메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 109, Issue 3, 1999, Pages 417-504

A consumer-welfare approach to the mandatory unbundling of telecommunications networks

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0010332510     PISSN: 00440094     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.2307/797409     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (52)

References (314)
  • 1
    • 84923728105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 119 S. Ct. 721 (1999).
    • 119 S. Ct. 721 (1999).
  • 2
    • 84923728104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Section 251(d)(2) provides in full: In determining what network elements should be made available for purposes of subsection (c)(3) of this section, the Commission shall consider, at a minimum, whether -(A) access to such network elements as are proprietary in nature is necessary; and (B) the failure to provide access to such network elements would impair the ability of the telecommunications carrier seeking access to provide the services that it seeks to offer. 47 U.S.C.A. § 251(d)(2) (West Supp. 1999).
  • 3
    • 84923728103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, FCC 99-70, ¶ 21 (released Apr. 16, 1999), available in 1999 WL 221834 ("We nevertheless seek comment on the significance of the essential facilities standard under section 251(d)(2)."); id. ¶ 22 ("We ask parties to describe [the essential facilities doctrine] and how it should be applied, if it all, to the determination of which network elements incumbent LECs must provide on an unbundled basis.").
  • 4
    • 0008323038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. §§ 251-252. For detailed discussions of this open-access regulation, see ALFRED E. KAHN, LETTING GO: DEREGULATING THE PROCESS OF DEREGULATION 47-53, 90-96 (1998); J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT (1997); Robert G. Harris & C. Jeffrey Kraft, Meddling Through: Regulating Local Telephone Competition in the United States, J. ECON. PERSP., Fall 1997, at 93, 102-11; and J. Gregory Sidak & Daniel F. Spulber, The Tragedy of the Telecommons: Government Pricing of Unbundled Network Elements Under the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 97 COLUM. L. REV. 1081 (1997). For an analysis of unbundling policy pursued through antitrust law rather than through regulation, see Abbott B. Lipsky, Jr. & J. Gregory Sidak, Essential Facilities, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1187 (1999).
    • (1998) Letting Go: Deregulating the Process of Deregulation , pp. 47-53
    • Kahn, A.E.1
  • 5
    • 0003528027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. §§ 251-252. For detailed discussions of this open-access regulation, see ALFRED E. KAHN, LETTING GO: DEREGULATING THE PROCESS OF DEREGULATION 47-53, 90-96 (1998); J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT (1997); Robert G. Harris & C. Jeffrey Kraft, Meddling Through: Regulating Local Telephone Competition in the United States, J. ECON. PERSP., Fall 1997, at 93, 102-11; and J. Gregory Sidak & Daniel F. Spulber, The Tragedy of the Telecommons: Government Pricing of Unbundled Network Elements Under the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 97 COLUM. L. REV. 1081 (1997). For an analysis of unbundling policy pursued through antitrust law rather than through regulation, see Abbott B. Lipsky, Jr. & J. Gregory Sidak, Essential Facilities, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1187 (1999).
    • (1997) Deregulatory Takings and the Regulatory Contract
    • Sidak, J.G.1    Spulber, D.F.2
  • 6
    • 0006352352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Meddling through: Regulating local telephone competition in the United States
    • Fall
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. §§ 251-252. For detailed discussions of this open-access regulation, see ALFRED E. KAHN, LETTING GO: DEREGULATING THE PROCESS OF DEREGULATION 47-53, 90-96 (1998); J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT (1997); Robert G. Harris & C. Jeffrey Kraft, Meddling Through: Regulating Local Telephone Competition in the United States, J. ECON. PERSP., Fall 1997, at 93, 102-11; and J. Gregory Sidak & Daniel F. Spulber, The Tragedy of the Telecommons: Government Pricing of Unbundled Network Elements Under the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 97 COLUM. L. REV. 1081 (1997). For an analysis of unbundling policy pursued through antitrust law rather than through regulation, see Abbott B. Lipsky, Jr. & J. Gregory Sidak, Essential Facilities, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1187 (1999).
    • (1997) J. Econ. Persp. , pp. 102-111
    • Harris, R.G.1    Kraft, C.J.2
  • 7
    • 0346089931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The tragedy of the telecommons: Government pricing of unbundled network elements under the telecommunications act of 1996
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. §§ 251-252. For detailed discussions of this open-access regulation, see ALFRED E. KAHN, LETTING GO: DEREGULATING THE PROCESS OF DEREGULATION 47-53, 90-96 (1998); J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT (1997); Robert G. Harris & C. Jeffrey Kraft, Meddling Through: Regulating Local Telephone Competition in the United States, J. ECON. PERSP., Fall 1997, at 93, 102-11; and J. Gregory Sidak & Daniel F. Spulber, The Tragedy of the Telecommons: Government Pricing of Unbundled Network Elements Under the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 97 COLUM. L. REV. 1081 (1997). For an analysis of unbundling policy pursued through antitrust law rather than through regulation, see Abbott B. Lipsky, Jr. & J. Gregory Sidak, Essential Facilities, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1187 (1999).
    • (1997) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.97 , pp. 1081
    • Sidak, J.G.1    Spulber, D.F.2
  • 8
    • 0346617007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Essential facilities
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. §§ 251-252. For detailed discussions of this open-access regulation, see ALFRED E. KAHN, LETTING GO: DEREGULATING THE PROCESS OF DEREGULATION 47-53, 90-96 (1998); J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT (1997); Robert G. Harris & C. Jeffrey Kraft, Meddling Through: Regulating Local Telephone Competition in the United States, J. ECON. PERSP., Fall 1997, at 93, 102-11; and J. Gregory Sidak & Daniel F. Spulber, The Tragedy of the Telecommons: Government Pricing of Unbundled Network Elements Under the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 97 COLUM. L. REV. 1081 (1997). For an analysis of unbundling policy pursued through antitrust law rather than through regulation, see Abbott B. Lipsky, Jr. & J. Gregory Sidak, Essential Facilities, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1187 (1999).
    • (1999) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 1187
    • Lipsky A.B., Jr.1    Sidak, J.G.2
  • 9
    • 84923728102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499 (1996). This order was vacated in part by the Eighth Circuit; the Supreme Court then modified the Eighth Circuit's decision in Iowa Utilities Board. See Iowa Utils. Bd. v. FCC, 120 F.3d 753 (8th Cir. 1997), rev'd in part and aff'd in part sub nom. AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721 (1999)
    • First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499 (1996). This order was vacated in part by the Eighth Circuit; the Supreme Court then modified the Eighth Circuit's decision in Iowa Utilities Board. See Iowa Utils. Bd. v. FCC, 120 F.3d 753 (8th Cir. 1997), rev'd in part and aff'd in part sub nom. AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721 (1999).
  • 10
    • 84923728101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 734-36
    • See Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 734-36.
  • 11
    • 84923728100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Chevron U.S.A. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, 467 U.S. 837, 842-45 (1984)
    • See Chevron U.S.A. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, 467 U.S. 837, 842-45 (1984).
  • 12
    • 84923728099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Endorsing Justice Breyer's analogy to the essential facilities doctrine as "inescapable" logic, Professor Hovenkamp writes: The principal purpose of the 1996 Telecommunications Act is to deregulate, and deregulation can be accomplished only by minimizing the occasions for regulatory supervision. Competition requires that inputs economically capable of being supplied competitively - that is, by numerous independent sources - be supplied in that manner. Forced sharing of such inputs acts as a disincentive to producing them competitively in the first place and exacerbates and prolongs agency supervision. PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW: AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATION ¶ 787'c, at 247 (Supp. 1999).
  • 13
    • 84928459352 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust, deregulation, and the newly liberated marketplace
    • This principle is well established in antitrust law. See, e.g., NCAA v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85, 107 (1984); Reiter v. Sonotone Corp., 442 U.S. 330, 343 (1979) (citing ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 66 (1978)). For special application of the consumer-welfare criterion to industries undergoing deregulation, see Stephen G. Breyer, Antitrust, Deregulation, and the Newly Liberated Marketplace, 75 CAL. L. REV. 1005 (1987).
    • (1987) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 1005
    • Breyer, S.G.1
  • 14
    • 84923728098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, pmbl., 110 Stat. 56, 56
    • Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, pmbl., 110 Stat. 56, 56.
  • 15
    • 0003446526 scopus 로고
    • Two years before passage of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Professor William J. Baumol and one of the present authors wrote: [R]egulators considerably influence the firm's demand elasticity by their decisions and policies that affect the firm's actual or potential competitors. Clearly, severe constraint of firms' entry and pricing will somewhat immunize each enterprise from the competitive pressures of others. That immunity from competition will reduce the elasticity of each supplier's demand - that is, it will reduce the loss of business that results from a rise in its prices. The firm's price elasticity of demand thus must be said to be endogenously determined by the regulatory process itself . . . . It appears especially clear in telecommunications that a firm's price elasticity of demand is endogenously determined by its regulatory environment. WILLIAM J. BAUMOL & J. GREGORY SIDAK, TOWARD COMPETITION IN LOCAL TELEPHONY 40-41 (1994).
    • (1994) Toward Competition in Local Telephony , pp. 40-41
    • Baumol, W.J.1    Sidak, J.G.2
  • 16
    • 0039272769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Our previous writings have emphasized the equivalence between the public-interest standard and a consumer-welfare standard. See id.; JERRY HAUSMAN, TAXATION BY TELECOMMUNICATIONS REGULATION: THE ECONOMICS OF THE E-RATE 4 (1998); SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 309-10, 340; Jerry Hausman, Valuing the Effect of Regulation on New Services in Telecommunications, 1997 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY: MICROECONOMICS 1; Jerry Hausman & Howard A. Shelanski, Economic Welfare and Telecommunications Welfare: The E-Rate Policy for Universal Service Subsidies, 16 YALE J. ON REG. 19, 26-29 (1999); J. Gregory Sidak, Telecommunications in Jericho, 81 CAL. L. REV. 1209, 1234-38 (1993) (review essay).
    • (1998) Taxation by Telecommunications Regulation: The Economics of rhe E-Rate , pp. 4
    • Hausman, J.1
  • 17
    • 0002544620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Valuing the effect of regulation on new services in telecommunications
    • Our previous writings have emphasized the equivalence between the public-interest standard and a consumer-welfare standard. See id.; JERRY HAUSMAN, TAXATION BY TELECOMMUNICATIONS REGULATION: THE ECONOMICS OF THE E-RATE 4 (1998); SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 309-10, 340; Jerry Hausman, Valuing the Effect of Regulation on New Services in Telecommunications, 1997 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY: MICROECONOMICS 1; Jerry Hausman & Howard A. Shelanski, Economic Welfare and Telecommunications Welfare: The E-Rate Policy for Universal Service Subsidies, 16 YALE J. ON REG. 19, 26-29 (1999); J. Gregory Sidak, Telecommunications in Jericho, 81 CAL. L. REV. 1209, 1234-38 (1993) (review essay).
    • Brookings Papers on Econ. Activity: Microeconomics , vol.1997 , pp. 1
    • Hausman, J.1
  • 18
    • 0041646959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic welfare and telecommunications welfare: The e-rate policy for universal service subsidies
    • Our previous writings have emphasized the equivalence between the public-interest standard and a consumer-welfare standard. See id.; JERRY HAUSMAN, TAXATION BY TELECOMMUNICATIONS REGULATION: THE ECONOMICS OF THE E-RATE 4 (1998); SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 309-10, 340; Jerry Hausman, Valuing the Effect of Regulation on New Services in Telecommunications, 1997 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY: MICROECONOMICS 1; Jerry Hausman & Howard A. Shelanski, Economic Welfare and Telecommunications Welfare: The E-Rate Policy for Universal Service Subsidies, 16 YALE J. ON REG. 19, 26-29 (1999); J. Gregory Sidak, Telecommunications in Jericho, 81 CAL. L. REV. 1209, 1234-38 (1993) (review essay).
    • (1999) Yale J. on Reg. , vol.16 , pp. 19
    • Hausman, J.1    Shelanski, H.A.2
  • 19
    • 85050421053 scopus 로고
    • Telecommunications in Jericho
    • review essay
    • Our previous writings have emphasized the equivalence between the public-interest standard and a consumer-welfare standard. See id.; JERRY HAUSMAN, TAXATION BY TELECOMMUNICATIONS REGULATION: THE ECONOMICS OF THE E-RATE 4 (1998); SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 309-10, 340; Jerry Hausman, Valuing the Effect of Regulation on New Services in Telecommunications, 1997 BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY: MICROECONOMICS 1; Jerry Hausman & Howard A. Shelanski, Economic Welfare and Telecommunications Welfare: The E-Rate Policy for Universal Service Subsidies, 16 YALE J. ON REG. 19, 26-29 (1999); J. Gregory Sidak, Telecommunications in Jericho, 81 CAL. L. REV. 1209, 1234-38 (1993) (review essay).
    • (1993) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.81 , pp. 1209
    • Sidak, J.G.1
  • 20
    • 84923728097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552, 41,560-61 (1992)
    • See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552, 41,560-61 (1992).
  • 21
    • 84875128652 scopus 로고
    • Market power in antitrust cases
    • The seminal article is William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, Market Power in Antitrust Cases, 94 HARV. L. REV. 937, 944-45 (1981).
    • (1981) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 937
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 22
    • 84900965142 scopus 로고
    • See 5 ALFRED MARSHALL, PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS 381-93 (1922). For other explications of Marshall's rules of derived demand, see P.R.G. LAYARD & A.A. WALTERS, MICROECONOMIC THEORY 259-72 (1978). Derived demand is similar to, but distinguishable from, residual demand in the sense that the latter focuses on the demand for the end product and is calculated for any given firm by subtracting the supply of other firms from the market demand. See DENNIS W. CARLTON & JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 100 (2d ed. 1994).
    • (1922) Principles of Economics , pp. 381-393
    • Marshall, A.1
  • 23
    • 0004204955 scopus 로고
    • See 5 ALFRED MARSHALL, PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS 381-93 (1922). For other explications of Marshall's rules of derived demand, see P.R.G. LAYARD & A.A. WALTERS, MICROECONOMIC THEORY 259-72 (1978). Derived demand is similar to, but distinguishable from, residual demand in the sense that the latter focuses on the demand for the end product and is calculated for any given firm by subtracting the supply of other firms from the market demand. See DENNIS W. CARLTON & JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 100 (2d ed. 1994).
    • (1978) Microeconomic Theory , pp. 259-272
    • Layard, P.R.G.1    Walters, A.A.2
  • 24
    • 0004239155 scopus 로고
    • 2d ed.
    • See 5 ALFRED MARSHALL, PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS 381-93 (1922). For other explications of Marshall's rules of derived demand, see P.R.G. LAYARD & A.A. WALTERS, MICROECONOMIC THEORY 259-72 (1978). Derived demand is similar to, but distinguishable from, residual demand in the sense that the latter focuses on the demand for the end product and is calculated for any given firm by subtracting the supply of other firms from the market demand. See DENNIS W. CARLTON & JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 100 (2d ed. 1994).
    • (1994) Modern Industrial Organization , pp. 100
    • Carlton, D.W.1    Perloff, J.M.2
  • 26
    • 0041150819 scopus 로고
    • Many books have been written about the AT&T breakup. See, e.g., ROBERT W. CRANDALL, AFTER THE BREAKUP: U.S. TELECOMMUNICATIONS IN A MORE COMPETITIVE ERA (1991); PAUL W. MACAVOY, THE FAILURE OF ANTITRUST AND REGULATION TO ESTABLISH COMPETITION IN LONG-DISTANCE TELEPHONE SERVICES (1996); PETER TEMIN, THE FALL OF THE BELL SYSTEM: A STUDY IN PRICES AND POLITICS (1987).
    • (1991) After the Breakup: U.S. Telecommunications in a More Competitive Era
    • Crandall, R.W.1
  • 28
    • 0004147398 scopus 로고
    • Many books have been written about the AT&T breakup. See, e.g., ROBERT W. CRANDALL, AFTER THE BREAKUP: U.S. TELECOMMUNICATIONS IN A MORE COMPETITIVE ERA (1991); PAUL W. MACAVOY, THE FAILURE OF ANTITRUST AND REGULATION TO ESTABLISH COMPETITION IN LONG-DISTANCE TELEPHONE SERVICES (1996); PETER TEMIN, THE FALL OF THE BELL SYSTEM: A STUDY IN PRICES AND POLITICS (1987).
    • (1987) The Fall of the Bell System: A Study in Prices and Politics
    • Temin, P.1
  • 29
    • 84923728096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Modification of Final Judgment, in United States v. American Tel. & Tel. Co., 552 F. Supp. 131, 226-34 (D.D.C. 1982), aff'd sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983). The settlement was a "modification" of an earlier "final judgment" in the sense that it modified a consent decree into which AT&T and the government had entered in 1956
    • Modification of Final Judgment, in United States v. American Tel. & Tel. Co., 552 F. Supp. 131, 226-34 (D.D.C. 1982), aff'd sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983). The settlement was a "modification" of an earlier "final judgment" in the sense that it modified a consent decree into which AT&T and the government had entered in 1956.
  • 31
    • 0010984928 scopus 로고
    • The future evolution of the central office Switch industry
    • Stephen P. Bradley & Jerry A. Hausman eds.
    • For instance, the New England and New York Telephone Companies became part of NYNEX, which subsequently merged with Bell Atlantic. Recent and pending mergers are likely to lead to four remaining RBOCs with GTE, the largest independent company, merging with Bell Atlantic; U S WEST, the smallest RBOC, merging with Qwest, a new long-distance company; SBC acquiring Ameritech (after having acquired Pacific Telesis); and BellSouth remaining independent but with an equity interest in Qwest. AT&T divested its equipment manufacturing company, now called Lucent, in 1998. For an early explanation of the economic rationale behind this very successful divestiture, see Jerry A. Hausman & Elon Kohlberg, The Future Evolution of the Central Office Switch Industry, in FUTURE COMPETITION IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS 193 (Stephen P. Bradley & Jerry A. Hausman eds., 1989).
    • (1989) Future Competition in Telecommunications , pp. 193
    • Hausman, J.A.1    Kohlberg, E.2
  • 32
    • 84923728095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 55-99
    • See SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 55-99.
  • 33
    • 84923728094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Modification of Final Judgment § II.D, 552 F. Supp. at 227-28. Information services were defined to be the interaction of computer services and telecommunications
    • See Modification of Final Judgment § II.D, 552 F. Supp. at 227-28. Information services were defined to be the interaction of computer services and telecommunications.
  • 34
    • 84923728093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To "cross-subsidize" means to set prices below incremental cost. See, e.g., BAUMÖL & SIDAK, supra note 11, at 62. In actuality, long-distance service had long cross-subsidized local service at the direction of regulators, and so the Department of Justice's theory was incorrect. The amount of the cross-subsidy had increased greatly as the cost of providing long-distance service fell rapidly after 1950, with regulators refusing to allow long-distance prices to fall as rapidly. See CRANDALL, supra note 17, at 24-27. MCI recognized the economic opportunity of providing long-distance service when prices far exceeded costs and regulators would not permit a reduction in prices by the regulated company. Events soon after divestiture made evident the direction of cross-subsidy from long-distance to local, as the FCC established above-cost access fees (in actuality, a tax) on long-distance to continue the cross-subsidy to local service. See TEMIN, supra note 17, at 306-17.
  • 35
    • 84923728092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Modification of Final Judgment § VIII.C, 552 F. Supp. at 231
    • Modification of Final Judgment § VIII.C, 552 F. Supp. at 231.
  • 36
    • 84923728091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ironically, 1976 was the year of the introduction of both digital electronic switches and fiber-optic transmission. MCI, the first long-distance competitor of AT&T, had based its long-distance service on microwave transmission (hence the name from which "MCI" was derived: Microwave Communications, Inc.), but this technology was becoming obsolete at the time of the AT&T trial
    • Ironically, 1976 was the year of the introduction of both digital electronic switches and fiber-optic transmission. MCI, the first long-distance competitor of AT&T, had based its long-distance service on microwave transmission (hence the name from which "MCI" was derived: Microwave Communications, Inc.), but this technology was becoming obsolete at the time of the AT&T trial.
  • 37
    • 84986846036 scopus 로고
    • Costs of delay and rent-seeking under the modification of final judgment
    • See Paul H. Rubin & Hashem Dezhbakhsh, Costs of Delay and Rent-Seeking Under the Modification of Final Judgment, 16 MANAGERIAL & DECISION ECON. 385, 385-87 (1995).
    • (1995) Managerial & Decision Econ. , vol.16 , pp. 385
    • Rubin, P.H.1    Dezhbakhsh, H.2
  • 38
    • 84923728090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 392
    • See id. at 392.
  • 39
    • 84923728089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 389, 392
    • See id. at 389, 392.
  • 40
    • 84923728088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hausman, supra note 12, at 13-24
    • See Hausman, supra note 12, at 13-24.
  • 41
    • 84986841374 scopus 로고
    • Competition in long-distance and telecommunications equipment markets: Effects of the MFJ
    • See Jerry A. Hausman, Competition in Long-Distance and Telecommunications Equipment Markets: Effects of the MFJ, 16 J. MANAGERIAL & DECISION ECON. 365 (1995).
    • (1995) J. Managerial & Decision Econ. , vol.16 , pp. 365
    • Hausman, J.A.1
  • 42
    • 0345985833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The bell doctrine: Application in telecommunications, electricity, and other network industries
    • For a recent review praising the MFJ, see Paul L. Joskow & Roger G. Noll, The Bell Doctrine: Application in Telecommunications, Electricity, and Other Network Industries, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1249, 1271-78 (1999). Joskow and Noll, however, conspicuously fail to consider the MFJ's deleterious effect on consumer welfare.
    • (1999) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 1249
    • Joskow, P.L.1    Noll, R.G.2
  • 43
    • 84923728087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., MACAVOY, supra note 17, at 31-34
    • See, e.g., MACAVOY, supra note 17, at 31-34.
  • 44
    • 84923728086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • All other ILECs, except the BOCs, have been permitted to provide long-distance service. Indeed, SNET, the local telephone company in Connecticut, which for historic reasons was not considered a BOC by the MFJ, has been quite successful in providing long-distance service at generally lower prices than AT&T has offered to Connecticut residential customers
    • All other ILECs, except the BOCs, have been permitted to provide long-distance service. Indeed, SNET, the local telephone company in Connecticut, which for historic reasons was not considered a BOC by the MFJ, has been quite successful in providing long-distance service at generally lower prices than AT&T has offered to Connecticut residential customers.
  • 45
    • 84923728085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 271(c)(2)(B) (West Supp. 1999)
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 271(c)(2)(B) (West Supp. 1999).
  • 46
    • 0038920061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare PETER W. HUBER ET AL., THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS ACT OF 1996: SPECIAL REPORT 32-33 (1996) (describing the requirements a Bell company must now meet to receive interexchange relief under the Act), with MACAVOY, supra note 17, at 190-200 (describing companies' experiences with the interLATA restrictions before the Telecommunications Act of 1996).
    • (1996) The Telecommunications Act of 1996: Special Report , pp. 32-33
    • Huber, P.W.1
  • 47
    • 84923728084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 271(c)(1)(A). Alternatively, if the state PUC had approved a generic interconnection plan offered by the RBOC, but the RBOC had received no request for interconnection within the first seven months after enactment of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, then the RBOC would have been entitled to be evaluated under the checklist. See id. § 27(c)(1)(B)
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 271(c)(1)(A). Alternatively, if the state PUC had approved a generic interconnection plan offered by the RBOC, but the RBOC had received no request for interconnection within the first seven months after enactment of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, then the RBOC would have been entitled to be evaluated under the checklist. See id. § 27(c)(1)(B).
  • 48
    • 84923728083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 271(d)(3)
    • See id. § 271(d)(3).
  • 49
    • 84923728082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commands to honor the "public interest" pervade the Telecommunications Act of 1996. It has long been recognized that advancing the "public interest" is the touchstone of telecommunications regulation in the United States. See generally sources cited supra note 12
    • Commands to honor the "public interest" pervade the Telecommunications Act of 1996. It has long been recognized that advancing the "public interest" is the touchstone of telecommunications regulation in the United States. See generally sources cited supra note 12.
  • 50
    • 84923728081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 271(d)(6)(B)
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 271(d)(6)(B).
  • 51
    • 84923728080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Using a long-distance elasticity estimate of -0.723 and an economic model of AT&T's price leadership in residential long-distance service, one of us has computed that BOC entry will decrease long-distance prices by at least 15% to 25%. See Declaration of Professor Jerry A. Hausman, Second Application by BellSouth Corporation et al. for Provision of In-Region, InterLATA Services in Louisiana, FCC 98-121, ¶ 15 (filed July 9, 1998) (on file with The Yale Law Journal).
    • The Yale Law Journal
  • 52
    • 84923728079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MACAVOY, supra note 17, at 176
    • MACAVOY, supra note 17, at 176.
  • 53
    • 84923728078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 47 U.S.C.A. §§ 251-252. In addition, Congress abolished any remaining legal barriers to entry: "No State or local statute or regulation, or other State or local legal requirement, may prohibit or have the effect of prohibiting the ability of any entity to provide any interstate or intrastate telecommunications service." Id. § 253(a)
    • 47 U.S.C.A. §§ 251-252. In addition, Congress abolished any remaining legal barriers to entry: "No State or local statute or regulation, or other State or local legal requirement, may prohibit or have the effect of prohibiting the ability of any entity to provide any interstate or intrastate telecommunications service." Id. § 253(a).
  • 54
    • 84923728077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If the entrant and the ILEC cannot negotiate mutually acceptable terms of interconnection, resale, or unbundling, then the Telecommunications Act directs the state PUC to resolve the dispute through compulsory arbitration. See id. § 252(b). By the fall of 1996, entrants and ILECs were unable to reach any voluntary agreements on the pricing of resale and unbundled network elements. As a consequence, hundreds of arbitration proceedings began in the fall of 1996. In most cases, each arbitration was a one-on-one proceeding between a single entrant and the ILEC
    • If the entrant and the ILEC cannot negotiate mutually acceptable terms of interconnection, resale, or unbundling, then the Telecommunications Act directs the state PUC to resolve the dispute through compulsory arbitration. See id. § 252(b). By the fall of 1996, entrants and ILECs were unable to reach any voluntary agreements on the pricing of resale and unbundled network elements. As a consequence, hundreds of arbitration proceedings began in the fall of 1996. In most cases, each arbitration was a one-on-one proceeding between a single entrant and the ILEC.
  • 55
    • 84923728076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 251(f)
    • See id. § 251(f).
  • 56
    • 84923728075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Section 251(c)(3) provides that "[i]n addition to the duties contained in subsection [251(b)], each incumbent local exchange carrier" has certain other duties, including: (3) Unbundled access. - The duty to provide, to any requesting telecommunications carrier for the provision of a telecommunications service, nondiscriminatory access to network elements on an unbundled basis at any technically feasible point on rates, terms, and conditions that are just, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory in accordance with the terms and conditions of the agreement and the requirements of this section and section 252 of this title. An incumbent local exchange carrier shall provide such unbundled network elements in a manner that allows requesting carriers to combine such elements in order to provide such telecommunications service. Id. § 251(c)(3).
  • 57
    • 84923728074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 251(d)(2)
    • Id. § 251(d)(2).
  • 58
    • 84923728073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, pmbl., 110 Stat. 56, 56
    • Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, pmbl., 110 Stat. 56, 56.
  • 59
    • 84923728072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H.R. REP. NO. 104-458, at 1 (1996)
    • H.R. REP. NO. 104-458, at 1 (1996).
  • 60
    • 84923728071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 47 U.S.C.A. § 251(d)(2)(A)
    • 47 U.S.C.A. § 251(d)(2)(A).
  • 61
    • 84923728070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499 (1996)
    • First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499 (1996).
  • 62
    • 84923728069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 282. An ILEC's signaling protocols that adhere to Bellcore standards, however, were not proprietary in the FCC's view because they are industry-wide protocols. See id. ¶ 481
    • Id. ¶ 282. An ILEC's signaling protocols that adhere to Bellcore standards, however, were not proprietary in the FCC's view because they are industry-wide protocols. See id. ¶ 481.
  • 63
    • 84923728068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 282
    • Id. ¶ 282.
  • 64
    • 84923728067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 65
    • 84923728066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 283
    • Id. ¶ 283.
  • 66
    • 84923728065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 11.
    • Id. ¶ 11.
  • 68
    • 84923728064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 285
    • Id. ¶ 285.
  • 69
    • 84923728063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ¶ 366 (to have been codified at 47 C.F.R. § 51.319)
    • See id. ¶ 366 (to have been codified at 47 C.F.R. § 51.319).
  • 70
    • 0039097983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 4th ed. (explaining Chevron)
    • See Chevron U.S.A. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, 467 U.S. 837, 843-44 (1984) (giving "controlling weight" to regulations devised by agencies pursuant to a congressional grant of authority "unless they are arbitrary, capricious or manifestly contrary to the statute"). See generally STEPHEN G. BREYER ET AL., ADMINISTRATIVE LAW AND REGULATORY POLICY: PROBLEMS, TEXT, AND CASES 256-57 (4th ed. 1999) (explaining Chevron).
    • (1999) Administrative Law and Regulatory Policy: Problems, Text, and Cases , pp. 256-257
    • Breyer, S.G.1
  • 71
    • 84923728062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Iowa Utils. Bd. v. FCC, 120 F.3d 753, 810-12 (8th Cir. 1997), rev'd in part and aff'd in part sub nom. AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721 (1999)
    • See Iowa Utils. Bd. v. FCC, 120 F.3d 753, 810-12 (8th Cir. 1997), rev'd in part and aff'd in part sub nom. AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721 (1999).
  • 72
    • 84923728061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FCC v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 118 S. Ct. 683 (1998). The other grounds for appeal included the fact that state PUCs, and not the FCC, had jurisdiction to promulgate these rules, and that the substantive pricing standards that the FCC had adopted were so low as to effect an uncompensated taking of the property of ILECs in violation of the Fifth Amendment
    • See FCC v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 118 S. Ct. 683 (1998). The other grounds for appeal included the fact that state PUCs, and not the FCC, had jurisdiction to promulgate these rules, and that the substantive pricing standards that the FCC had adopted were so low as to effect an uncompensated taking of the property of ILECs in violation of the Fifth Amendment.
  • 73
    • 84923728060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 119 S. Ct. 721
    • 119 S. Ct. 721.
  • 74
    • 84923728059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 251(c)(3) (West Supp. 1999). The Court, however, affirmed other aspects of the First Report and Order, including provisions relating to the pricing of unbundled network elements. See Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 732-33
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 251(c)(3) (West Supp. 1999). The Court, however, affirmed other aspects of the First Report and Order, including provisions relating to the pricing of unbundled network elements. See Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 732-33.
  • 75
    • 84923728058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 736
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 736.
  • 76
    • 84923728057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 726
    • Id. at 726.
  • 77
    • 84923728056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 738
    • Id. at 738.
  • 78
    • 84923728055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 734
    • Id. at 734.
  • 79
    • 84923728054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 734-35 (emphasis added) (citation omitted)
    • Id. at 734-35 (emphasis added) (citation omitted).
  • 80
    • 84923728053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 735 (quoting First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶ 283 (1996))
    • Id. at 735 (quoting First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶ 283 (1996)).
  • 81
    • 84923728052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (quoting First Report and Order, 11 F.C.C.R. ¶ 285 (emphasis added by the Court)) (citation omitted)
    • Id. (quoting First Report and Order, 11 F.C.C.R. ¶ 285 (emphasis added by the Court)) (citation omitted).
  • 82
    • 84923728051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 83
    • 84923728050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 84
    • 84923728049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 85
    • 84923728048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 86
    • 84923728047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 739 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • See id. at 739 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 87
    • 84923728046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 735 n.11 (quoting id. at 739 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)) (citation omitted)
    • Id. at 735 n.11 (quoting id. at 739 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)) (citation omitted).
  • 88
    • 84923728045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (quoting id. at 740 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)) (citation omitted)
    • Id. (quoting id. at 740 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)) (citation omitted).
  • 89
    • 84923728044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Economic profits are zero when total revenues equal total costs, inclusive of a competitive return on capital." SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 313
    • "Economic profits are zero when total revenues equal total costs, inclusive of a competitive return on capital." SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 313.
  • 90
    • 0003740491 scopus 로고
    • Economic rent is a return to a factor of production in excess of the payment that is necessary to prevent that factor from being redeployed to an alternative use. See, e.g., PAUL MILGROM & JOHN ROBERTS, ECONOMICS, ORGANIZATION AND MANAGEMENT 269 (1992); Armen A. Alchian, Rent, in 4 THE NEW PALGRAVE: A DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS 141 (John Eatwell et al. eds., 1987).
    • (1992) Economics, Organization and Management , pp. 269
    • Milgrom, P.1    Roberts, J.2
  • 91
    • 0011755520 scopus 로고
    • Rent
    • John Eatwell et al. eds.
    • Economic rent is a return to a factor of production in excess of the payment that is necessary to prevent that factor from being redeployed to an alternative use. See, e.g., PAUL MILGROM & JOHN ROBERTS, ECONOMICS, ORGANIZATION AND MANAGEMENT 269 (1992); Armen A. Alchian, Rent, in 4 THE NEW PALGRAVE: A DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS 141 (John Eatwell et al. eds., 1987).
    • (1987) The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics , vol.4 , pp. 141
    • Alchian, A.A.1
  • 92
    • 84923728043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 735
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 735.
  • 93
    • 84923728042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 94
    • 84923728041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 736 (quoting First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶ 278 (1996) (emphasis added by the Court)); see also id. ("[W]e conclude that the statute does not require us to interpret the 'impairment' standard in a way that would significantly diminish the obligation imposed by section 251(c)(3)." (quoting First Report and Order, 11 F.C.C.R. ¶ 286))
    • Id. at 736 (quoting First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶ 278 (1996) (emphasis added by the Court)); see also id. ("[W]e conclude that the statute does not require us to interpret the 'impairment' standard in a way that would significantly diminish the obligation imposed by section 251(c)(3)." (quoting First Report and Order, 11 F.C.C.R. ¶ 286)).
  • 95
    • 84923728040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 96
    • 84923728039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (quoting Iowa Utils. Bd. v. FCC, 120 F.3d at 810 (emphasis added by the Court))
    • Id. (quoting Iowa Utils. Bd. v. FCC, 120 F.3d at 810 (emphasis added by the Court)).
  • 97
    • 84923728038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. (citation omitted). As evidence of that erroneous premise, Justice Scalia quoted the following language from the Local Competition First Report and Order: "To give effect to both sections 251(c)(3) and 251(d)(2), we conclude that the proprietary and impairment standards in section 251(d)(2) grant us the authority to refrain from requiring incumbent LECs to provide all network elements for which it is technically feasible to provide access on an unbundled basis." Id. (quoting First Report and Order, 11 F.C.C.R. ¶ 279).
  • 98
    • 84923728037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 99
    • 84923728036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Justice Thomas concurred with this part of the Court's decision but wrote a separate opinion, joined by Chief Justice Rehnquist and Justice Breyer, which dissented from other parts of the Court's decision that are not pertinent to our discussion. See id. at 741-46 (Thomas, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • Id. Justice Thomas concurred with this part of the Court's decision but wrote a separate opinion, joined by Chief Justice Rehnquist and Justice Breyer, which dissented from other parts of the Court's decision that are not pertinent to our discussion. See id. at 741-46 (Thomas, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 100
    • 84923728035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 746-54 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part). Much of Justice Breyer's opinion was devoted to his dissent from the Court's holding concerning the FCC's jurisdiction to promulgate pricing rules that were binding on the states
    • Id. at 746-54 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part). Much of Justice Breyer's opinion was devoted to his dissent from the Court's holding concerning the FCC's jurisdiction to promulgate pricing rules that were binding on the states.
  • 101
    • 84923728034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 746, For historical analysis, Justice Breyer relied upon Justice Thomas's opinion
    • Id. at 746, For historical analysis, Justice Breyer relied upon Justice Thomas's opinion.
  • 102
    • 84923728033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 103
    • 0004266101 scopus 로고
    • Justice Breyer, of course, has made his own contributions to that scholarly literature. See, e.g., STEPHEN G. BREYER, REGULATION AND ITS REFORM (1982); Breyer, supra note 9.
    • (1982) Regulation and its Reform
    • Breyer, S.G.1
  • 104
    • 84923728032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 746-47 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • See Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 746-47 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 105
    • 84923728031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 747.
    • See id. at 747.
  • 106
    • 84923728030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 107
    • 84923728029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (citing 47 U.S.C.A. §§ 251(c)(2)-(4), 253(a) (West Supp. 1999))
    • Id. (citing 47 U.S.C.A. §§ 251(c)(2)-(4), 253(a) (West Supp. 1999)).
  • 108
    • 84923728028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 748
    • Id. at 748.
  • 109
    • 84923728027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 110
    • 84923728026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Justice O'Connor did not participate in the case. See id. at 721.
    • Justice O'Connor did not participate in the case. See id. at 721.
  • 111
    • 84923728025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 112
    • 84923728024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 749-50 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 749-50 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 113
    • 84923728023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 751 (citing First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶¶ 672-715 (1996))
    • Id. at 751 (citing First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶¶ 672-715 (1996)).
  • 114
    • 84923728022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 115
    • 84923728021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ("Nor can the FCC successfully argue that the Act requires the particular rate-setting system that its regulations contain.").
    • See id. ("Nor can the FCC successfully argue that the Act requires the particular rate-setting system that its regulations contain.").
  • 116
    • 84923728020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 117
    • 84923728019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 118
    • 0041646943 scopus 로고
    • rev. ed.
    • Id. at 752. With respect to the "the FCC's decision to prohibit use" of the efficient component-pricing rule (ECPR), Justice Breyer noted: "The FCC rejected that [ECPR] system, but in doing so it did not claim, nor did its reasoning support the claim, that the use of such a system would be arbitrary or unreasonable." Id. Of "the FCC's decision to forbid the use" of Ramsey pricing, Justice Breyer wrote: "Many experts strongly prefer the use of such a system [and some argue] that the FCC's prohibition of Ramsey pricing will 'minimize rather than maximize consumer welfare.' The FCC disfavors Ramsey pricing, but it does not explain why a contrary judgment would conflict with the statute or otherwise be arbitrary or unreasonable." Id. (quoting Sidak & Spulber, supra note 4, at 1109, and citing 1 ALFRED E. KAHN, THE ECONOMICS OF REGULATION: PRINCIPLES AND INSTITUTIONS 137-41 (rev. ed. 1988)).
    • (1988) The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions , pp. 137-141
    • Kahn, A.E.1
  • 119
    • 84923728018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 753
    • Id. at 753.
  • 120
    • 84923728017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 121
    • 84923728016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 122
    • 84923728015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 123
    • 84923728014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ("[T]he Act's language itself suggests some such limits.")
    • See id. ("[T]he Act's language itself suggests some such limits.").
  • 124
    • 84923728013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 126
    • 84923728012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 754
    • Id. at 754.
  • 128
    • 84923728011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 754 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 754 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 129
    • 84923728010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 130
    • 84923728009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 131
    • 84923728008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 132
    • 84923728007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 739 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • Id. at 739 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 133
    • 84923728006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Justice Thomas wrote a dissenting opinion as well. See supra note 87
    • Justice Thomas wrote a dissenting opinion as well. See supra note 87.
  • 134
    • 84923728005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 739 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 739 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 135
    • 84923728004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 136
    • 84923728003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 740
    • Id. at 740.
  • 137
    • 84923728002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If I want to replace a light bulb, I would be within an ordinary and fair meaning of the word "necessary" to say that a stepladder is "necessary" to install the bulb, even though I could stand instead on a chair, a milk can, or eight volumes of Gibbon. I could just as easily say that the want of a ladder would "impair" my ability to install the bulb under the same circumstances. Id. at 739. For Justice Scalia's comments, see supra text accompanying notes 75-77
    • If I want to replace a light bulb, I would be within an ordinary and fair meaning of the word "necessary" to say that a stepladder is "necessary" to install the bulb, even though I could stand instead on a chair, a milk can, or eight volumes of Gibbon. I could just as easily say that the want of a ladder would "impair" my ability to install the bulb under the same circumstances. Id. at 739. For Justice Scalia's comments, see supra text accompanying notes 75-77.
  • 138
    • 84923728001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3.
  • 139
    • 84923728000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 14
    • Id. ¶ 14.
  • 140
    • 84923727999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ¶¶ 16-23
    • See id. ¶¶ 16-23.
  • 141
    • 0043149794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A boom for the baby bells?
    • Nov. 1
    • See Steve Rosenbush, A Boom for the Baby Bells?, BUS. WK., Nov. 1, 1999, at 47.
    • (1999) Bus. Wk.
    • Rosenbush, S.1
  • 142
    • 84923727998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hausman, supra note 12
    • See Hausman, supra note 12.
  • 143
    • 84923727997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BAUMÖL & SIDAK, supra note 11, at 26
    • BAUMÖL & SIDAK, supra note 11, at 26.
  • 144
    • 84923727996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NCAA v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85, 107 (1984); Reiter v. Sonotone Corp., 442 U.S. 330, 343 (1979)
    • NCAA v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85, 107 (1984); Reiter v. Sonotone Corp., 442 U.S. 330, 343 (1979).
  • 145
    • 84923727995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BAUMOL & SIDAK, supra note 11, at 26-27
    • See BAUMOL & SIDAK, supra note 11, at 26-27.
  • 146
    • 84923727994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 754 (1999) (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • AT&T v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 754 (1999) (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 147
    • 84923727993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced Telecommunications Capability to All Americans in a Reasonable and Timely Fashion, 14 F.C.C.R. 2398, app. ¶ 13 (1999)
    • See Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced Telecommunications Capability to All Americans in a Reasonable and Timely Fashion, 14 F.C.C.R. 2398, app. ¶ 13 (1999).
  • 148
    • 84923727992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Roland Mach. Co. v. Dresser Indus., 749 F.2d 380, 395 (7th Cir. 1984) (citing Product Liab. Ins. Agency v. Crum & Forster Ins. Cos., 682 F.2d 660, 663-65 (7th Cir. 1982) (Posner, J.))
    • Roland Mach. Co. v. Dresser Indus., 749 F.2d 380, 395 (7th Cir. 1984) (citing Product Liab. Ins. Agency v. Crum & Forster Ins. Cos., 682 F.2d 660, 663-65 (7th Cir. 1982) (Posner, J.)).
  • 149
    • 84923727991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Marrese v. American Academy of Orthopaedic Surgeons, 706 F.2d 1488, 1497 (7th Cir. 1983) (citing University Life Ins. Co. of America v. Unimarc Ltd., 699 F.2d 846, 853 (7th Cir. 1983) (Posner, J.); Products Liab., 682 F.2d at 663-64). In Products Liability, Chief Judge Posner wrote: "The consumer does not care how many sellers of a particular good or service there are; he cares only that there be enough to assure him a competitive price and quality." Products Liab., 682 F.2d at 664. In another antitrust decision the following year, he wrote that "competition in the antitrust sense signifies not the preservation of all existing competitors but the maintenance of a sufficient number to assure that consumers get the best possible quality of product at the lowest possible price." University Life, 699 F.2d at 852 (citing Products Liab., 682 F.2d at 663-64).
  • 150
    • 84923727990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interface Group v. Massachusetts Port Auth., 816 F.2d 9, 10 (1st Cir. 1987) (citation omitted)
    • Interface Group v. Massachusetts Port Auth., 816 F.2d 9, 10 (1st Cir. 1987) (citation omitted).
  • 151
    • 84923727989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 506 U.S. 447 (1993)
    • 506 U.S. 447 (1993).
  • 152
    • 84923727988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 458 (citations omitted)
    • Id. at 458 (citations omitted).
  • 153
    • 84923727987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 429 U.S. 477 (1977)
    • 429 U.S. 477 (1977).
  • 154
    • 84923727986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 489 (emphasis omitted). For similar statements of the Court following, or foreshadowing, the Brunswick articulation of "antitrust injury," see Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328, 338-39 (1990); Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colo., 479 U.S. 104, 116-17 (1986); Associated Gen. Contractors v. California State Council of Carpenters, 459 U.S. 519, 539-40 (1983); Blue Shield v. McCready, 457 U.S. 465, 483 n.19 (1982); J. Truett Payne Co. v. Chrysler Motors Corp., 451 U.S. 557, 562 (1981); and Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 320 (1962).
  • 155
    • 84923727985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 6 (quoting First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶¶ 282, 285 (1996)) (emphasis added)
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 6 (quoting First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶¶ 282, 285 (1996)) (emphasis added).
  • 156
    • 84923726115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ¶ 20
    • See id. ¶ 20.
  • 157
    • 84923726114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 27
    • Id. ¶ 27.
  • 158
    • 84923726113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 17 (emphasis added)
    • Id. ¶ 17 (emphasis added).
  • 159
    • 84923726112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 47 U.S.C.A. § 251(d)(2)(B) (West Supp. 1999)
    • 47 U.S.C.A. § 251(d)(2)(B) (West Supp. 1999).
  • 160
    • 84923726111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Marrese v. American Academy of Orthopaedic Surgeons, 706 F.2d 1488, 1497 (7th Cir. 1983)
    • Marrese v. American Academy of Orthopaedic Surgeons, 706 F.2d 1488, 1497 (7th Cir. 1983).
  • 161
    • 84923726110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 162
    • 84923726109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1495-96
    • Id. at 1495-96.
  • 163
    • 84923726108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • University Life Ins. Co. of Am. v. Unimarc Ltd., 699 F.2d 846, 853 (7th Cir. 1983)
    • University Life Ins. Co. of Am. v. Unimarc Ltd., 699 F.2d 846, 853 (7th Cir. 1983).
  • 164
    • 84923726107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (quoting WILLIAM SHAKESPEARE, HAMLET, act 5, sc. 2)
    • Id. (quoting WILLIAM SHAKESPEARE, HAMLET, act 5, sc. 2).
  • 165
    • 84923726106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 754 (1999) (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • AT&T v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 754 (1999) (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 166
    • 84923726105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 735
    • Id. at 735.
  • 167
    • 84923726104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., BAUMÖL & SIDAK, supra note 11, at 7, 9, 34
    • See, e.g., BAUMÖL & SIDAK, supra note 11, at 7, 9, 34.
  • 168
    • 84923726103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶ 682 (1996)
    • See First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶ 682 (1996).
  • 169
    • 84923726102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 359
    • See SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 359.
  • 170
    • 0347563470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Givings, takings, and the fallacy of forward-looking costs
    • Id. at 565; see also J. Gregory Sidak & Daniel F. Spulber, Givings, Takings, and the Fallacy of Forward-Looking Costs, 72 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1068, 1163 (1997) (criticizing the FCC's use of TELRIC pricing).
    • (1997) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 1068
    • Sidak, J.G.1    Spulber, D.F.2
  • 171
    • 0043149788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The CLEC market: Prospects, problems, and opportunities
    • Nov. 1
    • The recent consolidations in the CLEC industry (for example, the merger of MCI and WorldCom) would serve as a countervailing source of market power in any voluntary negotiation. For a review of the recent mergers in the CLEC industry, see Sterling Perrin, The CLEC Market: Prospects, Problems, and Opportunities, TELECOMMUNICATIONS INT'L, Nov. 1, 1998, at 41.
    • (1998) Telecommunications Int'l , pp. 41
    • Perrin, S.1
  • 172
    • 84923726101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 271(c)(2)(B) (West Supp. 1999)
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 271(c)(2)(B) (West Supp. 1999).
  • 173
    • 84923726100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 751 (1999) (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 751 (1999) (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 174
    • 0040773649 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Telecommunications: Building the infrastructure for value creation
    • Stephen P. Bradley & Richard L. Nolan eds.
    • See SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 403-26, 545-51. For a discussion of the important gains that have been realized by innovation in the Internet, see Jerry A. Hausman, Telecommunications: Building the Infrastructure for Value Creation, in SENSE AND RESPOND 63 (Stephen P. Bradley & Richard L. Nolan eds., 1998).
    • (1998) Sense and Respond , pp. 63
    • Hausman, J.A.1
  • 176
    • 85015692260 scopus 로고
    • The pricing of options and corporate liabilities
    • See AVINASH K. DIXIT & ROBERT S. PINDYCK, INVESTMENT UNDER UNCERTAINTY (1994); Fisher Black & Myron Scholes, The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, 81 J. POL. ECON. 637 (1973).
    • (1973) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.81 , pp. 637
    • Black, F.1    Scholes, M.2
  • 177
  • 179
    • 84923726099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of particular cases in which regulations were estimated to cost U.S. consumers and businesses billions of dollars because of regulatory delay of new services, see generally Hausman, supra note 12
    • For a discussion of particular cases in which regulations were estimated to cost U.S. consumers and businesses billions of dollars because of regulatory delay of new services, see generally Hausman, supra note 12.
  • 180
    • 0001299326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Anatomy of a failure: Picturephone revisited
    • See, e.g., A. Michael Noll, Anatomy of a Failure: Picturephone Revisited, 16 TELECOMMUNICATIONS POL'Y 307 (1992); A. Michael Noll, Conspicuous (Lack of) Consumption, TELE.COM. Feb. 8, 1999, available in 1999 WL 18391710.
    • (1992) Telecommunications Pol'y , vol.16 , pp. 307
    • Noll, A.M.1
  • 181
    • 0001299326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • TELE.COM. Feb. 8, available in 1999 WL 18391710
    • See, e.g., A. Michael Noll, Anatomy of a Failure: Picturephone Revisited, 16 TELECOMMUNICATIONS POL'Y 307 (1992); A. Michael Noll, Conspicuous (Lack of) Consumption, TELE.COM. Feb. 8, 1999, available in 1999 WL 18391710.
    • (1999) Conspicuous (Lack of) Consumption
    • Noll, A.M.1
  • 182
    • 0141715952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulation by TSLRIC: Economic effects on investment and innovation
    • Mar.
    • See Jerry Hausman, Regulation by TSLRIC: Economic Effects on Investment and Innovation, MULTIMEDIA UND RECHT, Mar. 1999, at 22, 22; Hausman, supra note 12; see also SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 375.
    • (1999) Multimedia und Recht
    • Hausman, J.1
  • 183
    • 84923726098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As noted in Part III, Justice Breyer warned of this perverse outcome. See supra text accompanying notes 113-114
    • As noted in Part III, Justice Breyer warned of this perverse outcome. See supra text accompanying notes 113-114.
  • 184
    • 84923726097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Memorandum Opinion and Order, and Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, Deployment of Wireline Services Offering Advanced Telecommunications Capability, 13 F.C.C.R. 24,012, ¶¶ 95-100 (1998)
    • See Memorandum Opinion and Order, and Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, Deployment of Wireline Services Offering Advanced Telecommunications Capability, 13 F.C.C.R. 24,012, ¶¶ 95-100 (1998).
  • 185
    • 84923726096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 3
    • See Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 3.
  • 186
    • 84923726095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. This passage is the only reference to investment or innovation in the entire Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
    • Id. This passage is the only reference to investment or innovation in the entire Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking.
  • 187
    • 84923726094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ¶ 4
    • See id. ¶ 4.
  • 188
    • 84923726093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Local Competition (1 May 1997), No. 97-8, ¶ 74 (C.R.T.C.)
    • Local Competition (1 May 1997), No. 97-8, ¶ 74 (C.R.T.C.).
  • 189
    • 84923726092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 190
    • 84923726091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 410-12
    • See SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 410-12.
  • 191
    • 84923726090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The FCC requests commentators to provide an analysis of the effect of sunk costs in defining the "necessary" and "impair" standard. See Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 26
    • The FCC requests commentators to provide an analysis of the effect of sunk costs in defining the "necessary" and "impair" standard. See Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 26.
  • 192
    • 84923726089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 78-82
    • See SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 78-82.
  • 193
    • 84923726088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 26
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 26.
  • 194
    • 84923726087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶ 641 n.1562 (1996)
    • See First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶ 641 n.1562 (1996).
  • 195
    • 84923726086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hausman, supra note 168, at 24-26; Hausman, supra note 12, at 26-35
    • See Hausman, supra note 168, at 24-26; Hausman, supra note 12, at 26-35.
  • 196
    • 84923726085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, digital subscriber line (DSL) technology may allow for broadband to be offered over ILEC loops. The point is that the technological evolution of competition is sufficiently uncertain to make investment in sunk-cost elements equally uncertain
    • Of course, digital subscriber line (DSL) technology may allow for broadband to be offered over ILEC loops. The point is that the technological evolution of competition is sufficiently uncertain to make investment in sunk-cost elements equally uncertain.
  • 197
    • 0004125846 scopus 로고
    • 3d ed.
    • A technical caveat is necessary here. In the case of an isoelastic demand curve, such as one associated with a Cobb-Douglas utility function, the price elasticity of demand is constant at all points along the (nonlinear) demand curve. Cf. JAMES M. HENDERSON & RICHARD E. QUANDT, MICROECONOMIC THEORY: A MATHEMATICAL APPROACH 111-13 (3d ed. 1980) (discussing constant elasticity of substitution of the Cobb-Douglas production function). Even in such a case of an isoelastic demand curve, however, it is still true that the FCC, by setting too low a price for the UNE, would suppress competitive supply of that element. As will become clear from our discussion infra Part V, such a regulatory distortion would make it more difficult for the ILEC to meet the "critical share" calculation, which would establish that the ILEC could not impair competition in the market for telecommunications services sold to end-users by declining to lease a particular network element to a CLEC at a TELRIC price.
    • (1980) Microeconomic Theory: A Mathematical Approach , pp. 111-113
    • Henderson, J.M.1    Quandt, R.E.2
  • 198
    • 84923726084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 404 (1956)
    • See United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 404 (1956).
  • 199
    • 0003401865 scopus 로고
    • In the Cellophane case, the government claimed that du Pont was exercising unilateral monopoly power over food wrappings. By allegedly increasing the price of Cellophane to monopoly levels, du Pont caused competitors to supply, and consumers to buy, other wrapping materials. The government claimed that such supply and demand substitution did not prove that Cellophane would exhibit significant cross-price elasticity at a competitive price. See RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW: AN ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE 127-28 (1976).
    • (1976) Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective , pp. 127-128
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 200
    • 84923726083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Time Warner Entertainment Co. v. FCC, 105 F.3d 723, 724 n.2 (D.C. Cir. 1997) (Williams, J., dissenting from the denial of rehearing in banc)
    • Time Warner Entertainment Co. v. FCC, 105 F.3d 723, 724 n.2 (D.C. Cir. 1997) (Williams, J., dissenting from the denial of rehearing in banc).
  • 201
    • 84923726082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • visited Nov. 22
    • For summaries of pending FCC spectrum auctions, see (visited Nov. 22, 1999).
    • (1999)
  • 202
    • 84923726081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 197, 218-221
    • See infra text accompanying notes 197, 218-221.
  • 203
    • 84923726080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The following discussion directly responds to the FCC's request for "comment on the significance of the essential facilities standard under section 251(d)(2)." Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 21; see also id. ¶¶ 22-23. Of necessity, our discussion here treats in summary fashion a topic that merits lengthier analysis. For a thorough and up-to-date examination, see generally Lipsky & Sidak, supra note 4
    • The following discussion directly responds to the FCC's request for "comment on the significance of the essential facilities standard under section 251(d)(2)." Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 21; see also id. ¶¶ 22-23. Of necessity, our discussion here treats in summary fashion a topic that merits lengthier analysis. For a thorough and up-to-date examination, see generally Lipsky & Sidak, supra note 4.
  • 204
    • 84923726079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 708 F.2d 1081 (7th Cir. 1983)
    • 708 F.2d 1081 (7th Cir. 1983).
  • 205
    • 84923726078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1132-33
    • Id. at 1132-33.
  • 206
    • 84923726077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 753 (1999) (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • See AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 753 (1999) (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 207
    • 84923726076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 734-35; id. at 753 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • See id. at 734-35; id. at 753 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 208
    • 84923726075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lipsky & Sidak, supra note 4
    • See Lipsky & Sidak, supra note 4.
  • 209
    • 84923726074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 753 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 753 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 210
    • 84923726073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 735 n.11; id. at 739 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part); supra text accompanying note 76
    • See id. at 735 n.11; id. at 739 (Souter, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part); supra text accompanying note 76.
  • 211
    • 84923726072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Illinois ex rel. Hartigan v. Panhandle E. Pipe Line Co., 730 F. Supp. 826, 866 (C.D. Ill. 1990) (defining the concept of "derived demand"); United States v. Standard Oil Co., 155 F. Supp. 121, 146 (S.D.N.Y. 1957) ("The demand for ocean tankers is a derived demand reflecting changes in the demand for petroleum and its products. An increase in the demand for crude and its products would ordinarily bring an increased demand for ocean tankers and an increase in ocean tanker rates."). The former Interstate Commerce Commission employed such an analysis of demand and supply substitution in the 1980s when reforming rate-regulation principles for rail transportation supplied to "captive shippers." See Burlington N.R.R. v. ICC, 985 F.2d 589, 595-99 (D.C. Cir. 1993).
  • 212
    • 84923726071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Those decisions are surveyed in Lipsky & Sidak, supra note 4, at 1191-93
    • Those decisions are surveyed in Lipsky & Sidak, supra note 4, at 1191-93.
  • 213
    • 0006608377 scopus 로고
    • Essential facilities: An epithet in need of limiting principles
    • See Phillip E. Areeda, Essential Facilities: An Epithet in Need of Limiting Principles, 58 ANTITRUST L.J. 841 (1989) (arguing that no Supreme Court case has provided a consistent rationale for the doctrine or has explored either the social costs and benefits or the administrative costs of requiring the creator of an asset to share it with a rival); Donald I. Baker, Compulsory Access to Network Joint Ventures Under the Sherman Act: Rules or Roulette?, 1993 UTAH L. REV. 999 (arguing that the core conceptual problem with compulsory access orders is that mandating cooperation among businesses is futile); Lipsky & Sidak, supra note 4, at 1191-93.
    • (1989) Antitrust L.J. , vol.58 , pp. 841
    • Areeda, P.E.1
  • 214
    • 0039538995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compulsory access to network joint ventures under the Sherman act: Rules or roulette?
    • See Phillip E. Areeda, Essential Facilities: An Epithet in Need of Limiting Principles, 58 ANTITRUST L.J. 841 (1989) (arguing that no Supreme Court case has provided a consistent rationale for the doctrine or has explored either the social costs and benefits or the administrative costs of requiring the creator of an asset to share it with a rival); Donald I. Baker, Compulsory Access to Network Joint Ventures Under the Sherman Act: Rules or Roulette?, 1993 UTAH L. REV. 999 (arguing that the core conceptual problem with compulsory access orders is that mandating cooperation among businesses is futile); Lipsky & Sidak, supra note 4, at 1191-93.
    • Utah L. Rev. , vol.1993 , pp. 999
    • Baker, D.I.1
  • 215
    • 84923726070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 753-54 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)
    • See Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. at 753-54 (Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 216
    • 84923726069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For proprietary network elements, the statutory requirement is conjunctive: "necessary . . . and . . . impair." 47 U.S.C.A. § 251(d)(2) (West Supp. 1999) (emphasis added)
    • For proprietary network elements, the statutory requirement is conjunctive: "necessary . . . and . . . impair." 47 U.S.C.A. § 251(d)(2) (West Supp. 1999) (emphasis added).
  • 217
    • 84923726068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 218
    • 84923726067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3 (separate statement of Commissioner Powell) ("I disagree sharply . . . that we should designate the same elements of the incumbent's network for unbundling of every region of the nation.")
    • Cf. Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3 (separate statement of Commissioner Powell) ("I disagree sharply . . . that we should designate the same elements of the incumbent's network for unbundling of every region of the nation.").
  • 219
    • 84923726066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ¶ 14
    • See id. ¶ 14.
  • 220
    • 84923726065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 221
    • 84923726064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Memorandum Opinion and Order, Applications of NYNEX Corp., Transferor, and Bell Atlantic Corp., Transferee, for Consent to Transfer Control of NYNEX Corp. and Its Subsidiaries, 12 F.C.C.R. 19,985, ¶¶ 49-57 (1997)
    • See, e.g., Memorandum Opinion and Order, Applications of NYNEX Corp., Transferor, and Bell Atlantic Corp., Transferee, for Consent to Transfer Control of NYNEX Corp. and Its Subsidiaries, 12 F.C.C.R. 19,985, ¶¶ 49-57 (1997).
  • 222
    • 0347722915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cyberjam: The law and economics of internet congestion of the telephone network
    • See, e.g., J. Gregory Sidak & Daniel F. Spulber, Cyberjam: The Law and Economics of Internet Congestion of the Telephone Network, 21 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 327, 336 (1998).
    • (1998) Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.21 , pp. 327
    • Sidak, J.G.1    Spulber, D.F.2
  • 224
    • 84923726063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 26
    • See Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 26.
  • 225
    • 84923726062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, the definition and geographical scope of the LATAs took account of customer density and its expected effect on long-distance competition. See KELLOGG ET AL., supra note 19, at 227-34
    • Indeed, the definition and geographical scope of the LATAs took account
  • 226
    • 84923726061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3 (separate statement of Commissioner Powell)
    • See Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3 (separate statement of Commissioner Powell).
  • 228
    • 84923726060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552, 41,554-58 (1992)
    • See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552, 41,554-58 (1992).
  • 229
    • 84923726059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Memorandum Opinion and Order, Application of WorldCom, Inc. and MCI Communications Corporation for Transfer of Control of MCI Communications Corporation to WorldCom, Inc., 13 F.C.C.R. 18,025, ¶¶ 37-39 (1998)
    • See, e.g., Memorandum Opinion and Order, Application of WorldCom, Inc. and MCI Communications Corporation for Transfer of Control of MCI Communications Corporation to WorldCom, Inc., 13 F.C.C.R. 18,025, ¶¶ 37-39 (1998).
  • 230
    • 84923726058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. at 41,556
    • 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. at 41,556.
  • 231
    • 84923726057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This approach is similar to that found in economics textbooks, see, e.g., CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 15, at 801-07, and in the legal literature, see, e.g., Landes & Posner, supra note 14
    • This approach is similar to that found in economics textbooks, see, e.g., CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 15, at 801-07, and in the legal literature, see, e.g., Landes & Posner, supra note 14.
  • 232
    • 84923726056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 223-229
    • See infra text accompanying notes 223-229.
  • 233
    • 84923726055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 5 MARSHALL, supra note 15, at 381-93
    • See 5 MARSHALL, supra note 15, at 381-93.
  • 234
    • 84923726054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STIGLER, supra note 16, at 252
    • STIGLER, supra note 16, at 252.
  • 235
    • 84923726053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Marshall first derived those conditions for the two-factor case, given constant returns to scale. See LAYARD & WALTERS, supra note 15, at 259
    • Marshall first derived those conditions for the two-factor case, given constant returns to scale. See LAYARD & WALTERS, supra note 15, at 259.
  • 236
    • 0042648722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T test-markets mobile telephone as alternative to second home line
    • Nov. 12, available in 1998 WL 16348120
    • See Jennifer Files, AT&T Test-Markets Mobile Telephone as Alternative to Second Home Line, DALLAS MORNING NEWS, Nov. 12, 1998, available in 1998 WL 16348120.
    • (1998) Dallas Morning News
    • Files, J.1
  • 237
    • 84923712011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Switching grows up: The entire report
    • May 4
    • For a discussion of an example of competition in the switching industry, see Susan Breidenbach, Switching Grows up: The Entire Report, NETWORK WORLD (May 4, 1998) .
    • (1998) Network World
    • Breidenbach, S.1
  • 238
    • 84923726052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552, 41,556 (1992)
    • See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552, 41,556 (1992).
  • 239
    • 84923726051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 106th Cong.
    • For recent examples of the use of the price discrimination approach of merger guidelines by the FTC in the petroleum market, see The Exxon-Mobile Merger: Hearings Before the Subcommittee on Energy and Power of the Committee on Commerce, House of Representatives, 106th Cong. 9-16 (1999) (statement of William J. Baer, Director, Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission). For similar use of the Merger Guidelines with respect to the airline industry, see Comments of the Department of Justice, Joint Application of American Airlines, Inc. and British Airways PLC for Approval of and Antitrust Immunity for Alliance Agreement, No. OST-97-2058 (May 21, 1998), available in .
    • (1999) The Exxon-Mobile Merger: Hearings Before the Subcommittee on Energy and Power of the Committee on Commerce, House of Representatives , pp. 9-16
  • 240
    • 84923726050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. at 41,556. For convenience, we will use the five percent level, although for some purposes a 10% level may be more appropriate
    • 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. at 41,556. For convenience, we will use the five percent level, although for some purposes a 10% level may be more appropriate.
  • 241
    • 84923726049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demand elasticities and supply elasticities have long been recognized in law and economics as important to assessing the possibility of the exercise of unilateral market power. See, e.g., Landes & Posner, supra note 14
    • Demand elasticities and supply elasticities have long been recognized in law and economics as important to assessing the possibility of the exercise of unilateral market power. See, e.g., Landes & Posner, supra note 14.
  • 242
    • 84923726048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. at 41,556. The other type of monopoly power recognized by the Merger Guidelines is coordinated interaction among all suppliers of a product. Such a possibility is not relevant here because competitors of an ILEC have very different cost structures and product offerings. Moreover, it is far-fetched to imagine firms such as AT&T and MCI WorldCom attempting to achieve coordination interactions with the RBOCs and GTE
    • See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. at 41,556. The other type of monopoly power recognized by the Merger Guidelines is coordinated interaction among all suppliers of a product. Such a possibility is not relevant here because competitors of an ILEC have very different cost structures and product offerings. Moreover, it is far-fetched to imagine firms such as AT&T and MCI WorldCom attempting to achieve coordination interactions with the RBOCs and GTE.
  • 243
    • 84923726047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The own-price elasticity of demand is the percentage change in demand when the product's own price is raised by, say, 10%. The cross-price elasticity of demand is the percentage change in demand in response to the change in a competitor's price by, say, 10%. The two elasticity measures are related by the Slutsky equation in economic theory. The share-weighted (negative) own-price elasticity of demand equals the sum of the share-weighted cross-price elasticities of demand. See, e.g., HENDERSON & QUANDT, supra note 183, at 22-26.
  • 244
    • 21344441869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market definition under price discrimination
    • For a more extensive discussion of critical share, see Jerry A. Hausman et al., Market Definition Under Price Discrimination, 64 ANTITRUST L.J. 367 (1996).
    • (1996) Antitrust L.J. , vol.64 , pp. 367
    • Hausman, J.A.1
  • 245
    • 0042147831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What is wrong with American telecommunications?
    • Mar.
    • We have previously argued that the essential facilities doctrine identifies necessary, but not sufficient, conditions for mandatory unbundling at long-run incremental cost. See Hausman, supra note 168, at 22 ("Economic principles suggest that only the 'essential facility' elements of the network, which cannot be economically reproduced in the short run by new competitors, should be unbundled by regulation."); Paul W. MacAvoy & J. Gregory Sidak, What Is Wrong with American Telecommunications?, MULTIMEDIA UND RECHT, Mar. 1999, at 15, 15 ("Surely it is economic folly to mandate unbundling of any network element that is not 'essential' in the antitrust sense - that is, a network element that cannot be readily duplicated by the entrant or procured at competitive prices from the same vendors who supply the element to the incumbent firm subject to the unbundling obligation."); see also ROBERT W. CRANDALL, MANAGED COMPETITION IN U.S. TELECOMMUNICATIONS 17 (AEI-Brookings Joint Ctr. for Regulatory Studies Working Paper No. 99-1, 1999) ("[T]he decision to unbundle everything and to require its leasing at cost-based rates is wildly excessive."). For a similar conclusion by German scholars, applying American antitrust principles to German telecommunications law, see CHRISTOPH ENGEL & GÜNTER KNIEPS, DIE VORSCHRIFTEN DES TELEKOMMUNIKATIONSGESETZES ÜBER DEN ZUGANG ZU WESENTLICHEN LEISTUNGEN (1998); and Christoph Engel, Der Weg der Deutscher Telekommunikation in den Wettbewerb, MULTIMEDIA UND RECHT, Mar. 1999, at 7, 12-13. As noted earlier, Canada employs an essential facilities approach to mandatory unbundling. See supra text accompanying notes 174-175.
    • (1999) Multimedia und Recht
    • MacAvoy, P.W.1    Sidak, J.G.2
  • 246
    • 84923721732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We have previously argued that the essential facilities doctrine identifies necessary, but not sufficient, conditions for mandatory unbundling at long-run incremental cost. See Hausman, supra note 168, at 22 ("Economic principles suggest that only the 'essential facility' elements of the network, which cannot be economically reproduced in the short run by new competitors, should be unbundled by regulation."); Paul W. MacAvoy & J. Gregory Sidak, What Is Wrong with American Telecommunications?, MULTIMEDIA UND RECHT, Mar. 1999, at 15, 15 ("Surely it is economic folly to mandate unbundling of any network element that is not 'essential' in the antitrust sense - that is, a network element that cannot be readily duplicated by the entrant or procured at competitive prices from the same vendors who supply the element to the incumbent firm subject to the unbundling obligation."); see also ROBERT W. CRANDALL, MANAGED COMPETITION IN U.S. TELECOMMUNICATIONS 17 (AEI-Brookings Joint Ctr. for Regulatory Studies Working Paper No. 99-1, 1999) ("[T]he decision to unbundle everything and to require its leasing at cost-based rates is wildly excessive."). For a similar conclusion by German scholars, applying American antitrust principles to German telecommunications law, see CHRISTOPH ENGEL & GÜNTER KNIEPS, DIE VORSCHRIFTEN DES TELEKOMMUNIKATIONSGESETZES ÜBER DEN ZUGANG ZU WESENTLICHEN LEISTUNGEN (1998); and Christoph Engel, Der Weg der Deutscher Telekommunikation in den Wettbewerb, MULTIMEDIA UND RECHT, Mar. 1999, at 7, 12-13. As noted earlier, Canada employs an essential facilities approach to mandatory unbundling. See supra text accompanying notes 174-175.
    • Managed Competition in U.S. Telecommunications , pp. 17
    • Crandall, R.W.1
  • 247
    • 0039551561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We have previously argued that the essential facilities doctrine identifies necessary, but not sufficient, conditions for mandatory unbundling at long-run incremental cost. See Hausman, supra note 168, at 22 ("Economic principles suggest that only the 'essential facility' elements of the network, which cannot be economically reproduced in the short run by new competitors, should be unbundled by regulation."); Paul W. MacAvoy & J. Gregory Sidak, What Is Wrong with American Telecommunications?, MULTIMEDIA UND RECHT, Mar. 1999, at 15, 15 ("Surely it is economic folly to mandate unbundling of any network element that is not 'essential' in the antitrust sense - that is, a network element that cannot be readily duplicated by the entrant or procured at competitive prices from the same vendors who supply the element to the incumbent firm subject to the unbundling obligation."); see also ROBERT W. CRANDALL, MANAGED COMPETITION IN U.S. TELECOMMUNICATIONS 17 (AEI-Brookings Joint Ctr. for Regulatory Studies Working Paper No. 99-1, 1999) ("[T]he decision to unbundle everything and to require its leasing at cost-based rates is wildly excessive."). For a similar conclusion by German scholars, applying American antitrust principles to German telecommunications law, see CHRISTOPH ENGEL & GÜNTER KNIEPS, DIE VORSCHRIFTEN DES TELEKOMMUNIKATIONSGESETZES ÜBER DEN ZUGANG ZU WESENTLICHEN LEISTUNGEN (1998); and Christoph Engel, Der Weg der Deutscher Telekommunikation in den Wettbewerb, MULTIMEDIA UND RECHT, Mar. 1999, at 7, 12-13. As noted earlier, Canada employs an essential facilities approach to mandatory unbundling. See supra text accompanying notes 174-175.
    • (1998) Die Vorschriften Des Telekommunikationsgesetzes Über Den Zugang Zu Wesentlichen Leistungen
    • Engel, C.1    Knieps, G.2
  • 248
    • 0042147829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Der weg der deutscher telekommunikation in den wettbewerb
    • Mar.
    • We have previously argued that the essential facilities doctrine identifies necessary, but not sufficient, conditions for mandatory unbundling at long-run incremental cost. See Hausman, supra note 168, at 22 ("Economic principles suggest that only the 'essential facility' elements of the network, which cannot be economically reproduced in the short run by new competitors, should be unbundled by regulation."); Paul W. MacAvoy & J. Gregory Sidak, What Is Wrong with American Telecommunications?, MULTIMEDIA UND RECHT, Mar. 1999, at 15, 15 ("Surely it is economic folly to mandate unbundling of any network element that is not 'essential' in the antitrust sense - that is, a network element that cannot be readily duplicated by the entrant or procured at competitive prices from the same vendors who supply the element to the incumbent firm subject to the unbundling obligation."); see also ROBERT W. CRANDALL, MANAGED COMPETITION IN U.S. TELECOMMUNICATIONS 17 (AEI-Brookings Joint Ctr. for Regulatory Studies Working Paper No. 99-1, 1999) ("[T]he decision to unbundle everything and to require its leasing at cost-based rates is wildly excessive."). For a similar conclusion by German scholars, applying American antitrust principles to German telecommunications law, see CHRISTOPH ENGEL & GÜNTER KNIEPS, DIE VORSCHRIFTEN DES TELEKOMMUNIKATIONSGESETZES ÜBER DEN ZUGANG ZU WESENTLICHEN LEISTUNGEN (1998); and Christoph Engel, Der Weg der Deutscher Telekommunikation in den Wettbewerb, MULTIMEDIA UND RECHT, Mar. 1999, at 7, 12-13. As noted earlier, Canada employs an essential facilities approach to mandatory unbundling. See supra text accompanying notes 174-175.
    • (1999) Multimedia und Recht
    • Engel, C.1
  • 249
    • 84923726046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We focus here on the "impairment" standard. As we shall explain presently, our understanding of the "necessary" standard is that it would raise the bar of our five-part test in cases where the desired element embodied some type of intellectual property to which the ILEC had a legally recognizable form of protection
    • We focus here on the "impairment" standard. As we shall explain presently, our understanding of the "necessary" standard is that it would raise the bar of our five-part test in cases where the desired element embodied some type of intellectual property to which the ILEC had a legally recognizable form of protection.
  • 250
    • 84923726045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • n), then the ILEC could not exercise market power.
  • 251
    • 84923726044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Landes & Posner, supra note 14, at 975-76
    • Landes & Posner, supra note 14, at 975-76.
  • 252
    • 84923726043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 976
    • Id. at 976.
  • 253
    • 84923726042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Metro Mobile CTS v. NewVector Communications, 892 F.2d 62, 63 (9th Cir. 1989) (citations omitted); accord Consolidated Gas Co. v. City Gas Co., 880 F.2d 297, 300 (11th Cir. 1989), aff'd on reh'g, 912 F.2d 1262 (11th Cir. 1990), rev'd per curiam on other grounds, 499 U.S. 915 (1991)
    • Metro Mobile CTS v. NewVector Communications, 892 F.2d 62, 63 (9th Cir. 1989) (citations omitted); accord Consolidated Gas Co. v. City Gas Co., 880 F.2d 297, 300 (11th Cir. 1989), aff'd on reh'g, 912 F.2d 1262 (11th Cir. 1990), rev'd per curiam on other grounds, 499 U.S. 915 (1991).
  • 254
    • 84923726041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 37
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 37.
  • 255
    • 0004217626 scopus 로고
    • It has long been recognized in the economics literature that the private incentive to innovate is too low relative to the socially optimal outcome that maximizes consumer welfare even when a patent is granted. See, e.g., JEAN TIROLE, THE THEORY OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 389-414 (1988). The FCC will further decrease the already insufficient incentive to innovate if it requires mandatory unbundling of elements based on intellectual property and requires them to be sold at TELRIC-based prices.
    • (1988) The Theory of Industrial Organization , pp. 389-414
    • Tirole, J.1
  • 256
    • 84923726040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property, 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,132, at 20,734 & n.1 (Apr. 11, 1995). The Guidelines state: "The intellectual property laws and the antitrust laws share the common purpose of promoting innovation and enhancing consumer welfare." Id. at 20,734
    • See Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property, 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,132, at 20,734 & n.1 (Apr. 11, 1995). The Guidelines state: "The intellectual property laws and the antitrust laws share the common purpose of promoting innovation and enhancing consumer welfare." Id. at 20,734.
  • 257
    • 84923726039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶ 282 (1996)
    • First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶ 282 (1996).
  • 260
    • 84923726038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • First Report and Order, 11 F.C.C.R. ¶ 282
    • First Report and Order, 11 F.C.C.R. ¶ 282.
  • 261
    • 0039450630 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The meaning of monopoly: Antitrust analysis in high-technology industries
    • See, e.g., David J. Teece & Mary Coleman, The Meaning of Monopoly: Antitrust Analysis in High-Technology Industries, 43 ANTITRUST BULL. 801, 820-22 (1998) (discussing entrepreneurial rents derived from innovation).
    • (1998) Antitrust Bull. , vol.43 , pp. 801
    • Teece, D.J.1    Coleman, M.2
  • 262
    • 84923726037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The following analysis responds to the FCC's request for "comment on when we should deem a substitute sufficiently available so as to render access to the incumbent's network element unnecessary." Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 21; see also id. ¶ 24 (asking "how the Commission should consider the availability of network elements outside of the incumbent's network")
    • The following analysis responds to the FCC's request for "comment on when we should deem a substitute sufficiently available so as to render access to the incumbent's network element unnecessary." Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 21; see also id. ¶ 24 (asking "how the Commission should consider the availability of network elements outside of the incumbent's network").
  • 263
    • 84923726036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, marginal costs are either constant or decreasing for most UNEs. Otherwise, we would expect to see numerous small competitors entering the market to supply UNEs
    • Indeed, marginal costs are either constant or decreasing for most UNEs. Otherwise, we would expect to see numerous small competitors entering the market to supply UNEs.
  • 264
    • 84923726035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 735 (1999)
    • See AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 735 (1999).
  • 265
    • 84923726034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is well recognized that a barrier to exit becomes a barrier to entry. For a discussion of the absence of exit barriers in the wireless industry because fixed investment is amenable to redeployment by other firms or in other geographic markets, see SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 78-79
    • It is well recognized that a barrier to exit becomes a barrier to entry. For a discussion of the absence of exit barriers in the wireless industry because fixed investment is amenable to redeployment by other firms or in other geographic markets, see SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 78-79.
  • 266
    • 84923726033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To a limited extent, the Commission recognized this notion of cost in its 1996 interconnection proceeding. See First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶¶ 638-52, 686-95 (1996) (discussing testimony of Jerry Hausman). For further discussion, see Hausman, supra note 168, at 24-26; Hausman, supra note 12, at 26-35
    • To a limited extent, the Commission recognized this notion of cost in its 1996 interconnection proceeding. See First Report and Order, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 F.C.C.R. 15,499, ¶¶ 638-52, 686-95 (1996) (discussing testimony of Jerry Hausman). For further discussion, see Hausman, supra note 168, at 24-26; Hausman, supra note 12, at 26-35.
  • 267
    • 84923726032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 184-185
    • See supra text accompanying notes 184-185.
  • 269
    • 0043149760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • May 26
    • See Peter W. Huber & Evan T. Leo, UNE Fact Report, FCC 96-98 (May 26, 1999) (submitted by United States Telephone Association and prepared for Ameritech, Bell Atlantic, BellSouth, GTE, and U S WEST) (on file with The Yale Law Journal).
    • (1999) UNE Fact Report, FCC 96-98
    • Huber, P.W.1    Leo, E.T.2
  • 270
    • 84923726031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Peter W. Huber & Evan T. Leo, UNE Fact Report, FCC 96-98 (May 26, 1999) (submitted by United States Telephone Association and prepared for Ameritech, Bell Atlantic, BellSouth, GTE, and U S WEST) (on file with The Yale Law Journal).
    • The Yale Law Journal
  • 271
    • 84923726030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Petition of AT&T Corp. To Deny Application, GTE Corp. & Bell Atlantic Corp. for Consent to Transfer of Control, FCC 98-184, at 24 (Nov. 23, 1998) (on file with The Yale Law Journal).
    • The Yale Law Journal
  • 272
    • 84923726029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This section addresses only supply-side effects. With respect to demand-side constraints on market power, as soon as AT&T begins to supply cable telephony, unbundled loops should no longer meet the impairment test. At that time, an ILEC should no longer be compelled to supply CLECs unbundled loops at a TELRIC price
    • This section addresses only supply-side effects. With respect to demand-side constraints on market power, as soon as AT&T begins to supply cable telephony, unbundled loops should no longer meet the impairment test. At that time, an ILEC should no longer be compelled to supply CLECs unbundled loops at a TELRIC price.
  • 273
    • 84923726028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 32
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 32.
  • 274
    • 84923726027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Order Granting Petition, Petition of U S WEST Communications, Inc. for Competitive Classification of its Directory Assistance Services, Dkt. UT-990259 (Wash. Utils. & Transp. Comm'n Apr. 29, 1999), available in 1999 Wash. UTC LEXIS 346
    • See Order Granting Petition, Petition of U S WEST Communications, Inc. for Competitive Classification of its Directory Assistance Services, Dkt. UT-990259 (Wash. Utils. & Transp. Comm'n Apr. 29, 1999), available in 1999 Wash. UTC LEXIS 346.
  • 275
    • 84923726026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced Telecommunications Capability to All Americans in a Reasonable and Timely Fashion, 14 F.C.C.R. 2398, ¶ 12 (1999)
    • Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced Telecommunications Capability to All Americans in a Reasonable and Timely Fashion, 14 F.C.C.R. 2398, ¶ 12 (1999).
  • 276
    • 84923726025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 13 (footnote omitted)
    • Id. ¶ 13 (footnote omitted).
  • 277
    • 84923726024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 36
    • Id. ¶ 36.
  • 278
    • 84923726023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 32; see also id. ¶ 34 (seeking comment on whether to "modify the definition of 'loops' or 'transport' to include dark fiber"); id. ¶ 35 (seeking comment on mandatory unbundling of DSLAMs and packet switches)
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 32; see also id. ¶ 34 (seeking comment on whether to "modify the definition of 'loops' or 'transport' to include dark fiber"); id. ¶ 35 (seeking comment on mandatory unbundling of DSLAMs and packet switches).
  • 279
    • 84923726022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 2
    • Id. ¶ 2.
  • 280
    • 84923726021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., STIGLER, supra note 16, at 24
    • See, e.g., STIGLER, supra note 16, at 24.
  • 281
    • 84923726020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Alex Best, Senior Vice President, Engineering, Cox Communications, Presentation at 1999 Fifth Annual Goldman Sachs Communications Technology Retreat (Mar. 1, 1999) (on file with The Yale Law Journal).
    • The Yale Law Journal
  • 282
    • 0040903165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T: Too big once again?
    • Apr. 27
    • See Paul Farhi, AT&T: Too Big Once Again?, WASH. POST, Apr. 27, 1999, at E1. AT&T would pass a much higher percentage of homes.
    • (1999) Wash. Post
    • Farhi, P.1
  • 283
    • 84923714576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T plans to enter some areas using "fixed wireless" technology
    • Mar. 19
    • See Rebecca Blumenstein, AT&T Plans To Enter Some Areas Using "Fixed Wireless" Technology, WALL ST. J., Mar. 19, 1999, at B6.
    • (1999) Wall St. J.
    • Blumenstein, R.1
  • 284
    • 0042648725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Phone co-op pulls plug on wireless competitor
    • Jan. 13
    • See Joe Gardyasz, Phone Co-Op Pulls Plug on Wireless Competitor, BISMARCK TRIB., Jan. 13, 1999, at 5.
    • (1999) Bismarck Trib. , pp. 5
    • Gardyasz, J.1
  • 285
    • 84923726019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 14
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 14.
  • 286
    • 84923726018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ¶ 28 (asking "whether and the extent to which the language of the statute and the Supreme Court's opinion constrain the factors that we can or should consider in evaluating the availability of elements outside the incumbent's network")
    • See id. ¶ 28 (asking "whether and the extent to which the language of the statute and the Supreme Court's opinion constrain the factors that we can or should consider in evaluating the availability of elements outside the incumbent's network").
  • 287
    • 84923726017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 425
    • SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 425.
  • 288
    • 84923726016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 42 ("[W]e seek comment on whether the existence of a competitive market for a network element is necessary to demonstrate that an element is sufficiently available outside the incumbent's network so that failure of the incumbent to provide the element would not be 'necessary' or would not 'impair' a carrier's ability to provide service.")
    • See Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 42 ("[W]e seek comment on whether the existence of a competitive market for a network element is necessary to demonstrate that an element is sufficiently available outside the incumbent's network so that failure of the incumbent to provide the element would not be 'necessary' or would not 'impair' a carrier's ability to provide service.").
  • 289
    • 25844484675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCI to buy sprint in swap of stock for $108 billion
    • Oct. 5
    • See Laura M. Holson & Seth Schiesel, MCI To Buy Sprint in Swap of Stock for $108 Billion, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 5, 1999, at A1.
    • (1999) N.Y. Times
    • Holson, L.M.1    Schiesel, S.2
  • 290
    • 84923726015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hausman, supra note 168, at 24-26; see also SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 421 (discussing the Hatfield model)
    • See Hausman, supra note 168, at 24-26; see also SIDAK & SPULBER, supra note 4, at 421 (discussing the Hatfield model).
  • 291
    • 84923726014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In early 1999, the FCC stated: "Our role is not to pick winners and losers, or to select the best technology to meet consumer demand. We intend to rely as much as possible on free markets and private enterprise." Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced Telecommunications Capability to All Americans in a Reasonable and Timely Fashion, 14 F.C.C.R. 2398, ¶ 5 (1999)
    • In early 1999, the FCC stated: "Our role is not to pick winners and losers, or to select the best technology to meet consumer demand. We intend to rely as much as possible on free markets and private enterprise." Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced Telecommunications Capability to All Americans in a Reasonable and Timely Fashion, 14 F.C.C.R. 2398, ¶ 5 (1999).
  • 292
    • 84923726013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, pmbl., 110 Stat. 56, 56
    • Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, pmbl., 110 Stat. 56, 56.
  • 293
    • 84923721441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic analysis of evidentiary law: An underused tool, an underplowed field
    • See Richard D. Friedman, Economic Analysis of Evidentiary Law: An Underused Tool, an Underplowed Field, 19 CARDOZO L. REV. 1531, 1533 (1998); Bruce L. Hay, Allocating the Burden of Proof, 12 IND. L.J. 651 (1997); Jason S. Johnston, Bayesian Fact-Finding and Efficiency: Toward an Economic Theory of Liability Under Uncertainty, 61 S. CAL. L. REV. 137 (1987); Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to the Law of Evidence, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1477 (1999); Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration, 2 J. LEGAL STUD. 399, 410 (1973).
    • (1998) Cardozo L. Rev. , vol.19 , pp. 1531
    • Friedman, R.D.1
  • 294
    • 21744448088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Allocating the burden of proof
    • See Richard D. Friedman, Economic Analysis of Evidentiary Law: An Underused Tool, an Underplowed Field, 19 CARDOZO L. REV. 1531, 1533 (1998); Bruce L. Hay, Allocating the Burden of Proof, 12 IND. L.J. 651 (1997); Jason S. Johnston, Bayesian Fact-Finding and Efficiency: Toward an Economic Theory of Liability Under Uncertainty, 61 S. CAL. L. REV. 137 (1987); Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to the Law of Evidence, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1477 (1999); Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration, 2 J. LEGAL STUD. 399, 410 (1973).
    • (1997) Ind. L.J. , vol.12 , pp. 651
    • Hay, B.L.1
  • 295
    • 0042648755 scopus 로고
    • Bayesian fact-finding and efficiency: Toward an economic theory of liability under uncertainty
    • See Richard D. Friedman, Economic Analysis of Evidentiary Law: An Underused Tool, an Underplowed Field, 19 CARDOZO L. REV. 1531, 1533 (1998); Bruce L. Hay, Allocating the Burden of Proof, 12 IND. L.J. 651 (1997); Jason S. Johnston, Bayesian Fact-Finding and Efficiency: Toward an Economic Theory of Liability Under Uncertainty, 61 S. CAL. L. REV. 137 (1987); Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to the Law of Evidence, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1477 (1999); Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration, 2 J. LEGAL STUD. 399, 410 (1973).
    • (1987) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 137
    • Johnston, J.S.1
  • 296
    • 0346515486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An economic approach to the law of evidence
    • See Richard D. Friedman, Economic Analysis of Evidentiary Law: An Underused Tool, an Underplowed Field, 19 CARDOZO L. REV. 1531, 1533 (1998); Bruce L. Hay, Allocating the Burden of Proof, 12 IND. L.J. 651 (1997); Jason S. Johnston, Bayesian Fact-Finding and Efficiency: Toward an Economic Theory of Liability Under Uncertainty, 61 S. CAL. L. REV. 137 (1987); Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to the Law of Evidence, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1477 (1999); Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration, 2 J. LEGAL STUD. 399, 410 (1973).
    • (1999) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 1477
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 297
    • 85050169518 scopus 로고
    • An economic approach to legal procedure and judicial administration
    • See Richard D. Friedman, Economic Analysis of Evidentiary Law: An Underused Tool, an Underplowed Field, 19 CARDOZO L. REV. 1531, 1533 (1998); Bruce L. Hay, Allocating the Burden of Proof, 12 IND. L.J. 651 (1997); Jason S. Johnston, Bayesian Fact-Finding and Efficiency: Toward an Economic Theory of Liability Under Uncertainty, 61 S. CAL. L. REV. 137 (1987); Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to the Law of Evidence, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1477 (1999); Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration, 2 J. LEGAL STUD. 399, 410 (1973).
    • (1973) J. Legal Stud. , vol.2 , pp. 399
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 298
    • 84923726012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Apartment Source, L.P. v. Philadelphia Newspapers, No. 98-5472, 1999 WL 191649, at *7-*8 (E.D. Pa. Apr. 1, 1999)
    • See Apartment Source, L.P. v. Philadelphia Newspapers, No. 98-5472, 1999 WL 191649, at *7-*8 (E.D. Pa. Apr. 1, 1999).
  • 299
    • 84923726011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 11; see also id. ¶ 36 ("[W]hether the Commission should adopt a mechanism by which network elements would no longer have to be unbundled at a future date."); id. ("[W]hether affirmative steps by the parties or the Commission should be necessary to remove a particular element from unbundling requirements, or whether affirmative action should be necessary to continue requiring the unbundling of particular elements.").
  • 300
    • 84923726010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 39
    • Id. ¶ 39.
  • 301
    • 84923726009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 12
    • Id. ¶ 12.
  • 302
    • 84923726008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 14
    • Id. ¶ 14.
  • 303
    • 84923726007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 12
    • Id. ¶ 12.
  • 304
    • 84923726006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • INDUSTRY ANALYSIS DIV., supra note 212, at 3
    • INDUSTRY ANALYSIS DIV., supra note 212, at 3.
  • 305
    • 0001073135 scopus 로고
    • The use of knowledge in society
    • See generally Friedrich A. Hayek, The Use of Knowledge in Society, 35 AM. ECON. REV. 519 (1945).
    • (1945) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.35 , pp. 519
    • Hayek, F.A.1
  • 306
    • 84923726005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 36 (discussing "whether the Commission should adopt a mechanism by which network elements would no longer have to be unbundled at a future date")
    • Cf. Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 36 (discussing "whether the Commission should adopt a mechanism by which network elements would no longer have to be unbundled at a future date").
  • 307
    • 84923726004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 252(b) (West Supp. 1999)
    • See 47 U.S.C.A. § 252(b) (West Supp. 1999).
  • 308
    • 84923726003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 271(c)(1)(A) (describing the requirements for state approval of the RBOC's generic interconnection plan); id. § 271(c)(1)(B) (setting forth alternative procedures if no requests for interconnection are forthcoming); id. § 272(b) (providing a competitive checklist)
    • See id. § 271(c)(1)(A) (describing the requirements for state approval of the RBOC's generic interconnection plan); id. § 271(c)(1)(B) (setting forth alternative procedures if no requests for interconnection are forthcoming); id. § 272(b) (providing a competitive checklist).
  • 309
    • 84923726002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sidak & Spulber, supra note 4, at 1082-83
    • See Sidak & Spulber, supra note 4, at 1082-83.
  • 310
    • 84923726001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 14
    • Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, supra note 3, ¶ 14.
  • 311
    • 84923726000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ¶ 38
    • Id. ¶ 38.
  • 312
    • 84923725999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 736 (1999)
    • AT&T v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 119 S. Ct. 721, 736 (1999).
  • 313
    • 84923725998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, pmbl., 110 Stat. 56, 56
    • Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, pmbl., 110 Stat. 56, 56.
  • 314
    • 84923725997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.