메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 111, Issue 6, 2011, Pages 1332-1384

Rethinking the laws of good faith purchase

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 80054906487     PISSN: 00101958     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (39)

References (237)
  • 1
    • 80054911702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The facts are reported in DeWeerth v. Baldinger, 836 F.2d 103, 104-06 (2d Cir. 1987). The plaintiff sued within the three-year New York statute of limitations, which runs from the time the owner demands the good's return and the purchaser refuses. Id. At 106-107.
  • 2
    • 80054908524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 107-08. The "theft" rule is an application of the fundamental common law principle that one cannot convey greater rights in property than one has. It applies to sales transactions through U.C.C. § 1-103 (2011). The rights of good faith purchasers when the goods have been voluntarily transferred to a miscreant are embodied in subsections (1) and (2) of U.C.C. § 2-403.
  • 5
    • 80054945860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • DeWeerth, 836 F.2d at 110.
  • 6
    • 80054880153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The trial court granted summary judgment for the purchaser, following the DeWeerth precedent. The Appellate Division reversed on the ground that, under New York's demand and refusal rule, no due diligence was imposed on the owner to search for stolen goods. Solomon R. Guggenheim Found. v. Lubell, 550 N.Y.S.2d 618, 621-22 (App. Div. 1990), aff'd 569 N.E.2d 426 (N.Y. 1991). The New York Appellate Division did recognize the potential right of the buyer to use the lack of due diligence by the owner to support a laches defense. Id. at 622. Laches would lie, however, only if "it [was] clear that a plaintiff unreasonably delayed in initiating an action and a defendant was prejudiced by the delay." Robins Island Pres. Fund, Inc. v. Southold Dev. Corp., 959 F.2d 409, 423 (2d Cir. 1992).
  • 7
    • 80054910446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Guggenheim Found., 569 N.E.2d at 428. For an excellent discussion of the case.
  • 8
    • 79954544248 scopus 로고
    • A Tale of Two Innocents: Creating an Equitable Balance Between the Rights of Former Owners and Good Faith Purchasers of Stolen Art
    • Ashton Hawkins, Richard A. Rothman & David B. Goldstein, A Tale of Two Innocents: Creating an Equitable Balance Between the Rights of Former Owners and Good Faith Purchasers of Stolen Art, 64 Fordham L. Rev. 49, 55-69 (1995).
    • (1995) Fordham L. Rev , vol.64 , Issue.49 , pp. 55-69
    • Hawkins, A.1    Rothman, R.A.2    Goldstein, D.B.3
  • 9
    • 80054955486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 569 N.E.2d at 428-29.
  • 10
    • 80054957651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The owner's right to recover stolen goods in jurisdictions, such as the United States, that follow the theft rule is contingent on the owner bringing suit within the statute of limitations for an action in replevin. See infra text accompanying notes 17-20 for discussion of the wide variety in limitation periods.
  • 11
    • 80054907632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra note 16.
  • 12
    • 80054938107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Art theft is the third most profitable worldwide crime behind drug smuggling and illegal arms trading. William Tuohy, Picture This: Art Thievery Is Thriving, L.A. Times, Aug. 16, 1994, at H1. The market for stolen artwork and looted artifacts reaches an estimated two billion dollars annually.
  • 13
    • 80054937191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stolen-Art Market Is a Big Business at $2 Billion a Year
    • note
    • David Holmstrom, Stolen-Art Market Is a Big Business at $2 Billion a Year, Christian Sci. Monitor, Aug. 11, 1994, at 1.
    • Christian Sci. Monitor
    • Holmstrom, D.1
  • 15
    • 80054933129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • [hereinafter Schwartz & Scott, Sales Law] (criticizing American theft rule on efficiency grounds).
  • 16
    • 0346123607 scopus 로고
    • The Eternal Triangles of the Law": Toward a Theory of Priorities in Conflicts Involving Remote Parties
    • Menachem Mautner, "The Eternal Triangles of the Law": Toward a Theory of Priorities in Conflicts Involving Remote Parties, 90 Mich. L. Rev. 95, 151-152 (1991).
    • (1991) Mich. L. Rev , vol.90 , Issue.95 , pp. 151-152
    • Mautner, M.1
  • 17
    • 0344081248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Augmenting the Value of Ownership by Protecting It Only Partially: The "Market-Overt" Rule Revisited
    • Barak Medina, Augmenting the Value of Ownership by Protecting It Only Partially: The "Market-Overt" Rule Revisited, 19 J.L. Econ. & Org. 343 (2003)
    • (2003) J.L. Econ. & Org , vol.19 , pp. 343
    • Medina, B.1
  • 18
    • 80054963166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (arguing for relative efficiency of "Market-Overt" rule in protecting rights of good faith purchasers of stolen goods).
  • 19
    • 0346123608 scopus 로고
    • Sales Law, Economics, and the Negotiability of Goods
    • Harold R. Weinberg, Sales Law, Economics, and the Negotiability of Goods, 9 J. Legal Stud. 569 (1980)
    • (1980) J. Legal Stud , vol.9 , pp. 569
    • Weinberg, H.R.1
  • 20
    • 80054931271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (arguing for efficiency of American "theft rule" protecting rights of original owners of stolen goods in contests with good faith purchasers).
  • 21
    • 80054899472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We review the laws of leading jurisdictions in Part V.
  • 22
    • 80054936624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra Appendix (canvassing good faith purchase laws of several countries, each of which adopts nemo dat principle).
  • 23
    • 80054945515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.C.C. § 2-403(1) (2011) provides: A person with voidable title has power to transfer a good title to a good faith purchaser for value. When goods have been delivered under a transaction of purchase the purchaser has such power even though (a) the transferor was deceived as to the identity of the purchaser, or (b) the delivery was in exchange for a check which is later dishonored, or (c) it was agreed that the transaction was to be a "cash sale", or (d) the delivery was procured through fraud punishable as larcenous under the criminal law.
  • 24
    • 80054957195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.C.C. § 2-403(2) provides: "Any entrusting of possession of goods to a merchant that deals in goods of that kind gives him power to transfer all rights of the entruster to a buyer in ordinary course of business." U.C.C. § 1-201(9) defines "buyer in ordinary course of business" as "a person that buys in good faith, without knowledge that the sale violates the rights of another person in the goods, and in the ordinary course from a person, other than a pawnbroker, in the business of selling goods of that kind."
  • 25
    • 80054952126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Jurisdictions that have some version of the Market Overt rule include Brazil, Canada (Québec), China, France, Germany, Israel, Italy, Japan, Mexico, and Spain. See, e.g., Código Civil [C.C.] art. 1268 (Braz.) (Leslie Rose trans., Renovar 2008).
  • 26
    • 80054933128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Civil Code of Québec [C.C.Q.] arts. 1713-14 (Can.) (Jean-Maurice Brisson & Nicholas Kasirer trans., Éditions Yvon Blais 2002).
  • 27
    • 80054884531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Xianxing Fagui Huibian [Property Law] art. 107 (China) (trans. on file with the Columbia Law Review); Code civil [C. civ.] art. 2277 (Fr.) (John H. Crabb trans., Fred B. Rothman & Co. 1995).
  • 28
    • 80054903139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Bürgerliches Gesetzbuch [BGB] [Civil Code] § 935 (Ger.) (Langenscheidt Translation Serv. trans., Fed. Ministry of Justice 2010).
  • 29
    • 80054879157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sale Law, 5728-1968, § 34 (Isr.), translated in 1 Business Laws of Israel 1.5-79, 1.5-85 (Louis Garb et al. eds. & trans., 2006).
  • 30
    • 80054954129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Codice civile [C.c.] art. 1153 (It.) (Mario Beltramo et al. trans., Oceana 2010); Minpō [Minpō] [Civ. C.] art. 194 (Japan) (Ministry of Justice trans., 2009).
  • 31
    • 80054928166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Código Civil Federal [CC] art. 799 (Mex.) (Julio Romanach, Jr. trans., Lawrence Publ'g Co. 2002).
  • 32
    • 80054911259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Código Civil [C.C.] art. 464 (Spain) (Julio Romanach, Jr. trans., Lawrence Publ'g Co. 1994).
  • 33
    • 80054890476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sources cited infra in Appendix. The rule traces its lineage to the Code of Hammurabi, the Ordinances of Manu (India), early Saxon law, and early Hebraic laws.
  • 34
    • 84976131588 scopus 로고
    • Sale in Market Overt
    • Daniel E. Murray, Sale in Market Overt, 9 Int'l & Comp. L.Q. 24, 29-32 (1960).
    • (1960) Int'l & Comp. L.Q , vol.9 , Issue.24 , pp. 29-32
    • Murray, D.E.1
  • 35
    • 80054960410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In order to qualify as a Market Overt, the merchant-dealer must display the goods openly for sale. In the true Market Overt, the good faith buyer who purchases in a qualifying market gets good title to the purchased goods. See, e.g., Sale of Goods Act, 1979, c. 54, § 22, (Eng.); C. civ. art. 2277 (Fr.).
  • 36
    • 80054896185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • BGB § 935 (Ger.).
  • 37
    • 80054909583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sale Law, 5728-1968, § 34 (Isr.), translated in 1 Business Laws of Israel, supra note 15, at 1.5-79, 1.5-85.
  • 38
    • 80054915935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • C.c. art. 1153 (It.). In many civil law jurisdictions, as well as in regimes ranging from early India to Japan, the original owner is entitled to the return of his goods, but only if he pays the buyer the purchase price the buyer paid to acquire them. See, e.g., Property Law art. 107 (China); C. civ. art. 2277 (Fr.); Civ. C. art. 194 (Japan).
  • 39
    • 80054962783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • CC art. 799 (Mex.).
  • 40
    • 80054932250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • C.C. art. 464 (Spain). We criticize this version of the theft rule at infra text accompanying notes 133-135. A number of jurisdictions-Canada, England today, India, and Russia-reject the Market Overt rule and follow the American rule allowing the original owner to recover stolen goods from the good faith purchaser. See infra Appendix. The American rejection of the Market Overt rule evolved as an artifact of the revolutionary period and path dependence largely explains why it remains to this day. Early U.S. courts declined to import the English rule of Market Overt in the period just after the Constitution was ratified because, as Chancellor Kent stated in an early New York case, "[There is] no usage or regulation within this state, no Saxon institution of markets-overt, which controls or interferes with the application of the common law." Wheelwright v. Depeyster, 1 Johns. 471, 480 (N.Y. 1806). The common law rule in England permitted the good faith buyer to prevail over the original owner if he bought in any "open" market (that is, a market where the goods were openly displayed to customers) in the City of London or in any of the country fairs that were regularly held.
  • 41
    • 0346615605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Valediction to Market Overt
    • Peter M. Smith, Valediction to Market Overt, 41 Am. J. Legal Hist. 225, 226-230, 242-244 (1997).
    • (1997) Am. J. Legal Hist , vol.41 , Issue.225 , pp. 226-230
    • Smith, P.M.1
  • 42
    • 80054902052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The English rule continued unchanged for several hundred years until repealed by statute in 1994. Sale of Goods (Amendment) Act, 1994, c. 32, § 1 (Eng.). The repeal was not prompted by a principled preference for vindicating the original owner's rights, but because the British courts apparently encountered line-drawing problems. Smith, supra, at 248-249.
  • 43
    • 80054944149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Under New York law, the statute of limitations for a suit in replevin is three years. N.Y. C.P.L.R. § 214(3) (McKinney 1990). The demand and refusal rule, under which the statute of limitations is not triggered until a demand is made and return refused, was adopted by the New York Court of Appeals in Gillet v. Roberts, 57 N.Y. 28, 30 (1874). See also Menzel v. List, 267 N.Y.S.2d 804, 809 (Sup. Ct. 1966) ("[T]he cause of action against a person who lawfully comes by a chattel arises, not upon the stealing or the taking, but upon the defendant's refusal to convey the chattel upon demand."). The rule has been justified on the grounds that it protects the purchaser who, as a result of the rule, is not liable in conversion until a demand is made.
  • 44
    • 0041596461 scopus 로고
    • Note, Stolen Artwork: Deciding Ownership Is No Pretty Picture
    • Andrea E. Hayworth, Note, Stolen Artwork: Deciding Ownership Is No Pretty Picture, 43 Duke L.J. 337, 361 (1993)
    • (1993) Duke L.J , vol.43 , Issue.337 , pp. 361
    • Hayworth, A.E.1
  • 45
    • 80054888632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "This requirement makes the innocent purchaser aware that a claim against the property is pending and offers an opportunity to return the property before being treated as a wrongdoer.". At least one foreign jurisdiction has adopted a similar statute of limitations. See Občanský zákoník [Civil Code] č. 102, 134/2001 Sb. (Czech) (Trade Links trans., 2002) (stipulating owner can assert property right against good faith purchaser for three years from when said right was asserted to good faith purchaser).
  • 46
    • 80054890912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., C. civ. art. 2276 (Fr.); Civ. C. art. 193 (Japan); Code Civil [CC] arts. 722, 728 (Switz.) (Rebecca Brunner-Peters et al. trans., Schulthess 2007).
  • 47
    • 80054946157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., S.F. Credit Clearing House v. Wells, 239 P. 319, 321 (Cal. 1925) (finding possession lacked continuity and openness, thereby precluding operation of adverse possession); Reynolds v. Bagwell, 198 P.2d 215, 216 (Okla. 1948) ("The statute of limitations as to personal property, though stolen, when held in good faith for value, open and notoriously, runs in favor of such adverse possession so as to bar a recovery by the true owner after the expiration of [the statutory period]." (quoting Shelby v. Sharner, 115 P. 785, 785 (Okla. 1911))). The adverse possession rule suffers from a verifiability problem: Proving open and notorious possession of personal property is more problematic than it is in the case of real property. For discussion of the adverse possession rule, see infra notes 104-105 and accompanying text.]
  • 48
    • 80054916805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Autocephalous Greek-Orthodox Church of Cyprus v. Goldberg & Feldman Fine Arts, Inc., 717 F. Supp. 1374, 1391 (S.D. Ind. 1989) ("[T]he plaintiffs' cause of action did not accrue until they knew or were reasonably on notice of the identity of the possessor of the [stolen goods]."); O'Keeffe v. Snyder, 416 A.2d 862, 870 (N.J. 1980) (adopting discovery rule for action in replevin); see also Property Law art. 107 (China).
  • 49
    • 80054903138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Grazhdanskii Kodeks Rossiiskoi Federatsii [GK RF] [Civil Code] arts. 196, 200, & 234 (Russ.) (William E. Butler trans., Wildy, Simmonds & Hill Publ'g 2010).
  • 50
    • 80054923639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For examples of recent cases see infra notes 103, 139, 146.
  • 51
    • 80054945859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See cases cited infra notes 141-146.
  • 52
    • 80054913724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For an excellent discussion of the "chaos" that results from the interaction of disparate good faith purchase laws and neutral choice of law rules.
  • 53
    • 0346125273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Chaotic Palette: Conflict of Laws in Litigation Between Original Owners and Good-Faith Purchasers of Stolen Art
    • Patricia Youngblood Reyhan, A Chaotic Palette: Conflict of Laws in Litigation Between Original Owners and Good-Faith Purchasers of Stolen Art, 50 Duke L.J. 955 (2001).
    • (2001) Duke L.J , vol.50 , pp. 955
    • Reyhan, P.Y.1
  • 54
    • 80054933769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A "thief" is either the person who actually steals goods, or is a voluntary transferee who wrongfully misappropriates the goods and sells them to a third party. As an example of this latter case, the transferee/thief acquires the goods in return for a check or a promise to pay cash later. Subsequently, the check is dishonored or the cash is not paid, and the thief sells the goods to a third party.
  • 55
    • 80054895711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.C.C. § 2-312 (2011). If sellers in the relevant trade disclaim this warranty, the demand curve will reflect the risk that buyers bear, so a seller cannot entirely escape the consequences of selling untitled goods.
  • 56
    • 80054919029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Under property law principles, the original owner can maintain an action in conversion against any person, even an innocent third party, who takes possession of her goods without her permission. Carey v. Cyr, 113 A.2d 614, 616 (Me. 1955). Much prior analysis overlooks the possibility that owners can sue dealers for conversion. A notable exception is Hanoch Dagan, Takanat Ha-Sahuk Bituakh [The Market Overt as Insurance], in Mekhkarey Mishpat Likhvodo Shel Yehoshua Weisman [Essays in Honor of Joshua Weisman] 15-42 (S. Lerner & D. Lewinsohn-Zamir eds., 2002) (trans. on file with the Columbia Law Review).
  • 57
    • 80054953672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We argue below, however, that dealer/buyers should face higher damages than ultimate purchasers. See infra text accompanying notes 72-77.
  • 58
    • 80054937647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We define an "involuntary transfer" as the theft of goods from O, or a voluntary transfer from O after which the transferee sells the goods to another without O's authorization. See supra note 24.
  • 59
    • 80054903137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In economics, difficulties of this kind are referred to as "double moral hazard" problems. For discussion of the problem of double moral hazard in the tort law context, see Steven Shavell, Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law 203-04 (2004) [hereinafter Shavell, Foundations] (explaining why neither negligence nor strict liability regimes induce parties to take optimal level of care).
  • 60
    • 80054915129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Most jurisdictions that have adopted the theft rule also have the voidable title and entrustment rules as well, thus creating the dilemma for the buyer that is described in the text. See infra Appendix.
  • 61
    • 80054879155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra notes 60-62, 67 and accompanying text.
  • 62
    • 80054912095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Canada (Ontario), England, and India also apply two rules to the same goods. See infra Appendix. In these jurisdictions, the buyer wins if the goods were stolen but the owner's conduct was such as to estop her from asserting her title. The owner wins, however, if she was merely negligent. When an ultimate buyer purchases, he does not know how the original owner behaved.
  • 63
    • 80054919499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In Part III.C, we discuss the cases that a negligence solution does not resolve: when O and B both are negligent or when neither is negligent. We argue there that owners should prevail when neither is negligent and buyers should prevail when both are negligent.
  • 64
    • 80054892987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As we show infra in text accompanying notes 107-109, there is no need for courts to evaluate buyer behavior. Under our proposed reform, the buyer always loses to the owner who takes efficient precautions and always prevails over an owner who does not.
  • 65
    • 80054922729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Negligence proxies can also be implemented as revisions to the statutes and civil codes that govern good faith purchase contests in other commercial jurisdictions. See infra Appendix.
  • 66
    • 80054954601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.C.C. §§ 3-404 to 406 (2011); see also infra text accompanying notes 90-94.
  • 67
    • 80054898133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An example of a customary standard is the installation of a burglar alarm. We discuss these proxies infra in Part III.B.
  • 68
    • 80054883400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Failure to make reasonable search efforts would include a failure to make a reasonable investigation of a voluntary transferee. This obligation is necessary when O would lose to a good faith purchaser and thus, we show, would search suboptimally.
  • 69
    • 80054897661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, Foundations, supra note 29, at 285-87. A negligence standard in tort functions suboptimally because the expected liability of a potential injurer is not the damage he causes times the probability of harm, but rather the damages of litigious victims times the probability of their harm. The potential injurer takes suboptimal care because his expected liability is less than the actual harm he causes.
  • 70
    • 80054912554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra text accompanying notes 76-77. Alternatives to tort fines include punitive damages or subsidizing litigation (by awarding attorneys' fees to successful plaintiffs). Tort fines are discussed in Shavell, Foundations, supra note 29, at 272-275.
  • 71
    • 80054889246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra Part II.A.
  • 73
    • 0006996735 scopus 로고
    • Ethics, Economics, and the Law of Property
    • note
    • Frank I. Michelman, Ethics, Economics, and the Law of Property, in Nomos XXIV: Ethics, Economics, and the Law 3, 25 (J. Roland Pennock & John W. Chapman eds., 1982).
    • (1982) Nomos XXIV: Ethics, Economics, and The Law , vol.3 , pp. 25
    • Michelman, F.I.1
  • 74
    • 80054926910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Posner, supra note 42, at 205. A more extensive discussion of this point.
  • 75
    • 0031231816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Surprisingly Complex Case Against Theft
    • Richard L. Hasen & Richard H. McAdams, The Surprisingly Complex Case Against Theft, 17 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. 367, 370-374 (1997).
    • (1997) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ , vol.17 , Issue.367 , pp. 370-374
    • Hasen, R.L.1    McAdams, R.H.2
  • 76
    • 80054891823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These authors argue that when a theft is for resale, which a large number are, the thief values the goods for their "exchange value": The price the thief can get for the goods in the market place. The owner values the goods in excess of their exchange value, else the owner would already have sold the goods. Thus, in the usual case the owner has a higher valuation than the thief.
  • 77
    • 80054894287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We note here that the domain of this Essay is tangible goods; we do not consider the stealing or "appropriation" of the creative goods that are the subject of the patent and copyright laws. In those domains, the case against theft is more nuanced and complex.
  • 78
    • 79958090911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What's So Bad About Stealing?
    • Jonathan M. Barnett, What's So Bad About Stealing?, 4 J. Tort L., no. 1, 2011 at 1+7-11+13-17.
    • (2011) J. Tort L , vol.4 , Issue.1 , pp. 1-7
    • Barnett, J.M.1
  • 79
    • 80054904014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An owner may be thought to overinvest in protection if she chooses a pathological precaution, such as installing a spring gun on her property. The law specifically deters such behaviors. See, e.g., Katko v. Briney, 183 N.W.2d 657, 660-61 (Iowa 1971) (collecting cases finding liability when property owners injure tresspassers with spring guns).
  • 80
    • 80054937646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra Part II.C.3.
  • 81
    • 80054935229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Formally, the value of found goods is: = The term outside the braces is the probability that the goods are stolen times the probability that they are found. The first term in braces is the expected value of the goods if the owner repossesses them; the second term is the expected value of the price the buyer pays to keep them (when his value is higher). The a before the integral indexes the owner's bargaining power (0 < a < 1).
  • 82
    • 80054879725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Technically, we assume that the marginal benefit of precaution and search is positive, starting at the zero level; that precaution and search costs are convex; and that it is suboptimal to protect or search infinitely. The assumption that the optimal level of precaution exceeds zero is explained below. See infra note 53. The assumption that the owner always searches is relaxed below. There seems no reason to believe, as a general matter, that v(t0) is higher or lower than v(t3). Some goods may fall in value due to later use or abuse. Other goods, such as art and jewelry, may increase in value. As a practical matter, owners only search for valuable goods, so the conflicts the law must resolve, and thus the domain of our analysis, concern valuable goods.
  • 83
    • 80054956714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Recall that the probability that the owner finds stolen goods is x(z), so the probability that the goods remain hidden is 1-x(z).
  • 84
    • 80054888187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Our model is similar to the model.
  • 85
    • 84872567949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Legal Disputes over the Ownership of Works of Art and Other Collectibles
    • note
    • William Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Economics of Legal Disputes over the Ownership of Works of Art and Other Collectibles, in Economics of the Arts: Selected Essays 177, 185 (V.A. Ginsburgh & P.M. Menger eds., 1996).
    • (1996) Economics of the Arts: Selected Essays , vol.177 , pp. 185
    • Landes, W.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 86
    • 80054915934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Landes and Posner's excellent analysis of the art market omits dealers, and assumes that the owner can recover stolen art with certainty, that the owner and the buyer place the same value on stolen goods, that the buyer attempts to conceal his possession, and that parties function under some legal uncertainty. These assumptions are plausible for the art market but not generally, so we do not make them. For example, the buyer of a stolen Matisse may display it in a locked room, but the buyer of a stolen machine must openly use it. Also, because Landes and Posner focus on the art market, they do not derive generally applicable legal reforms nor do they make a comparative law analysis. A thoughtful paper by Omri Ben-Shahar also considers the incentives of owners and buyers.
  • 88
    • 80054959034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Ben-Shahar stays largely within the property rights paradigm and omits dealers but he helpfully integrates the thief's incentives into the owner's problem. Doing this here would not change our policy proposals. Ben-Shahar also does not consider how courts could apply a negligence solution, nor does he make a comparative analysis.
  • 89
    • 80054888186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The representation of the buyer's problem above is oversimplified. The buyer actually faces what is called an optimal stopping problem. He should incur inquiry costs in checking title until it is optimal for him to stop, which is when the probability that the seller's title is good is sufficiently high to make further inquiries not worth their cost, or when the probability that the seller's title is bad is sufficiently high to make further inquiry not cost-justified. The mathematical representation of optimal stopping problems is complex. The complexity is unnecessary for our purposes. In an optimal stopping model, the buyer will stop searching too soon because he discounts the productivity of search by the likelihood that the owner will not find him. The text represents the buyer's problem as choosing a level of inquiry into title because this yields the same result in a more intuitively obvious way.
  • 90
    • 80054913723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • t3.
  • 91
    • 80054915933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 0). When the owner can recover stolen goods, she chooses a precaution level such that the bracketed term lies between zero and one, which is inefficient.
  • 92
    • 80054878682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 0)). To be sure, delay does not necessarily reduce the value of discovery in all cases. For example, the owner, in pursuing an action in conversion against the buyer, may be able to recover the depreciated value of found goods.
  • 93
    • 80054882513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.C.C. § 2-403(1) (2011).
    • (2011)
  • 94
    • 80054918088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id.
  • 95
    • 80054902542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Even though the goods in this case are not "stolen" from the owner but rather are misappropriated, it is appropriate to designate this transferee as a "thief" because his acquisition of the goods is accomplished through "larceny by trick," and thus is a violation of the criminal law. Id. cmt. 2.
  • 96
    • 80054942031 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Atlas Auto Rental Corp. v. Weisberg, 281 N.Y.S.2d 400, 403-404 (1967).
    • (1967) , pp. 403-404
  • 97
    • 80054938106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • vt)vr = 1, which reflects a suboptimal level of search.
  • 98
    • 80054953065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Our assumption here accurately describes jurisdictions that adopt the Market Overt rule, which protects good faith purchasers from merchants.
  • 99
    • 80054890910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.C.C. § 1-201(20).
  • 100
    • 80054918575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. cmt.
  • 101
    • 80054959961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. § 2-403(2).
  • 102
    • 80054905192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. §§ 1-201(9), 2-403(2).
  • 103
    • 80054916875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Sale Law, 5728-1968, § 34 (Isr.), translated in 1 Business Laws of Israel, supra note 15, at 1.5-79, 1.5-85 (mandating that good faith purchaser of stolen goods from merchant-dealer who takes possession of goods prevails over rights of original owner).
  • 104
    • 80054894750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra notes 55-62 and accompanying text (discussing inefficiencies of voidable title rule).
  • 105
    • 80054912094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A sophisticated buyer may assign probabilities to the various legal possibilities and then choose an intermediate inquiry level. There is no reason to believe that the result would be more efficient than the result either rule alone induces.
  • 106
    • 80054945513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra notes 70-72 and accompanying text. Formally, a negligence rule, if effective, changes the owner's maximization problem to the problem that Expression (1) solves rather than the problem that Expression (4) solves. That is, the owner is induced to take first-best precautions. The standard does not affect the problem that Expression (3) solves because the owner does not search for goods unless she loses them.
  • 107
    • 80054927722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Under a comparative negligence rule, if both the injurer and the victim fail to take due care, each party bears a fraction of the accident losses. The fraction is based on comparing the degree to which each party's actual precautions departed from the optimal level. The incentive effects of a comparative negligence rule are discussed in Shavell, Foundations, supra note 29, at 187. As we note below, the current version of Article 3 of the U.C.C. adopts a comparative negligence rule in allocating responsibility between owners and good faith purchasers of forged or altered negotiable instruments. See U.C.C. §§ 3-404 to 3-406; infra note 92.
  • 108
    • 80054889243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra Part II.B (modeling owner's precaution level).
  • 109
    • 80054925043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra Proposition One. Note that the presence of owner's insurance should not negatively affect the incentives to search for stolen goods, as the insurer is subrogated to the owner's rights-the insurer, that is, has an absolute right to keep what it finds. Hence, the insurer would search efficiently so as to reduce losses from settling claims. On the other hand, a negligence rule will increase the insurer's incentives to monitor the actions of the insured and to use its expertise to propose precautions: More effective precautions by the owner reduce the insurer's risk exposure. Thus, by raising premiums or deductibles, or by requiring certain precautions (e.g., an alarm system attached to a valuable painting), insurers can induce conduct that the owner would not otherwise have taken.
  • 110
    • 70349804926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Devil Made Me Do It: The Corporate Purchase of Insurance
    • Victor P. Goldberg, The Devil Made Me Do It: The Corporate Purchase of Insurance, 5 Rev. L. & Econ. 541, 544 (2009).
    • (2009) Rev. L. & Econ , vol.5 , pp. 544
    • Goldberg, V.P.1
  • 111
    • 80054884049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Here precaution entails optimally investigating a transferee.
  • 112
    • 80054892001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For discussion of this underenforcement concern.
  • 113
    • 67649844658 scopus 로고
    • The Social Versus the Private Incentive to Bring Suit in a Costly Legal System
    • Steven Shavell, The Social Versus the Private Incentive to Bring Suit in a Costly Legal System, 11 J. Legal Stud. 333 (1982).
    • (1982) J. Legal Stud , vol.11 , pp. 333
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 114
    • 80054902680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For discussion of both approaches.
  • 115
    • 0009086328 scopus 로고
    • Private Versus Social Costs in Bringing Suit
    • Louis Kaplow, Private Versus Social Costs in Bringing Suit, 15 J. Legal Stud. 371 (1986).
    • (1986) J. Legal Stud , vol.15 , pp. 371
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 116
    • 0009046796 scopus 로고
    • A Note on the Private Versus Social Incentives to Sue in a Costly Legal System
    • Peter S. Menell, A Note on the Private Versus Social Incentives to Sue in a Costly Legal System, 12 J. Legal Stud. 41 (1983).
    • (1983) J. Legal Stud , vol.12 , pp. 41
    • Menell, P.S.1
  • 117
    • 0009001819 scopus 로고
    • The Divergence Between Social and Private Incentive to Sue: A Comment on Shavell, Menell, and Kaplow
    • Susan Rose-Ackerman & Mark Geistfeld, The Divergence Between Social and Private Incentive to Sue: A Comment on Shavell, Menell, and Kaplow, 16 J. Legal Stud. 483 (1987).
    • (1987) J. Legal Stud , vol.16 , pp. 483
    • Rose-Ackerman, S.1    Geistfeld, M.2
  • 118
    • 80054915931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Under a gross-up solution, let there be Q owners whose goods were stolen, and let q of them find the ultimate buyer. Then a buyer faces the probability q/Q = a of being dispossessed. A buyer who is found would have to pay vr/a as damages. This liability could be large because the probability of being found, a, is usually small.
  • 119
    • 80054879723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The benefit of using civil fines to improve incentives was first proposed.
  • 120
    • 84959825935 scopus 로고
    • Consumer Misperceptions, Product Failure and Producer Liability
    • Michael Spence, Consumer Misperceptions, Product Failure and Producer Liability, 44 Rev. Econ. Stud. 561, 566-567 (1977).
    • (1977) Rev. Econ. Stud , vol.44 , Issue.561 , pp. 566-567
    • Spence, M.1
  • 121
    • 80054902679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The full fine should not be paid to the losing party because that would defeat the incentives the negligence solution creates. A small bounty is needed, however, to insure that a nontrivial fraction of losing parties report that their dealer sold untitled goods.
  • 122
    • 80054963864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The difficulty of verifying compliance with broad negligence standards has been noted. See, e.g., Solomon R. Guggenheim Found. v. Lubell, 569 N.E.2d 426, 430 (N.Y. 1991) (criticizing proposal to impose due diligence obligation on owner because "the facts of this case reveal how difficult it would be to specify the type of conduct that would be required for a showing of reasonable diligence"). The court also stated that "it would be difficult, if not impossible, to craft a reasonable diligence requirement." Id. at 432. For discussion of due diligence, see Hawkins et al., supra note 5, at 81-83 (highlighting fact- intensive nature of due diligence inquiry); Ben-Shahar, supra note 50, at 15-21 (analyzing owner's incentives to take care under negligence regime).
  • 124
    • 80054950800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Restatement (Second) of Contracts ch. 11, intro. note (1981).
  • 125
    • 80054899895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The strong preference for strict liability in common law contract exists although contract doctrine appears in some areas to invite a negligence analysis. For example, if a promisor carelessly fails to take efficient precautions ex ante which results in breach ex post, the "willful breach doctrine" invites courts to increase damages to deter such inefficient behavior. Yet an analysis of decided cases shows that courts decline to employ the doctrine to deter an inefficient breach. Similarly, if the promisee fails to take efficient precautions prior to the breach that would reduce or eliminate losses, the mitigation principle invites courts to apply a "contributory negligence" bar to recovery. Yet courts adhere strictly to the rule that the promisee's mitigation responsibility is not triggered until the promisor breaches. For a discussion of plausible reasons why courts adhere to strict liability in these settings.
  • 126
    • 66749179825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In (Partial) Defense of Strict Liability in Contract
    • Robert E. Scott, In (Partial) Defense of Strict Liability in Contract, 107 Mich. L. Rev. 1381 (2009).
    • (2009) Mich. L. Rev , vol.107 , pp. 1381
    • Scott, R.E.1
  • 127
    • 80054937645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For discussion of rules versus standards in contracts.
  • 128
    • 32544460867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Anticipating Litigation in Contract Design
    • Robert E. Scott & George G. Triantis, Anticipating Litigation in Contract Design, 115 Yale L.J. 814, 839-855 (2006).
    • (2006) Yale L.J , vol.115 , Issue.814 , pp. 839-855
    • Scott, R.E.1    Triantis, G.G.2
  • 129
    • 80054957649 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For discussion of how negligence standards may yield unpredictable results.
  • 130
    • 0347609003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Trouble with Negligence
    • Kenneth S. Abraham, The Trouble with Negligence, 54 Vand. L. Rev. 1187 (2001).
    • (2001) Vand. L. Rev , vol.54 , pp. 1187
    • Abraham, K.S.1
  • 131
    • 80054962780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Scott & Triantis, supra note 82, at 836-839.
    • Scott1    Triantis2
  • 132
    • 80054947002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. To illustrate, assume parties wish to pair particular future contingencies with corresponding performance obligations, i.e., when X occurs, the promisor must pay $Y. The parties can define X in several ways. X may be a rule, which conditions on a relatively specific fact, such as the delivery of a widget with a specified weight. Here, parties delegate to the court only the determination of what evidence is sufficient to satisfy X. Alternatively, X may be a standard, such as the delivery of a widget in excellent condition. Here the court must determine not only what evidence is sufficient to establish the weight of the widget, but also the degree to which weight is relevant to the determination of whether the widget satisfies the standard. Id. at 826 ("Courts do not observe facts directly; rather, they make factual determinations by relying on proxies for the truth. The performance of a contractual obligation is proved or disproved by the presentation of evidence rather than by the court's direct observation.").
  • 133
    • 80054932700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We use the term "proxy" in this Essay to describe what proceduralists refer to as the "operative facts" that are relevant to establishing compliance with rules or standards. A precise rule narrowly confines the content of the operative facts. Indeed, in the limiting case the rule directly specifies the evidentiary proxy. A vague standard defines a broader space within which a court can select the evidentiary proxy that best establishes compliance with the standard.
  • 134
    • 80054906465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Justice Holmes famously predicted that repeated transactions would permit the evolution of negligence proxies: But supposing a state of facts often repeated in practice, is it to be imagined that the court is to go on leaving the standard to the jury forever? Is it not manifest, on the contrary, that if the jury is, on the whole, as fair a tribunal as it is represented to be, the lesson that can be got from that source will be learned?.
  • 135
    • 0004264409 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Oliver Wendell Holmes, The Common Law 98 (Mark DeWolfe Howe ed., 1963) (1881).
    • (1963) The Common Law , pp. 98
    • Holmes, O.W.1
  • 136
    • 80054925960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., The T.J. Hooper, 60 F.2d 737, 739-40 (2d Cir. 1932) ("Indeed in most cases reasonable prudence is in fact common prudence.... Courts [however] must in the end say what is required."); Sinclair v. Block, 633 A.2d 1137, 1141-42 (Pa. 1993) ("The law provides that '[w]here competent medical authority is divided, a physician will not be held responsible if in the exercise of his judgment he followed a course of treatment advocated by a considerable number of recognized and respected professionals in his given area of expertise.'" (quoting Jones v. Chidester, 610 A.2d 964, 969 (Pa. 1992)) (alteration in original)); Abraham, supra note 83, at 1199 ("[D]esignating a practice as 'custom' tends to cut down the degree of rule-making discretion exercised by the finder of fact.").
  • 137
    • 80054950340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Abraham, supra note 83, at 1201; see also Martin v. Herzog, 126 N.E. 814, 815 (N.Y. 1920) (holding unexcused violation of safety statute is "negligence in itself" rather than merely evidence of negligence).
  • 138
    • 80054893813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In addition to the example of commercial paper, negligence principles have also been applied potentially to preclude the owner of real property from reclaiming mineral rights under a misappropriated deed that was transferred to a good faith purchaser. Hauck v. Crawford, 62 N.W.2d 92, 94 (S.D. 1953).
  • 139
    • 80054928608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The nemo dat principle applies to negotiable instruments as well. Thus, as a general rule, neither a thief nor a good faith purchaser from the thief can acquire property rights superior to that of the original owner. Article 3 of the U.C.C. then provides several exceptions to the nemo dat principle. In addition to the familiar rule that a thief of bearer paper can transfer good title to a holder (U.C.C. § 3-201(b) (2011)), sections 3-404, 3-405, and 3-406 specify exceptions to the theft rule that apply to instruments that require an indorsement by the owner to transfer title. That these exceptions rely on negligence principles is perhaps less surprising once we recall that the principal drafter of Article 3 in the initial U.C.C. project was William Prosser. For discussion of the negligence rules in Article 3.
  • 140
    • 0347934821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rules, Standards, and Precautions in Payment Systems
    • Clayton P. Gillette, Rules, Standards, and Precautions in Payment Systems, 82 Va. L. Rev. 181 (1996).
    • (1996) Va. L. Rev , vol.82 , pp. 181
    • Gillette, C.P.1
  • 141
    • 80054951208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.C.C. § 3-404(a), (d). The 1990 revisions to Article 3 of the U.C.C. adopted a comparative negligence rule in section 3-404(d) (as well as in sections 3-405(b) and 3- 406(b)) in lieu of the pure contributory negligence principles that applied under the pre- 1990 Code. While there are differences in terms of proportionate responsibility, the underlying incentive effects are similar.
  • 142
    • 80054949860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.C.C. § 3-405(b).
  • 143
    • 80054891396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.C.C. § 3-103(a)(9). See HSBC Bank USA v. F&M Bank N. Va., 246 F.3d 335, 337-39 (4th Cir. 2001) (observing that leaving open space on check such that it could be altered was not failure to exercise due care).
  • 144
    • 80054917815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Bank of Tex. v. VR Elec., Inc., 276 S.W.3d 671, 682-83 (Tex. App. 2008) (holding bank's failure to maintain written or clear verbal policy regarding when checks should be manually examined constituted failure to observe prevailing industry standards).
  • 145
    • 80054921166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Other examples of anonymous goods include electronic equipment that is untagged, chopped-up automobiles, melted silverware, and cut-up diamonds. Whether goods are anonymous or identifiable may depend on when they are taken. Thus, while an individual GPS may be anonymous, a carton of them would be identifiable if the merchant owner found the carton before it was broken up.
  • 146
    • 80054913505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • When x(z), the probability of recovering stolen goods, is zero, the owner solves the same maximization problem that the social planner solves, so she invests efficiently in precaution. Referring to Part II.C above, Expression (4) reduces to Expression (1).
  • 147
    • 80054960409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Formally, when x(z) = 0, the left-hand side of Expression (5) becomes zero: The marginal return from buyer inquiry vanishes so the buyer will not incur costs to check title. Stepping outside the analysis, the purchaser may incur liability to public authorities if he violates criminal statutes against knowingly receiving stolen goods.
  • 148
    • 80054882084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There are a number of proxies indicative of negligence in protecting artwork. These include factors that occur on an owner's premises, such as setting up a functioning alarm system, placing functioning security cameras in strategic locations, hiring guards, and placing glass protectors over paintings to preclude viewers from actually touching artwork in a museum. Proxies also include actions post-theft, such as reporting the loss to local police or domestic Interpol or customs officials, registering the stolen item with a country's customs office and with organizations such as the Art Loss Register, a group based in New York that tracks lost or stolen works of art and employs private investigators to track it. See, e.g., 11 from Egypt Ministry Sentenced for Negligence, N.Y. Times, Oct. 13, 2010, at C3 (describing how "[e]leven employees of Egypt's cultural ministry were sentenced to three years in prison for negligence that led to the theft of a van Gogh painting from a museum in Giza in August... [which had] only some working cameras and no working alarms").
  • 149
    • 80054947471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Thieves Had It Easy in Cairo Art Heist
    • note
    • Kristen Chick, The Thieves Had It Easy in Cairo Art Heist, Christian Sci. Monitor, Aug. 24, 2010, at 13-14.
    • Christian Sci. Monitor , pp. 13-14
    • Chick, K.1
  • 150
    • 80054897167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Enumerating failures that led to negligence charges, including (1) "[n]one of the alarms meant to protect the artwork in the museum sounded," (2) "[o]nly seven of 43 security cameras were working," (3) paintings lacked glass protectants and hung easily within reach of viewers, and (4) "guards were scarce enough that the thieves were able to drag a couch underneath the painting to stand on while cutting the $55 million painting from its frame in broad daylight". Julian Radcliffe, founder of The Art Loss Register, which maintains a stolen art database, explained: "[P]roperly protecting artwork is no simple task. It requires costly technological safeguards, such as burglar alarms and camera surveillance, and guards in every room." Id.
  • 151
    • 80054954599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Search Results for "Anti-Theft Tagging", Google.com, http://www.google.com/search?q=Anti-Theft+Tagging (last visited Sept. 12, 2011) (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
    • Search Results For "Anti-Theft Tagging
  • 152
    • 80054923161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As one archeologist observed: "The classic rule in preservation is that you can't preserve something until you know you have it."
  • 154
    • 80054934620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id.
  • 155
    • 80054936593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Examples of transiently identifiable goods include goods that are in an original, labeled package or have not had tags disabled.
  • 156
    • 80054939937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Guillermo Contreras, Painting Sold in S.A. Ruled to Be Stolen, San Antonio Express-News, Jan. 15, 2010, at B3 (citing U.S. Immigration and Customs Enforcement and Art Loss Register as critical players in returning stolen art from San Antonio to French museum from which it was stolen in 1980s by notifying French authorities after stolen painting was submitted to auction).
  • 157
    • 80054878245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Canada Hot for Stolen Art
    • note
    • Greg Quill, Canada Hot for Stolen Art, Toronto Star, Mar. 27, 2010, at 4.
    • Toronto Star , pp. 4
    • Quill, G.1
  • 158
    • 80054948442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Suggesting various options for owners of stolen artwork, including reporting theft to local Interpol office, or registering stolen item with country's customs and with Art Loss Register.
  • 159
    • 79959620977 scopus 로고
    • Fraudulent Concealment and Statutes of Limitation
    • John P. Dawson, Fraudulent Concealment and Statutes of Limitation, 31 Mich. L. Rev. 875, 897-901 (1933)
    • (1933) Mich. L. Rev , vol.31 , Issue.875 , pp. 897-901
    • Dawson, J.P.1
  • 160
    • 80054929779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "With the positive result of adverse possession, in transferring title to the adverse possessor of chattels, there need be no quarrel and there is very little doubt in American decisions.".
  • 161
    • 1842756754 scopus 로고
    • The Adverse Possession of Personal Property
    • Patty Gerstenblith, The Adverse Possession of Personal Property, 37 Buff. L. Rev. 119 (1988).
    • (1988) Buff. L. Rev , vol.37 , pp. 119
    • Gerstenblith, P.1
  • 162
    • 84886449985 scopus 로고
    • Wrongful Possession of Chattels: Hornbook Law and Case Law
    • R.H. Helmholz, Wrongful Possession of Chattels: Hornbook Law and Case Law, 80 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1221 (1986).
    • (1986) Nw. U. L. Rev , vol.80 , pp. 1221
    • Helmholz, R.H.1
  • 163
    • 79959622290 scopus 로고
    • The Georgia Grind: Can the Common Law Accommodate the Problems of Title in the Art World, Observations on a Recent Case
    • Nicholas D. Ward, The Georgia Grind: Can the Common Law Accommodate the Problems of Title in the Art World, Observations on a Recent Case, 8 J.C. & U.L. 533 (1982).
    • (1982) J.C. & U.L , vol.8 , pp. 533
    • Ward, N.D.1
  • 164
    • 80054899471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Gaillard v. Hudson, 8 S.E. 534, 534-35 (Ga. 1889) (permitting buyer to tack prior purchasers' periods of possession); Dragoo v. Cooper, 72 Ky. 629, 632 (1873) ("[W]e perceive no valid reason why the rule of construction adopted in suits relating to realty shall not be applied in actions for the recovery of personalty."); Burroughs Adding Mach. Co. v. Bivens-Corhn Co., 119 P.2d 58, 59 (Okla. 1941) (holding that using typewriter in plain view at business for long period of time constituted "open and notorious possession"); Hull v. Davidson, 25 S.W. 1047, 1047-48 (Tex. Civ. App. 1894) (finding for buyer who had been "claiming and holding [a horse] notoriously and adversely"); Dee v. Hyland, 3 P. 388, 388-89 (Utah 1883) (finding for purchaser whose use of horse was open and notorious).
  • 165
    • 80054892982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 20 and accompanying text. A growing number of American jurisdictions have adopted the "discovery" rule for triggering the statute of limitations in replevin.
  • 166
    • 80054882081 scopus 로고
    • Note, The Case Against Statutes of Limitations for Stolen Art
    • Steven A. Bibas, Note, The Case Against Statutes of Limitations for Stolen Art, 103 Yale L.J. 2437, 2446-2448 (1994).
    • (1994) Yale L.J , vol.103 , Issue.2437 , pp. 2446-2448
    • Bibas, S.A.1
  • 167
    • 80054942507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra text accompanying notes 68-69.
  • 168
    • 80054899030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra notes 113-114 and accompanying text.
  • 169
    • 80054946591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra note 114 and accompanying text.
  • 170
    • 80054957648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • When a market exhibits price dispersion, purchase at a price that is more than one standard deviation below the mean would be considered to be in bad faith, as such a price is likely to be below the cost of reputable dealers.
  • 171
    • 80054910445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This argument shows that our analysis illuminates the case when neither party is negligent. Courts and commentators sometimes express sympathy for buyers who may be dispossessed though they apparently purchased in good faith. We offer two comments by way of rebuttal. First, buyers keep anonymous goods because owners do not search for them; a buyer will not lose a sweater or a stereo. Second, buyers can repurchase goods from owners who find them. Hence, a buyer would be dispossessed only when the owner values the goods more highly than he does. This suggests that the owner who never finds the goods is the more sympathetic party.
  • 172
    • 80054887725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Schwartz & Scott, Sales Law, supra note 10, at 491 ("Metaphors of freely flowing commerce or unclogged channels of trade do not illuminate [the good faith purchase] issue.").
  • 173
    • 80054885324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In this case, the owner's immediate transferee cannot respond in damages, so she asserts an in rem claim to the goods in the hands of the third party.
  • 174
    • 80054965243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A virtue of this result, as stated above, is that there is no need for courts to evaluate buyer behavior: Buyers always lose when owners are not negligent, and buyers always win when owners are negligent. An objection to letting negligent buyers prevail is that buyers would behave strategically by seeking out negligent owners from whom to purchase. This objection seems implausible. Owners behave optimally in equilibrium. In practice, this means that many owners would behave well, so that buyers would have to search extensively to find possibly negligent owners. Also, whether an owner invested efficiently in precautions may not be conveniently observable to an outsider. The costs to buyer search for negligent owners thus probably exceed the gain. Also, permitting "passively" negligent buyers to prevail but barring "actively" negligent buyers creates another litigation issue: A negligent owner would have an incentive to litigate the category of buyer negligence. The social gain from so expanding good faith litigations seems too slight to justify the expansion.
  • 175
    • 84937294883 scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of Private Legislatures
    • Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, The Political Economy of Private Legislatures, 143 U. Pa. L. Rev. 595, 633-638, 645-650 (1995)
    • (1995) U. Pa. L. Rev , vol.143 , Issue.595 , pp. 633-638
    • Schwartz, A.1    Scott, R.E.2
  • 176
    • 80054958543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Modeling high probability that group lobbying private legislature to maintain status quo will defeat similarly sized group lobbying for rule change. One of us has applied the insights from this model to the products of the groups formulating international rules governing the sale of goods.
  • 177
    • 33745033970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of International Sales Law
    • Clayton P. Gillette & Robert E. Scott, The Political Economy of International Sales Law, 25 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. 446, 459-473 (2005)
    • (2005) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ , vol.25 , Issue.446 , pp. 459-473
    • Gillette, C.P.1    Scott, R.E.2
  • 178
    • 80054879153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Arguing efforts to accommodate diverse political and economic interests result in highly abstract rules. A similar analysis of the products of such international treaties can be found.
  • 179
    • 0348134353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Futility of Unification and Harmonization in International Commercial Law
    • Paul B. Stephan, The Futility of Unification and Harmonization in International Commercial Law, 39 Va. J. Int'l L. 743, 756-787 (1999).
    • (1999) Va. J. Int'l L , vol.39 , Issue.743 , pp. 756-787
    • Stephan, P.B.1
  • 180
    • 80054902678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra notes 76-77 and accompanying text.
  • 181
    • 80054886705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We are grateful to Paul Stephan for this point.
  • 182
    • 80054942506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There is an analogy to the cigarette companies, who did not oppose bans on advertising in many popular media. The companies' increased cost of reaching buyers was outweighed by the ban-created barrier to the entry of new competitors.
  • 183
    • 84977317212 scopus 로고
    • Competition and the Cigarette TV Advertising Ban
    • note
    • E. Woodrow Eckard, Jr., Competition and the Cigarette TV Advertising Ban, 29 Econ. Inquiry 119 (1991) (analyzing empirical study showing cigarette advertising restrictions reduced competition and increased profit margins).
    • (1991) Econ. Inquiry , vol.29 , pp. 119
    • Woodrow Eckard, E.1
  • 185
    • 80054948004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • O'Keeffe v. Snyder, 416 A.2d 862, 869 (N.J. 1980) (describing how discovery rule gained acceptance in negligence cases); supra text accompanying note 106.
  • 187
    • 80054917813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Private property is a vital need of the soul.... All men have an invincible inclination to appropriate in their own minds anything which over a long, uninterrupted period they have used for their work, pleasure or the necessities of life.".
  • 189
    • 80054922263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Though the Earth and all inferior Creatures be common to all Men, yet every Man has a Property in his own Person."
  • 190
    • 0000861359 scopus 로고
    • The New Property
    • Charles A. Reich, The New Property, 73 Yale L.J. 733, 771 (1964)
    • (1964) Yale L.J , vol.73 , Issue.733 , pp. 771
    • Reich, C.A.1
  • 191
    • 80054910873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Arguing property "performs the function of maintaining independence, dignity and pluralism"
  • 192
    • 0000542896 scopus 로고
    • Property and Personhood
    • Margaret Jane Radin, Property and Personhood, 34 Stan. L. Rev. 957, 1005 (1982)
    • (1982) Stan. L. Rev , vol.34 , Issue.957 , pp. 1005
    • Radin, M.J.1
  • 193
    • 80054881619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Arguing rich theories of personhood and human flourishing are inconsistent with commodification and property rights in persons.
  • 195
    • 80054958095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Under U.C.C. § 2-403(1) (2011), an owner's voluntary transfer enables her transferee to convey good title to a good faith purchaser if the "goods have been delivered [to the transferee] under a transaction of purchase." See also U.C.C. § 2-326 (stating consignor loses to a good faith purchaser).
  • 196
    • 4344671883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law
    • Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law, 113 Yale L.J. 541, 556 (2003)
    • (2003) Yale L.J , vol.113 , pp. 556
    • Schwartz, A.1    Scott, R.E.2
  • 197
    • 80054906952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Arguing business firms are "artificial persons whose autonomy the state need not respect on moral grounds, and whose morality is ordinarily required by positive law".
  • 198
    • 80054914175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The void/voidable title distinction seems to have become part of U.S. law in consequence of a poorly thought out borrowing from the English common law. See supra note 16. Other countries also make the distinction, however. See infra Appendix.
  • 199
    • 80054925490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Some cases apparently apply this distinction. In West v. Roberts, the court distinguished the voidable from the void title cases because in the former the owner made a voluntary transfer of his property. 143 P.3d 1037, 1045 (Colo. 2006).
  • 200
    • 79961219032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Doctrine of Double Effect
    • note
    • Alison McIntyre, Doctrine of Double Effect, in Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Edward N. Zalta ed., 2009), http://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2009/entries/double-effect (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
    • (2009) Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy
    • McIntyre, A.1
  • 201
    • 80054892000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id.
  • 202
    • 80054938528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The following discussion owes much to Thomas Scanlon.
  • 204
    • 80054906951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Reasons for the lack of uniformity in good faith purchase laws are discussed.
  • 205
    • 0039126632 scopus 로고
    • Variety and Uniformity in the Treatment of the Good-Faith Purchaser
    • Saul Levmore, Variety and Uniformity in the Treatment of the Good-Faith Purchaser, 16 J. Legal Stud. 43 (1987).
    • (1987) J. Legal Stud , vol.16 , pp. 43
    • Levmore, S.1
  • 206
    • 80054951683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra Appendix. In England, Canada (Ontario), and India the owner cannot recover under the theft rule if the owner's conduct precludes him from denying the seller's authority to sell. However, mere negligence by the owner in failing to take precautions against theft does not constitute grounds for invoking an estoppel. See Sale of Goods Act, R.S.O. 1990, c. S.1, § 22 (Can. Ont.).
  • 207
    • 80054881186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sale of Goods Act, 1979, c. 54, § 21 (Eng.).
  • 209
    • 80054948441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rreproducing § 27 of Indian Sale of Goods Act as amended by Act No. 33 of 1963. As indicated in the Introduction, these jurisdictions create a legal origin problem for buyers because two legal rules can apply to the same goods. Our unitary reform proposal would eliminate this additional inefficiency. In Germany and Mexico, the theft rule applies in part: The owner loses to a good faith purchaser who bought at a public auction. See, e.g., Bürgerliches Gesetzbuch [BGB] [Civil Code] § 935 (Ger.) (Langenscheidt Translation Serv. trans., Fed. Ministry of Justice 2010); C ódigo Civil Federal [CC] art. 799 (Mex.) (Julio Romanach, Jr. trans., Lawrence Publ'g Co. 2002). 133. See infra Appendix.
  • 210
    • 80054940184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 3)] < z. The left-hand side of (1) is the expected value of searching for goods under the pure theft rule (finding probability times value); the righthand side is search costs. The left-hand side of (2) is the expected value of searching for goods under the reimbursement version of the theft rule. The first term is the (lower) probability that the owner finds the goods under this rule; the term in brackets is the owner's net gain from recovery. As is apparent from (2), as the current price approaches the buyer's current value, search costs are more likely to preclude owner pursuit.
  • 211
    • 80054912092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Spain adopts the reimbursement version of the theft rule for goods bought at a public sale and China adopts the version for goods bought at auction or at a public market. See infra Appendix.
  • 212
    • 80054917315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Countries that adopt the voidable title rule include the Czech Republic, England, France, Italy, Germany, Japan, Russia, and Switzerland. Countries that also adopt the entrustment rule include England, France, Germany, Italy, Russia, and Switzerland. See infra Appendix.
  • 213
    • 80054946156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Italy has the most buyer-friendly version of the Market Overt rule. Article 1153 of the Italian Civil Code provides: "He to whom movable property is conveyed by one who is not the owner acquires ownership of it through possession, provided that he be in good faith at the moment of consignment and there be an instrument or transaction capable of transferring ownership." Codice Civile [C.c.] art. 1153 (It.) (Mario Beltramo et al. trans., Oceana 2010) (internal citations omitted). Article 1153 also provides that "[o]wnership is acquired free of rights of others in the thing, if they do not appear in the instrument or transaction and the acquirer is in good faith." Id. Other countries with a pure Market Overt rule include Israel and Germany (public auction only). Brazil, China, France, Japan, Mexico, Spain, and Switzerland have the reimbursement version of the Market Overt rule under which the owner can reclaim his property from the good faith purchaser if he reimburses him for his original purchase price. See infra Appendix.
  • 214
    • 80054897166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Some illustrations of short limitation periods include Canada (one year); China and Japan (two years); France, Mexico, and Spain (three years); and Switzerland (five years). See infra Appendix.
  • 215
    • 80054879721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For discussion of the trafficking in stolen art and the problem of safe haven jurisdictions.
  • 217
    • 80054886248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Hidden Art of Theft, U.S. News & World Rep., Apr. 2, 1990, at 13 (noting Japan's laws protecting bona fide purchaser).
  • 218
    • 80054910054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Art & Avarice
    • note
    • Stanley Meisler, Art & Avarice, L.A. Times Mag., Nov. 12, 1989, at 8+11 (discussing Swiss law that allows good faith purchaser to keep stolen goods).
    • L.A. Times Mag
    • Meisler, S.1
  • 219
    • 77958167070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It's a Steal
    • note
    • James Walsh, It's a Steal, Time, Nov. 25, 1991, at 86+87 (commenting on laws of Switzerland, Liechtenstein, and Cayman Islands).
    • Time
    • Walsh, J.1
  • 220
    • 80054910053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Recall that under the demand and refusal rule, the statute of limitations does not begin to run until the owner finds the stolen goods in the possession of the buyer, the owner demands their return, and the buyer refuses to return them. See supra note 17 and accompanying text.
  • 221
    • 80054912551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • No. 03 Civ. 4119 (RLE), 2006 WL 2239594 (S.D.N.Y. Aug. 4, 2006).
  • 222
    • 80054931824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at *1-*2.
  • 223
    • 80054911256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at *2.
  • 224
    • 80054901382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Kunstsammlungen Zu Weimar v. Elicofon, 536 F. Supp. 829, 833 (E.D.N.Y. 1981) ("It is a fundamental rule of law in New York that a thief or someone who acquires possession of stolen property after a theft cannot transfer a good title even to a bona fide purchaser...." (internal quotation marks omitted)); Candela v. Port Motors Inc., 617 N.Y.S.2d 49, 50 (App. Div. 1994) ("[I]f it is proven that [buyer] purchased the vehicle from documentaan actual car thief, or from the successor in interest to a car thief, then [buyer's] title would be void, and not merely 'voidable.'").
  • 225
    • 80054952582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Section 34 of Israeli Sales Law states: Where any movable property is sold by a person who carries on the sale of property of the kind of the thing sold, and the sale is made in the ordinary course of his business, ownership passes to the buyer free of every charge, attachment or other right in the thing sold even if the seller is not the owner thereof or is not entitled to transfer it as aforesaid, provided that the buyer buys and takes possession of it in good faith. Sale Law, 5728-1968, § 34 (Isr.), translated in 1 Business Laws of Israel, supra note 15, at 1.5-79, 1.5-85. For discussion of Market Overt in Israel.
  • 226
    • 80054925489 scopus 로고
    • Market Overt in the Sale of Goods: Israeli Law in a Comparative Perspective
    • Eyal Zamir, Market Overt in the Sale of Goods: Israeli Law in a Comparative Perspective, 24 Isr. L. Rev. 82 (1990).
    • (1990) Isr. L. Rev , vol.24 , pp. 82
    • Zamir, E.1
  • 227
    • 80054945032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Zarian, 2006 WL 2239594, at 2 (citing Greek Orthodox Patriarchate v. Christie's, Inc., No. 98 Civ. 7664 (KMW), 1999 WL 673347, at 4 (S.D.N.Y. Aug. 30, 1999); Wertheimer v. Cirker's Hayes Storage Warehouse, Inc., No. 105575/00, 2001 WL 1657237, at 5 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. Sept. 28, 2001)). In applying the law of the jurisdiction where the property was located at the time of the transfer, the New York court in Zarian was following the widely recognized lex locus situs rule of private international law. This rule focuses on the law of the transaction that led to the possession of the goods by the buyer, a transfer that typically involves, as we have seen, a sale from a dealer to a bona fide purchaser. The lex locus situs rule thus neglects the issues surrounding the rights of the original owner, issues that are relevant in common law jurisdictions that retain the theft, voidable title, and entrustment rules. In this way, the lex locus situs rule facilitates the laundering of stolen goods by protecting transfers from intermediaries to good faith purchasers in jurisdictions that follow Market Overt. See Winkworth v. Christie Manson & Woods Ltd., [1980] Ch. 496 at 501-02, 513-14 (Eng.) (discussing lex situs rule in English law and holding that Italian law determined titled to goods stolen in England, sold in Italy, and later brought back into England).
  • 228
    • 79959594592 scopus 로고
    • The Law and Stolen Art, Artifacts, and Antiquities
    • Robin Morris Collin, The Law and Stolen Art, Artifacts, and Antiquities, 36 How. L.J. 17, 22-25 (1993).
    • (1993) How. L.J , vol.36 , Issue.17 , pp. 22-25
    • Collin, R.M.1
  • 229
    • 80054942030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "The lex locus situs rule permits the manipulation of stolen art in such a way that the goods will obtain market value, resulting in substantial profits."
  • 230
    • 80054938104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For discussion of relational contracting in the diamond trade and its global implications.
  • 232
    • 11244292154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Firms, Courts, and Reputation Mechanisms: Towards a Positive Theory of Private Ordering
    • note
    • Barak D. Richman, Firms, Courts, and Reputation Mechanisms: Towards a Positive Theory of Private Ordering, 104 Colum. L. Rev. 2328, 2351-2354 (2004) (describing extralegal mechanisms for ordering and sanctioning behavior within the diamond industry).
    • (2004) Colum. L. Rev , vol.104 , Issue.2328 , pp. 2351-2354
    • Richman, B.D.1
  • 233
    • 80054928606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Zarian, 2006 WL 2239594, at *10.
  • 234
    • 80054924117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at *4.
  • 235
    • 80054931268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id.
  • 236
    • 80054963863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at *2.
  • 237
    • 80054936590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 16.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.