-
1
-
-
36949033577
-
-
Larry Diamond and Juan J. Linz, 'Introduction: Politics, Society, and Democracy in Latin America', in Juan J. Linz and Seymour M. Lipset, eds, Democracy in Developing Countries, IV, Latin America (Boulder, Colo, and London: Lynne Rienner and Adamanture Press, 1989) pp. 1-66;
-
Larry Diamond and Juan J. Linz, 'Introduction: Politics, Society, and Democracy in Latin America', in Juan J. Linz and Seymour M. Lipset, eds, Democracy in Developing Countries, Vol. IV, Latin America (Boulder, Colo, and London: Lynne Rienner and Adamanture Press, 1989) pp. 1-66;
-
-
-
-
3
-
-
0004024714
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
Herbert Kitschelt, Zdenka Mansfeldova, Radoslaw Markowski and Gabor Toka, Post-Communist Party Systems: Competition, Representation and Inter-Party Cooperation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999);
-
(1999)
Post-Communist Party Systems: Competition, Representation and Inter-Party Cooperation
-
-
Kitschelt, H.1
Mansfeldova, Z.2
Markowski, R.3
Toka, G.4
-
5
-
-
0007471889
-
Parties and Electoral Choices in East-Central Europe
-
Geoffrey Pridham and Paul G. Lewis, eds, London: Routledge
-
Gabor Toka, 'Parties and Electoral Choices in East-Central Europe', in Geoffrey Pridham and Paul G. Lewis, eds, Stabilising Fragile Democracies: Comparing New Party Systems in Southern and Eastern Europe (London: Routledge, 1995), pp. 93-134.
-
(1995)
Stabilising Fragile Democracies: Comparing New Party Systems in Southern and Eastern Europe
, pp. 93-134
-
-
Toka, G.1
-
6
-
-
24944447566
-
Party Systems in the Third Wave
-
July
-
Scott Mainwaring, 'Party Systems in the Third Wave', Journal of Democracy, 9 (July 1998), 67-81.
-
(1998)
Journal of Democracy
, vol.9
, pp. 67-81
-
-
Mainwaring, S.1
-
11
-
-
84972102803
-
Left-Libertarian Parties: Explaining Innovation in Competitive Party Systems
-
Herbert Kitschelt, 'Left-Libertarian Parties: Explaining Innovation in Competitive Party Systems', World Politics, 40 (1988), 194-234;
-
(1988)
World Politics
, vol.40
, pp. 194-234
-
-
Kitschelt, H.1
-
13
-
-
24944456664
-
Competition Between Unequals: The Role of Mainstream Party Strategy in Niche Party Success
-
see also
-
see also Bonnie M. Meguid, 'Competition Between Unequals: The Role of Mainstream Party Strategy in Niche Party Success', American Political Science Review, 99 (2005), 347-59.
-
(2005)
American Political Science Review
, vol.99
, pp. 347-359
-
-
Meguid, B.M.1
-
14
-
-
0002878272
-
The Influence of New Parties on Old Parties' Platforms: The Cases of Progress Parties and Conservative Parties of Denmark and Norway
-
Robert Harmel and Lars Svasand, 'The Influence of New Parties on Old Parties' Platforms: The Cases of Progress Parties and Conservative Parties of Denmark and Norway', Party Politics, 3 (1997), 315-40;
-
(1997)
Party Politics
, vol.3
, pp. 315-340
-
-
Harmel, R.1
Svasand, L.2
-
15
-
-
84933490577
-
The Silent Counter-Revolution: Hypotheses on the Emergence of Extreme Right Wing Parties in Europe
-
Piero Ignazi, 'The Silent Counter-Revolution: Hypotheses on the Emergence of Extreme Right Wing Parties in Europe', European Journal of Political Research, 22 (1992), 3-34;
-
(1992)
European Journal of Political Research
, vol.22
, pp. 3-34
-
-
Ignazi, P.1
-
16
-
-
0038069265
-
Explaining Variation in the Success of Extreme Right Wing Parties in Western Europe
-
Matt Golder, 'Explaining Variation in the Success of Extreme Right Wing Parties in Western Europe', Comparative Political Studies, 36 (2003), 432-66.
-
(2003)
Comparative Political Studies
, vol.36
, pp. 432-466
-
-
Golder, M.1
-
20
-
-
0003217547
-
The Development of New Parties in Western Democracies since 1945
-
Louis Maisel and Joseph Cooper, eds, Beverly Hills, Calif: Sage
-
Charles Hauss and David Rayside, 'The Development of New Parties in Western Democracies since 1945', in Louis Maisel and Joseph Cooper, eds, Political Parties: Development and Decay (Beverly Hills, Calif: Sage, 1978), pp. 31-57;
-
(1978)
Political Parties: Development and Decay
, pp. 31-57
-
-
Hauss, C.1
Rayside, D.2
-
22
-
-
18044397122
-
Political Parties and the Study of Political Development
-
Marcus Kreuzer and Vello Pettai, 'Political Parties and the Study of Political Development', World Politics, 56 (2004), 608-33.
-
(2004)
World Politics
, vol.56
, pp. 608-633
-
-
Kreuzer, M.1
Pettai, V.2
-
24
-
-
36949022849
-
-
see also pp. 120-1 and fn. 63 for more discussion on defining new parties.
-
see also pp. 120-1 and fn. 63 for more discussion on defining new parties.
-
-
-
-
35
-
-
0036132376
-
Do Mixed Electoral Systems Matter? A Cross-National Analysis of Their Effects in Eastern Europe
-
Tatiana Kostadinova, 'Do Mixed Electoral Systems Matter? A Cross-National Analysis of Their Effects in Eastern Europe', Electoral Studies, 21 (2004), 23-34;
-
(2004)
Electoral Studies
, vol.21
, pp. 23-34
-
-
Kostadinova, T.1
-
36
-
-
0033034258
-
Electoral Systems and the Number of Parties in Postcommunist States
-
Robert G. Moser, 'Electoral Systems and the Number of Parties in Postcommunist States', World Politics, 51 (1999), 359-84.
-
(1999)
World Politics
, vol.51
, pp. 359-384
-
-
Moser, R.G.1
-
38
-
-
31044439170
-
Party System Change: Testing a Model of New Party Entry
-
Margit Tavits, 'Party System Change: Testing a Model of New Party Entry', Party Politics, 12 (2006), 99-119.
-
(2006)
Party Politics
, vol.12
, pp. 99-119
-
-
Tavits, M.1
-
40
-
-
34347362795
-
Electoral Systems and Party System Stability in Post-Communist Europe
-
paper presented at the, San Francisco
-
Sarah Birch, 'Electoral Systems and Party System Stability in Post-Communist Europe' (paper presented at the Annual Meeting of American Political Science Association, San Francisco, 2001).
-
(2001)
Annual Meeting of American Political Science Association
-
-
Birch, S.1
-
42
-
-
0003417642
-
-
Notre Dame, Ind, Notre Dame University Press, In some cases, such as the United States and France, presidentialism. has also been related to less fragmented party systems
-
Mark P. Jones, Electoral Laws and the Survival of Presidential Democracies (Notre Dame, Ind.: Notre Dame University Press, 1995). In some cases, such as the United States and France, presidentialism. has also been related to less fragmented party systems
-
(1995)
Electoral Laws and the Survival of Presidential Democracies
-
-
Jones, M.P.1
-
44
-
-
36949001069
-
-
I thank Sarah Birch for alerting me to the potential effect of presidentialism on new party entry
-
I thank Sarah Birch for alerting me to the potential effect of presidentialism on new party entry.
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
4043055045
-
Endogenous Selection of Institutions and Their Exogenous Effects
-
Olga Shvetsova, 'Endogenous Selection of Institutions and Their Exogenous Effects', Constitutional Political Economy, 14 (2003), 191-212.
-
(2003)
Constitutional Political Economy
, vol.14
, pp. 191-212
-
-
Shvetsova, O.1
-
50
-
-
0037495913
-
Do Parties Benefit From Electoral Manipulation? Electoral Laws and Heresthetics in Poland, 1989-93
-
Marek M. Kaminski, 'Do Parties Benefit From Electoral Manipulation? Electoral Laws and Heresthetics in Poland, 1989-93', Journal of Theoretical Politics, 14 (2002), 325-58;
-
(2002)
Journal of Theoretical Politics
, vol.14
, pp. 325-358
-
-
Kaminski, M.M.1
-
52
-
-
1642348228
-
Inter-Party Mobility among Parliamentary Candidates in Post-Communist East Central Europe
-
Goldie Shabad and Kazimierz M. Slomczynski, 'Inter-Party Mobility among Parliamentary Candidates in Post-Communist East Central Europe', Party Politics, 10 (2004), 151-76.
-
(2004)
Party Politics
, vol.10
, pp. 151-176
-
-
Shabad, G.1
Slomczynski, K.M.2
-
53
-
-
0002495619
-
Party Membership in Twenty European Democracies, 1980-2000
-
Peter Mair and Ingrid van Biezen, 'Party Membership in Twenty European Democracies, 1980-2000', Party Politics, 7 (2001), 5-21.
-
(2001)
Party Politics
, vol.7
, pp. 5-21
-
-
Mair, P.1
van Biezen, I.2
-
55
-
-
27744510921
-
The Development of Stable Party Support: Electoral Dynamics in Post-Communist Europe
-
Margit Tavits, 'The Development of Stable Party Support: Electoral Dynamics in Post-Communist Europe', American Journal of Political Science, 49 (2005), 283-98;
-
(2005)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.49
, pp. 283-298
-
-
Tavits, M.1
-
56
-
-
0005964451
-
Postauthoritarian Elections: Testing Expectations About First Elections
-
Arthur W. Turner, 'Postauthoritarian Elections: Testing Expectations About First Elections', Comparative Political Studies, 26 (1993), 330-49.
-
(1993)
Comparative Political Studies
, vol.26
, pp. 330-349
-
-
Turner, A.W.1
-
58
-
-
33344471813
-
Learning to Make Votes Count: The Role of Democratic Experience
-
Margit Tavits and Taavi Annus, 'Learning to Make Votes Count: The Role of Democratic Experience', Electoral Studies, 25 (2006), 72-90.
-
(2006)
Electoral Studies
, vol.25
, pp. 72-90
-
-
Tavits, M.1
Annus, T.2
-
60
-
-
36949015758
-
-
Cox, Making Votes Count, argues that viability is not clear 'in elections held in new democracies' (p. 152), yet given that over time viability becomes clearer 'a typical scenario in emerging democracies [is one] whereby a great number of parties spring up in the first elections, and there is a relatively slow winnowing out process' (p. 159).
-
Cox, Making Votes Count, argues that viability is not clear 'in elections held in new democracies' (p. 152), yet given that over time viability becomes clearer 'a typical scenario in emerging democracies [is one] whereby a great number of parties spring up in the first elections, and there is a relatively slow winnowing out process' (p. 159).
-
-
-
-
68
-
-
0040524557
-
Prophets, Purifiers and Prolocutros: Towards a Theory of New Party Emergence
-
Paul Lucardie, 'Prophets, Purifiers and Prolocutros: Towards a Theory of New Party Emergence', Party Politics, 6 (2000), 175-85;
-
(2000)
Party Politics
, vol.6
, pp. 175-185
-
-
Lucardie, P.1
-
70
-
-
36949039360
-
-
The entry model assumes that those who form parties are instrumentally rational, i.e. that they care about getting elected or influencing policy or both. If this assumption is incorrect and most of those who form parties instead derive the highest utility from simply participating in the electoral process, the model will be less efficient. In that case, neither the cost of winning a seat, nor the benefit from holding an office nor low probability of electoral support would deter entry. The only deterrence mechanism would be the cost of registering a party. Thus, if there is little or inconsistent empirical support for the entry model, the original assumption of instrumental party formers is called into question. However, as long as the empirical observations support the arguments, there is less concern about the correctness of these assumptions. Additionally, the new party entry argument rests largely within the institutionalist tradition. Institutions themselves are not entirely exoge
-
The entry model assumes that those who form parties are instrumentally rational, i.e. that they care about getting elected or influencing policy or both. If this assumption is incorrect and most of those who form parties instead derive the highest utility from simply participating in the electoral process, the model will be less efficient. In that case, neither the cost of winning a seat, nor the benefit from holding an office nor low probability of electoral support would deter entry. The only deterrence mechanism would be the cost of registering a party. Thus, if there is little or inconsistent empirical support for the entry model, the original assumption of instrumental party formers is called into question. However, as long as the empirical observations support the arguments, there is less concern about the correctness of these assumptions. Additionally, the new party entry argument rests largely within the institutionalist tradition. Institutions themselves are not entirely exogenous but may depend on cultural or marco-historical factors. This, however, does not undermine the usefulness of considering the effects of institutions.
-
-
-
-
73
-
-
36949021293
-
-
It is possible that opposition parties also attract disappointed voters. This poses an uphill battle for empirically detecting the relationships outlined below. Yet, if the expected empirical patterns are detected, confidence in their robustness is increased
-
It is possible that opposition parties also attract disappointed voters. This poses an uphill battle for empirically detecting the relationships outlined below. Yet, if the expected empirical patterns are detected, confidence in their robustness is increased.
-
-
-
-
74
-
-
84929872706
-
The Political Economy of Competitive Elections in the Developing World
-
Alexander C. Pacek and Benjamin Radcliff, "The Political Economy of Competitive Elections in the Developing World', American Journal of Political Science, 39 (1995), 745-59.
-
(1995)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.39
, pp. 745-759
-
-
Pacek, A.C.1
Radcliff, B.2
-
77
-
-
0036406631
-
The First Decade of Post-Communist Elections and Voting: What Have We Studied, and How Have We Studied It?
-
Joshua A. Tucker, 'The First Decade of Post-Communist Elections and Voting: What Have We Studied, and How Have We Studied It?' Annual Reviews of Political Science, 5 (2002), 271-304.
-
(2002)
Annual Reviews of Political Science
, vol.5
, pp. 271-304
-
-
Tucker, J.A.1
-
78
-
-
0031390093
-
Unemployment Matters: Voting Patterns During the Economic Transition in Poland, 1990-1995
-
Janice Bell, 'Unemployment Matters: Voting Patterns During the Economic Transition in Poland, 1990-1995', Europe-Asia Studies, 49 (1997), 1263-91;
-
(1997)
Europe-Asia Studies
, vol.49
, pp. 1263-1291
-
-
Bell, J.1
-
79
-
-
0033995963
-
Economics of Voting in Post-Communist Countries
-
Jan Fidrmuc, 'Economics of Voting in Post-Communist Countries', Electoral Studies, 19(2000), 199-217;
-
(2000)
Electoral Studies
, vol.19
, pp. 199-217
-
-
Fidrmuc, J.1
-
80
-
-
84937314505
-
Macroeconomic Conditions and Electoral Politics in East Central Europe
-
Alexander C. Pacek, 'Macroeconomic Conditions and Electoral Politics in East Central Europe', American Journal of Political Science, 38 (1994), 123-44.
-
(1994)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.38
, pp. 123-144
-
-
Pacek, A.C.1
-
82
-
-
0037590216
-
Social Security Reform in Central and Eastern Europe: Variations on a Latin American Theme
-
Barbara E. Kritzer, 'Social Security Reform in Central and Eastern Europe: Variations on a Latin American Theme', Social Security Bulletin, 64 (2001/02), 16-32.
-
(2002)
Social Security Bulletin
, vol.64
, pp. 16-32
-
-
Kritzer, B.E.1
-
84
-
-
84926201963
-
-
but see also Joshua A. Tucker, Regional Economic Voting: Russia, Poland, Hungary, and the Czech Republic, 1990-1999 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006).
-
but see also Joshua A. Tucker, Regional Economic Voting: Russia, Poland, Hungary, and the Czech Republic, 1990-1999 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006).
-
-
-
-
85
-
-
84937329487
-
-
Robert E. Bohrer II, Alexander C. Pacek and Benjamin Radcliff, 'Electoral Participation, Ideology, and Party Politics and Post-Communist Europe', Journal of Politics, 62 (2000), 1161-72;
-
Robert E. Bohrer II, Alexander C. Pacek and Benjamin Radcliff, 'Electoral Participation, Ideology, and Party Politics and Post-Communist Europe', Journal of Politics, 62 (2000), 1161-72;
-
-
-
-
86
-
-
84976922433
-
Turnout and the Democratic Vote
-
Benjamin Radcliff, 'Turnout and the Democratic Vote', American Politics Quarterly, 22 (1994), 259-76;
-
(1994)
American Politics Quarterly
, vol.22
, pp. 259-276
-
-
Radcliff, B.1
-
91
-
-
0036406921
-
Political Cleavages and Post-Communist Polities
-
Stephen Whitefield, 'Political Cleavages and Post-Communist Polities', Annual Reviews of Political Science, 5 (2002), 181-200.
-
(2002)
Annual Reviews of Political Science
, vol.5
, pp. 181-200
-
-
Whitefield, S.1
-
96
-
-
0039850204
-
Domestic Ethnic Conflict and Ethnic Nepotism: A Comparative Analysis
-
Tatu Vanhanen, 'Domestic Ethnic Conflict and Ethnic Nepotism: A Comparative Analysis', Journal of Peace Research, 36 (1999), 55-73.
-
(1999)
Journal of Peace Research
, vol.36
, pp. 55-73
-
-
Vanhanen, T.1
-
97
-
-
36949040546
-
-
M. Seymour Lipset and Stein Rokkan, 'Cleavage Structures, Party Systems, and Voter Alignments: An Introduction', in M. Seymour Lipset and Stein Rokkan, eds, Party Systems and Voter Alignment: Cross-National Perspectives (New York: The Free Press, 1967);
-
M. Seymour Lipset and Stein Rokkan, 'Cleavage Structures, Party Systems, and Voter Alignments: An Introduction', in M. Seymour Lipset and Stein Rokkan, eds, Party Systems and Voter Alignment: Cross-National Perspectives (New York: The Free Press, 1967);
-
-
-
-
98
-
-
0002476389
-
Ethnic Heterogeneity, District Magnitude, and the Number of Parties
-
Peter Ordeshook and Olga Shvetsova, 'Ethnic Heterogeneity, District Magnitude, and the Number of Parties', American Journal of Political Science, 38 (1994), 100-23.
-
(1994)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.38
, pp. 100-123
-
-
Ordeshook, P.1
Shvetsova, O.2
-
99
-
-
36949028885
-
-
I thank, again, Sarah Birch for pointing out the potential importance of this option on the ballot
-
I thank, again, Sarah Birch for pointing out the potential importance of this option on the ballot.
-
-
-
-
100
-
-
0008998935
-
-
Jean Blondel and Ferdinand Müller-Rommel, eds, New York: Palgrave Macmillan
-
Jean Blondel and Ferdinand Müller-Rommel, eds, Cabinets in Eastern Europe (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2001).
-
(2001)
Cabinets in Eastern Europe
-
-
-
101
-
-
0030801896
-
Substance and Process in the Development of Party Systems in East Central Europe
-
Jack Bielasiak, 'Substance and Process in the Development of Party Systems in East Central Europe', Communist and Post-Communist Studies, 30 (1997), 23-44;
-
(1997)
Communist and Post-Communist Studies
, vol.30
, pp. 23-44
-
-
Bielasiak, J.1
-
104
-
-
36949001291
-
-
The following elections were included: Armenia 2003; Bulgaria 1991, 1994, 1997 and 200.1; the Czech Republic 1992, 1996, 1998 and 2002; Estonia 1995, 1999 and 2003; Georgia 1999; Hungary 1994, 1998 and 2002; Latvia 1995,1998 and 2002; Lithuania 1996, 2000 and 2004; Moldova 1998 and 2001; Poland 1993, 1997 and 2001; Romania 1992, 1996, 2000 and 2004; Russia 1995, 1999 and 2003; Slovakia 1992, 1994, 1998 and 2002; Slovenia 1992, 1996, 2000 and 2004; Ukraine 1998 and 2000. Elections in Albania and Croatia, countries that passed the Freedom. House threshold, were not included because election results were available only for parties that won a seat in parliament. Disregarding other competitors would have introduced a clear bias. Furthermore, both countries were until very recently (Albania until 1997, when the state almost collapsed due to pyramid schemes, and Croatia until 2000, after the death of president Franjo Tudjman, essentially one-party states Irena Grudzinska Gross, When Pyra
-
The following elections were included: Armenia 2003; Bulgaria 1991, 1994, 1997 and 200.1; the Czech Republic 1992, 1996, 1998 and 2002; Estonia 1995, 1999 and 2003; Georgia 1999; Hungary 1994, 1998 and 2002; Latvia 1995,1998 and 2002; Lithuania 1996, 2000 and 2004; Moldova 1998 and 2001; Poland 1993, 1997 and 2001; Romania 1992, 1996, 2000 and 2004; Russia 1995, 1999 and 2003; Slovakia 1992, 1994, 1998 and 2002; Slovenia 1992, 1996, 2000 and 2004; Ukraine 1998 and 2000. Elections in Albania and Croatia - countries that passed the Freedom. House threshold - were not included because election results were available only for parties that won a seat in parliament. Disregarding other competitors would have introduced a clear bias. Furthermore, both countries were until very recently (Albania until 1997, when the state almost collapsed due to pyramid schemes, and Croatia until 2000, after the death of president Franjo Tudjman), essentially one-party states (Irena Grudzinska Gross, 'When Pyramids Collapse', East European Constitutional Review, 1 (1998), 〈http://www.law.nyu.edu/eecr/vol7numl/special/conversation.html>, last accessed on 9 February 2006;
-
-
-
-
105
-
-
36949008287
-
-
British Helsinki Human Rights Group, Croatia 2000: Parliamentary Elections, last accessed on 9 February 2006, the election results were manipulated in Albania, the government in office did not actually control the country in Croatia until 1995 and was autocratic there until 2000. Albania has held only two truly democratic elections and Croatia only one. Thus, leaving out these countries costs only a single case. Additionally, none of the analyses below is sensitive to case selection: the relationships hold whether or not any of the more dubious cases, such as Armenia or Georgia, are included
-
British Helsinki Human Rights Group, Croatia 2000: Parliamentary Elections, 〈http://www.bhhrg.org/ CountryReport.asp?CountryID = 7〉, last accessed on 9 February 2006): the election results were manipulated in Albania, the government in office did not actually control the country in Croatia until 1995 and was autocratic there until 2000. Albania has held only two truly democratic elections and Croatia only one. Thus, leaving out these countries costs only a single case. Additionally, none of the analyses below is sensitive to case selection: the relationships hold whether or not any of the more dubious cases, such as Armenia or Georgia, are included.
-
-
-
-
107
-
-
36949020168
-
-
As previous studies have noted, it is almost impossible to differentiate between a splinter and a 'genuinely new' party (Peter Mair, New Political Parties in Established Party Systems: How Successful Are They, in E. Beukel, K. K. Klausen and P. E. Mouritzen, eds, Elites, Parties and Democracy: Festschrift for Professor Mogens N. Pedersen Odense: Odense University Press, 1999, pp. 207-21, Even if those who originally formed the party have had no ties to other political parties, by the time of the election most new parties have recruited previous members of other parties to be on the ballot or even in the party leadership. This makes the difference between splinters and genuinely new parties very dubious. Indeed, in practical terms it makes no difference whether a party was created or is led/represented by somebody who used to belong to another party. Yet, strictly following the definitions, the former would be classified as a splinter while the latter would be genuinely new
-
As previous studies have noted, it is almost impossible to differentiate between a splinter and a 'genuinely new' party (Peter Mair, 'New Political Parties in Established Party Systems: How Successful Are They?' in E. Beukel, K. K. Klausen and P. E. Mouritzen, eds, Elites, Parties and Democracy: Festschrift for Professor Mogens N. Pedersen (Odense: Odense University Press, 1999), pp. 207-21). Even if those who originally formed the party have had no ties to other political parties, by the time of the election most new parties have recruited previous members of other parties to be on the ballot or even in the party leadership. This makes the difference between splinters and genuinely new parties very dubious. Indeed, in practical terms it makes no difference whether a party was created or is led/represented by somebody who used to belong to another party. Yet, strictly following the definitions, the former would be classified as a splinter while the latter would be genuinely new. This empirical obscurity makes the definition of 'genuinely new' much less straightforward and the classification of parties very difficult.
-
-
-
-
108
-
-
0004697153
-
-
The threshold is applied mainly for a simple practical reason, 0.3 per cent is the minimum threshold at which it is possible to find reliable information about the history of parties and hence to determine their newness. Using a 0.3 per cent threshold has virtually no effect on the measure of the success of new parties, parties left out of the analysis contribute to the vote totals only marginally. In the case of the new party formation, the threshold may be more problematic. On the one hand, the analysis of new party entry should include all new parties that were formed regardless of their electoral returns. Leaving out the least successful new parties restricts the applicability of the arguments to a subset of new parties, those that are instrumentally rational. However, considering that the question about the emergence and success of new parties is important mostly to the extent that these new parties really have an impact on the existing party system, the threshold may be less p
-
The threshold is applied mainly for a simple practical reason - 0.3 per cent is the minimum threshold at which it is possible to find reliable information about the history of parties and hence to determine their newness. Using a 0.3 per cent threshold has virtually no effect on the measure of the success of new parties - parties left out of the analysis contribute to the vote totals only marginally. In the case of the new party formation, the threshold may be more problematic. On the one hand, the analysis of new party entry should include all new parties that were formed regardless of their electoral returns. Leaving out the least successful new parties restricts the applicability of the arguments to a subset of new parties - those that are instrumentally rational. However, considering that the question about the emergence and success of new parties is important mostly to the extent that these new parties really have an impact on the existing party system, the threshold may be less problematic. Indeed, several authors have argued that including parties with very low vote totals in the count of new parties artificially inflates the count and have advised using even higher thresholds (David M. Olson, 'Party Formation and Party System. Consolidation in the New Democracies of Central Europe', Political Studies, 46 (1998), 589-610;
-
-
-
-
109
-
-
36949034658
-
-
Richard Rose, What is Europe? A Dynamic Perspective (New York: HarperCollins, 1996, The 0.3 per cent threshold is arbitrary, but it is high, enough to filter out the most hopeless cases and avoid the results being driven by those parties that are largely irrelevant to the political process. At the same time, the threshold is low enough to take into account parties whose performance may not have been outstanding in their first election, but which are able to build their strength for the subsequent elections. In order to control the potential bias in choosing the 0.3 per cent threshold, I have replicated the analysis of the count of new parties using a threshold of 0.5 per cent see Table 1, The results of the analyses improve when the threshold is increased suggesting, indeed, that the theoretical arguments of new party entry may be more applicable to the subset of new parties that are serious about the political process
-
Richard Rose, What is Europe? A Dynamic Perspective (New York: HarperCollins, 1996)). The 0.3 per cent threshold is arbitrary, but it is high, enough to filter out the most hopeless cases and avoid the results being driven by those parties that are largely irrelevant to the political process. At the same time, the threshold is low enough to take into account parties whose performance may not have been outstanding in their first election, but which are able to build their strength for the subsequent elections. In order to control the potential bias in choosing the 0.3 per cent threshold, I have replicated the analysis of the count of new parties using a threshold of 0.5 per cent (see Table 1). The results of the analyses improve when the threshold is increased suggesting, indeed, that the theoretical arguments of new party entry may be more applicable to the subset of new parties that are serious about the political process.
-
-
-
-
111
-
-
36949020273
-
-
More detailed coding rules, the list of new parties, the vote share for new parties by country and by election and the complete list of sources are available at 〈www.missou.ri.edu/~ tavitsm〉.
-
More detailed coding rules, the list of new parties, the vote share for new parties by country and by election and the complete list of sources are available at 〈www.missou.ri.edu/~ tavitsm〉.
-
-
-
-
112
-
-
36949015122
-
-
Harmel and Robertson, 'Formation and Success of New Parties'; Hauss and Rayside, 'The Development of New Parties in Western Democracies since 1945';
-
Harmel and Robertson, 'Formation and Success of New Parties'; Hauss and Rayside, 'The Development of New Parties in Western Democracies since 1945';
-
-
-
-
119
-
-
36949034030
-
-
Information for these three variables is gathered from the electoral laws. Most of these laws are available at 〈www.essex.ac.uk/elections〉, last accessed on 9 February 2006; for Armenia the information was obtained from the Central Election Commission at 〈http://www.elections.am/〉 , last accessed on 9 February 2006; for Georgia from 〈http://www.ifes.ge〉, last accessed on 9 February 2006; for Slovenia from 〈http://www.mnz.gov.si/ 〉 , last accessed on 9 February 2006.
-
Information for these three variables is gathered from the electoral laws. Most of these laws are available at 〈www.essex.ac.uk/elections〉, last accessed on 9 February 2006; for Armenia the information was obtained from the Central Election Commission at 〈http://www.elections.am/〉 , last accessed on 9 February 2006; for Georgia from 〈http://www.ifes.ge〉, last accessed on 9 February 2006; for Slovenia from 〈http://www.mnz.gov.si/ 〉 , last accessed on 9 February 2006.
-
-
-
-
121
-
-
0034754775
-
-
The source of this material is Thorsten Beck, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philip Keefer and Patrick. Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions', World Bank Economic Review, 15 (2001), 165-76. Other potential indicators suchas formal electoral threshold and effective number of parties may capture disproportionality. In the preliminary analyses, neither of these indicators appeared significant or altered the performance of other variables in the model when used as a replacement for or in combination with the mean district magnitude. Given this, 1 have resorted to reporting the results with the latter variable only.
-
The source of this material is Thorsten Beck, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philip Keefer and Patrick. Walsh, 'New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions', World Bank Economic Review, 15 (2001), 165-76. Other potential indicators suchas formal electoral threshold and effective number of parties may capture disproportionality. In the preliminary analyses, neither of these indicators appeared significant or altered the performance of other variables in the model when used as a replacement for or in combination with the mean district magnitude. Given this, 1 have resorted to reporting the results with the latter variable only.
-
-
-
-
126
-
-
0039484139
-
Gaining Legislative Control through Strategic District Nomination: The Case of the Russian Left in 1995
-
Olga Shvetsova, 'Gaining Legislative Control through Strategic District Nomination: The Case of the Russian Left in 1995', Legislative Studies Quarterly, 27 (2002), 635-57.
-
(2002)
Legislative Studies Quarterly
, vol.27
, pp. 635-657
-
-
Shvetsova, O.1
-
127
-
-
36949038143
-
-
A preliminary analysis also included a control variable for changes to the electoral system such as change of the electoral system type, district structure, seat allocation formula or threshold, The variable was not significant and including it did not alter the effects of other variables
-
A preliminary analysis also included a control variable for changes to the electoral system (such as change of the electoral system type, district structure, seat allocation formula or threshold). The variable was not significant and including it did not alter the effects of other variables.
-
-
-
-
128
-
-
0037910432
-
Comparative Presidencies: The Inadequacy of the Presidential, Semi-Presidential and Parliamentary Distinction
-
Alan Siaroff, 'Comparative Presidencies: The Inadequacy of the Presidential, Semi-Presidential and Parliamentary Distinction', European Journal of Political Research, 42 (2003), 287-312.
-
(2003)
European Journal of Political Research
, vol.42
, pp. 287-312
-
-
Siaroff, A.1
-
129
-
-
36949028886
-
-
All three variables constitute yearly averages measured in the election year. The reliability of the unemployment measure is of slight concern. The two sources at my disposal - International Labour Organization (〈http://www. ilo.org〉, last accessed on 9 February 2006) and International Monetary Fund (〈http://ifs.apdi.net/imf/logon.aspx〉, last accessed on 9 February 2006) - did not always agree on the unemployment rates. However, both variables performed more or less the same way in all equations increasing the confidence in the significance level and direction of the relationship. I resorted to using the IMF indicators only, because the data for the other two economic indicators are coded from the same source.
-
All three variables constitute yearly averages measured in the election year. The reliability of the unemployment measure is of slight concern. The two sources at my disposal - International Labour Organization (〈http://www. ilo.org〉, last accessed on 9 February 2006) and International Monetary Fund (〈http://ifs.apdi.net/imf/logon.aspx〉, last accessed on 9 February 2006) - did not always agree on the unemployment rates. However, both variables performed more or less the same way in all equations increasing the confidence in the significance level and direction of the relationship. I resorted to using the IMF indicators only, because the data for the other two economic indicators are coded from the same source.
-
-
-
-
132
-
-
36949002425
-
-
Replacing the Number of new parties with the list of institutional variables predicting the number of new parties does not alter the effect of other variables in the model of new party success.
-
Replacing the Number of new parties with the list of institutional variables predicting the number of new parties does not alter the effect of other variables in the model of new party success.
-
-
-
-
133
-
-
36949023946
-
-
See above; see also
-
See above; see also Cox, Altering Party Systems, pp. 151-72.
-
Altering Party Systems
, pp. 151-172
-
-
Cox1
-
134
-
-
36949016370
-
-
As the variance of the dependent variable was twice its mean, indicating potential overdispersion, I estimated the model originally with, negative binomial regression. However, it reduced to the Poisson regression (alpha = 4.2e-08).
-
As the variance of the dependent variable was twice its mean, indicating potential overdispersion, I estimated the model originally with, negative binomial regression. However, it reduced to the Poisson regression (alpha = 4.2e-08).
-
-
-
-
135
-
-
84936027856
-
Regression in Time and Space: A Statistical Essay
-
James Stimson, 'Regression in Time and Space: A Statistical Essay', American Journal of Political Science, 29 (1985), 914-47.
-
(1985)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.29
, pp. 914-947
-
-
Stimson, J.1
-
136
-
-
84974183585
-
What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time Series Cross-Section Data in Comparative Polities
-
Nathaniel Beck and Jonathan N. Katz, 'What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time Series Cross-Section Data in Comparative Polities', American Political Science Review, 89 (1985), 634-47.
-
(1985)
American Political Science Review
, vol.89
, pp. 634-647
-
-
Beck, N.1
Katz, J.N.2
-
137
-
-
36949006435
-
-
The analyses are performed with ST AT A. 9. Panel corrected standard errors are not available for the Poisson regression, but (Huber/White/Sandwich) robust standard errors within country clusters are reasonable substitutes for dealing withheteroscedasticity. The country effects for all analyses were checked by running a series of separate equations with a dummy for each country. The substantive results of the models presented here were not altered in those estimations. The residual test (see Hug, Altering Party Systems, p. 183) did not reveal any outliers to the models.
-
The analyses are performed with ST AT A. 9. Panel corrected standard errors are not available for the Poisson regression, but (Huber/White/Sandwich) robust standard errors within country clusters are reasonable substitutes for dealing withheteroscedasticity. The country effects for all analyses were checked by running a series of separate equations with a dummy for each country. The substantive results of the models presented here were not altered in those estimations. The residual test (see Hug, Altering Party Systems, p. 183) did not reveal any outliers to the models.
-
-
-
-
138
-
-
36949005359
-
-
Various readers have suggested controlling for the following factors in the models estimating new party emergence: federalism, bicameralism and ethnic fragmentation. None of these variables appeared significant in the preliminary analyses of the two different models presented in Table 1. Including these variables did not change the performance of other variables in the model. Further, given that the entry theory in this article does not provide clear predictions for the effect of any of these variables, 1 decided not to include them, in the final models
-
Various readers have suggested controlling for the following factors in the models estimating new party emergence: federalism, bicameralism and ethnic fragmentation. None of these variables appeared significant in the preliminary analyses of the two different models presented in Table 1. Including these variables did not change the performance of other variables in the model. Further, given that the entry theory in this article does not provide clear predictions for the effect of any of these variables, 1 decided not to include them, in the final models.
-
-
-
-
139
-
-
36949038675
-
-
Hug, Altering Party Systems, p. 1.19;
-
Hug, Altering Party Systems, p. 1.19;
-
-
-
-
140
-
-
36949000819
-
Party System
-
See also
-
See also Tavits, 'Party System. Change'.
-
Change
-
-
Tavits1
-
141
-
-
36949036196
-
-
As noted above, the original model included electoral histories as the only basis for elite level anticipation of electoral support (Cox, Making Votes Count, pp. 151-72). Indeed, when the whole battery of variables predicting the vote share for new parties is included in the model of new party entry, none of these variables is significant. The effect of democratic maturation, the variable capturing the original theoretical construct of the probability of electoral support remains robust.
-
As noted above, the original model included electoral histories as the only basis for elite level anticipation of electoral support (Cox, Making Votes Count, pp. 151-72). Indeed, when the whole battery of variables predicting the vote share for new parties is included in the model of new party entry, none of these variables is significant. The effect of democratic maturation, the variable capturing the original theoretical construct of the probability of electoral support remains robust.
-
-
-
-
142
-
-
36949024632
-
-
To be sure, the effect of ethnic heterogeneity on the success of new parties is not clear even in the context of advanced democracies: previous studies have not found a significant relationship between these variables (Hug, Altering Party Systems, pp. 132-3; Harmel and Robertson, 'Formation and Success of New Parties').
-
To be sure, the effect of ethnic heterogeneity on the success of new parties is not clear even in the context of advanced democracies: previous studies have not found a significant relationship between these variables (Hug, Altering Party Systems, pp. 132-3; Harmel and Robertson, 'Formation and Success of New Parties').
-
-
-
-
143
-
-
36949004473
-
Identifying the Bases of Party Competition in Eastern Europe
-
Political Cleavages and Post-Communist Polities
-
Evans and Whitefield, 'Identifying the Bases of Party Competition in Eastern Europe'; Whitefield, 'Political Cleavages and Post-Communist Polities'.
-
Whitefield
-
-
Evans1
Whitefield2
-
144
-
-
0034004572
-
Economic Voting and Information
-
Toke S. Aidt, 'Economic Voting and Information', Electoral Studies, 19 (2000), 349-62;
-
(2000)
Electoral Studies
, vol.19
, pp. 349-362
-
-
Aidt, T.S.1
-
145
-
-
0033995964
-
What Do Voters Know About Economy? A Study of Danish Data, 1990-1993
-
Martin Paldam and Peter Nannenstad, 'What Do Voters Know About Economy? A Study of Danish Data, 1990-1993', Electoral Studies, 19 (2000), 363-91.
-
(2000)
Electoral Studies
, vol.19
, pp. 363-391
-
-
Paldam, M.1
Nannenstad, P.2
-
146
-
-
36949027080
-
-
Different tests (see fn. 85) allowed the conclusion that the models presented in Table 2 were robust.
-
Different tests (see fn. 85) allowed the conclusion that the models presented in Table 2 were robust.
-
-
-
-
148
-
-
36949015961
-
-
This is calculated using the following formula:, b 1/2b2, 0.38.1 )/20.023, 8.28
-
2 = - ( - 0.38.1 )/2(0.023) = 8.28.
-
-
-
|