-
1
-
-
0030301517
-
A new data set measuring income inequality
-
Klaus Deininger and Lyn Squire, 'A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequality', World Bank Economic Review, 10 (1996), 565-91.
-
(1996)
World Bank Economic Review
, vol.10
, pp. 565-591
-
-
Deininger, K.1
Squire, L.2
-
2
-
-
0031955813
-
Explaining international and intertemporal variations in income inequality
-
See, for example, and
-
See, for example, Hongyi Li, Lyn Squire and Heng-fu Zou, 'Explaining International and Intertemporal Variations in Income Inequality', Economic Journal, 108 (1998), 26-43;
-
(1998)
Economic Journal
, vol.108
, pp. 26-43
-
-
Li, H.1
Squire, L.2
Zou, H.3
-
3
-
-
3142726279
-
Inequality, democracy, and persistence: Is there a political kuznets curve?
-
Alberto Chong, 'Inequality, Democracy, and Persistence: Is There a Political Kuznets Curve?' Economics & Politics, 16 (2004), 189-212;
-
(2004)
Economics & Politics
, vol.16
, pp. 189-212
-
-
Chong, A.1
-
4
-
-
0038506502
-
Economic openness, democracy, and income inequality: An empirical analysis
-
and Rafael Reuveny and Quan Li, 'Economic Openness, Democracy, and Income Inequality: An Empirical Analysis', Comparative Political Studies, 36 (2003), 575-601.
-
(2003)
Comparative Political Studies
, vol.36
, pp. 575-601
-
-
Reuveny, R.1
Li, Q.2
-
5
-
-
4744358520
-
Does liberté = egalité? A survey of the empirical links between democracy and inequality with some evidence on the transition economies
-
p. 528
-
Mark Gradstein and Branko Milanovic, 'Does Liberté = Egalité? A Survey of the Empirical Links between Democracy and Inequality with some Evidence on the Transition Economies', Journal of Economic Surveys, 14 (2004), 515-37, p. 528.
-
(2004)
Journal of Economic Surveys
, vol.14
, pp. 515-537
-
-
Gradstein, M.1
Milanovic, B.2
-
6
-
-
0029484919
-
Inequality and growth reconsidered: Lessons from east asia
-
For Asia, see, and
-
For Asia, see Nancy Birdsall, David Ross and Richard Sabot, 'Inequality and Growth Reconsidered: Lessons from East Asia', World Bank Economic Review, 9 (1995), 477-508;
-
(1995)
World Bank Economic Review
, vol.9
, pp. 477-508
-
-
Birdsall, N.1
Ross, D.2
Sabot, R.3
-
7
-
-
56249137178
-
The 1990s in latin america: Another decade of persistent inequality, but with somewhat lower poverty
-
for Latin America, see, Washington, D. C.: Inter-American Development Bank
-
for Latin America, see Miguel Szekely, 'The 1990s in Latin America: Another Decade of Persistent Inequality, but with Somewhat Lower Poverty', IADB Working Paper No. 454 (Washington, D. C.: Inter-American Development Bank, 2001).
-
(2001)
IADB Working Paper No. 454
-
-
Szekely, M.1
-
8
-
-
78650044040
-
-
UNO-WIDER World Institute for Development Economics Research, Version 2, Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economics Research of the United Nations University/UNDP, May, The DS dataset contains 2, 634 observations versus 4, 982 for WIID. The sample selection criteria discussed later determine the effective increase in observations. Our dataset probably contains a 25-40 per cent increase in country/year observations vis-a-vis most studies using DS
-
UNO-WIDER (World Institute for Development Economics Research), World Income Database (WIID), Version 2 (Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economics Research of the United Nations University/UNDP, May 2007). The DS dataset contains 2, 634 observations versus 4, 982 for WIID. The sample selection criteria (discussed later) determine the effective increase in observations. Our dataset probably contains a 25-40 per cent increase in country/year observations vis-a-vis most studies using DS.
-
(2007)
World Income Database (WIID)
-
-
-
9
-
-
78650058909
-
-
the longer working paper version available on SSRN, 'Does Democracy Reduce Inequality: If So How?', interested parties can find a more in-depth examination of the mechanisms
-
In the longer working paper version (available on SSRN), 'Does Democracy Reduce Inequality: If So How?', interested parties can find a more in-depth examination of the mechanisms.
-
-
-
-
10
-
-
84953401803
-
-
Most people who argue that inequality affects the birth and death of democracy believe elite hostility to democracy stems from its redistributional threat. See, for example, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
Most people who argue that inequality affects the birth (and death) of democracy believe elite hostility to democracy stems from its redistributional threat. See, for example, Carles Boix, Democracy and Redistribution (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003).
-
(2003)
Democracy and Redistribution
-
-
Boix, C.1
-
11
-
-
0001314915
-
A rational theory of the size of government
-
benchmark voter model is, and, For its application to political regimes
-
The benchmark voter model is Allan Meltzer and Scott Richard, 'A Rational Theory of the Size of Government', Journal of Political Economy, 89 (1981), 914-27. For its application to political regimes
-
(1981)
Journal of Political Economy
, vol.89
, pp. 914-927
-
-
Meltzer, A.1
Richard, S.2
-
12
-
-
0011080101
-
Why did the west extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective
-
see, and, It should be noted that regime type does not map perfectly onto overall inequality without further assumptions about the distribution of factor income pre-tax. To take one example: if factor income in a non-democracy were equally distributed, to start with no democratic process could reduce economic inequality. Because factor endowments may vary within regime-type, the democratization hypothesis may be on firmer grounds. That is, given initial endowments, democracy will reduce inequality from whatever be its pre-existing level
-
see Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson, 'Why Did the West Extend the Franchise? Democracy, Inequality, and Growth in Historical Perspective', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115 (1998), 1167-99. It should be noted that regime type does not map perfectly onto overall inequality without further assumptions about the distribution of factor income (pre-tax). To take one example: if factor income in a non-democracy were equally distributed, to start with no democratic process could reduce economic inequality. Because factor endowments may vary within regime-type, the democratization hypothesis may be on firmer grounds. That is, given initial endowments, democracy will reduce inequality from whatever be its pre-existing level.
-
(1998)
Quarterly Journal of Economics
, vol.115
, pp. 1167-1199
-
-
Acemoglu, D.1
Robinson, J.2
-
13
-
-
0027834939
-
Education, democracy, and growth
-
Gilles Saint-Paul and Thierry Verdier, 'Education, Democracy, and Growth', Journal of Development Economics, 42 (1993), 399-407.
-
(1993)
Journal of Development Economics
, vol.42
, pp. 399-407
-
-
Saint-Paul, G.1
Verdier, T.2
-
15
-
-
0001504224
-
Democracies pay higher wages
-
Dani Rodrik, 'Democracies Pay Higher Wages', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114 (1998), 707-38.
-
(1998)
Quarterly Journal of Economics
, vol.114
, pp. 707-738
-
-
Rodrik, D.1
-
16
-
-
0011250812
-
The median-voter hypothesis, income inequality, and income redistribution: An empirical test with the required data
-
For a critique of the median-voter model, see
-
For a critique of the median-voter model, see Branko Milanovic, 'The Median-Voter Hypothesis, Income Inequality, and Income Redistribution: An Empirical Test with the Required Data', European Journal of Political Economy, 16 (2000), 367-410.
-
(2000)
European Journal of Political Economy
, vol.16
, pp. 367-410
-
-
Milanovic, B.1
-
18
-
-
0034767883
-
Globalization, domestic politics, and social spending in latin america 1973-1997: A cross-sectional time series analysis
-
Compare Robert Kaufman and Alex Segura-Ubiergo, 'Globalization, Domestic Politics, and Social Spending in Latin America 1973-1997: A Cross-Sectional Time Series Analysis, ' World Politics, 53 (2001), 553-87
-
(2001)
World Politics
, vol.53
, pp. 553-587
-
-
Kaufman, C.R.1
Segura-Ubiergo, A.2
-
19
-
-
2542558849
-
Do democracies have different public policies than nondemocracies?
-
against, and
-
against Casey Mulligan, Robert Gil and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, 'Do Democracies Have Different Public Policies than Nondemocracies?', Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18 (2004), 51-74.
-
(2004)
Journal of Economic Perspectives
, vol.18
, pp. 51-74
-
-
Mulligan, C.1
Gil, R.2
Sala-i-Martin, X.3
-
20
-
-
4244049621
-
Income distribution and tax, and government social spending policies in developing countries
-
See, and, Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economics Research
-
See Ke-young Chu, Hamid Davoodi and Sanjeev Gupta, 'Income Distribution and Tax, and Government Social Spending Policies in Developing Countries', WIDER Working Paper No. 214 (Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economics Research, 2000).
-
(2000)
WIDER Working Paper No. 214
-
-
Chu, K.1
Davoodi, H.2
Gupta, S.3
-
21
-
-
84936824439
-
Democracy, economic development, and income inequality
-
Edward Muller, 'Democracy, Economic Development, and Income Inequality', American Sociological Review, 53 (1988), 50-68;
-
(1988)
American Sociological Review
, vol.53
, pp. 50-68
-
-
Muller, E.1
-
22
-
-
0035597618
-
The invisible hand of democracy: Political control and the provision of public services
-
David Lake and Matthew Baum, 'The Invisible Hand of Democracy: Political Control and the Provision of Public Services', Comparative Political Studies, 34 (2001), 587-621.
-
(2001)
Comparative Political Studies
, vol.34
, pp. 587-621
-
-
Lake, D.1
Baum, M.2
-
23
-
-
0006081576
-
-
See, and, unpublished paper, UCLA
-
See Stanley Engerman, Elisa Mariscal and Kenneth Sokoloff, 'Schooling, Suffrage, and the Persistence of Inequality in the Americas, 1800-1945' (unpublished paper, UCLA, 2001);
-
(2001)
Schooling, Suffrage, and the Persistence of Inequality in the Americas, 1800-1945
-
-
Engerman, S.1
Mariscal, E.2
Sokoloff, K.3
-
25
-
-
0038980895
-
The origins of technology-skill complementarity
-
Claudia Goldin and Lawrence Katz, 'The Origins of Technology-Skill Complementarity', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113 (1998), 693-732.
-
(1998)
Quarterly Journal of Economics
, vol.113
, pp. 693-732
-
-
Goldin, C.1
Katz, L.2
-
26
-
-
77956724779
-
Changes in the wage structure and earnings inequality
-
in Orley Ashenfelter and David Card, eds, Amsterdam: Elsevier
-
Lawrence Katz and David Autor, 'Changes in the Wage Structure and Earnings Inequality', in Orley Ashenfelter and David Card, eds, Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3 A (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1998), 1463-555.
-
(1998)
Handbook of Labor Economics
, vol.3 A
, pp. 1463-1555
-
-
Katz, L.1
Autor, D.2
-
27
-
-
0347094398
-
-
One of Rodrik's measures - labour's share of national income - is misleading; labour's share is typically higher in the United States and United Kingdom than other OECD countries
-
Rodrik, 'Democracies Pay Higher Wages'. One of Rodrik's measures - labour's share of national income - is misleading; labour's share is (typically) higher in the United States and United Kingdom than other OECD countries.
-
Democracies Pay Higher Wages
-
-
Rodrik1
-
28
-
-
33645345141
-
Where did the productivity growth go? Inflation dynamics and the distribution of income
-
See, and, The SSRN version of this article examines the labour mechanism using wage inequality data
-
See Ian Dew-Becker and Robert Gordon, 'Where did the Productivity Growth Go? Inflation Dynamics and the Distribution of Income', Brooking Papers on Economic Activities, 2 (2005), 67-127. The SSRN version of this article examines the labour mechanism using wage inequality data.
-
(2005)
Brooking Papers on Economic Activities
, vol.2
, pp. 67-127
-
-
Dew-Becker, I.1
Gordon, R.2
-
29
-
-
78650069092
-
-
Mathematically, the Gini coefficient is a reasonable measure of inequality; in practice, however, existing Ginis are based on different definitions of inequality, limiting their comparability
-
Mathematically, the Gini coefficient is a reasonable measure of inequality; in practice, however, existing Ginis are based on different definitions of inequality, limiting their comparability.
-
-
-
-
30
-
-
0025672169
-
The effects of democracy on economic growth and inequality: A review
-
See, and
-
See Larry Sirowy and Alex Inkeles, 'The Effects of Democracy on Economic Growth and Inequality: A Review', Studies in Comparative International Development, 25 (1990), 126-57.
-
(1990)
Studies in Comparative International Development
, vol.25
, pp. 126-157
-
-
Sirowy, L.1
Inkeles, A.2
-
31
-
-
84936823874
-
Political democracy and the size distribution of income
-
Kenneth Bollen and Robert Jackman, 'Political Democracy and the Size Distribution of Income', American Sociological Review, 50 (1985), 438-57.
-
(1985)
American Sociological Review
, vol.50
, pp. 438-457
-
-
Bollen, K.1
Jackman, R.2
-
32
-
-
0001650534
-
Promise and pitfalls in the use of 'secondary' data-sets: Income inequality in oecd countries as a case study
-
An insightful critique can be found in, and
-
An insightful critique can be found in Anthony Atkinson and Andrea Brandolini, 'Promise and Pitfalls in the Use of 'Secondary' Data-sets: Income Inequality in OECD Countries as a Case Study', Journal of Economic Literature, 39 (2001), 771-99.
-
(2001)
Journal of Economic Literature
, vol.39
, pp. 771-799
-
-
Atkinson, A.1
Brandolini, A.2
-
35
-
-
78650051032
-
-
and Chong, 'Inequality, Democracy, and Persistence: Is There a Political Kuznets Curve?'. Reuveny and Li had roughly sixty Google citations as of May 2009. While Li, Squire and Zou had more citations, their written explanation does not match the years/countries in their models and their econometric models are not ones we favour. Their left-hand side variable begins as early as 1947, but their right-hand side measure of democracy (Freedom House) only appears in 1972; Hong Kong is supposedly one of their countries, but Freedom House does not publish ratings for it. They run a panel model with two time-invariant variables on the right-hand side, no lagged dependent variable, no time dummies and no country-fixed effects. They also report a rho ≈0.9, indicating substantial serial correlation. Chong uses a generalized method of moments (GMM) model, but countries/years in the panel are unclear and there is no explanation for the lag structure used as instruments, making it impossible to replicate. We also note that he used a one-step estimator, which is not robust to heteroscedasticity. He also claimed a non-linear relationship; we tested for this, using Polity2, and found nothing to report.
-
(2009)
Inequality, Democracy, and Persistence: Is There A Political Kuznets Curve?
-
-
Chong1
-
36
-
-
0001015388
-
Life during growth
-
Easterly does not specify how he cleaned the data in the paper Reuveny and Li reference. It seems that he meant only to include surveys with national coverage, regardless of the quality
-
William Easterly, 'Life during Growth', Journal of Economic Growth, 4 (1999), 239-75. Easterly does not specify how he cleaned the data in the paper Reuveny and Li reference. It seems that he meant only to include surveys with national coverage, regardless of the quality.
-
(1999)
Journal of Economic Growth
, vol.4
, pp. 239-275
-
-
Easterly, W.1
-
37
-
-
78650055568
-
-
logit transformation unbounds the dependent variable
-
The logit transformation unbounds the dependent variable.
-
-
-
-
38
-
-
78650040996
-
-
WIID has four quality ratings: 1 indicates that the income concept is known and the survey methodologically sound; 2 indicates that either the income concept is problematic, or that the primary source is problematic or unknown; 3 indicates that both the income concept and source are problematic or unknown; 4 indicates a memorandum, based in many cases on unreliable sources
-
The WIID has four quality ratings: 1 indicates that the income concept is known and the survey methodologically sound; 2 indicates that either the income concept is problematic, or that the primary source is problematic or unknown; 3 indicates that both the income concept and source are problematic or unknown; 4 indicates a memorandum, based in many cases on unreliable sources.
-
-
-
-
39
-
-
78650049758
-
-
Adding Q3 and Q4 surveys and dropping the population matching restriction yields 1, 201 countryyear observations. Matching on Polity eliminates Barbados 2 observations, Bahamas 2, Hong Kong 5, Guyana 1, Luxembourg 1 and Puerto Rico 2. Using data for 1960 to the present day eliminates 17 observations
-
Adding Q3 and Q4 surveys and dropping the population matching restriction yields 1, 201 countryyear observations. Matching on Polity eliminates Barbados (2 observations), Bahamas (2), Hong Kong (5), Guyana (1), Luxembourg (1) and Puerto Rico (2). Using data for 1960 to the present day eliminates 17 observations.
-
-
-
-
40
-
-
78650044473
-
-
Mexico, for example, had three Quality 1 surveys in 2000, all of which were comparable on all seven dimensions; yet the calculated Gini coefficients ranged from 53.2 to 55.6
-
Mexico, for example, had three Quality 1 surveys in 2000, all of which were comparable on all seven dimensions; yet the calculated Gini coefficients ranged from 53.2 to 55.6.
-
-
-
-
41
-
-
78650062683
-
-
Li, Squire and Zou and Chong used five-year averages; Reuveny and Li used ten-year averages
-
Li, Squire and Zou and Chong used five-year averages; Reuveny and Li used ten-year averages.
-
-
-
-
43
-
-
78650038029
-
-
Unlike DS, WIID reports two Gini coefficients: a 'preferred' one and the original from the study. We made the 'preferred' Gini our benchmark, but also tested with the 'reported' Gini; with and without the recommended income adjustments e.g. adding 6.6 to expenditure-based surveys and 3 to post-tax surveys; with and without the logit transformation; and with Reuveny and Li's sample when possible and other samples e.g., all countries, countries with more than observations. Note that the tax adjustment was applied to surveys based on disposable income and net earnings. The various permutations of the dependent variable were inconsequential in terms of our results for democracy; they did, however, affect our control variables
-
Unlike DS, WIID reports two Gini coefficients: a 'preferred' one and the original from the study. We made the 'preferred' Gini our benchmark, but also tested with the 'reported' Gini; with and without the recommended income adjustments (e.g. adding 6.6 to expenditure-based surveys and 3 to post-tax surveys); with and without the logit transformation; and with Reuveny and Li's sample (when possible) and other samples (e.g., all countries, countries with more than observations). Note that the tax adjustment was applied to surveys based on disposable income and net earnings. The various permutations of the dependent variable were inconsequential in terms of our results for democracy; they did, however, affect our control variables.
-
-
-
-
46
-
-
78650065776
-
-
Unless otherwise noted, data for the control variables come from the World Bank, World Development Indicators Washington, D. C.: World Bank, 2007
-
Unless otherwise noted, data for the control variables come from the World Bank, World Development Indicators (Washington, D. C.: World Bank, 2007/2008).
-
(2008)
-
-
-
47
-
-
78650057148
-
-
Portfolio inflows are no longer reported for many countries; since the theoretical rationale for portfolio inflows was thin and it was never significant in their tests, we exclude it gdp = gross domestic product
-
Portfolio inflows are no longer reported for many countries; since the theoretical rationale for portfolio inflows was thin and it was never significant in their tests, we exclude it (gdp = gross domestic product).
-
-
-
-
48
-
-
78650063909
-
-
We favour Models 4 and 6 because the fixed effects are jointly significant
-
We favour Models 4 and 6 because the fixed effects are jointly significant.
-
-
-
-
49
-
-
78650037823
-
-
Results with other data samples are available from the author
-
Results with other data samples are available from the author.
-
-
-
-
50
-
-
0034386958
-
A new dataset for measuring democracy, 1810-1998
-
While perhaps no measure of democracy adequately captures the most relevant theoretical concept of a leftward shift in the median-voter/citizen, we presume that moving up the Polity scale or down the Freedom House scale is a close approximation. The Polity measures are highly correlated with alternative measures, notably those found in, They have also faired reasonably well in head-to-head comparisons. But they are clearly imperfect, especially when interpreted linearly
-
While perhaps no measure of democracy adequately captures the (most) relevant theoretical concept of a leftward shift in the median-voter/citizen, we presume that moving up the Polity scale or down the Freedom House scale is a close approximation. The Polity measures are highly correlated with alternative measures, notably those found in Tatu Vananhen, 'A New Dataset for Measuring Democracy, 1810-1998', Journal of Peace Research, 37 (2000), 251-65. They have also faired reasonably well in head-to-head comparisons. But they are clearly imperfect, especially when interpreted linearly.
-
(2000)
Journal of Peace Research
, vol.37
, pp. 251-265
-
-
Vananhen, T.1
-
51
-
-
33846087987
-
-
See, for example, and, unpublished paper, University of Uppsala
-
See, for example, Axel Hadenius and Jan Teorell, 'Same, Same - But Different: Assessing Alternative Indices of Democracy' (unpublished paper, University of Uppsala, 2005).
-
(2005)
Same, Same - But Different: Assessing Alternative Indices of Democracy
-
-
Hadenius, A.1
Teorell, J.2
-
52
-
-
78650071677
-
-
-20; the joint significance of the lags was assessed with a Wald test. These models test the relationship between inequality and the average level of democracy over time
-
-20); the joint significance of the lags was assessed with a Wald test. These models test the relationship between inequality and the average level of democracy over time.
-
-
-
-
53
-
-
78650045103
-
-
We tried to fit generalized method of moments GMM models with deeper lags of the relevant variables. Unfortunately, there were insufficient observations
-
We tried to fit generalized method of moments (GMM) models with deeper lags of the relevant variables. Unfortunately, there were insufficient observations.
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
78650056159
-
-
2 had any predictive power in terms of determining which becomes a democracy - consistent with a recent analysis by, and, unpublished paper, Swiss Federal Institute of Technology, Zurich
-
2 had any predictive power in terms of determining which becomes a democracy - consistent with a recent analysis by Martin Gassebner, Michael Lamla and James Vreeland, 'Extreme Bounds of Democracy' (unpublished paper, Swiss Federal Institute of Technology, Zurich, 2008).
-
(2008)
Extreme Bounds of Democracy
-
-
Gassebner, M.1
Lamla, M.2
Vreeland, J.3
-
55
-
-
78650056550
-
-
We present models with both lagged levels and first differences for Polity given that some theories suggest simultaneous changes, while others suggest an equilibrium relationship. Models without any first differences and models with a full set of first differences can be found in the SSRN version
-
We present models with both lagged levels and first differences for Polity given that some theories suggest simultaneous changes, while others suggest an equilibrium relationship. Models without any first differences and models with a full set of first differences can be found in the SSRN version.
-
-
-
-
57
-
-
0034918605
-
International data on educational attainment: Updates and implications
-
data come from, and, They provide multiple measures of education. Theoretically, a measure reflecting the dispersion of human capital should be most relevant e.g., the difference between the percentage of people with no schooling and those with university education; empirically, secondary education completed fits the data well. Changing the measure of human capital or excluding it altogether does not change the democracy result
-
The data come from Robert Barro and Jong-Wa Lee, 'International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications', Oxford Economic Papers, 53 (2001), 541-63. They provide multiple measures of education. Theoretically, a measure reflecting the dispersion of human capital should be most relevant (e.g., the difference between the percentage of people with no schooling and those with university education); empirically, secondary education completed fits the data well. Changing the measure of human capital or excluding it altogether does not change the democracy result.
-
(2001)
Oxford Economic Papers
, vol.53
, pp. 541-563
-
-
Barro, R.1
Lee, J.2
-
58
-
-
78650056357
-
-
Results from the first stage are available
-
Results from the first stage are available.
-
-
-
-
59
-
-
78650061882
-
-
SSRN version gives details of these controls
-
The SSRN version gives details of these controls.
-
-
-
-
60
-
-
1542605536
-
Inequality and growth
-
See, in Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, eds, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press
-
See Roland Bénabou, 'Inequality and Growth', in Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, eds, NBER Macroeconomics Annual (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1996), pp. 11-74.
-
(1996)
NBER Macroeconomics Annual
, pp. 11-74
-
-
Bénabou, R.1
-
61
-
-
78650069091
-
-
To retain observations, negative values for inflation were replaced with infinitesimal positive values e.g., 0.0000009 in a way that preserved the rank order GDP=Gross Domestic Product.
-
To retain observations, negative values for inflation were replaced with infinitesimal positive values (e.g., 0.0000009) in a way that preserved the rank order (GDP=Gross Domestic Product.)
-
-
-
-
62
-
-
78650054079
-
-
Establishing a preferred specification posed a challenge because missing data changed the sample; secondary education and female labour force participation particularly constrained the sample. Secondary education reduced the width, while female labour force participation reduced the time dimension to post-1985 observations. We choose to include secondary education in the reported results, despite the loss of observations, because it was one of only three relatively robust controls, with inflation logged and manufacturing value-added being the others. The results for a fourth one variable GDPPC logged depended on the other conditioning variables in the model. None of the other control variables consistently had T-stats above 1. Because changing the control variables within our universe of potential covariates does not alter the conclusions about Polity/democracy, models with non-robust controls have been relegated to the SSRN version
-
Establishing a preferred specification posed a challenge because missing data changed the sample; secondary education and female labour force participation particularly constrained the sample. Secondary education reduced the width, while female labour force participation reduced the time dimension (to post-1985 observations). We choose to include secondary education in the reported results, despite the loss of observations, because it was one of only three relatively robust controls, with inflation (logged) and manufacturing value-added being the others. The results for a fourth one variable GDPPC (logged) depended on the other conditioning variables in the model. None of the other control variables consistently had T-stats above 1. Because changing the control variables (within our universe of potential covariates) does not alter the conclusions about Polity/democracy, models with non-robust controls have been relegated to the SSRN version.
-
-
-
-
63
-
-
78650071043
-
-
Dropping the lagged DV and/or the unit FE does not alter this conclusion. Neither does changing the definition of democracy Table 3B in the SSRN version or moving to any other data configuration
-
Dropping the lagged DV and/or the unit FE does not alter this conclusion. Neither does changing the definition of democracy (Table 3B in the SSRN version) or moving to any other data configuration.
-
-
-
-
64
-
-
78650052732
-
-
We ran multiple IV specifications, ranging from merely including the lag of polity as an instrument for polity to specifications in which most right-hand side variables, including the lagged DV, were instrumented with their lags. With IV regressions, the point estimate on Polity was generally positive, even with the most favourable data sample
-
We ran multiple IV specifications, ranging from merely including the lag of polity as an instrument for polity to specifications in which most right-hand side variables, including the lagged DV, were instrumented with their lags. With IV regressions, the point estimate on Polity was generally positive, even with the most favourable data sample.
-
-
-
-
65
-
-
56249130411
-
Inequality, poverty and the kuznets curve in spain, 1850-2000
-
Spain probably comes closest. Even there, however, the decline was gradual, modest and ephemeral see, Universidad Carlos de Madrid
-
Spain probably comes closest. Even there, however, the decline was gradual, modest and ephemeral (see Leandro Prados de la Escosura, 'Inequality, Poverty and the Kuznets Curve in Spain, 1850-2000' (Working Papers in Economic History 07-13, Universidad Carlos de Madrid, 2007).
-
(2007)
(Working Papers in Economic History 07-13
-
-
De La Escosura, L.P.1
-
66
-
-
84858948946
-
Regional poverty and income inequality in central and eastern europe: Evidence from the luxembourg income study
-
See, and, Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economics Research of the United Nations University, 2003
-
See Michael Forster, David Jesuit and Timothy Smeeding, 'Regional Poverty and Income Inequality in Central and Eastern Europe: Evidence from the Luxembourg Income Study', UNO-WIDER Working Paper No. 65 (Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economics Research of the United Nations University, 2003).
-
UNO-WIDER Working Paper No. 65
-
-
Forster, M.1
Jesuit, D.2
Smeeding, T.3
-
68
-
-
78650043438
-
-
Several reasons for the different findings stand out. First, Easterly's version of DS contained some unusual observations, notably for Argentina. These observations appear to have been influential omitting them reduces the significance level of Polity, even using just pre-1997 data. Secondly, we added additional years for a number of countries, generating many of the sign switches in Table 3. Finally, we added more countries Table 4
-
Several reasons for the different findings stand out. First, Easterly's version of DS contained some unusual observations, notably for Argentina. These observations appear to have been influential (omitting them reduces the significance level of Polity, even using just pre-1997 data). Secondly, we added additional years for a number of countries, generating many of the sign switches in Table 3. Finally, we added more countries (Table 4).
-
-
-
-
71
-
-
69249150525
-
Institutions, partisanship, and inequality in the long run
-
Ken Scheve and David Stasavage, 'Institutions, Partisanship, and Inequality in the Long Run', World Politics, 61 (2009), 215-53.
-
(2009)
World Politics
, vol.61
, pp. 215-253
-
-
Scheve, K.1
Stasavage, D.2
-
72
-
-
78650053341
-
Impacto distributivo do gasto público: Uma análise a partir da pcv/1998
-
Rio de Janeiro: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica
-
Carlos Ramos, 'Impacto Distributivo do Gasto Público: Uma Análise a Partir da PCV/1998', Textos para Discussão, No. 732 (Rio de Janeiro: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica, 2000).
-
(2000)
Textos Para Discussão, No. 732
-
-
Ramos, C.1
-
73
-
-
0035088206
-
Inequality, growth and democracy
-
See, for example, and
-
See, for example, Dimitri Landa and Ethan Kapstein, 'Inequality, Growth and Democracy', World Politics, 53 (2001), 264-96.
-
(2001)
World Politics
, vol.53
, pp. 264-296
-
-
Landa, D.1
Kapstein, E.2
-
75
-
-
0032325207
-
Why the poor do not expropriate the rich: An old argument in new garb
-
John Roemer, 'Why the Poor Do Not Expropriate the Rich: An Old Argument in New Garb', Journal of Public Economics, 70 (1998), 399-424.
-
(1998)
Journal of Public Economics
, vol.70
, pp. 399-424
-
-
Roemer, J.1
-
76
-
-
33746058993
-
Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: Why some democracies redistribute more than others
-
relationship between democratic forms and inequality is worth exploring. We confined ourselves to the democracy/non-democracy distinction for several reasons: first, it is consistent with the theories we worked with; secondly, the data do not readily lend themselves to such an analysis because changes in the form of democracy are rare. For contrasting views, see:, and
-
The relationship between democratic forms and inequality is worth exploring. We confined ourselves to the democracy/non-democracy distinction for several reasons: first, it is consistent with the theories we worked with; secondly, the data do not readily lend themselves to such an analysis because changes in the form of democracy are rare. For contrasting views, see: Torben Iversen and David Soskice, 'Electoral Institutions and the Politics of Coalitions: Why Some Democracies Redistribute More than Others', American Political Science Review, 100 (2006), 165-81;
-
(2006)
American Political Science Review
, vol.100
, pp. 165-181
-
-
Iversen, T.1
Soskice, D.2
-
77
-
-
31544468077
-
Democracy comes to europe: Franchise extension and fiscal outcomes 1830-1938
-
and T. S. Aidt, Jayasri Dutta and Elena Loukoianovo, 'Democracy Comes to Europe: Franchise Extension and Fiscal Outcomes 1830-1938', European Economic Review, 50 (2006), 249-83.
-
(2006)
European Economic Review
, vol.50
, pp. 249-283
-
-
Aidt, T.S.1
Dutta, J.2
Loukoianovo, E.3
|