메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 76, Issue 1, 2007, Pages 39-71

Amenities and pitfalls of a reputational theory of compliance with international law

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 34547630490     PISSN: 09027351     EISSN: 15718107     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1163/090273507X181656     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (9)

References (28)
  • 1
    • 34547623450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This article is broadly based on a monograph published by the author. See M. Burgstaller, Theories of Compliance with International Law Martinus Nijhoff Publishers, Leiden, 2005, For a review of this book
    • This article is broadly based on a monograph published by the author. See M. Burgstaller, Theories of Compliance with International Law (Martinus Nijhoff Publishers, Leiden, 2005). For a review of this book,
  • 3
    • 33751561884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, 20-21 May
    • See Financial Times, 20-21 May 2006, p. 3.
    • (2006) Financial Times , pp. 3
  • 4
    • 34547641805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also The Economist, 13 May 2006, p. 49 (quoting Mr. Bellinger as to have insisted on the US's absolute commitment to upholding our national and international obligations to eradicate torture and prevent cruel, inhuman or degrading treatment or punishment anywhere).
    • See also The Economist, 13 May 2006, p. 49 (quoting Mr. Bellinger as to have insisted on the US's "absolute commitment to upholding our national and international obligations to eradicate torture and prevent cruel, inhuman or degrading treatment or punishment anywhere").
  • 5
    • 27644583460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Krisch, 'International Law in Times of Hegemony: Unequal Power and the Shaping of the International Legal Order', 16 European Journal of International Law (2005) pp. 369-408 (analysing the multiple ways in which dominant states interact with international law).
    • N. Krisch, 'International Law in Times of Hegemony: Unequal Power and the Shaping of the International Legal Order', 16 European Journal of International Law (2005) pp. 369-408 (analysing the multiple ways in which dominant states interact with international law).
  • 6
    • 34547642197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also S. H. Cleveland, 'Our International Constitution', 31 Yale Journal of International Law (2006) pp. 1-125 (arguing that international law has been a part of United States constitutional interpretation from the beginning and a principled resort to international law is fully part of the American tradition).
    • See also S. H. Cleveland, 'Our International Constitution', 31 Yale Journal of International Law (2006) pp. 1-125 (arguing that international law has been a part of United States constitutional interpretation from the beginning and a principled resort to international law is fully part of the American tradition).
  • 7
    • 34547616886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. A. Cassese, International Law (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2001) pp. 212-213.
    • Cf. A. Cassese, International Law (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2001) pp. 212-213.
  • 9
    • 34547624384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Macchiavelli (trans. W. K. Marriott), The Prince (Knopf Publishing, New York, 1981) p. 78.
    • N. Macchiavelli (trans. W. K. Marriott), The Prince (Knopf Publishing, New York, 1981) p. 78.
  • 10
    • 34547634083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally e.g. R. Dworkin, Law's Empire (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, 1986);
    • See generally e.g. R. Dworkin, Law's Empire (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, 1986);
  • 11
    • 34547647690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J. Habermas (trans. T. McCardiy), Communication and the Evolution of Society (Beacon Press, Boston, MA, 1970).
    • J. Habermas (trans. T. McCardiy), Communication and the Evolution of Society (Beacon Press, Boston, MA, 1970).
  • 12
    • 0003690687 scopus 로고
    • Columbia University Press, New York, 2nd ed
    • L. Henkin, How Nations Behave (Columbia University Press, New York, 2nd ed., 1979) p. 47.
    • (1979) How Nations Behave , pp. 47
    • Henkin, L.1
  • 13
    • 34547645296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The United Nations Treaty Series currendy contains over 150,000 treaties. United Nations Treaty Series Overview (2006), 〈untreaty.un.org/ English/overview.asp〉.
    • The United Nations Treaty Series currendy contains over 150,000 treaties. United Nations Treaty Series Overview (2006), 〈untreaty.un.org/ English/overview.asp〉.
  • 14
    • 34547613777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See e.g. the summary provided by O. Yasuaki, 'International Law in and with International Politics: The Functions of International Law in International Society', 14 European Journal of International Law (2003) p. 105.
    • See e.g. the summary provided by O. Yasuaki, 'International Law in and with International Politics: The Functions of International Law in International Society', 14 European Journal of International Law (2003) p. 105.
  • 16
    • 34547614858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I have given an overview of various dieories of compliance with international law in Burgstaller, supra note 1, pp. 103-190
    • I have given an overview of various dieories of compliance with international law in Burgstaller, supra note 1, pp. 103-190.
  • 17
    • 0041743213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See e.g. O. A. Hathaway, 'The Cost of Commitment', 55 Stanford Law Review (2003) p. 1821 (arguing that scholars have almost entirely ignored the questions of why treaties come into being and what motivates nations to join them). But,
    • See e.g. O. A. Hathaway, 'The Cost of Commitment', 55 Stanford Law Review (2003) p. 1821 (arguing that scholars have almost entirely ignored the questions of why treaties come into being and what motivates nations to join them). But,
  • 18
    • 34547644512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also O. A. Hathaway, 'Between Power and Principle: An Integrated Theory of International Law', 71 University of Chicago Law Review (2005) pp. 473-474 (arguing that we find that compliance not only depends upon the decision to commit, but commitment also depends upon the decision to comply).
    • see also O. A. Hathaway, 'Between Power and Principle: An Integrated Theory of International Law', 71 University of Chicago Law Review (2005) pp. 473-474 (arguing that we find that compliance not only depends upon the decision to commit, but commitment also depends upon the decision to comply).
  • 19
    • 27844609036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. e.g. A. T. Guzman, 'The Design of International Agreements', 16 European Journal of International Law (2005) pp. 579-612 (explaining why rational states sometimes prefer to draft their agreements in such a way as to make them less credible and therefore more easily violated; arguing further that parties, when deciding which design elements to include, must balance the benefits of increased compliance against the costs triggered in the event of a violation; hereinafter 'Design');
    • Cf. e.g. A. T. Guzman, 'The Design of International Agreements', 16 European Journal of International Law (2005) pp. 579-612 (explaining why rational states sometimes prefer to draft their agreements in such a way as to make them less credible and therefore more easily violated; arguing further that parties, when deciding which design elements to include, must balance the benefits of increased compliance against the costs triggered in the event of a violation; hereinafter 'Design');
  • 20
    • 0042169059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A. T. Guzman, 'The Cost of Credibility: Explaining Resistance to Interstate Dispute Resolution Mechanisms', 31 Journal of Legal Studies (2002) pp. 303-326 (explaining why the use of mandatory dispute resolution is the exception rather than the rule in international agreements; hereinafter 'Cost of Credibility').
    • A. T. Guzman, 'The Cost of Credibility: Explaining Resistance to Interstate Dispute Resolution Mechanisms', 31 Journal of Legal Studies (2002) pp. 303-326 (explaining why the use of mandatory dispute resolution is the exception rather than the rule in international agreements; hereinafter 'Cost of Credibility').
  • 21
    • 0036958756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 90 California
    • A Compliance-Based Theory of International Law
    • A. T. Guzman, A Compliance-Based Theory of International Law", 90 California Law Review (2002) p. 1823;
    • (2002) Law Review , pp. 1823
    • Guzman, A.T.1
  • 22
    • 0042540000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J. K. Setear, An Iterative Perspective on Treaties: A Synthesis of International Relations Theory and International Law', 37 Harvard International Law Journal (1996) p. 156. I will also mostly forego a discussion of the-increasingly somewhat blurred-differentiation between various forms of 'legalisation' of international relations.
    • J. K. Setear, An Iterative Perspective on Treaties: A Synthesis of International Relations Theory and International Law', 37 Harvard International Law Journal (1996) p. 156. I will also mostly forego a discussion of the-increasingly somewhat blurred-differentiation between various forms of 'legalisation' of international relations.
  • 24
    • 0039438255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Conclusion: The Causes and Consequences of Legalization', 54
    • M. Kahler, 'Conclusion: The Causes and Consequences of Legalization', 54 International Organization (2000) pp. 661-683;
    • (2000) International Organization , pp. 661-683
    • Kahler, M.1
  • 25
    • 34547646393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • D. Shelton, 'Law, Non-Law and the Problem of Soft Law, in D. Shelton (ed.), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Non-Binding Norms in the International. Legal System (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2000) pp. 7-23 (hereinafter 'Commitment and Compliance');
    • D. Shelton, 'Law, Non-Law and the Problem of Soft Law, in D. Shelton (ed.), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Non-Binding Norms in the International. Legal System (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2000) pp. 7-23 (hereinafter 'Commitment and Compliance');
  • 26
    • 0036385995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compliance and International Soft Law: Why Do Countries Implement the Basle Accord?', 5
    • D. H. Ho, 'Compliance and International Soft Law: Why Do Countries Implement the Basle Accord?', 5 Journal of International Economic Law (2002) pp. 647-688;
    • (2002) Journal of International Economic Law , pp. 647-688
    • Ho, D.H.1
  • 27
    • 27844488612 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • K Raustiala, 'Form and Substance in International Agreements', 99 American Journal of International Law (2005) pp. 581-614 (arguing that widespread preference for contracts often unduly weakens the substance and structure of multilateral agreements when states are uncertain about compliance costs). Unless otherwise addressed, I will concentrate on compliance with international treaty law.
    • K Raustiala, 'Form and Substance in International Agreements', 99 American Journal of International Law (2005) pp. 581-614 (arguing that widespread preference for contracts often unduly weakens the substance and structure of multilateral agreements when states are uncertain about compliance costs). Unless otherwise addressed, I will concentrate on compliance with international treaty law.
  • 28
    • 0034557605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A successful answer to the question of why people obey laws reveals nothing about whether or why they are obliged to do so. E. M. Peñalver, 'The Persistent Problem of Obligation in International Law', 36 Stanford Journal of International Law (2000) p. 274.
    • "A successful answer to the question of why people obey laws reveals nothing about whether or why they are obliged to do so." E. M. Peñalver, 'The Persistent Problem of Obligation in International Law', 36 Stanford Journal of International Law (2000) p. 274.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.