메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 4, Issue 2, 2008, Pages 271-278

Should "price Squeeze" be a recognized form of anticompetitive conduct?

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 50449109362     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: 17446422     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhn012     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (26)

References (14)
  • 1
    • 50449105957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 503 F.3d 876 (9th Cir. 2007).
    • 503 F.3d 876 (9th Cir. 2007).
  • 2
    • 50449111328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As I explain below, if there is competition in the sale of Product A and Firm 1 is a price taker in that market, then the price squeeze would occur only if Firm 1 depressed the price of Product B because Firm 1 could not raise the price of Product A. In that situation, the analysis would be identical to the analysis of predatory pricing in Product B and there is no need for a separate price squeeze theory of antitrust liability.
    • As I explain below, if there is competition in the sale of Product A and Firm 1 is a price taker in that market, then the price squeeze would occur only if Firm 1 depressed the price of Product B because Firm 1 could not raise the price of Product A. In that situation, the analysis would be identical to the analysis of predatory pricing in Product B and there is no need for a separate "price squeeze" theory of antitrust liability.
  • 3
    • 0035583308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Dennis W. Carlton, A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal - Why Aspen and Kodak are Misguided, 68 Antitrust L.J. 659 (2001)
    • See, e.g., Dennis W. Carlton, A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal - Why Aspen and Kodak are Misguided, 68 Antitrust L.J. 659 (2001)
  • 4
    • 17244362860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Monopoly Dominance or Level Playing Field? The New Antitrust Paradox, 72
    • Richard A. Epstein, Monopoly Dominance or Level Playing Field? The New Antitrust Paradox, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 49 (2005)
    • (2005) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.49
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 5
    • 17244378162 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusion and the Sherman Act, 72
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, Exclusion and the Sherman Act, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 147 (2005).
    • (2005) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.147
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 6
    • 50449097140 scopus 로고
    • Group Ltd
    • See, e.g, 509 U.S
    • See, e.g., Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993).
    • (1993) Tobacco Corp , vol.Brown and Williamson , pp. 209
    • Brooke1
  • 7
    • 50449083638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 224.
    • See id. at 224.
  • 8
    • 50449097140 scopus 로고
    • Group Ltd
    • See, e.g, 509 U.S
    • See, e.g., Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993).
    • (1993) Tobacco Corp , vol.Brown and Williamson , pp. 209
    • Brooke1
  • 9
    • 17244378477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Designing Antitrust Rules for Assessing Unilateral Practices: A Neo-Chicago Approach, 72
    • See
    • See David S. Evans & Jorge Padilla, Designing Antitrust Rules for Assessing Unilateral Practices: A Neo-Chicago Approach, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 73 (2005).
    • (2005) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.73
    • Evans, D.S.1    Padilla, J.2
  • 10
    • 50449110002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If Firm 1 was not as efficient as Firm 2 in the production of Product B, then Firm 1 would willingly deal with Firm 2 at prices under which Firm 2 makes profits.
    • If Firm 1 was not as efficient as Firm 2 in the production of Product B, then Firm 1 would willingly deal with Firm 2 at prices under which Firm 2 makes profits.
  • 11
    • 50449108315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I assume that the duty to deal is imposed under the antitrust laws. In Verizon Communications, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP the Supreme Court spoke about the reluctance that courts have in imposing an antitrust duty to deal on a firm such as Firm 1. 540 U.S. 398 (2004). The reluctance stems from the weighing of the costs and benefits of such a duty.
    • I assume that the duty to deal is imposed under the antitrust laws. In Verizon Communications, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP the Supreme Court spoke about the reluctance that courts have in imposing an antitrust duty to deal on a firm such as Firm 1. 540 U.S. 398 (2004). The reluctance stems from the weighing of the costs and benefits of such a duty.
  • 12
    • 50449098720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, may benefit consumers, a duty to deal reduces property rights and as such reduces the fundamental incentives of a capitalist system to reward those who create products that consumers want. Any reduction in this incentive will generally harm consumers, especially when one realizes how important new products have been in raising living standards
    • See id. at 414. Although one can think of instances where a duty to deal may benefit consumers, a duty to deal reduces property rights and as such reduces the fundamental incentives of a capitalist system to reward those who create products that consumers want. Any reduction in this incentive will generally harm consumers, especially when one realizes how important new products have been in raising living standards.
    • at 414. Although one can think of instances where a duty to deal
    • Evans, D.S.1    Padilla, J.2
  • 13
    • 50449099135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carlton, supra note 2. I note that regulatory duties to deal are not relevant to this inquiry. If a regulator imposes a duty to deal, the regulator should also establish the terms of dealing.
    • See Carlton, supra note 2. I note that regulatory duties to deal are not relevant to this inquiry. If a regulator imposes a duty to deal, the regulator should also establish the terms of dealing.
  • 14
    • 50449098980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Trinko, 540 U.S. at 411-12.
    • See Trinko, 540 U.S. at 411-12.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.