset (1996-2004) uncovers seventy-six articles on independent telecommunications regulators in the Financial Times alone.
    • A search of Lexis-Nexis during the period of our dataset (1996-2004) uncovers seventy-six articles on independent telecommunications regulators in the Financial Times alone.
  • 79
    • 0034754775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions
    • Thorsten Beck, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philip Keefer and Patrick Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions', World Bank Economic Review, 15 (2001), 165-76.
    • (2001) World Bank Economic Review , vol.15 , pp. 165-176
    • Beck, T.1    Clarke, G.2    Groff, A.3    Keefer, P.4    Walsh, P.5
  • 80
    • 67749144104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beck, Clarke, Groff, Keefer and Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy'.
    • Beck, Clarke, Groff, Keefer and Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy'.
  • 81
    • 67749110306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beck, Clarke, Groff, Keefer and Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy'.
    • Beck, Clarke, Groff, Keefer and Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy'.
  • 82
    • 67749122500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beck, Clarke, Groff, Keefer and Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy'.
    • Beck, Clarke, Groff, Keefer and Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy'.
  • 84
    • 67749145671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beck, Clarke, Groff, Keefer and Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy'.
    • Beck, Clarke, Groff, Keefer and Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy'.
  • 85
    • 67749096182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Colonial Origins of Comparative
    • Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson, 'The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development';
    • Development
    • Acemoglu, J.1    Robinson2
  • 88
    • 0004296209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5th edn Upper Saddle River, N.J, Prentice-Hall
    • William H. Greene, Econometric Analysis, 5th edn (Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 2003), pp. 787-9.
    • (2003) Econometric Analysis , pp. 787-789
    • Greene, W.H.1
  • 91
    • 67749104025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spulber and Besanko, 'Delegation, Commitment, and the Regulatory Mandate'.
    • Spulber and Besanko, 'Delegation, Commitment, and the Regulatory Mandate'.
  • 92
    • 67749088525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Montinola and Robert Jackman, 'Sources of Corruption: A Cross-Country Study'.
    • Montinola and Robert Jackman, 'Sources of Corruption: A Cross-Country Study'.
  • 93
    • 67749135770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These data are available at http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/pubs/ govmatters5.html. See Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi, 'Governance Matters III', for full details.
    • These data are available at http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/pubs/ govmatters5.html. See Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi, 'Governance Matters III', for full details.
  • 94


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.