메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 5, Issue 3, 2002, Pages 647-688

Compliance and international soft law: Why do countries implement the Basle Accord?

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0036385995     PISSN: 13693034     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/jiel/5.3.647     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (77)

References (166)
  • 1
    • 0032349842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compliance with International Agreements
    • On compliance, see, for example, Beth A. Simmons, 'Compliance with International Agreements', 1 Ann R Pol Sci 75 (1998); Abram Chayes and Antonia Chayes, 'On Compliance', 47 Int'l Org 175 (1993); and Harold H. Koh, 'Why do Nations Obey International Law?', 106 Yale LJ 2599 (1997). On soft law, see, for example, Dinah Shelton (ed), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Nonbinding Norms in the International Legal System (2000); Charles Lipson, 'Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?', 45 Int'l Org 495 (1991); Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, 'Hard and Soft Law in International Governance', 54 Int'l Org 421 (2000); but cf. Francis A. Boyle, 'The Irrelevance of International Law: The Schism Between International Law and International Polities', 10 Cal W Int'l LJ 193 (1980). See also Louis Henkin, How Nations Behave (1979).
    • (1998) Ann R Pol Sci , vol.1 , pp. 75
    • Simmons, B.A.1
  • 2
    • 0032349842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Compliance
    • On compliance, see, for example, Beth A. Simmons, 'Compliance with International Agreements', 1 Ann R Pol Sci 75 (1998); Abram Chayes and Antonia Chayes, 'On Compliance', 47 Int'l Org 175 (1993); and Harold H. Koh, 'Why do Nations Obey International Law?', 106 Yale LJ 2599 (1997). On soft law, see, for example, Dinah Shelton (ed), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Nonbinding Norms in the International Legal System (2000); Charles Lipson, 'Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?', 45 Int'l Org 495 (1991); Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, 'Hard and Soft Law in International Governance', 54 Int'l Org 421 (2000); but cf. Francis A. Boyle, 'The Irrelevance of International Law: The Schism Between International Law and International Polities', 10 Cal W Int'l LJ 193 (1980). See also Louis Henkin, How Nations Behave (1979).
    • (1993) Int'l Org , vol.47 , pp. 175
    • Chayes, A.1    Chayes, A.2
  • 3
    • 0347981231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why do Nations Obey International Law?
    • On compliance, see, for example, Beth A. Simmons, 'Compliance with International Agreements', 1 Ann R Pol Sci 75 (1998); Abram Chayes and Antonia Chayes, 'On Compliance', 47 Int'l Org 175 (1993); and Harold H. Koh, 'Why do Nations Obey International Law?', 106 Yale LJ 2599 (1997). On soft law, see, for example, Dinah Shelton (ed), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Nonbinding Norms in the International Legal System (2000); Charles Lipson, 'Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?', 45 Int'l Org 495 (1991); Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, 'Hard and Soft Law in International Governance', 54 Int'l Org 421 (2000); but cf. Francis A. Boyle, 'The Irrelevance of International Law: The Schism Between International Law and International Polities', 10 Cal W Int'l LJ 193 (1980). See also Louis Henkin, How Nations Behave (1979).
    • (1997) Yale LJ , vol.106 , pp. 2599
    • Koh, H.H.1
  • 4
    • 0032349842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On compliance, see, for example, Beth A. Simmons, 'Compliance with International Agreements', 1 Ann R Pol Sci 75 (1998); Abram Chayes and Antonia Chayes, 'On Compliance', 47 Int'l Org 175 (1993); and Harold H. Koh, 'Why do Nations Obey International Law?', 106 Yale LJ 2599 (1997). On soft law, see, for example, Dinah Shelton (ed), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Nonbinding Norms in the International Legal System (2000); Charles Lipson, 'Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?', 45 Int'l Org 495 (1991); Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, 'Hard and Soft Law in International Governance', 54 Int'l Org 421 (2000); but cf. Francis A. Boyle, 'The Irrelevance of International Law: The Schism Between International Law and International Polities', 10 Cal W Int'l LJ 193 (1980). See also Louis Henkin, How Nations Behave (1979).
    • (2000) Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Nonbinding Norms in the International Legal System
    • Shelton, D.1
  • 5
    • 84976128766 scopus 로고
    • Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?
    • On compliance, see, for example, Beth A. Simmons, 'Compliance with International Agreements', 1 Ann R Pol Sci 75 (1998); Abram Chayes and Antonia Chayes, 'On Compliance', 47 Int'l Org 175 (1993); and Harold H. Koh, 'Why do Nations Obey International Law?', 106 Yale LJ 2599 (1997). On soft law, see, for example, Dinah Shelton (ed), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Nonbinding Norms in the International Legal System (2000); Charles Lipson, 'Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?', 45 Int'l Org 495 (1991); Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, 'Hard and Soft Law in International Governance', 54 Int'l Org 421 (2000); but cf. Francis A. Boyle, 'The Irrelevance of International Law: The Schism Between International Law and International Polities', 10 Cal W Int'l LJ 193 (1980). See also Louis Henkin, How Nations Behave (1979).
    • (1991) Int'l Org , vol.45 , pp. 495
    • Lipson, C.1
  • 6
    • 0034408291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hard and Soft Law in International Governance
    • On compliance, see, for example, Beth A. Simmons, 'Compliance with International Agreements', 1 Ann R Pol Sci 75 (1998); Abram Chayes and Antonia Chayes, 'On Compliance', 47 Int'l Org 175 (1993); and Harold H. Koh, 'Why do Nations Obey International Law?', 106 Yale LJ 2599 (1997). On soft law, see, for example, Dinah Shelton (ed), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Nonbinding Norms in the International Legal System (2000); Charles Lipson, 'Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?', 45 Int'l Org 495 (1991); Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, 'Hard and Soft Law in International Governance', 54 Int'l Org 421 (2000); but cf. Francis A. Boyle, 'The Irrelevance of International Law: The Schism Between International Law and International Polities', 10 Cal W Int'l LJ 193 (1980). See also Louis Henkin, How Nations Behave (1979).
    • (2000) Int'l Org , vol.54 , pp. 421
    • Abbott, K.W.1    Snidal, D.2
  • 7
    • 0032349842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Irrelevance of International Law: The Schism between International Law and International Polities
    • On compliance, see, for example, Beth A. Simmons, 'Compliance with International Agreements', 1 Ann R Pol Sci 75 (1998); Abram Chayes and Antonia Chayes, 'On Compliance', 47 Int'l Org 175 (1993); and Harold H. Koh, 'Why do Nations Obey International Law?', 106 Yale LJ 2599 (1997). On soft law, see, for example, Dinah Shelton (ed), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Nonbinding Norms in the International Legal System (2000); Charles Lipson, 'Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?', 45 Int'l Org 495 (1991); Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, 'Hard and Soft Law in International Governance', 54 Int'l Org 421 (2000); but cf. Francis A. Boyle, 'The Irrelevance of International Law: The Schism Between International Law and International Polities', 10 Cal W Int'l LJ 193 (1980). See also Louis Henkin, How Nations Behave (1979).
    • (1980) Cal W Int'l LJ , vol.10 , pp. 193
    • Boyle, F.A.1
  • 8
    • 0032349842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On compliance, see, for example, Beth A. Simmons, 'Compliance with International Agreements', 1 Ann R Pol Sci 75 (1998); Abram Chayes and Antonia Chayes, 'On Compliance', 47 Int'l Org 175 (1993); and Harold H. Koh, 'Why do Nations Obey International Law?', 106 Yale LJ 2599 (1997). On soft law, see, for example, Dinah Shelton (ed), Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Nonbinding Norms in the International Legal System (2000); Charles Lipson, 'Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?', 45 Int'l Org 495 (1991); Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, 'Hard and Soft Law in International Governance', 54 Int'l Org 421 (2000); but cf. Francis A. Boyle, 'The Irrelevance of International Law: The Schism Between International Law and International Polities', 10 Cal W Int'l LJ 193 (1980). See also Louis Henkin, How Nations Behave (1979).
    • (1979) How Nations Behave
    • Henkin, L.1
  • 9
    • 0344771228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The distinction between hard law and soft law is not clear throughout the literature. To the degree that states operate in environments without a supranational enforcement mechanism) all forms of international law are soft. I use a more tailored definition that distinguishes between the binding nature of an agreement (or as the legalization literature would have it, obligation). The Basle Accord is thereby 'softer' than NAFTA or even Article VIII commitments under the IMF Articles of Agreement. See Abbott and Snidal, above n 1, at 2 (noting that '[t]he realm of soft law begins once legal arrangements are weakened along one or more of the dimensions of obligation, precision, and delegation . . . the choice between hard law and soft law is not a binary one').
  • 10
    • 0004122529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For exceptions of scholarly work that has provided substantial empirical evidence of compliance, see Edith B. Weiss and Harold K. Jacobson (eds), Engaging Countries: Strengthening Compliance with International Accords (1998); Beth A. Simmons, 'The Legalization of International Monetary Affairs', 54 Int'l Org 573 (2000); Beth A. Simmons, 'International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs', 94 Am Pol Sc Rev 819 (2000). Beth A. Simmons, 'Money and the Law: Why Comply with the Public International Law of Money?', 25 Yale J Int'l L 323 (2000).
    • (1998) Engaging Countries: Strengthening Compliance with International Accords
    • Weiss, E.B.1    Jacobson, H.K.2
  • 11
    • 0034370862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Legalization of International Monetary Affairs
    • For exceptions of scholarly work that has provided substantial empirical evidence of compliance, see Edith B. Weiss and Harold K. Jacobson (eds), Engaging Countries: Strengthening Compliance with International Accords (1998); Beth A. Simmons, 'The Legalization of International Monetary Affairs', 54 Int'l Org 573 (2000); Beth A. Simmons, 'International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs', 94 Am Pol Sc Rev 819 (2000). Beth A. Simmons, 'Money and the Law: Why Comply with the Public International Law of Money?', 25 Yale J Int'l L 323 (2000).
    • (2000) Int'l Org , vol.54 , pp. 573
    • Simmons, B.A.1
  • 12
    • 0034557302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs
    • For exceptions of scholarly work that has provided substantial empirical evidence of compliance, see Edith B. Weiss and Harold K. Jacobson (eds), Engaging Countries: Strengthening Compliance with International Accords (1998); Beth A. Simmons, 'The Legalization of International Monetary Affairs', 54 Int'l Org 573 (2000); Beth A. Simmons, 'International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs', 94 Am Pol Sc Rev 819 (2000). Beth A. Simmons, 'Money and the Law: Why Comply with the Public International Law of Money?', 25 Yale J Int'l L 323 (2000).
    • (2000) Am Pol Sc Rev , vol.94 , pp. 819
    • Simmons, B.A.1
  • 13
    • 0345633759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Money and the Law: Why Comply with the Public International Law of Money?
    • For exceptions of scholarly work that has provided substantial empirical evidence of compliance, see Edith B. Weiss and Harold K. Jacobson (eds), Engaging Countries: Strengthening Compliance with International Accords (1998); Beth A. Simmons, 'The Legalization of International Monetary Affairs', 54 Int'l Org 573 (2000); Beth A. Simmons, 'International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs', 94 Am Pol Sc Rev 819 (2000). Beth A. Simmons, 'Money and the Law: Why Comply with the Public International Law of Money?', 25 Yale J Int'l L 323 (2000).
    • (2000) Yale J Int'l L , vol.25 , pp. 323
    • Simmons, B.A.1
  • 15
    • 0344339239 scopus 로고
    • (25 July) [hereafter Basle Accord]
    • Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards, reprinted in 51 Banking Rep (BNA) 143 (25 July 1988) [hereafter Basle Accord].
    • (1988) Banking Rep (BNA) , vol.51 , pp. 143
  • 16
    • 84976156430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • (1989) Int'l Org , vol.43 , pp. 323
    • Kapstein, E.B.1
  • 17
    • 84972279294 scopus 로고
    • Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • (1992) Int'l Org. , vol.46 , pp. 265
    • Kapstein, E.B.1
  • 18
    • 0032340404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • (1998) Int'l Org , vol.52 , pp. 35
    • Oatley, T.1    Nabors, R.2
  • 19
    • 0040240267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • (1996) J Fin , vol.51 , pp. 1321
    • Wagster, J.D.1
  • 20
    • 84976156430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • mimeo
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • (1990) Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-country Evidence
    • De Bondt, G.J.1    Prast, H.M.2
  • 21
    • 84976156430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord
    • April
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • (1999) Working Papers , vol.1
    • Jackson, P.1
  • 22
    • 84976156430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks
    • Mario Giovanoli (ed)
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • (2000) International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium , pp. 291
    • Follak, K.P.1
  • 23
    • 0347116311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • (2001) Bus L , vol.56 , pp. 767
    • Tarbert, H.P.1
  • 24
    • 84976156430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • (1992) Dick J Int'l L , vol.10 , pp. 189
    • Alford, D.E.1
  • 25
    • 0035618099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • (2001) Int'l Org , vol.55 , pp. 589
    • Simmons, B.A.1
  • 26
    • 84976156430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks
    • Although I do not retell the process of negotiating the Basle Accord here, my study largely relies on previous theories. For the background on the politics of the Basle Accord, which is particularly revealing in terms of the particular country preferences towards the Basle Accord, see Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations', 43 Int'l Org 323 (1989); Ethan Barnaby Kapstein, 'Between Power and Purpose: Central Bankers and the Politics of Regulatory Convergence', 46 Int'l Org. 265 (1992); cf. Thomas Oatley and Robert Nabors, Redistributive 'Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord', 52 Int'l Org 35 (1998). For empirical analyses at the bank level on the impact of the Basle Accord, see John Douglas Wagster, 'Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on International Banks', 51 J Fin 1321 (1996); G. J. de Bondt and H. M. Prast, 'Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-Country Evidence' (mimeo); and Patricia Jackson, 'Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Capital Requirements and Bank Behavior: The Impact of the Basle Accord', Working Papers, No. 1 (April 1999) for a good review of the capital adequacy literature. For a legal analysis, see Klaus Peter Follak, 'International Harmonization of Regulatory and Supervisory Frameworks', in Mario Giovanoli (ed), International Monetary Law: Issues for the New Millennium 291 (2000); Heath Price Tarbert, 'Rethinking Capital Adequacy: The Basle Accord and the New Framework', 56 Bus L 767 (2001); and Duncan E. Alford, 'Basle Committee International Capital Adequacy Standards: Analysis and Implications for the Banking Industry', 10 Dick J Int'l L 189 (1992). For an institutionalist framework, see Beth A. Simmons, 'The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation' 55 Int'l Org 589 (2001). See also Robert E. Krainer, 'Banking in a Theory of the Business Cycle: A Model and Critique of the Basle Accord on Risk Based Capital Requirements for Banks', SSRN Working Paper.
    • SSRN Working Paper
    • Krainer, R.E.1
  • 27
    • 0003425989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5th edn
    • Bank capital (equity) is traditionally defined as assets (loans) minus liabilities (deposits). See Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld, International Economics: Theory and Policy 659-67 (5th edn 2000). The Basle Accord goes further in dividing capital into two tiers. Tier 1, defined as paid-up share capital/common stock and published reserves from post-tax retained earnings, must comprise at least 5 per cent of a bank's capital base. Tier 2, defined as undisclosed reserves, asset revaluation reserves, general provisions/general loan-loss reserves; hybrid (debt/equity) capital instruments, and subordinated debt, is limited to 10 per cent of Tier 1 and combined with Tier 1 must comprise 8 per cent of the risk-weighted assets. See Basle Accord, above n 4, Annex 17. On-balance sheet assets are assigned to one of four risk buckets as part of the risk-weighting procedure, as I discuss below.
    • (2000) International Economics: Theory and Policy , pp. 659-667
    • Krugman, P.R.1    Obstfeld, M.2
  • 29
    • 84894513246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jackson, above n 5. The Basle Accord has been amended five times since 1988, most importantly in 1996 to cover market risks. The BIS is currently in the process of drafting a new Basle Capital Accord that would incorporate Internal Risk Based Assessment under a three-pillar framework.
    • Working Paper
    • Jackson1
  • 31
    • 0000748318 scopus 로고
    • International Law in a World of Liberal States
    • There is significant dispute in the legal academy as to what forms of agreement should be considered international law. From a positivist perspective, any form of international law that exhibits an independent effect on state behaviour should be considered, which is why I adopt a broad conception here. This is similar to Slaughter's conception of international law as 'comprising] all the law that regulates activity across and between territorial boundaries'. Anne-Marie Slaughter, 'International Law in a World of Liberal States', 6 Eur J Int'l L 503 (1995). If empirical tests show that weaker forms of international law, such as soft law or customary international law, do not exhibit an independent effect on state behaviour, scholars will need to reconceptualize theories of compliance (as well as international law) accordingly. Soft law and customary law constitute a critical test for realist conceptions of international law and also represent crucial cases for a general theory of compliance. See Andrew T. Guzman, 'International Law: A Compliance Based Theory', 90 Cal L Rev (2002) (forthcoming) (proposing a theory of compliance based upon reputational harm that applies broadly to forms or international law and arguing that '[b]y allowing states to establish clear rules and pledge their reputation, treaties cause the behavior of states to change, which I term binding force'). But cf. Jack L. Goldsmith and Eric A. Posner, 'A Theory of Customary International Law', 66 U Chi L Rev 1113 (1999) (arguing that reputation does not play an independent role in customary international law outside of punishment strategies in repeated games). In the end, the definition of international law is by no means dispositive of the analysis presented.
    • (1995) Eur J Int'l L , vol.6 , pp. 503
    • Slaughter, A.-M.1
  • 32
    • 42949162543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Law: A Compliance Based Theory
    • forthcoming
    • There is significant dispute in the legal academy as to what forms of agreement should be considered international law. From a positivist perspective, any form of international law that exhibits an independent effect on state behaviour should be considered, which is why I adopt a broad conception here. This is similar to Slaughter's conception of international law as 'comprising] all the law that regulates activity across and between territorial boundaries'. Anne-Marie Slaughter, 'International Law in a World of Liberal States', 6 Eur J Int'l L 503 (1995). If empirical tests show that weaker forms of international law, such as soft law or customary international law, do not exhibit an independent effect on state behaviour, scholars will need to reconceptualize theories of compliance (as well as international law) accordingly. Soft law and customary law constitute a critical test for realist conceptions of international law and also represent crucial cases for a general theory of compliance. See Andrew T. Guzman, 'International Law: A Compliance Based Theory', 90 Cal L Rev (2002) (forthcoming) (proposing a theory of compliance based upon reputational harm that applies broadly to forms or international law and arguing that '[b]y allowing states to establish clear rules and pledge their reputation, treaties cause the behavior of states to change, which I term binding force'). But cf. Jack L. Goldsmith and Eric A. Posner, 'A Theory of Customary International Law', 66 U Chi L Rev 1113 (1999) (arguing that reputation does not play an independent role in customary international law outside of punishment strategies in repeated games). In the end, the definition of international law is by no means dispositive of the analysis presented.
    • (2002) Cal L Rev , vol.90
    • Guzman, A.T.1
  • 33
    • 0347758908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Customary International Law
    • There is significant dispute in the legal academy as to what forms of agreement should be considered international law. From a positivist perspective, any form of international law that exhibits an independent effect on state behaviour should be considered, which is why I adopt a broad conception here. This is similar to Slaughter's conception of international law as 'comprising] all the law that regulates activity across and between territorial boundaries'. Anne-Marie Slaughter, 'International Law in a World of Liberal States', 6 Eur J Int'l L 503 (1995). If empirical tests show that weaker forms of international law, such as soft law or customary international law, do not exhibit an independent effect on state behaviour, scholars will need to reconceptualize theories of compliance (as well as international law) accordingly. Soft law and customary law constitute a critical test for realist conceptions of international law and also represent crucial cases for a general theory of compliance. See Andrew T. Guzman, 'International Law: A Compliance Based Theory', 90 Cal L Rev (2002) (forthcoming) (proposing a theory of compliance based upon reputational harm that applies broadly to forms or international law and arguing that '[b]y allowing states to establish clear rules and pledge their reputation, treaties cause the behavior of states to change, which I term binding force'). But cf. Jack L. Goldsmith and Eric A. Posner, 'A Theory of Customary International Law', 66 U Chi L Rev 1113 (1999) (arguing that reputation does not play an independent role in customary international law outside of punishment strategies in repeated games). In the end, the definition of international law is by no means dispositive of the analysis presented.
    • (1999) U Chi L Rev , vol.66 , pp. 1113
    • Goldsmith, J.L.1    Posner, E.A.2
  • 35
    • 0345633772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I am indebted to James Perry for sparking this discussion
    • I am indebted to James Perry for sparking this discussion.
  • 36
    • 0030500365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is the Good News about Compliance Good News about Cooperation?
    • The 'enforcement school' views international cooperation as strictly limited by its depth. Incentives of unilateral defection rise with the depth of cooperation, and therefore the only method of ensuring compliance as the requirements of international law become more onerous is to increase enforcement. See George W. Downs et al. 'Is the Good News About Compliance Good News About Cooperation?', 50 Int'l Org 379, 384-87, 380 (1996) (noting that 'the high level of compliance and the marginality of enforcement result from the fact that most treaties require states to make only modest departures from what they would have done in the absence of an agreement').
    • (1996) Int'l Org , vol.50 , pp. 379
    • Downs, G.W.1
  • 37
    • 0345201837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, sanctioning outside of the regulatory agreement is still possible
    • Of course, sanctioning outside of the regulatory agreement is still possible.
  • 38
    • 0344771223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Realists have paid little attention to the factors affecting compliance, merely asserting that compliance arises from the selection effect at the drafting stage. International law is therefore held out as epiphenomenal. However, first, it is not clear that the selection effect arises merely from power capacity issues internationally, as I explore here. Secondly, from a dynamic perspective, we can test whether the likelihood of compliance is affected more by power capacities (however defined) or institutionalist factors. In this short article I have the much less ambitious objective of answering merely the first question of why states opt in.
  • 40
    • 0345201841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Theorists have pointed out that regardless of whether national capital requirements exist, banks may still maintain particular capital-assets ratios as a signalling device to attract investors and depositors in accordance with its appetite for risk and return.
  • 41
    • 1842555879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bank Capital Regulation in Contemporary Banking Theory
    • For a good review of the theoretical literature, see João A.C. Santos, 'Bank Capital Regulation in Contemporary Banking Theory', BIS Working Papers No. 90 (2000). For a review of the empirical literature, see Jackson, above n 5.
    • (2000) BIS Working Papers No. 90 , vol.90
    • Santos, J.A.C.1
  • 42
    • 84894513246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a good review of the theoretical literature, see João A.C. Santos, 'Bank Capital Regulation in Contemporary Banking Theory', BIS Working Papers No. 90 (2000). For a review of the empirical literature, see Jackson, above n 5.
    • Working Papers
    • Jackson1
  • 43
    • 0344339243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Much of this section draws on insight from industry comments solicited for the new Basle Capital Accord. I am aware of the methodological problems of inferring bank preferences towards the original Basle Accord from industry comments for the new Basle Accord. While the new Basle Accord's provisions for the Internal Risk Based Approach is in many respects more complex, reviewing reactions of national supervisory authorities and subnational interest groups is still one of the best methods of highlighting the distributional concerns of CAR. in general, especially in light of the dearth of other available data. Moreover, the fact that (a) national supervisors first collected industry comments and subsequently submitted them to the Basle committee, (b) subnational firms submitted comments directly, and (c) international organizations submitted comments directly sheds tremendous light into the pressures on the formulation of international soft law.
  • 46
    • 0344339241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Banks with higher tastes for risk, for example, may shift to the riskier types of capital within each risk bucket. Such a task may entail greater costs for banks that have portfolios spread across more risk buckets as a proportion of their overall capital structure.
  • 47
    • 0344577221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wealth Effects of the Basle Accord on Small Banks
    • See, e.g. Chiuling Lu et al. 'Wealth Effects of the Basle Accord on Small Banks', 23 J Econ Fin 246 (1999).
    • (1999) J Econ Fin , vol.23 , pp. 246
    • Lu, C.1
  • 49
    • 0344339242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • National supervisors have recognized this concern, and attempted to provide a 'menu' of risk assessment geared towards different types of banks in the new Basle Accord.
  • 50
    • 0002072240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Emerging Problems with the Basel Accord: Regulatory Capital Arbitrage and Related Issues
    • See D. Jones, 'Emerging Problems with the Basel Accord: Regulatory Capital Arbitrage and Related Issues' 14 J Banking Fin 35 (2000).
    • (2000) J Banking Fin , vol.14 , pp. 35
    • Jones, D.1
  • 54
    • 0000907042 scopus 로고
    • The Macroeconomic Implications of Capital Adequacy Requirements for Banks
    • But see Juerg Blum and Martin Hellwig, 'The Macroeconomic Implications of Capital Adequacy Requirements for Banks', 39 Eur Econ Rev 739, 741 (1995).
    • (1995) Eur Econ Rev , vol.39 , pp. 739
    • Blum, J.1    Hellwig, M.2
  • 55
    • 0344339237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These two perspectives roughly represent the Kapstein and Oatley and Nabors debate. See Kapstein, above n 5 (explaining the Basle Accord from a public goods perspective whereby leadership of the UK and US 'learned' from the 1982 debt crisis); Oatley and Nabors, above n 5 (arguing that international redistributive factors prevailed). My argument is in some sense an extension from this debate. I argue that we cannot explain individual national decisions to implement the Basle Accord without extending the distributional analysis to a domestic institutional level. I also ascertain the applicability of the learning hypothesis (that Congress learned after the debt crisis and responded to voters' demands to prevent irresponsible lending by US banks after the 1983 IMF bailout), and its applicability to other countries.
    • Minimum Capital Requirements and the Design of the New Basel Accord
    • Milne1
  • 56
    • 0344771222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These two perspectives roughly represent the Kapstein and Oatley and Nabors debate. See Kapstein, above n 5 (explaining the Basle Accord from a public goods perspective whereby leadership of the UK and US 'learned' from the 1982 debt crisis); Oatley and Nabors, above n 5 (arguing that international redistributive factors prevailed). My argument is in some sense an extension from this debate. I argue that we cannot explain individual national decisions to implement the Basle Accord without extending the distributional analysis to a domestic institutional level. I also ascertain the applicability of the learning hypothesis (that Congress learned after the debt crisis and responded to voters' demands to prevent irresponsible lending by US banks after the 1983 IMF bailout), and its applicability to other countries.
    • Int'l Org
    • Kapstein1
  • 57
    • 0344339236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These two perspectives roughly represent the Kapstein and Oatley and Nabors debate. See Kapstein, above n 5 (explaining the Basle Accord from a public goods perspective whereby leadership of the UK and US 'learned' from the 1982 debt crisis); Oatley and Nabors, above n 5 (arguing that international redistributive factors prevailed). My argument is in some sense an extension from this debate. I argue that we cannot explain individual national decisions to implement the Basle Accord without extending the distributional analysis to a domestic institutional level. I also ascertain the applicability of the learning hypothesis (that Congress learned after the debt crisis and responded to voters' demands to prevent irresponsible lending by US banks after the 1983 IMF bailout), and its applicability to other countries.
    • Int'l Org
    • Oatley1    Nabors2
  • 58
    • 0345201838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Se subsection I.B above and 17-28
    • See subsection I.B above and 17-28.
  • 59
    • 84923754407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Guzman, above n 10; Simmons, above n 3. For the domestic analogue of reputational theories of norms and law from a game theoretic perspective, see Eric A. Posner, Law and Social Norms (2000).
    • Cal L Rev
    • Guzman1
  • 60
    • 0345201840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Guzman, above n 10; Simmons, above n 3. For the domestic analogue of reputational theories of norms and law from a game theoretic perspective, see Eric A. Posner, Law and Social Norms (2000).
    • Int'l Org
    • Simmons1
  • 61
    • 78149446644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Guzman, above n 10; Simmons, above n 3. For the domestic analogue of reputational theories of norms and law from a game theoretic perspective, see Eric A. Posner, Law and Social Norms (2000).
    • (2000) Law and Social Norms
    • Posner, A.1
  • 62
    • 84894513246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jackson, above n 5, at 2. Granted, the tests in this study are by no means definitive proof of this framework, but only suggestive evidence.
    • Working Papers
    • Jackson1
  • 64
    • 0345201833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Issues in Financial Institution Capital in Emerging Market Economies
    • See Allen B. Frankel, 'Issues in Financial Institution Capital in Emerging Market Economies', Federal Reserve Bank of New York 22 (1998).
    • (1998) Federal Reserve Bank of New York , pp. 22
    • Frankel, A.B.1
  • 66
    • 0345633767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 30 May
    • See, e.g. Bank of Korea, Letter to Basle Committee on Banking Supervision (30 May 2001) (noting difference between financially weak banks of emerging markets making more difficult the raising of new capital).
    • (2001) Letter to Basle Committee on Banking Supervision
  • 67
    • 0345201835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Ideally, our indicator would measure only the banking sector's exposure so that we do not pick up the positive effect on insurance companies, who are likely to gain from implementation.
  • 68
    • 0347635032 scopus 로고
    • The Foreign Bank Supervision Enhancement Act of 1991
    • See Ann E. Misback, 'The Foreign Bank Supervision Enhancement Act of 1991', Fed Reserve Bulletin (1993).
    • (1993) Fed Reserve Bulletin
    • Misback, A.E.1
  • 69
    • 0345633766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 7 June
    • Concerns of competitive equity, for example, were voiced by National Australia Bank in response to the New Basle Accord, since Australian banks would ostensibly be subject to greater supervisory rigour than other Asian banks. See 'National Australia Bank, Comment to Basle Committee on Banking Supervision' § 2.3 (7 June 2001).
    • (2001) National Australia Bank, Comment to Basle Committee on Banking Supervision , pp. 23
  • 71
    • 0344339235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • On the other hand, higher savings may be indicative of deeper financial markets, which would make countries potentially less susceptible to banking crisis, but not necessarily systemic risk.
  • 72
    • 0344771218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also discussion below, I.E.4
    • See also discussion below, I.E.4.
  • 73
    • 84883102737 scopus 로고
    • Frieden provides ample evidence from the debt crises that mobilized broad coalitions in opposition to the banking sector. See, e.g. Jeffry A. Frieden, Banking on the World: The Politics of American International Finance 172 (1988) (stating the debt burdens in lesser developed countries led to international bankers being 'blamed rather than courted').
    • (1988) Banking on the World: The Politics of American International Finance , pp. 172
    • Frieden, J.A.1
  • 75
    • 0040922796 scopus 로고
    • Financial Deregulation and Interest Intermediation
    • Gary A. Hanson and Yasamori Sone (eds)
    • For a clearer statement of when producers dominate, see Frances McCall Rosenbluth, 'Financial Deregulation and Interest Intermediation', in Gary A. Hanson and Yasamori Sone (eds), Political Dynamics in Contemporary Japan (1993).
    • (1993) Political Dynamics in Contemporary Japan
    • Rosenbluth, F.M.1
  • 77
    • 0345633768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. The degree to which this pattern of lending has actually held true in emerging markets is still subject to debate. I only present the mechanism as a plausible mechanism for which domestic distributional concerns regarding the Basle Accord could vary along foreign-bank ownership in the market.
  • 78
    • 78249232103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 43
    • See Task Force Report, above n 43, at 44 (finding that '[s]tate-owned banks almost invariably have worse loan-loss experience and lower profitability than their commercial counterparts').
    • Task Force Report , pp. 44
  • 79
    • 0344339247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In particular, I have had to settle with less than optimal indicators of bank exposure. The most comprehensive international banking statistics are provided primarily by signatory countries to the Basle Accord and countries that have already opted into the Basle Accord. Therefore the ideal statistics (e.g. loans to developing countries, announced international equity issues, etc.) cannot be included in this set, but we can test their correlation with the variables we use as proxies for international exposure of the banking system. See Bondt and Prast, above n 5, at 19 (noting that 'bank-specific factors are not the only significant determinants of the [risk-adjusted capital ratio]').
    • Bank Capital Ratios in the 1990s: Cross-country Evidence , pp. 19
    • Bondt1    Prast2
  • 82
    • 0345633764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law, Finance, and Economic Growth
    • mimeo
    • See Ross Levine, 'Law, Finance, and Economic Growth', World Bank (1997) (mimeo).
    • (1997) World Bank
    • Levine, R.1
  • 83
    • 0004094016 scopus 로고
    • This brand of argument is related to the comparative literature on political determinants of economic reforms. See, e.g. Stephen Haggard and R. R. Kaufman (eds), The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions (1995) (providing evidence that insulated chief executives are better able to implement economic reforms); Stephen Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery (1990) (providing evidence that autocracies are better able to implement economic reforms).
    • (1995) The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions
    • Haggard, S.1    Kaufman, R.R.2
  • 84
    • 0003744495 scopus 로고
    • This brand of argument is related to the comparative literature on political determinants of economic reforms. See, e.g. Stephen Haggard and R. R. Kaufman (eds), The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions (1995) (providing evidence that insulated chief executives are better able to implement economic reforms); Stephen Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery (1990) (providing evidence that autocracies are better able to implement economic reforms).
    • (1990) Pathways from the Periphery
    • Haggard, S.1
  • 85
    • 84974486152 scopus 로고
    • Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England
    • Of course, some have pointed to the separation of powers under a republican constitution as an asset towards compliance of international commitments. The political fragmentation I address here is less about separation of powers than about partisan divisions and numbers of veto players in the government. See Douglass North and Barry Weingast, 'Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England' 49 J Econ Hist 803 (1989).
    • (1989) J Econ Hist , vol.49 , pp. 803
    • North, D.1    Barry, W.2
  • 86
    • 84973758328 scopus 로고
    • The Study of International Regimes
    • See Mark Levy et al. 'The Study of International Regimes', 1 Eur J Int'l Rel 267, 289 (1995).
    • (1995) Eur J Int'l Rel , vol.1 , pp. 267
    • Levy, M.1
  • 89
    • 0344339232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Section 3.1.2-3 and 4.2 for a succinct review
    • This is, of course, a caricature of the banking theory, which specifies much more precisely under what conditions depositors fail to monitor banks and the degree to which banks will not internalize the full cost of risks. See Santos, above n 18, at Section 3.1.2-3 and 4.2 for a succinct review.
    • BIS Working Papers No. 90 , vol.90
    • Santos1
  • 90
    • 0345633765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, at 14-15
    • Id, at 14-15.
  • 91
    • 0345633757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This has become an increasing concern with the increasing complexity of the New Basle Capital Accord. See, e.g. 'Report of the Institute of International Finance Steering Committee on Regulatory Capital', at 8 (voicing 'serious concerns with the technical capacity of banking regulators to implement the new framework in a consistent manner'); People's Bank of China, above n 59 (noting that 'banks in emerging markets still have a long way to go in order to improve their overall risk management system and supervisors in these countries are also under serious resource constraints').
    • Report of the Institute of International Finance Steering Committee on Regulatory Capital , pp. 8
  • 92
    • 0345633742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This has become an increasing concern with the increasing complexity of the New Basle Capital Accord. See, e.g. 'Report of the Institute of International Finance Steering Committee on Regulatory Capital', at 8 (voicing 'serious concerns with the technical capacity of banking regulators to implement the new framework in a consistent manner'); People's Bank of China, above n 59 (noting that 'banks in emerging markets still have a long way to go in order to improve their overall risk management system and supervisors in these countries are also under serious resource constraints').
    • People's Bank of China, Letter to Chairman of the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision
  • 94
    • 0039274376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 43
    • See Task Force Report, above n 43, at 45.
    • Task Force Report , pp. 45
  • 95
    • 84984517112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures
    • See Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, 'Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures', 7 Econ Pol 207 (1994); Paolo Mauro, 'Corruption and Growth', 110 QJ Econ 681 (1995); and Daniel Berkowitz, 'Economic Development, Legality, and the Transplant Effect' (1999) (unpublished manuscript, on file with author).
    • (1994) Econ Pol , vol.7 , pp. 207
    • Knack, S.1    Keefer, P.2
  • 96
    • 84959828858 scopus 로고
    • Corruption and Growth
    • See Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, 'Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures', 7 Econ Pol 207 (1994); Paolo Mauro, 'Corruption and Growth', 110 QJ Econ 681 (1995); and Daniel Berkowitz, 'Economic Development, Legality, and the Transplant Effect' (1999) (unpublished manuscript, on file with author).
    • (1995) QJ Econ , vol.110 , pp. 681
    • Mauro, P.1
  • 97
    • 84984517112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, 'Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures', 7 Econ Pol 207 (1994); Paolo Mauro, 'Corruption and Growth', 110 QJ Econ 681 (1995); and Daniel Berkowitz, 'Economic Development, Legality, and the Transplant Effect' (1999) (unpublished manuscript, on file with author).
    • (1999) Economic Development, Legality, and the Transplant Effect
    • Berkowitz, D.1
  • 98
    • 0032416910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and Finance
    • See Rafael La Porta et al., 'Law and Finance', 106 J Pol Econ 1113 (1998); Rafael La Porta et al., 'Legal Determinants of External Finance', 52 J Fin 1131 (1997).
    • (1998) J Pol Econ , vol.106 , pp. 1113
    • Porta, R.L.1
  • 99
    • 0001503097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal Determinants of External Finance
    • See Rafael La Porta et al., 'Law and Finance', 106 J Pol Econ 1113 (1998); Rafael La Porta et al., 'Legal Determinants of External Finance', 52 J Fin 1131 (1997).
    • (1997) J Fin , vol.52 , pp. 1131
    • Porta, R.L.1
  • 100
    • 84974486152 scopus 로고
    • Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England
    • See Douglass C. North and Barry R. Weingast, 'Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England', XLIX J Econ Hist 803 (1989); and Wallace Mendelson, 'Law and the Development of Nations', 32 J Pol 223 (1970).
    • (1989) J Econ Hist , vol.49 , pp. 803
    • North, D.C.1    Weingast, B.R.2
  • 101
    • 84974355991 scopus 로고
    • Law and the Development of Nations
    • See Douglass C. North and Barry R. Weingast, 'Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England', XLIX J Econ Hist 803 (1989); and Wallace Mendelson, 'Law and the Development of Nations', 32 J Pol 223 (1970).
    • (1970) J Pol , vol.32 , pp. 223
    • Mendelson, W.1
  • 103
    • 0345201840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Brown Weiss and Jacobson (eds) above n 3; and Simmons, above n 3.
    • Int'l Org
    • Simmons1
  • 104
    • 0001882974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bureaucratic Structure and Economic Performance
    • See James E. Rauch and Peter B. Evans, 'Bureaucratic Structure and Economic Performance', 74 J Pub Econ 49 (2000).
    • (2000) J Pub Econ , vol.74 , pp. 49
    • Rauch, J.E.1    Evans, P.B.2
  • 105
    • 0009007594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does 'Grease Money' Speed Up the Wheels of Commerce?
    • See Daniel Kaufmann and Shang-Jin Wei, Does 'Grease Money' Speed Up the Wheels of Commerce?, NBER Working Paper No 7093 (1999).
    • (1999) NBER Working Paper No 7093 , vol.7093
    • Kaufmann, D.1    Wei, S.-J.2
  • 108
    • 85023140283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Slaughter, above n 10. Of course, Slaughter does not explicitly theorize relations between liberal and illiberal states. For the analogue in the comparative literature on the effects of democratic institutions on economic reforms, see Jorge I. Domínguez, 'Free Politics and Free Markets', 9 J Dem 70 (1999).
    • Eur J Int'l L
    • Slaughter1
  • 109
    • 84855616687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Free Politics and Free Markets
    • See Slaughter, above n 10. Of course, Slaughter does not explicitly theorize relations between liberal and illiberal states. For the analogue in the comparative literature on the effects of democratic institutions on economic reforms, see Jorge I. Domínguez, 'Free Politics and Free Markets', 9 J Dem 70 (1999).
    • (1999) J Dem , vol.9 , pp. 70
    • Domínguez, J.I.1
  • 111
    • 0345201821 scopus 로고
    • July
    • OECD countries, as defined in the Basle Accord, includes full members of the OECD, as well as countries which have concluded special lending arrangements with the IMF under the Fund's General Arrangements to Borrow. See Basle Accord, § 35. To maintain consistency, I use the same definition here. Paragraph 34 of the Basle Accord was amended in 1994 to define the OECD groups of countries as excluding any country that has renegotiated its sovereign debt within the last five years. See Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Amendment to the Capital Accord of July 1988 (July 1994).
    • (1994) Amendment to the Capital Accord of July 1988
  • 112
    • 0344771220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Annex 2
    • In that case, the claim is also assigned a zero per cent risk-weight. See Basle Accord, above n 4, at Annex 2.
    • Banking Rep (BNA)
    • Accord, B.1
  • 113
    • 0344771220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Annex 2
    • Claims on banks incorporated outside the OECD with a residual maturity of over one year receive a 100 per cent risk-weight. See Basle Accord, above n 4, at Annex 2.
    • Banking Rep (BNA)
    • Accord, B.1
  • 114
    • 0345201816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dilemmas of International Financial Regulation
    • To this extent, Oatley is incorrect in stating that '[t]he accord . . . assign[ed] a zero risk weight to governments of nations in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), a 20 per cent risk weight to OECD banks and non-OECD governments, a 50 per cent risk for mortgage lending, and a 100 per cent risk to all other loans'. Thomas Oatley, 'The Dilemmas of International Financial Regulation', 23 Reg 36 (2001) (suggesting that 'the 1988 Basel Accord . . . may be more harmful than helpful'). In fact, no claim on any non-OECD central government would be assigned a 20 per cent risk-weight, as I outline.
    • (2001) Reg , vol.23 , pp. 36
    • Oatley, T.1
  • 116
    • 84855633804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§ 33-34, for a description of how these two options were being weighed by the Committee
    • See Basle Accord, §§ 33-34, for a description of how these two options were being weighed by the Committee.
    • Accord, B.1
  • 117
    • 0345201815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A rational expectations critique to bilateral treaty bargaining would argue that countries are aware of these institutional constraints ex ante, and that therefore compliance is only a reflection of these expectations. But as argued previously, this critique may not apply entirely to cases where countries unilaterally opt in to regulatory agreements (or for cases where actors have private information for that matter). Parties to the Basle Accord cannot, theoretically, exclude totalitarian states from implementing its guidelines.
  • 120
    • 84855633516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, at § 15
    • Id, at § 15.
  • 121
    • 84855633805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, at § 27
    • Id, at § 27.
  • 122
    • 0344771211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, at Annex 2
    • Id, at Annex 2.
  • 123
    • 84855639421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, at § 51
    • Id, at § 51.
  • 125
    • 0345633740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, at 205
    • Id, at 205.
  • 127
    • 0003591736 scopus 로고
    • Some may argue that because of the low noncompliance rate within the database, detailed case studies represent a more adequate choice of methodology. However, such case studies must still account for common factors between non-compliers and compilers. From an inferential and methodological perspective these two approaches are therefore similar. See Gary King et al., Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research (1994). Moreover, not only are the propositions testable with quantitative data, but this analysis is open to be supplemented and verified with additional data on the dependent variable, as well as a dynamic analysis of implementation. For these reasons, a logit analysis is apt. Of course, as Botcheva and Martin argue, the dependent variable may ultimately be even better captured by measuring the degree of convergence or divergence. See Liliana Botcheva and Lisa L. Martin, 'Institutional Effects on State Behavior: Convergence and Divergence' (2001) (manuscript).
    • (1994) Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research
    • King, G.1
  • 128
    • 0344339215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • manuscript
    • Some may argue that because of the low noncompliance rate within the database, detailed case studies represent a more adequate choice of methodology. However, such case studies must still account for common factors between non-compliers and compilers. From an inferential and methodological perspective these two approaches are therefore similar. See Gary King et al., Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research (1994). Moreover, not only are the propositions testable with quantitative data, but this analysis is open to be supplemented and verified with additional data on the dependent variable, as well as a dynamic analysis of implementation. For these reasons, a logit analysis is apt. Of course, as Botcheva and Martin argue, the dependent variable may ultimately be even better captured by measuring the degree of convergence or divergence. See Liliana Botcheva and Lisa L. Martin, 'Institutional Effects on State Behavior: Convergence and Divergence' (2001) (manuscript).
    • (2001) Institutional Effects on State Behavior: Convergence and Divergence
    • Botcheva, L.1    Martin, L.L.2
  • 129
    • 0002965999 scopus 로고
    • The Effectiveness of International Institutions: Hard Cases and Critical Variables
    • James N. Rosenau and Emst-Otto Czempiel (eds)
    • Ratification is hereby different from compliance per se as well as regime effectiveness. See Oran Young, 'The Effectiveness of International Institutions: Hard Cases and Critical Variables', in James N. Rosenau and Emst-Otto Czempiel (eds), Governance Without Government: Order and Change in World Politics 160 (1992).
    • (1992) Governance Without Government: Order and Change in World Politics , pp. 160
    • Young, O.1
  • 130
    • 0345201808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Ghana (1982-9) and Kenya (1985-9, 1992, 1993-5). South Africa, a survey respondent, also experienced bank insolvency much earlier in 1977.
  • 131
    • 0345201813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Benin (1988-90), Burkina Faso (late 1980s), Cameroon (1987-96), Central African Republic (1980s and 1994), Chad (1980s and 1990s), Congo (1980s and 1991), Côte d'Ivoire (1988-91), Eritrea (1993), Guinea (1993-4), Madagascar (1988), Mauritania (1983-93), Mozambique (1987-96), Nigeria (1990s), Senegal (1988-91), Tanzania (1995), Togo (1993-6), Uganda (1994), Zaire (1991-2), Zambia (1995). See Caprio and Klingebiel, above n 47, at 7.
    • Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics , pp. 7
    • Caprio1    Klingebiel2
  • 132
    • 0344771206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although Earth, Caprio and Levine describe their surveying procedure, it is unclear to what degree the selection effect is a result of the investigators or non-responses from countries that were actually solicited. In this paper, I will refer to countries that are not included in the survey for either reason as non-respondent countries, despite the fact that they may have never been originally solicited for information.
  • 133
    • 0344339216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note that this type of out of sample forecast relies on the fact that (a) non-response to the survey is negatively correlated with implementation, and (b) explanatory variables negatively affect both response and implementation.
  • 134
    • 0345633739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alternative results available from author
    • Alternative results available from author.
  • 135
    • 0034409890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making the Most of Statistical Analysis: Improving Interpretation and Presentation
    • I hereby adhere to the guidelines set forth in Gary Knight et al. 'Making the Most of Statistical Analysis: Improving Interpretation and Presentation', 44 Am J Pol Sci 347 (2000), using Clarify to estimate parameters with a number of draws (m = 1000). I also use Spost to generate graphs. See J. S. Long and J. Freese, Regression Models for Categorical Dependent Variables using Stata (2001). Since the substantive effects were calculated using Clarify, they are subject to change with new draws.
    • (2000) Am J Pol Sci , vol.44 , pp. 347
    • Knight, G.1
  • 136
    • 0034409890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I hereby adhere to the guidelines set forth in Gary Knight et al. 'Making the Most of Statistical Analysis: Improving Interpretation and Presentation', 44 Am J Pol Sci 347 (2000), using Clarify to estimate parameters with a number of draws (m = 1000). I also use Spost to generate graphs. See J. S. Long and J. Freese, Regression Models for Categorical Dependent Variables using Stata (2001). Since the substantive effects were calculated using Clarify, they are subject to change with new draws.
    • (2001) Regression Models for Categorical Dependent Variables Using Stata
    • Long, J.S.1    Freese, J.2
  • 137
    • 0345201809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • By appropriate I simply mean that if the effect is largest for the bottom of the sample and virtually undetectable at the upper range, given a particular explanatory variable, I interpret the variable where it has a substantively interesting effect. For example, it would be relatively uninteresting to interpret GDP per capita at its mean or median, where the compliance rate amongst countries is extremely high throughout.
  • 138
    • 0344771205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is of course not to say that such an exogenous increase is feasible, but merely to illustrate the effect.
  • 139
    • 0345201811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I also reanalyzed all of the models presented in Tables 4 and 5, excluding CRNTXFER, with no changes in substantive results.
  • 140
    • 0345201805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bahrain, Bhutan: Burundi: China, Egypt, Ghana, Indonesia, Jordan, Kenya, Kuwait, Malawi, Oman, Rwanda, Saudi Arabia, Tajikistan, and Vietnam
    • Bahrain, Bhutan: Burundi: China, Egypt, Ghana, Indonesia, Jordan, Kenya, Kuwait, Malawi, Oman, Rwanda, Saudi Arabia, Tajikistan, and Vietnam.
  • 141
    • 0345201840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Simmons, above n 3 (finding no support for the proposition that democratic regimes commit to openness with the same explanatory variable).
    • Int'l Org
    • Simmons1
  • 142
    • 0344339214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Jacobson and Brown Weiss find that democracies allow NGOs to operate, which thereby influences compliance.
  • 143
    • 0345201810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is confirmed also by a missing values analysis
    • This is confirmed also by a missing values analysis.
  • 146
    • 0345633734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is for this reason that banking crises of the Asian crises are not included in the sample.
  • 147
    • 0345633736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is the concern that Australia raised for its competitiveness in East Asia.
  • 148
    • 0345633732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Interestingly, when foreign ownership as added, the model fully explained all variation in implementation. However, two crucial observations were dropped from the sample, precisely those observations which Models 6 and 7 were unable to explain.
  • 149
    • 0345201840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This contradicts the findings on Simmon's study. See Simmons, above n 3 (finding substantial adherence to the regional norm).
    • Int'l Org
    • Simmons1
  • 150
    • 0345633738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Several alternative specifications were tested, using the dummy variable by itself and subsequently interacting DEPOSIT with other variables. None of the results improved our overall model. Results available from author.
  • 151
    • 0344339213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the most simple model, CAPTURE = POLCON * CONCEN
    • For the most simple model, CAPTURE = POLCON * CONCEN.
  • 152
    • 0344771189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Several different specifications using various measurements for a strong state were used, none of which provided any substantively different results. Ancillary tables available from author at request.
  • 154
    • 0345633735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, at 15 (noting a 'considerable time lag after the treaty is concluded before some or all of the parties can bring themselves into compliance')
    • Id, at 15 (noting a 'considerable time lag after the treaty is concluded before some or all of the parties can bring themselves into compliance').
  • 155
    • 0344771199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I am grateful to Jeff Frieden for making this point
    • I am grateful to Jeff Frieden for making this point.
  • 156
    • 0345633737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, consciously choosing variables to drop cases that are positive on the dependent variable would result in another bias, and all efforts were exerted to avoid this. As already stated, most of this problem can be remedied by merely collecting more data about the dependent variable.
  • 157
    • 78249232103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 43
    • See Task Force Report, above n 43, at 47.
    • Task Force Report , pp. 47
  • 158
    • 78249232103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 43
    • Although the report referred to 'international agreements for regulatory capital' in general, reference to the risk-weighting presumably refers only to the Basle Accord. See Task Force Report, above n 43 at 45.
    • Task Force Report , pp. 45
  • 159
    • 0344771201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I used those regulations applying to domestic banks (e.g. Aruba), those applying after two years of establishment (e.g. Belarus, Poland), and those applying to year 1999 (e.g. Canada, Lebanon). There were some other difficulties accurately scoring all the countries in the survey. Gibraltar, for example, did not specify which ratios applied to which institutions.
  • 161
    • 0344339205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Some uncertainty remained in the coding, since Caprio and Klingebiel provide only uncertain dates for some countries (e.g. Morocco, Kuwait).
  • 162
    • 0002322852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth
    • For further information on the construction of this index, see Witold J. Henisz, 'The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth', 12 Econ Pol 1 (2000).
    • (2000) Econ Pol , vol.12 , pp. 1
    • Henisz, W.J.1
  • 163
    • 0040321164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Polity III: Regime Change and Political Authority, 1800-1994
    • See also Keith Jaggers and Ted R. Gurr, Polity III: Regime Change and Political Authority, 1800-1994, Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research (1996); Keith Jaggers and Ted R. Gurr, 'Tracking Democracy's Third Wave with the Polity III Data', 32 J Peace Research 469 (1995).
    • (1996) Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research
    • Jaggers, K.1    Gurr, T.R.2
  • 164
    • 84970399719 scopus 로고
    • Tracking Democracy's Third Wave with the Polity III Data
    • See also Keith Jaggers and Ted R. Gurr, Polity III: Regime Change and Political Authority, 1800-1994, Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research (1996); Keith Jaggers and Ted R. Gurr, 'Tracking Democracy's Third Wave with the Polity III Data', 32 J Peace Research 469 (1995).
    • (1995) J Peace Research , vol.32 , pp. 469
    • Jaggers, K.1    Gurr, T.R.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.