메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 63, Issue 3, 2011, Pages 475-537

Regulatory dualism as a development strategy: Corporate reform in Brazil, the United States, and the European Union

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 79953064160     PISSN: 00389765     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (73)

References (215)
  • 1
    • 77955515343 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A large body of literature has sought to demonstrate the positive influence of financial development on overall economic growth. See, e.g., Valentina Bruno & Stijn Claessens, Corporate Governance and Regulation: Can There Be Too Much of a Good Thing?, 19 J. FIN. INTERMEDIATION 461, 479 (2010) (finding that companies with good corporate governance rely more heavily on external finance); Robert G. King & Ross Levine, Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right, 108 Q.J. ECON. 717 (1993) (finding that indicators of financial development are strongly correlated with economic growth, and that predetermined components of financial development indicators significantly predict future growth rates); Ross Levine & Sara Zervos, Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth, 88 AM. ECON. REV. 537 (1998) (finding a positive correlation between stock market liquidity and banking development and the contemporaneous and future rates of economic growth); Raghuram G. Rajan & Luigi Zingales, Financial Dependence and Growth, 88 AM. ECON. REV. 559 (1998) (finding that industrial sectors which are more dependent on external finance grow disproportionately faster in countries with well-developed financial markets); Asli Demirguc-Kunt & Ross Levine, Finance and Inequality: Theory and Evidence 2-3 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 15,275, 2009), available at http://www.nber.org/papers/ w15275.pdf (reviewing the literature on finance and inequality, and finding strong evidence that financial development helps improve economic opportunity and reduce inequality)
  • 2
    • 79953032485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, in particular, have sought to make the case that, as an empirical matter, strong shareholder protection laws are an important prerequisite for vibrant capital markets and, perhaps, overall economic development. Representative examples of a prominent series of articles are La Porta et al., Investor Protection and Corporate Governance, 58 J. FIN. ECON. 3 (2000) [hereinafter La Porta et al., Investor Protection and Corporate Governance]; La Porta et al., Law and Finance, 106 J. POL. ECON. 1113 (1998); and La Porta et al., Legal Determinants of External Finance, 52 J. FIN. 1131 (1997). Admittedly, the strength of these empirical results has been questioned. See, e.g., Holger Spamann, The "Antidirector Rights Index" Revisited, 23 REV. FIN. STUD. 467 (2010)
  • 3
    • 79953065343 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • MANCUR OLSON, THE RISE AND DECLINE OF NATIONS (1982). Twenty-five years after the publication of The Rise and Decline of Nations, the balance of more than fifty works attempting to test Olson's theory of institutional sclerosis was found to be positive. See Jac C. Heckelman, Explaining the Rain: The Rise and Decline of Nations After 25 Years, 74 S. ECON. J. 18 (2007), for a review of this literature. The political economy of capital market development, in particular, is interpreted in Olson-like terms by Raghuram G. Rajan & Luigi Zingales, The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial Development in the Twentieth Century, 69 J. FIN. ECON. 5 (2003)
  • 4
    • 79953051078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See OLSON, supra note 3, at 77
  • 5
    • 79953062244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In conceptual terms, a strategy of protecting elites so that they will not block reform is similar to Acemoglu and Robinson's development of constrained democracy as a means to persuade the elite not to resort to repression to maintain political, and therefore economic, power. See DARON ACEMOGLU & JAMES A. ROBINSON, ECONOMIC ORIGINS OF DICTATORSHIP AND DEMOCRACY 33-34 (2006)
  • 6
    • 77951223375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Bebchuk and Neeman have modeled the impact of different interest groups on the degree of investor protection. They argue that the political influence of insiders of publicly traded firms leads to an inefficient level of investor protection, a result that is only partially attenuated by countervailing pressures by entrepreneurs who want to take new firms public. See Lucian A. Bebchuk & Zvika Neeman, Investor Protection and Interest Group Politics, 23 REV. FIN. STUD. 1089, 1089, 1091 (2010). Regulatory dualism can mitigate these political economy barriers to an efficient level of investor protection by isolating the legal regimes of incumbents from those of new firms seeking to raise equity capital
  • 7
    • 79953031942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The decline may not be linear. The success of the "new" economy and economic growth generally may act as a catalyst for further reform, a possibility that the elite presumably will incorporate in their strategic calculus. As should already be apparent, the outcome of that calculus will depend heavily on local factors; while the structure of the analysis is general, the parameter values will depend on a country's particular circumstances. See infra Part IV.D
  • 8
    • 79953060689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ALBERT O. HIRSCHMAN, EXIT, VOICE, AND LOYALTY: RESPONSES TO DECLINE IN FIRMS, ORGANIZATIONS, AND STATES 4-5 (1970)
  • 9
    • 57849086176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • But see Aldo Musacchio, Law Versus Contracts: Shareholder Protections and Ownership Concentration in Brazil, 1890-1950, 82 BUS. HIST. REV. 445, 448-49 (2008) (noting that Brazil experienced a period of fairly developed capital markets between 1890 and 1914)
  • 10
    • 79953035015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., MB ASSOCIADOS, DESAFIOS E OPORTUNIDADES PARA O MERCADO DE CAPITAIS BRASILEIRO [CHALLENGES AND OPPORTUNITIES FOR BRAZILIAN CAPITAL MARKETS] (2000), available at http://www.bmfbovespa.com.br/Pdf/mercado_capitais_desafios.pdf (noting the historical insignificance of Brazilian capital markets and the prominent role of governmental loans as a source of long-term financing)
  • 11
    • 79953035982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., SOLUÇÕES PARA O DESENVOLVIMENTO DO MERCADO DE CAPITAIS BRASILEIRO [SOLUTIONS FOR THE DEVELOPMENT OF BRAZILIAN CAPITAL MARKETS] 28 (Carlos Antonio Rocca ed., 2001) (citing the lack of financing alternatives to the private sector as one of the main obstacles to the international competitiveness of the Brazilian economy)
  • 12
    • 79953036192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., MÁRIO HENRIQUE SIMONSEN, BRASIL 2002, at 124 (1972) (arguing that Brazil's tradition of closely held family firms was not due to sociological traits, but to the failure of existing corporate laws to adequately protect minority shareholders); FUNDAÇÃO GETÚLIO VARGAS, A MISSÃO COOKE NO BRASIL [THE COOKE MISSION IN BRAZIL] 91 (1949) (proposing that Brazil adopt a system of shareholder protections similar to that available in the United States in order to overcome investors' aversion to equity markets)
  • 13
    • 79953049153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a detailed description of the tax incentive policies adopted in Brazil, see David M. Trubek, Law, Planning, and the Development of the Brazilian Capital Market, BULLETIN (N.Y.U. Graduate Sch. of Bus. Admin. Inst. of Fin.), nos. 72-73, 1971
  • 14
    • 79953055335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., David M. Trubek, Toward a Social Theory of Law: An Essay on the Study of Law and Development, 82 YALE L.J. 1, 45-46 (1972) (noting that although it was the case that "[the] rules governing creditor and shareholder rights were imperfect, that courts were neither accessible nor efficient, and that sanctions were ineffective," there was initial hope that "as the markets boomed they would generate pressure for improvement of the private rights system"). This position has since been found to have some historical precedent. In both the United Kingdom and Germany, shareholdings became more dispersed before effective minority shareholder protection was adopted. See generally Julian Franks et al., The Origins of the German Corporation-Finance, Ownership and Control, 10 REV. FIN. 537, 538- 39 (2006) (describing the evolution of corporate ownership structures in Germany); Julian Franks et al., Spending Less Time with Family: The Decline in Family Ownership in the United Kingdom, in A HISTORY OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AROUND THE WORLD 581 (Randall K. Morck ed., 2005) (describing the timing of dispersal of family shareholdings in the United Kingdom)
  • 15
    • 79953033283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Since 1932, Brazilian firms were permitted to issue nonvoting stock so long as these securities provided either a dividend or a liquidation preference vis-à-vis common stock. In many firms, nonvoting preferred shares only had a liquidation preference. See Lei No. 6.404, de 15 de Dezembro de 1976, DIÁRIO OFICIAL DA UNIÃO [D.O.U.] de 17.12.1976, art 17.It was not until the legal reforms of 1997 and 2001 that Brazilian corporations were required to grant more substantial preferences (such as favorable dividend treatment or tagalong rights) to preferred nonvoting shares. See Lei No. 10.303, de 31 de Outubro de 2001, D.O.U. de 1.11.2001, art. 2; Lei No. 9.457, de 5 de Maio de 1997, D.O.U. de 6.5.1997, art 1.For a survey of the ownership structure of publicly traded Brazilian corporations in the 1970s, see Comissão de Valores Mobiliários, Valor de Mercado do Capital das Companhias Abertas Brasileiras [Market Capitalization of Brazilian Publicly Traded Companies], 4 REVISTA BRASILEIRA DO MERCADO DE CAPITAIS 283, 292 (1978) (finding that listed companies in Brazil typically had a controlling shareholder holding a majority of the company's voting stock)
  • 16
    • 71949083577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra notes 30, 209, and accompanying text; see also Luciano Coutinho & Flavio Marcilio Rabelo, Brazil: Keeping It in the Family, in CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN DEVELOPMENT 35, 49 (Charles P. Oman ed., 2003) (describing the role of the Brazilian Association of Public Companies as a "traditional representative of the business élite" in successfully opposing corporate governance reforms in 2001)
  • 17
    • 79953031156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Lei No. 6.404, de 15 de Dezembro de 1976, D.O.U. de 17.12.1976 as amended. Lei No. 6.404 remains Brazil's principal corporate law statute
  • 18
    • 79953038326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a critique of the 1976 Corporations Law, seeMODESTO CARVALHOSA, A NOVA LEI DAS SOCIEDADES ANÔNIMAS [THE NEW CORPORATIONS LAW] 11-17 (1977)
  • 19
    • 79953059902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Lei No. 9.457, de 5 de Maio de 1997, D.O.U. de 6.5.1997. For an examination of the role of the government as a shareholder in shaping corporate law reforms in Brazil and elsewhere, see Mariana Pargendler, State Ownership and Corporate Governance 13-22 (Jan. 2011) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with authors)
  • 20
    • 79953043120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Maria Helena Santana, The Novo Mercado, in NOVO MERCADO AND ITS FOLLOWERS 1, 9-10 (2008)
  • 21
    • 1842445955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Alexander Dyck & Luigi Zingales, Private Benefits of Control: An International Comparison, 59 J. FIN. 537, 554-56 (2004). Dyck and Zingales compared the price paid for a controlling block to the market share price following the change of control in a sample of 393 transactions, and found that private benefits of control ranged from -4% in Japan to 65% in Brazil. Id. According to a different study, which used dual-class price differentials to estimate private benefits of control, an average Brazilian controlling shareholder could expect to extract up to one-third of the value of the company by holding as little of one-sixth of total cash flow rights. Tatiana Nenova, The Value of Corporate Voting Rights and Control: A Cross-Country Analysis, 68 J. FIN. ECON. 325, 327 (2003)
  • 22
    • 79953035981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Santana, supra note 20, at 7. The São Paulo Stock Exchange was established in the late nineteenth century and was rivaled in importance by the Rio de Janeiro Stock Exchange for most of the twentieth century. In the late 1980s, however, the Rio de Janeiro Stock Exchange collapsed and was eventually shut down following a major stock price manipulation scheme. This led to the consolidation of all stock trading on the São Paulo Stock Exchange. In 2008, the S;o Paulo Stock Exchange merged with the São Paulo Commodities and Futures Exchange (Bolsa de Mercadorias e Futuros-BM&F) to form BM&F Bovespa, a publicly traded firm listed on the Novo Mercado
  • 23
    • 79953040446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Following an international trend of demutualization of stock exchanges, in 2007 the São Paulo Stock Exchange was transformed into an investor-owned firm and went public on the Novo Mercado. See id. at 5
  • 24
    • 79953065147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • MB ASSOCIADOS, supra note 10
  • 25
    • 79953050515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Cally Jordan & Mike Lubrano, How Effective Are Capital Markets in Exerting Governance on Corporations?, in FINANCIAL SECTOR GOVERNANCE 327, 342 (Robert E. Litan et al. eds., 2002) (describing the creation of the Novo Mercado as a "quasi private effort to make up for the perceived shortcomings of legislative reform")
  • 26
    • 79953052736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While the Brazilian Congress finally amended the Corporations Law in late 2001, the Olson problem was again apparent: the reform was quite limited. The new statute, Lei No. 10.303, de 31 de Outubro de 2001, D.O.U. de 1.11.2001, continued to permit the issuance of nonvoting preferred shares, but the ratio to total capital was reduced from 66.7% to 50% for new firms. Id. at art. 15, § 2. The 2001 law also reintroduced a mandatory bid rule, but only partially: it applied only to common shares and entitled common shareholders to receive only 80% of the price paid for the controlling block. Id. at art. 254-A. Other protective provisions in the statute-such as the right of minority shareholders to call a special meeting to deliberate on transactions tainted by the controlling shareholders' conflicts of interest- were vetoed by Brazil's President. See Mensagem No. 1.213, de 31 de Outubro de 2001, D.O.U. de 31.10.2001 (describing the reasons for the presidential veto)
  • 27
    • 79953035208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra Part II.A
  • 28
    • 79953046624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See CALIXTO SALOMÃO FILHO, O NOVO DIREITO SOCIETÁRIO [THE NEW CORPORATE LAW] 58 (3d ed. 2006)
  • 29
    • 79953042469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Santana, supra note 20, at 12
  • 30
    • 79953058164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ASSOCIAÇÃO BRASILEIRA DAS COMPANHIAS ABERTAS, RELATÓRIO DA DIRETORIA [ANNUAL MANAGEMENT REPORT] 6 (2005), available at http://www.abrasca.org.br/aabrasca/ Relatorio-Anual-Abrasca-2005.pdf
  • 31
    • 79953059690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Indeed, following the creation of the Novo Mercado the Brazilian Association of Public Companies began to argue that legal reforms banning nonvoting preferred shares were unnecessary precisely because "voluntary market mechanisms" had emerged to address this issue. ASSOCIAÇÃO BRASILEIRA DAS COMPANHIAS ABERTAS, RELATÓRIO DA DIRETORIA [ANNUAL MANAGEMENT REPORT] 24 (2006), available at http://www.abrasca.org.br/aabrasca/Relatorio_Anual_Abrasca_2006.pdf
  • 32
    • 79953046811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Santana, supra note 20, at 12
  • 33
    • 0036868524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As described in Part I.D, the Novo Mercado took a while to take off after it was adopted. Two years after its creation, commentators were skeptical of governance reforms through stock exchange standards, and attributed the "weak" response to the Novo Mercado experiment to its inability to compete with the stronger "reputational brand" of the NYSE. John C. Coffee, Jr., Racing Towards the Top?: The Impact of Cross-Listings and Stock Market Competition on International Corporate Governance, 102 COLUM. L. REV. 1757, 1807-08 (2002)
  • 34
    • 0348142492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Bernard S. Black, The Legal and Institutional Preconditions for Strong Securities Markets, 48 UCLA L. REV. 781, 782 (2001)
  • 35
    • 79953038325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See MB ASSOCIADOS, O MERCADO DE CAPITAIS BRASILEIRO FRENTE AOS DESAFIOS IMPOSTOS PELAS NEGOCIAÇÕES INTERNACIONAIS EM SERVIÇOS FINANCEIROS [BRAZILIAN CAPITAL MARKETS AND THE CHALLENGES IMPOSED BY INTERNATIONAL NEGOTIATIONS IN FINANCIAL SERVICES] 27 (2004), available at http://www.bmfbovespa.com.br/Pdf/Estudo2.pdf (noting that the Novo Mercado initially aimed at attracting medium-sized firms with ongoing investment projects)
  • 36
    • 79953054498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Rajan & Zingales, supra note 3, at 7 ("[W]hen a country's borders are open to both trade and capital flows,. the opposition to financial development will be most muted and development will flourish.")
  • 37
    • 79953043929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a discussion of the role of network effects in the implementation of regulatory dualism through private organizations, see Part IV.B.2
  • 38
    • 79953062243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We use the term "one share, one vote" loosely to describe the absence of nonvoting shares. Voting caps and pyramidal structures were not prohibited under initial Novo Mercado regulations. See BM&F BOVESPA, REGULAMENTO DE LISTAGEM DO NOVO MERCADO [NOVO MERCADO LISTING RULES] § 3.1 (2008), available at http://www.bmfbovespa.com.br/Pdf/RegulamentoNMercado.pdf
  • 39
    • 79953058547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., André Carvalhal-da-Silva & Ricardo Leal, Corporate Governance, Market Valuation and Dividend Policy in Brazil, 1 FRONTIERS FIN. & ECON. 1, 6 (2004) (finding that, as of 2000, the largest shareholder in a sample of 225 Brazilian firms held, on average, 72% of the company's voting capital and 51% of its total capital); Ricardo P.C. Leal & André L. Carvalhal-da-Silva, Corporate Governance and Value in Brazil (and in Chile) 5, 20-22 (Mar. 29, 2005) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=726261 (noting a rise in the concentration of voting rights in Brazilian firms from 1998 to 2002)
  • 40
    • 34548280834 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Andre Carvalhal da Silva & Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, Dual-Class Premium, Corporate Governance, and the Mandatory Bid Rule: Evidence from the Brazilian Stock Market, 13 J. CORP. FIN. 1, 4 (2007)
  • 41
    • 79953053926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Tatiana Nenova, Control Values and Changes in Corporate Law in Brazil 2 (Sept. 25, 2001) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm? abstract_id=294064
  • 42
    • 0039332047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a discussion of the economic properties of a mandatory bid rule, see Clas Bergström et al., The Optimality of the Mandatory Bid Rule, 13 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 433, 447- 48 (1997) (noting the mandatory bid rule makes control transactions more expensive by imposing greater interest expenses and risk); Frank H. Easterbrook & Daniel R. Fischel, Corporate Control Transactions, 91 YALE L.J. 698, 716, 737 (1982) (arguing that unequal sharing of gains in corporate control transactions maximizes shareholder wealth); and Marcel Kahan, Sales of Corporate Control, 9 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 368, 378 (1993) (arguing that equal sharing rules may be less efficient than private control transfers for sales of high fractions of corporate shares)
  • 43
    • 1442357045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The tradeoff between encouraging efficient transactions and protecting minority investors from expropriation upon control sales in countries lacking adequate regulation of going-private transactions remains open to investigation. For a description of different modalities of extraction of private benefits of control in operating decisions, control sales, and freezeouts, see Ronald J. Gilson & Jeffrey N. Gordon, Controlling Controlling Shareholders, 152 U. PA. L. REV. 785, 787 (2003)
  • 44
    • 79953064951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • BM&F BOVESPA, supra note 38, § 11.2
  • 45
    • 79953041434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. § 12.5.1(iii)
  • 46
    • 79953045670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. §§ 12.2-4
  • 47
    • 79953036755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The CVM was established by the Capital Markets Law, Lei No. 6.385, de 7 de Dezembro de 1976, D.O.U. de 9.12.1976, the same year of the enactment of the then-new Corporations Law. It was not until the last decade, however, that the CVM began taking a truly activist stance toward investor protection. See infra notes 206-08 and accompanying text
  • 48
    • 79953041862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • According to a 2010 cross-country comparison by the World Bank, Brazil ranks 98th out of 183 economies with respect to the ease of enforcing commercial contracts. THE WORLD BANK, DOING BUSINESS 2011: BRAZIL 64 (2010), available at http://doingbusiness.org/̃/media/fpdkm/doing%20business/documents/p rofiles/country/db11/bra.pdf
  • 49
    • 57649186596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For instance, arbitral panels have an infamous tendency to "split the baby" and find a mutually acceptable, even if unprincipled, solution to the dispute in question, while public courts can perform better in holding parties to their incentives for performance ex ante. For a discussion of the advantages of public courts over arbitration, see Jens Dammann & Henry Hansmann, Globalizing Commercial Litigation, 94 CORNELL L. REV. 1, 31-39 (2008)
  • 50
    • 79953064769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Public courts must ultimately enforce arbitration awards in the absence of voluntary compliance by the losing party, which reintroduces concerns about judicial effectiveness. But the procedure for the enforcement of arbitration awards is much simpler than the initial determination of a violation, and is subject to a limited scope of review
  • 51
    • 79953043736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The involvement of the São Paulo Stock Exchange in the Novo Mercado arbitration process is not trivial. The board of directors of the São Paulo Stock Exchange is responsible for appointing thirty arbitrators with renowned capital market expertise to compose the Panel, and the applicable regulations provide that the parties should preferably, although not necessarily, appoint arbitrators who are members of the Panel. Thus, the reputations of prominent individuals are placed behind the arbitration procedure. In addition, before the award is made final, the Arbitral Tribunal needs to submit a draft to the chairman or vice chairman of the Panel, who, without interfering with the arbitrators' judgment, may propose changes to the formal aspects of the award and draw attention to other substantive aspects of the dispute. See BOVESPA, CÂMARA DE ARBITRAGEM DO MERCADO: REGULAMENTO [MARKET ARBITRATION PANEL: REGULATION] §§ 7.8, 9.2.1 (2002), available at http://www.camaradomercado.com.br/InstDownload/regulamentonv07012002.pdf
  • 52
    • 79953064575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. § 9.13
  • 53
    • 79953062077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id.
  • 54
    • 79953037363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id note note. § 7.12.7
  • 55
    • 79953046041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Paulo Cezar Aragão, A CVM em Juízo: Limites e Possibilidades [The CVM Before the Courts: Limits and Possibilities], 34 REVISTA DE DIREITO BANCÁRIO E DO MERCADO DE CAPITAIS 38, 40 (2006) (noting that in the more than thirty years of authority of the 1940 Corporations Law, there was only one judicial lawsuit on the duties and liabilities of managers of Brazilian corporations)
  • 56
    • 79953031750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra notes 206-08 and accompanying text
  • 57
    • 79953035387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • BM&F BOVESPA, GOVERNANÇA CORPORATIVA E O DESENVOLVIMENTO DO MERCADO DE CAPITAIS BRASILEIRO [CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND THE DEVELOPMENT OF BRAZILIAN CAPITAL MARKETS] 7 (2009), http://www.valoronline.com.br/sites/default/files/ bmfbovespa_0.pdf
  • 58
    • 79953037747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • BM&F BOVESPA, GOVERNANÇA CORPORATIVA E O DESENVOLVIMENTO DO MERCADO DE CAPITAIS BRASILEIRO [CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND THE DEVELOPMENT OF BRAZILIAN CAPITAL MARKETS] 7 (2009), http://www.valoronline.com.br/sites/default/files/ bmfbovespa_0.pdf
  • 59
    • 79953051075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Estatísticas das Aberturas de Capital na BM&FBOVESPA [Statistics on IPOs on BM&FBOVESPA], BM&F BOVESPA, http://www.bmfbovespa.com.br/cias-listadas/ consultas/ ipos-recentes/ipos-recentes.aspx?Idioma=pt-br (last visited Feb. 20, 2011)
  • 60
    • 79953044724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ANBID, CÓDIGO DE AUTO-REGULAÇÃO DA ANBID PARA AS OFERTAS PÚBLICAS DE DISTRIBUIÇÃO E AQUISIÇÃO DE VALORES MOBILIÁRIOS [ANBID SELF-REGULATORY CODE FOR PUBLIC OFFERINGS FOR THE DISTRIBUTION OR ACQUISITION OF SECURITIES] art. 6 (2006), available at http://www.anbid.com.br/auto_regulacao_downloads/mercado_capitais/novo_codigo_mc.pdf
  • 61
    • 79953051264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Many of the recent IPOs that took place outside of the Novo Mercado did so due to regulatory restrictions on foreign control that prevented firms from issuing only voting shares without governmental approval. These firms generally opted for a Level 2 listing. See Érica Gorga, Changing the Paradigm of Stock Ownership from Concentrated Towards Dispersed Ownership? Evidence from Brazil and Consequences for Emerging Countries, 29 NW. J. INT'L L. & BUS. 439, 455 (2009)
  • 62
    • 0346250710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These reorganizations are examples of the "efficient restructurings" discussed in Henry Hansmann & Reinier Kraakman, Essay, The End of History for Corporate Law, 89 GEO. L.J. 439, 461 (2001). Hansmann and Kraakman note that efficient restructurings require that the controlling shareholders be able to extract the capitalized value of private benefits of control when opting for a superior corporate governance regime. Efficient restructurings, they argue, can be an antidote to the path-dependent nature of corporate ownership and governance identified in Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Mark J. Roe, A Theory of Path Dependence in Corporate Ownership and Governance, 52 STAN. L. REV. 127 (1999)
  • 63
    • 79953034801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Parecer de Orientação CVM [CVM Advisory Opinion] No. 34 (2006), available at http://www.cvm.gov.br/asp/cvmwww/atos/exiato.asp?File=/pare/pare034.htm. In a highly publicized transaction involving a major Brazilian telecom, minority shareholders rejected a proposal to migrate from the traditional segment to the Novo Mercado at conversion ratios by which common shares held by controlling shareholders would be worth three times more than preferred shares. See Simone Azevedo, O preço da escalada [The Price of the Upswing], 37 REVISTA CAPITAL ABERTO 10 (2006) (describing the structure of the proposed share exchange); Oi! Brazil's Shareholding Elite Receives a Black Eye from the Regulator, ECONOMIST, Aug. 26, 2006, at 63
  • 64
    • 79953037951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These figures are based on the authors' calculations from media reports on migrations and conversion prices through 2008. In addition, at least a handful of the firms that migrated to the Novo Mercado from the traditional segment had as a shareholder the investment arm of Brazil's National Development Bank (BNDES), an early and vocal supporter of the Novo Mercado-implying that the new segment may have been embraced in these cases owing to factors other than the invisible hand of the market. Still, the potential role of BNDES alone is insufficient to explain the success of the Novo Mercado, both because migrations from the basic segment represent only a small fraction of Novo Mercado listings and because most of the Bank's largest borrowers are not listed on the segment. See Alexandre Di Miceli da Silveira, The Role of the BNDES (Brazilian Development Bank) on the Corporate Governance of Large Companies in Brazil 5-6 (2010) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1639097 (showing that only five of the Bank's top thirty borrowers in 2009 were listed on the Novo Mercado, and arguing against the view that the BNDES promotes higher corporate governance standards in investee companies)
  • 65
    • 79953057898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Boletim Empresas [Companies' Bulletin], BM&F BOVESPA, http://www.bmfbovespa.com.br/empresas/boletim_empresas_janeiro10.asp (last visited Jan. 31, 2011)
  • 66
    • 79953066486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Gorga, supra note 61, at 447 (noting that on the Novo Mercado, firms' largest shareholders on average own 36% of the shares, but for Level 1 and Level 2, firms' largest shareholders average 65% and 63%, respectively)
  • 67
    • 79953057344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 446
  • 68
    • 79953043928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 474
  • 69
    • 0035604453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although many of the existing shareholder agreements are among related parties alone, raising concerns that they effectively create a potentially opportunistic controlling coalition, others arguably exhibit independence. Unlike a single controlling shareholder or an affiliated controlling group, unrelated blockholders face coordination problems in expropriating minority shareholders and dividing the respective proceeds, as they are unable towrite legal contracts to that effect. See Julian Franks & Colin Mayer, Ownership and Control of German Corporations, 14 REV. FIN. STUD. 943 (2001) (finding that blockholders in German firms effectively discipline management and extract low private benefits of control)
  • 70
    • 79953048371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As of 2008, Level 1 firms (where many of the old, traditional Brazilian firms are listed) still had on average slightly more widely distributed shareholdings as a percentage of total capital than Novo Mercado companies-though this is not the case if one counts only voting shares. See Gorga, supra note 61, at 523-24
  • 71
    • 79953056743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • BM&F BOVESPA, supra note 38, § 2.1 (defining "diffuse control" as the control exerted by a shareholder who holds less than 50% of the company's capital stock); see also Gorga, supra note 61, at 480 n.133 (adopting a 50% ownership threshold to identify the presence of a controlling shareholder)
  • 72
    • 0006761611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, the law and finance literature adopts a substantially lower threshold to ascertain the existence of a controlling shareholder. See, e.g., Rafael La Porta et al., Corporate Ownership Around the World, 54 J. FIN. 471, 491-98 (1999) (using 20% and 10% thresholds to determine control)
  • 73
    • 79953039274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The vast majority of firms going public in recent years adopted in their bylaws some form of enhanced mandatory bid rule, which is subject to triggers generally ranging from 10% to 35% of the company's shares. See Lucia Rebouças & Nelson Rocco, Conceitos Básicos de Governança Se Tornam Consensos de Mercado [Basic Corporate Governance Concepts Become Consensus in the Market], GAZETA MERCANTIL, May 19, 2008, available at 2008 WLNR 9428814. These mandatory bid rule requirements typically impose a minimum premium requirement-which, in the case of some companies, reaches the exorbitant amount of 50% above the firm's fifty-two-week high price, thus effectively serving as a takeover shield. See S. Wade Angus & Mariana Pargendler, Opportunities and Challenges for Foreign Private Equity Investors in Brazil, in INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS TRANSACTIONS WITH BRAZIL 63, 73 (Beatriz Franco et al. eds., 2008). Moreover, many such clauses were drafted as dead hand devices-that is, neither shareholders nor the boards can alter their content without first offering to buy out the remaining shareholders under the existing criteria. See Gorga, supra note 61, at 483. Despite their popularity, the CVM has recently asserted that these "immutable" provisions in firm bylaws are invalid under Brazilian law. See Parecer de Orientação CVM [CVM Advisory Opinion] No. 36 (2009), available at http://www.cvm.gov.br/asp/cvmwww/atos/Atos/pare/pare036.doc
  • 74
    • 79953038714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Improvements in domestic macroeconomic conditions, including the decline in interest rates of Brazilian public bonds and booming international financial markets, were also key to the renaissance in Brazil's capital markets starting in 2004. Previously, the combination of high inflation, staggering interest rates, and unstable economic policy had created an unsuitable environment that deterred Brazil's capital market development. See, e.g., Angus & Pargendler, supra note 73, at 73
  • 75
    • 79953044137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ERNST & YOUNG, GROWTH DURING ECONOMIC UNCERTAINTY: GLOBAL IPO TRENDS REPORT 2008, at 2 (2008). In 2007 Brazil raised $27.3 billion in IPOs, compared to $34.2 billion in the United States and $66 billion in China. Id
  • 76
    • 79953042943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Fabricio Vieira, Valor das empresas na Bolsa alcança o PIB [Value of Firms in the Exchanges Equals GDP], FOLHA DE SÃO PAULO, June 16, 2008, http://www1.folha.uol.com.br/folha/dinheiro/ult91u412753.shtml. In 1996, Brazil's stock market capitalization equaled 27% of GDP, and in 2000, 37% of GDP. Id
  • 77
    • 79953030586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There is also empirical support for the link between better corporate governance and better corporate performance in Brazil. Based on a large-sample 2004 survey of publicly traded Brazilian firms, Bernard Black, Antonio Gledson de Carvalho, and Érica Gorga find a positive statistically significant relation between quality of governance and corporate performance as measured by Tobin's q. Bernard Black et al., Does One Size Fit All in Corporate Governance? Evidence from Brazil (and Other BRIK Countries) 5 (Univ. of Tex. Law Sch. Law & Econ. Research Paper, Paper No. 152, 2009), available at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=1434116
  • 78
    • 79953056742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Boletim Empresas, supra note 65
  • 79
    • 84896299047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Recent empirical work suggests that, due in part to better corporate governance standards, the stock prices of companies listed on the São Paulo Exchange premium listing segments (Level 1, Level 2, and the Novo Mercado) were less sensitive to changes in the market and had lower volatility than the stock prices of companies listed on the traditional segment. See Pablo Rogers & José Roberto Securato, Corporate Governance and Volatility in the Capital Markets: Brazil Case Study, 7 J. CORP. OWNERSHIP & CONTROL 40 (2009). These findings, however, precede the 2008 financial crisis, a time when the share prices of firms listed on the Novo Mercado fell more than those of companies listed on the traditional segment. The stock prices of Novo Mercado firms have since largely recovered
  • 80
    • 79953035386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Lynn Cowan & Rogerio Jelmayer, Year's Biggest IPOs Make Debuts, WALL ST. J., Oct. 8, 2009, at C3. Banco Santander S.A. opted for a Level 2 listing, as did other banks going public in recent years
  • 81
    • 79953034407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Danilo Gregório & Simone Azevedo, Inspiration for the East: Encouraged by the Novo Mercado's Success, the Philippines and India Create Special Listing Tiers in Their Own Stock Exchanges, REVISTA CAPITAL ABERTO, Aug. 2009, at 38
  • 82
    • 79953049723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See OLSON, supra note 3, at 3, 77-79 (citing Britain after World War II as the most notable case of relative decline owing to the harmful influence of powerful interest groups)
  • 83
    • 79953039112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., TULLIO ASCARELLI, PANORAMA DO DIREITO COMERCIAL [PANORAMA OF COMMERCIAL LAW] 13 (1947) (noting that duality in private law, in which a new legal regime emerges parallel to the traditional system only to later achieve universal application, is pervasive in legal evolution)
  • 84
    • 79953056322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., id. at 46-49 (noting that the economic demands relating to the dynamism of the emerging commerce required a departure from the civil law principles, which continued to govern agrarian relations); A. CLAIRE CUTLER, PRIVATE POWER AND GLOBAL AUTHORITY 109 (2003) ("[T]he medieval law merchant supported a predominantly private commercial order, generating merchant laws and institutions that operated outside the local political economy of the period."); FRANCESCO GALGANO, LEX MERCATORIA 11 (2001) (describing the history of the lex mercatoria as a body of law directly created and applied by the merchant class, without the mediation of general politics). But see Stephen E. Sachs, From St. Ives to Cyberspace: The Modern Distortion of the Medieval 'Law Merchant,' 21 AM. U. INT'L L. REV. 685 (2006) (arguing that, contrary to the conventional view, medieval merchants were largely subject to local laws and customs, which varied substantially)
  • 85
    • 79953048966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Eric Nowak, Investor Protection and Capital Market Regulation in Germany, in THE GERMAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM 425, 426 (Jan Pieter Krahnen & Reinhard H. Schmidt eds., 2004) (noting that prior to World War I, Germany's stock markets boasted nearly twelve hundred listed companies compared to the approximately six hundred firms listed on the New York Stock Exchange)
  • 86
    • 79953038713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • MB ASSOCIADOS, supra note 10, at 42 (citing Simon Johnson, Which Rules Matter? Evidence from Germany's Neuer Markt (2000) (unpublished manuscript))
  • 87
    • 79953042942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • John Schmid, Menu Is Meager at 'New' Exchanges, INT'L HERALD TRIB. (Paris), Mar. 12, 2003, at 11
  • 88
    • 79953046999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Hans-Peter Burghof & Adrian Hunger, Access to Stock Markets for Small and Medium Sized Growth Firms: The Temporary Success and Ultimate Failure of Germany's Neuer Markt 2 (Oct. 2003) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=497404
  • 89
    • 79953040648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 3
  • 90
    • 79953052927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id
  • 91
    • 79953044543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The London Stock Exchange inaugurated the trend with the launch of the Alternative Investment Market (AIM) in 1995, and was followed by the Belgium-based pan- European EASDAQ and Paris Bourse's Nouveau Marché in 1996. See Gail Edmondson & Heidi Dawley, Europe as High-Tech Heaven?, BUSINESSWEEK, May 12, 1997, at 20. According to the Neuer Markt Rules and Regulations, "Issuers are, in particular, innovative enterprises which develop new sales markets, utilize new methods of, for example, procurement, production or distribution, or offer new products and/or services, and whose activities can be expected to generate high turnover and profits in the future." DEUTSCHE BÖRSE GRP., RULES AND REGULATIONS NEUER MARKT, at pt. 1, § 1 (1999), available at http://www.cnmv.es/delfos/tendencias/neuer.pdf
  • 92
    • 0035194896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Sigurt Vitols, Frankfurt's Neuer Markt and the IPO Explosion: Is Germany on the Road to Silicon Valley?, 30 ECON. & SOC'Y 553, 554 (2001)
  • 93
    • 79953038922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Erik Theissen, Organized Equity Markets, in THE GERMAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM, supra note 85, at 139, 144
  • 94
    • 79953036190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See La Porta et al., Investor Protection and Corporate Governance, supra note 2, at 22 ("[C]aptains of German industry have accepted [the Neuer Markt] because their firms were not directly affected.")
  • 95
    • 79953061695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See DEUTSCHE BÖRSE GRP., supra note 91, pt. 2, § 3.4
  • 96
    • 79953067036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id note note. § 3.10
  • 97
    • 79953050318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id note note. § 4.1.9
  • 98
    • 79953053925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id note note. § 2.2
  • 99
    • 79953041641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id note note. § 2.2
  • 100
    • 79953059300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id note note. § 3.8
  • 101
    • 79953056523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id note note. §§ 3.1(2), 3.2
  • 102
    • 79953030195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id note note. § 2.1(2). The listing committee rejected about 20% of the applicants based on a "subjective" approach. See Stewart Fleming, The Neuer Markt's Wild Ride, INSTITUTIONAL INVESTOR, Apr. 1999, at 42
  • 103
    • 79953066861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • DEUTSCHE BÖRSE GRP., supra note 91, pt. 5, § 2
  • 104
    • 79953055915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Sharon Reier, On the Continent, a Hodgepodge of Local Standards and Laws; Full Disclosure: Where (Outside the U.S.) to Find Company Data, INT'L HERALD TRIB. (Paris), Nov. 6, 1999, at 15 (citing early remarks by market participants that the Neuer Markt would "die in beauty" as the rigorous standards would discourage listings)
  • 105
    • 79953051457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Mark Landler, German Technology Stock Market to Be Dissolved, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 27, 2002, at W1
  • 106
    • 79953048965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Vanessa Fuhrmans, Playing by the Rules: How Neuer Markt Gets Respect, WALL ST. J., Aug. 21, 2000, at C1. The percentage of German adults holding shares soared from approximately 9% in 1997 to 20% in 2000. Landler, supra note 105
  • 107
    • 79953058546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Neuer Markt's Global Ambitions, MARKETWATCH (June 23, 1999), http://www.marketwatch.com/story/neuer-markts-global-ambitions
  • 108
    • 79953061137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Renault Enguerand, La guerre des nouveaux marchés d'actions fait rage en Europe; Le Neuer Markt allemand est en position de force [The War of New Equity Markets Rages Europe; The German Neuer Markt Is in a Strong Position], LE MONDE, Feb. 10, 1999
  • 109
    • 79953033460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Fuhrmans, supra note 106
  • 110
    • 79953040072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Schmid, supra note 87
  • 111
    • 79953053751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Fuhrmans, supra note 106. Little more than one year after its launch, the SMAX featured 125 listings. Id
  • 112
    • 79953057154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Burghof & Hunger, supra note 88, at 8
  • 113
    • 79953033633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Brian M. Carney, Teutonic Tailspin: A German Market's Rise and Fall, WALL ST. J., Oct. 1, 2002, at A20
  • 114
    • 79953036377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Danny Fortson, View from the City: AIM Carefully, DAILY DEAL, Apr. 18, 2005, available at 2005 WLNR 5939689
  • 115
    • 79953050125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Carney, supra note 113
  • 116
    • 79953051263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id note note note
  • 117
    • 79953051456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Edmund L. Andrews, Think Nasdaq. Now Double the Pain., N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 28, 2001, § 3, at 1
  • 118
    • 79953038154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • David Fairlamb, Down and Out in Frankfurt: The Neuer Markt's Woes Include a Tech-Stock Slump, Management Wrangles, and Fierce Rivalry from London, BUSINESSWEEK, Oct. 23, 2000, at 58
  • 119
    • 79953034406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Andrews, supra note 117
  • 120
    • 79953065522 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id
  • 121
    • 79953066860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Fuhrmans, supra note 106
  • 122
    • 79953051657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See DEUTSCHE BÖRSE GRP., supra note 91, pt. 2, § 2.1(4); Jack Ewing, The Neuer Markt Needs a Watchdog with Teeth, BUSINESSWEEK, Jan. 8, 2001, at 25
  • 123
    • 79953041242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Fuhrmans, supra note 106
  • 124
    • 79953039461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Josef Tobien & Olaf Schick, New Listing Regulations: Neuer Markt, in THE IFLR GUIDE TO GERMANY 27 (2001); Memorandum, Dewey Ballantine LLP, End of Neuer Markt 3-4 (Oct. 15, 2002) (on file with authors)
  • 125
    • 79953034010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Rachel Stevenson, Scandals and Bankruptcies Destroy Germany's Neuer Markt, INDEPENDENT (London), Sept. 27, 2002, at 23 (quoting an investor's statement that while the Neuer Markt was initially a "high-profile index," it eventually became "the last place you would want to list a business because of the negative associations"); see also Coffee, supra note 33, at 1805 (attributing the debacle of the Neuer Markt to "the strength of the network externalities that link firms traded on the same high profile market")
  • 126
    • 79953050316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Neal E. Boudette & Alfred Kueppers, Neuer Markt Faces Mounting Pressure from Members to Tighten Listing Rules, WALL ST. J., July 11, 2001, at C12
  • 127
    • 79953056955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Landler, supra note 105
  • 128
    • 0043194037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Case C-212/97, Centros Ltd. v. Erhervs-og Selskabsstyrelsen, 1999 E.C.R. I-1459. For a description of the Centros decision in terms of the Olson problem, see Ronald J. Gilson, Globalizing Corporate Governance: Convergence of Form or Function, 49 AM. J. COMP. L. 329, 350-56 (2001)
  • 129
    • 79953059689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The German codetermination system is composed of a complex set of statutes; however, for our purposes it consists of the requirement that the supervisory boards of corporations with more than five hundred employees have one-third employee representatives and those of corporations with more than two thousand employees have one-half employee representatives. See Betriebsverfassungsgesetz [BetrVG] [Industrial Constitution Act], Oct. 11, 1952, BUNDESGESETZBLATT, Teil I [BGBL. I] at 681; Mitbestimmungsgesetz [MitbestG] [Codetermination Act], Apr. 5, 1976, BGBL. I at 1153; see also Katharina Pistor, Codetermination: A Sociopolitical Model with Governance Externalities, in EMPLOYEES AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 163, 165-68 (Margaret M. Blair & Mark J. Roe eds., 1999) (summarizing the German codetermination system)
  • 130
    • 79953034009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Pistor, supra note 129, at 165-68 (tracing the political history of worker involvement in corporate governance)
  • 131
    • 79953042065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 165
  • 132
    • 79953048964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Case C-167/01, Kamer van Koophandel en Fabrieken voor Amsterdam v. Inspire Art Ltd., 2003 E.C.R. I-10155; Case C-208/00, Überseering BV v. Nordic Constr. Co. Baumanagement GmbH (NCC), 2002 E.C.R. I-9919; Centros, 1999 E.C.R. I-1459. Some question remains as to whether Centros actually prevents Germany from protecting codetermination. While Centros prevents Germany from blocking German businesses from incorporating elsewhere, some argue that Germany nonetheless could impose codetermination by legislation on such "pseudo-foreign" companies regardless of their state of incorporation. See, e.g., Jens C. Dammann, Note, The Future of Codetermination After Centros: Will German Corporate Law Move Closer to the U.S. Model?, 8 FORDHAM J. CORP. & FIN. L. 607, 613-14 (2003). Germany has not passed such legislation. Even assuming that such legislation would not conflict with the treaty, the effect of Centros is to shift the political burden of going forward with legislation. Before Centros, the business community required legislation to restrict codetermination, which the labor unions could block. After Centros, the labor unions require legislation to overcome Centros, which the business community can block
  • 133
    • 79953059128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The typical method for an established company to switch its state of incorporation is to merge the existing company into a subsidiary newly formed in the destination state. While the EU Cross-Border Merger Directive on cross-border mergers of companies with share capital, Parliament and Council Directive 2005/56, 2005 O.J. (L 310) 1 (EC), generally facilitates cross-border mergers, it is not of much help if the goal is to avoid employee governance participation. If the existing state of incorporation requires worker participation and the destination state does not, as contemplated here, the directive imposes a set of standard employee governance rules. See Mathias M. Siems, The European Directive on Cross- Border Mergers: An International Model, in CORPORATE MERGERS: MODERN APPROACHES 156, 167-68 (P.L. Jayanthi Reddy ed., 2009)
  • 134
    • 79953031550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A second method by which to shift a corporation's state of incorporation is to simply transfer the state of incorporation, accomplished by dissolving the existing corporation and reincorporating it in the target jurisdiction. This process is said to be unworkable. "Given the high costs involved, the time involved and the related administrative burden, with sometimes more than 35 procedural steps to overcome, this hardly ever occurs and European companies are, in practice, deprived of the possibility of moving their place of registration within the EU." Commission Staff Working Paper, Impact Assessment on the Directive on the Cross-Border Transfer of Registered Office, at 5, SEC (2007) 1707 (Dec. 12, 2007). While the European Commission has determined not to proceed with a transfer of registered office directive, the proposals all assumed that employee participation would be protected in much the same fashion as in the cross-border merger directive. See id.; see also European Parliament Resolution of 10 March 2009 with a Recommendation to the Commission on the Cross-Border Transfer of the Registered Office of a Company, 2010 O.J. (C 87) 5, 7 (recommending a transfer of registered office directive)
  • 135
    • 79953043312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A slightly more nuanced formulation of this point recognizes that the Centros dual regulatory regime provides companies a choice only with respect to worker participation imposed by the corporate governance system. Worker participation imposed by other regulatory regimes, like workers councils imposed by labor law, cannot be avoided by foreign incorporation
  • 136
    • 77954527180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To some extent, the text overstates the exit barriers confronting established German corporations. The maintenance of employee participation in governance required by the Cross-Border Merger Directive is diluted if the surviving firm then engages in another merger with a company chartered in the same member state. In that event, the Directive requires that employee participation be maintained only for an additional three years. Parliament and Council Directive 2005/56, art. 16, § 7, 2005 O.J. (L 310) 8 (EC). Since the language of the Directive refers only to "subsequent domestic mergers," an argument is available that changes in the legal form of the surviving company other than by merger will "launder" the employee participation requirement without the three-year lag. Id. (emphasis added). Finally, simple reincorporation may be available after the European Court of Justice's decision in Cartesio, which constrains a member state from restricting reincorporation by treating it as a liquidation under local law. Case C-210/06, Cartesio Oktató és Szolgáltató bt, 2008 E.C.R. I-9641. Here the doctrinal analysis remains quite uncertain. See, e.g., Andrzej W. Wiśniewski & Adam Opalski, Companies' Freedom of Establishment After the ECJ Cartesio Judgment, 10 EUR. BUS. ORG. L. REV. 595, 611 (2009). Notwithstanding the variety of techniques by which an established German company may, with patience and subtlety, escape an employee participation regime, the transactional and legal barriers stand in sharp contrast to the unfettered discretion of an early stage company simply to choose a more favorable jurisdiction in which to incorporate. The differential still operates as a dual regulatory regime
  • 137
    • 79953042467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Council Regulation 2157/2001, 2001 O.J. (L 294) 1 (EC); Council Directive 2001/86, 2001 O.J. (L 294) 22 (EC)
  • 138
    • 79953031152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Jochem Reichert, Experience with the SE in Germany, 4 UTRECHT L. REV. 22, 28 (2008)
  • 139
    • 77649175475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 28. Reichert reports that one German company converting to a European Company form disclosed to its shareholders that one motive for making the shift was to freeze its codetermination obligation at the one-third level. Id.; see also Horst Eidenmüller et al., Incorporating Under European Law: The Societas Europaea as a Vehicle for Legal Arbitrage, 10 EUR. BUS. ORG. L. REV. 1 (2009) (finding strong evidence that firms have adopted the SE form in order to avoid or mitigate the effects of mandatory codetermination laws). Efforts to test this hypothesis empirically using event study techniques have not found distinctive abnormal returns when the company shifting to a European Company previously had been subject to German codetermination. See, e.g., Horst Eidenmüller et al., The Societas Europaea: Good News for European Firms 20 (European Corporate Governance Inst., Working Paper No. 127/2009, 2009), available at http://www.ssrn.com/abstract=1409555; Felix Lamp, Value Creation and Value Destruction in the Societas Europaea: Evidence from the New Legal Form 22-23 (Dec. 18, 2010) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.ssrn.com/abstract=1728162. Because of the small sample size in both studies, the results are not persuasive
  • 140
    • 44649153501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As yet, the empirical evidence is consistent with half of the analysis: by and large, existing large firms have remained incorporated in Germany. With respect to newly formed corporations, however, the largest number of German-located businesses incorporating outside Germany are small local businesses, of the sort actually involved in Centros, rather than, like the example in the text, venture capital-backed technology start-ups. See Marco Becht, Colin Mayer & Hannes F. Wagner, Where Do Firms Incorporate? Deregulation and the Cost of Entry, 14 J. CORP. FIN. 241, 247-48 (2008) (providing empirical evidence concerning Germany-based firms incorporating in the United Kingdom)
  • 141
    • 1342268967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Alma Cohen, Firms' Decisions Where to Incorporate, 46 J.L. & ECON. 383, 386 (2003); Robert Daines, The Incorporation Choices of IPO Firms, 77 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1559, 1572 (2002) (describing a bimodal competition system in which nearly 95% of firms that incorporate outside of their home state choose Delaware)
  • 142
    • 22544453008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Mark J. Roe, Delaware's Politics, 118 HARV. L. REV. 2491, 2500 (2005); Roberta Romano, The States as a Laboratory: Legal Innovation and State Competition for Corporate Charters, 23 YALE J. ON REG. 209, 212-13 (2006)
  • 143
    • 0036978270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Marcel Kahan & Ehud Kamar, The Myth of State Competition in Corporate Law, 55 STAN. L. REV. 679, 688-89 (2002)
  • 144
    • 79953033280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Bebchuk & Cohen, supra note 141, at 386; Daines, supra note 141, at 1574
  • 145
    • 79953032699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Ian Ayres, Judging Close Corporations in the Age of Statutes, 70 WASH. U. L.Q. 365, 374-75 (1992) (describing costs); Jens Dammann & Matthias Schündeln, The Incorporation Choices of Privately Held Corporations, J.L. ECON. & ORG. (forthcoming 2011) (finding that 93% of a broad sample of closely held corporations are incorporated in their home state)
  • 146
    • 79953037950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Kahan & Kamar, supra note 143, at 735 (noting that politics drives the laws of states other than Delaware, which are more likely to favor management than if they were motivated by competition)
  • 147
    • 79953064219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Roe, supra note 142, at 2525-26
  • 148
    • 79953033459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In fact, it is common to see managers and their employees or labor unions working together for protective antitakeover action from a state legislature. See Daines, supra note 141, at 1579-80 & n.70 (noting that "[i]n state after state, managers have successfully lobbied for statutes that restrict takeovers and protect managers (and possibly employees) at the expense of shareholders," and citing a case in Massachusetts in which a company was able to secure favorable protective legislation because it "was a large employer and rallied its employees to spirited protest meetings"); Mark J. Roe, Takeover Politics, in THE DEAL DECADE: WHAT TAKEOVERS AND LEVERAGED BUYOUTS MEAN FOR CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 321, 339-40 (Margaret M. Blair ed., 1993) (describing a successful lobbying effort by Pennsylvania corporations and labor unions to get an antitakeover statute enacted)
  • 149
    • 79953061136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Bebchuk & Cohen, supra note 141, at 395 tbl.5 (showing, for all fifty states, the percentage of firms located in each state that are incorporated in that state, and revealing a negative correlation between local incorporation and state size); Daines, supra note 141, at 1606 tbl.A2 (revealing a similar negative correlation in thirty states and the District of Columbia between size and percentage of firms incorporated locally)
  • 150
    • 79953059127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Daines, supra note 141, at 1581, 1585
  • 151
    • 79953057720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Kahan & Kamar, supra note 143, at 740 ("[B]ecause, unlike noncompeting states, Delaware also had an interest in not antagonizing shareholders of companies that it might attract from other states. it passed a milder [antitakeover] statute."). There are also abundant examples of state-level corporate law reforms that have been hindered by local interest groups. For example, New York labor unions have been able to block the elimination of section 630 of the Business Corporation Law, which holds the ten largest shareholders of a corporation personally liable for unpaid employee wages. Id. at 732. Similarly, public interest lawyers and labor unions prevented the creation of a chancery court in Pennsylvania. Id. at 733
  • 152
    • 0345772821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., John C. Coates IV, Explaining Variation in Takeover Defenses: Blame the Lawyers, 89 CALIF. L. REV. 1301, 1340, 1366 (2001) (hypothesizing that companies incorporated in Delaware should have more takeover defenses because of the IPO process, and showing that firms incorporated in Delaware empirically have more takeover defenses than the average firm)
  • 153
    • 0346961398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Mark J. Roe, Delaware's Competition, 117 HARV. L. REV. 588, 624-32 (2003) [hereinafter Roe, Delaware's Competition]; Roe, supra note 142, at 2510-11
  • 154
    • 0040669878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Bernard Black & Reinier Kraakman, Delaware's Takeover Law: The Uncertain Search for Hidden Value, 96 NW. U. L. REV. 521, 565-66 (2002); Ronald J. Gilson, Unocal Fifteen Years Later (and What We Can Do About It), 26 DEL. J. CORP. L. 491, 502-06 (2001)
  • 155
    • 79953050889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Kahan & Kamar, supra note 143, at 705-06 & n.86 (noting the interest of corporate lawyers in establishing statutes that require litigation and sophisticated legal advice, and discussing lawyers' efforts to stop a proposed Nevada law reducing officers' and directors' liability to shareholders); Ehud Kamar, A Regulatory Competition Theory of Indeterminacy in Corporate Law, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 1908 (1998) (arguing that Delaware is successful at attracting corporate charters because its corporate law is vague enough to give its judges a high degree of power); Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Toward an Interest- Group Theory of Delaware Corporate Law, 65 TEX. L. REV. 469, 472 (1987) (arguing that the Delaware bar plays an outsized role in determining the content of Delaware corporate law)
  • 156
    • 0000821053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Roberta Romano, Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle, 1 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 225, 234 (1985)
  • 157
    • 79953031941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Illinois Business Take-Over Act, Pub. Act No. 80-1421, 1978 Ill. Laws 1581 (repealed 1983)
  • 158
    • 79953051261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Edgar v. Mite Corp., 457 U.S. 624, 639, 646 (1982) (striking the Illinois statute as preempted by the federal Williams Act and beyond state authority under the dormant Commerce Clause)
  • 159
    • 79953042256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See WILLIAM T. ALLEN, REINIER KRAAKMAN & GUHAN SUBRAMANIAN, COMMENTARIES AND CASES ON THE LAW OF BUSINESS ORGANIZATION 604-12 (2d ed. 2007)
  • 160
    • 79953032881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Henry N. Butler, Corporation-Specific Anti-Takeover Statutes and the Market for Corporate Charters, 1988 WIS. L. REV. 365, 382-83 (criticizing corporationspecific antitakeover statutes as egregious instances of managers' use of the political process for entrenchment purposes); Kahan & Kamar, supra note 143; Roberta Romano, The Future of Hostile Takeovers: Legislation and Public Opinion, 57 U. CIN. L. REV. 457, 461 (1988) (describing the evolution of state antitakeover statutes); Roberta Romano, The Political Economy of Takeover Statutes, 73 VA. L. REV. 111, 122-25 (1987) (noting that the adoption of Connecticut's takeover statute was driven by one major company incorporated in the state); Robert Daines, Do Classified Boards Affect Firm Value? Takeover Defenses After the Poison Pill 10-13 (2001) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with authors) (describing how Massachusetts imposed a classified board on all Massachusetts corporations in response to a request by one firm's management for protection from a single acquirer)
  • 161
    • 79953043733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Roe, Delaware's Competition, supra note 153 (arguing that the main legal competitor of Delaware is the federal government, not other states)
  • 162
    • 79953053750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See ROBERTA ROMANO, THE GENIUS OF AMERICAN CORPORATE LAW 75-84 (1993); Roe, supra note 142, at 2513-15 (using a formal model to illustrate how federal intervention could make the takeover market less efficient)
  • 163
    • 79953045307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ENTERPRISE AND AMERICAN LAW 1836-1937, at 241-67 (1991)
  • 164
    • 79953047586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • New Jersey, which in the late nineteenth century and early twentieth century played the role in corporate chartering now played by Delaware, was attractive to out-ofstate companies in part because it, unlike other states, did not restrict corporate combinations that were anticompetitive. New Jersey corporate law was also attractive because it eliminated arbitrary restrictions imposed by other states and focused on protection of shareholders and creditors. See Edward Q. Keasbey, New Jersey and the Great Corporations, 13 HARV. L. REV. 198, 205-12 (1899)
  • 165
    • 79953066859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra Part II.B
  • 166
    • 79953059899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The history of these restrictions is recounted briefly in Geoffrey P. Miller, Interstate Banking in the Court, 1985 SUP. CT. REV. 179, 181-83. See also Eugene Nelson White, The Political Economy of Banking Regulation, 1864-1933, 42 J. ECON. HIST. 33 (1982) (providing a political economy account of intrastate branching restrictions)
  • 167
    • 79953033827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Prasad Krishnamurthy, Branching Restrictions, Financial Market Integration, and Firm Growth: Evidence from U.S. Banking Deregulation (Aug. 17, 2009) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with authors), provides empirical evidence of the effects of U.S. branch banking restrictions on business growth and surveys the previous literature on the subject
  • 168
    • 79953052130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See JONATHAN R. MACEY & GEOFFREY P. MILLER, BANKING LAW AND REGULATION 9-11 (2d ed. 1997); Miller, supra note 166, at 181 (discussing federal legislation passed in 1933 "permit[ting] national banks to branch within a state on the same terms and conditions as state banks")
  • 169
    • 79953052129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • On the lack of real choice of regulation offered by this "dual" system, see Henry N. Butler & Jonathan R. Macey, The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System, 73 CORNELL L. REV. 677, 678 (1988). Butler and Macey emphasize that maintenance of this inefficient regulatory regime benefited yet another entrenched interest group, namely the regulators. See id. at 679
  • 170
    • 79953064022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Krishnamurthy, supra note 167, at 3
  • 171
    • 79953038921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., MARK J. ROE, STRONG MANAGERS, WEAK OWNERS 54-59 (1994)
  • 172
    • 79953066484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See MACEY & MILLER, supra note 168, at 29-32
  • 173
    • 79953066102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The two approaches can be combined, as they were by the Novo Mercado in a recent set of proposed amendments to its listing rules. See infra text accompanying notes 200- 01
  • 174
    • 47749108284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Steven Shavell, On Optimal Legal Change, Past Behavior, and Grandfathering, 37 J. LEGAL STUD. 37 (2008) (arguing that grandfathering is efficient when switching costs are high)
  • 175
    • 79953049925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Despite their grandfathering protection for old public firms, the new statutory rules were rather timid and were later dwarfed by the Novo Mercado requirements banning nonvoting shares altogether. See supra Part I.A-B
  • 176
    • 79953041860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., NYSE, LISTED COMPANY MANUAL § 313.00 (1994)
  • 177
    • 79953047968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Renee L. Crean, Recent Development in New York Law, 72 ST. JOHN'S L. REV. 695, 700 (1998)
  • 178
    • 79953035786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See TARUN KHANNA, BILLIONS OF ENTREPRENEURS 165-66 (2007)
  • 179
    • 79953031350 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., MODESTO CARVALHOSA, 1 COMENTÁRIOS À LEI DE SOCIEDADES ANÔNIMAS [COMMENTARIES TO THE CORPORATIONS LAW] 170 (4th ed. 2002) (arguing that the 2001 reform's different treatment of old and new Brazilian firms with respect to preferred shares is inequitable and unconstitutional)
  • 180
    • 33645775188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • On menus in general, particularly in the context of corporate law, see Ian Ayres, Menus Matter, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 3 (2006); and Yair Listokin, What Do Corporate Default Rules and Menus Do? An Empirical Examination (Yale Law Sch. John M. Olin Ctr. for Studies in Law, Econ., & Pub. Policy Research Paper, Paper No. 335, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=924578
  • 181
    • 33645575255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Ronald J. Gilson & Curtis J. Milhaupt, Choice as Regulatory Reform: The Case of Japanese Corporate Governance, 53 AM. J. COMP. L. 343, 346 (2005)
  • 182
    • 79953066683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Robert N. Eberhart, Corporate Governance Systems and Firm Value: Empirical Evidence from Japan's Natural Experiment 4 (July 2010) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://sprie.stanford.edu/publications/22480. Companies that adopted the iinkai secchi structure initially improved their performance compared to industry competitors that retained the traditional governance structure. Id. This advantage diminished after two years, illustrat
  • 183
    • 79953047407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 102(b)(7) (2010)
  • 184
    • 79953036948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 488 A.2d 858 (Del. 1985)
  • 185
    • 79953061694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As is widely understood, Delaware corporations had no difficulty making the choice-virtually every company adopted the contemplated charter amendment
  • 186
    • 79953059897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra Part IV
  • 187
    • 33646190368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Henry Hansmann, Corporation and Contract, 8 AM. L. & ECON. REV. 1, 2 (2006)
  • 188
    • 0035588238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 4-5; see also Robert Daines & Michael Klausner, Do IPO Charters Maximize Firm Value? Antitakeover Protection in IPOs, 17 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 83, 85 (2001)
  • 189
    • 79953037949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra notes 19-21 and accompanying text
  • 190
    • 79953049924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Gilson & Milhaupt, supra note 181, at 354
  • 191
    • 41849098552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In Stone v. Ritter, 911 A.2d 362 (Del. 2006), the Delaware Supreme Court held that the duty of oversight established under In re Caremark International Inc. Derivative Litigation, 698 A.2d 959 (Del. Ch. 1996), a classic duty of care case, could give rise to a violation of the duty of loyalty if the directors failed to discharge their fiduciary obligations in good faith. See Stephen M. Bainbridge et al., The Convergence of Good Faith and Oversight, 55 UCLA L. REV. 559, 597 (2008) (describing the Delaware Supreme Court's decision in Stone as "another case in which section 102(b)(7) seems to be driving the analysis"); Claire A. Hill & Brett H. McDonnell, Stone v. Ritter and the Expanding Duty of Loyalty, 76 FORDHAM L. REV. 1769, 1770 (2007) (defending the use of the duty of good faith to enlarge the scope of director liability for breach of the duty of loyalty)
  • 192
    • 0040076348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For some perspective on the tortured evolution of the duty of care under Delaware law, see William T. Allen et al., Realigning the Standard of Review of Director Due Care with Delaware Public Policy: A Critique of Van Gorkom and Its Progeny as a Standard of Review Problem, 96 NW. U. L. REV. 449, 458-65 (2002)
  • 193
    • 79953039673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In a limited fashion, Delaware has provided a menu that allows reducing fiduciary duty to the obligation of good faith and fair dealing, but this is limited to alternative forms of corporations, rather than traditional corporations. Some of these forms, however, like master limited partnerships, are suitable for public ownership. See JESSE H. CHOPER, JOHN C. COFFEE, JR. & RONALD J. GILSON, CASES AND MATERIALS ON CORPORATIONS 800-11 (7th ed. 2008) (describing development of the obligation of good faith and fair dealing as an alternative to fiduciary duty). Evidence showing that Delaware corporations going public typically have plain vanilla charters other than with respect to antitakeover provisions, even though the statute allows for substantial variation, suggests that Delaware understands that there is little market for higher standards. See Michael Klausner, The Contractarian Theory of Corporate Law: A Generation Later, 31 J. CORP. L. 779, 788-91 (2006) (summarizing evidence)
  • 194
    • 79953042062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Under a 2007 reform to the North Dakota Publicly Traded Corporations Act promoted by corporate governance advocates, firms incorporated under North Dakota law after July 1, 2007, can insert a provision in their articles of incorporation that subjects them to a bundle of strong shareholder rights, including majority voting for directors, advisory shareholder votes on executive compensation, the ability to propose board nominees on the company's proxy statement, and reimbursement of proxy expenses incurred by insurgent shareholders. North Dakota Publicly Traded Corporations Act, N.D. CENT. CODE §§ 10-35, 54-09-08 (2010). Since firms already incorporated in North Dakota before 2007 are presumably free to reincorporate and thereby take advantage of the new shareholder-oriented provisions, the established and the reformist regimes are available to both old and new firms, making this a straightforward example of regulatory dualism
  • 195
    • 79953046429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • BM&F BOVESPA, supra note 38, § 14.2
  • 196
    • 79953061092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Among other things, the stricter amendments, effective as of January 2006, require at least 20% of the directors of Novo Mercado firms be independent. Santana, supra note 20, at 32
  • 197
    • 79953052926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra Part II.A
  • 198
    • 79953062439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Leandro Modé, 'Reforma' do Novo Mercado fica pela metade [Novo Mercado 'Reform' Only Half Successful], O ESTADO DE S. PAULO, Sept. 10, 2010
  • 199
    • 79953056740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Vinícius Pinheiro, BM&FBovespa descarta criar novo nível de governança [BM&FBovespa Discards the Creation of New Governance Level], AGÊNCIA ESTADO, Sept. 9, 2010, http://economia.estadao.com.br/noticias/bmfbovespa-descarta-criar-novo-n ivel-de -governanca,not_34761.htm
  • 200
    • 79953048370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 73 and accompanying text
  • 201
    • 79953047782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra Part III.A
  • 202
    • 79953043117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • George Orwell highlighted the problem in the closing scene in Animal Farm; it became difficult to tell the pigs from the farmers. GEORGE ORWELL, ANIMAL FARM 86-93 (Alfred Knopf 1993) (1945).
  • 203
    • 0011088449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., John C. Coffee, Jr., The Rise of Dispersed Ownership: The Roles of Law And the State in the Separation of Ownership and Control, 111 YALE L.J. 1, 22-23, 80 (2001) (noting the reverse causality between capital markets developments and investor protection laws, as "[s]trong markets do create a demand for stronger legal rules")
  • 204
    • 79953050706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Bebchuk & Roe, supra note 62, at 129 ("[T]here are significant sources of path dependence in a country's patterns of corporate ownership structure.")
  • 205
    • 79953050123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Lei No. 11.638, de 28 de Dezembro de 2007, D.O.U. de 28.12.2007. Prior to the reform, Bovespa's premium listing segments required the adoption of either IAS or U.S. GAAP while old firms listed in the traditional segments generally followed the laxer Brazilian GAAP
  • 206
    • 79953053141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Parecer de Orientação CVM [CVM Advisory Opinion] No. 35 (2008), available at http://www.bmfbovespa.com.br/juridico/download/ParecerOrientacaoCVM_35.p df
  • 207
    • 79953063807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Yuki Yokoi, Happy Preferred Shareholders: Under CVM Pressure, Aracruz PN and ON Get Equal Treatment in VCP Merger, REVISTA CAPITAL ABERTO, Sept. 2009, http://www.capitalaberto.com.br/english/ler_artigo.php?pag=2&sec=77 &i=2584. Yokoi describes the process leading to the merger of Aracruz into Votorantim Papel e Celulose in September of 2009. The new company, Fibria, the world's largest pulp and paper company, is expected to migrate to the Novo Mercado. Id
  • 208
    • 79953060109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Instrução CVM [CVM Rule] No. 480, de 7 Dezembro de 2009
  • 209
    • 79953046998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a description of the process leading to the adoption of these regulations and of the decisions challenging their legality and constitutionality, see Diego Werneck Arguelhes & Mariana Pargendler, Collateral Costs of Violence: How Insecurity Is Shaping Legal Institutions in Brazil (2010) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with authors)
  • 210
    • 79953058759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra text accompanying note 5
  • 211
    • 79953047205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Roe, Delaware's Competition, supra note 153, at 616-20
  • 212
    • 77953117102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Natalya Shnitser, A Free Pass for Foreign Firms? An Assessment of SEC and Private Enforcement Against Foreign Issuers, 119 YALE L.J. 1638 (2009). This is particularly true when the foreign-listed company has few assets in the United States and is therefore practically immune from private enforcement of the securities law
  • 213
    • 79953033632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Dammann & Hansmann, supra note 49 (proposing to give parties to commercial contracts in countries with weak courts the option of committing to have their disputes adjudicated in the public courts of another country with a better-developed judiciary)
  • 214
    • 79953040644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The European Union, for example, following the American pattern, now offers a choice between having one's trademark rights governed by an established national legal regime or by the reformist European Union regime. See Julie Bak, OHIM: The European Community Trademark's PTO, 19 J. CONTEMP. LEGAL ISSUES 416, 418 n.10 (2010)
  • 215
    • 79953052925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • States in the United States that limit marriage to heterosexual couples but recognize gay marriages entered into in other states offer an example. See David D. Meyer, Fragmentation and Consolidation in the Law of Marriage and Same-Sex Relationships, 58 AM. J. COMP. L. 115, 130 n.70 (2010). Another example-involving a menu offered by a single jurisdiction- is the recent creation within three states of a rigorously committed form of "covenant marriage" as an alternative to conventional marriage. See Katherine Shaw Spaht, Covenant Marriage Seven Years Later: Its As Yet Unfulfilled Promise, 65 LA. L. REV. 605, 605- 06 (2005).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.