메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 104, Issue 1, 2010, Pages 49-104

A production theory of pure economic loss

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 78149295703     PISSN: 00293571     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (10)

References (514)
  • 1
    • 78149314601 scopus 로고
    • Co. v. N.Y. & N.H. R.R., 25 Conn
    • See Conn. Mut. Life Ins. Co. v. N.Y. & N.H. R.R., 25 Conn. 265, 270 (1856).
    • (1856) Conn. Mut. Life Ins. , vol.265 , pp. 270
  • 2
    • 78149319453 scopus 로고
    • Cattle v. Stockton Waterworks Co
    • Cattle v. Stockton Waterworks Co., (1875) 10 L.R.Q.B. 453, 456
    • (1875) L.R.Q.B. , vol.10
  • 3
    • 78649363972 scopus 로고
    • (intro-ducing fault as basis for accident law)
    • cf. Brown v. Kendall, 60 Mass. 292, 294 (1850) (intro-ducing fault as basis for accident law).
    • (1850) Mass , vol.60
    • Kendall1    Brown2
  • 5
    • 78149356309 scopus 로고
    • note
    • ("[A] virtually per se rule barring recovery for economic loss unless the negligent conduct also caused physical harm has evolved throughout this century, based, in part, on Robins Dry Dock & Repair Co. v. Flint, 275 U.S. 303 (1927), and Cattle v. Stockton Waterworks Co." (internal citations omitted)).
    • (1927) Robins Dry Dock & Repair Co. V. Flint , vol.275 , pp. 303
  • 6
    • 78149292478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §§ 924(b), 924(d), 927(2), 928(b), 929(1)(b) (Am. Law Inst. 1974)
  • 7
    • 78149333870 scopus 로고
    • PROSSER AND KEETON ON THE LAW OF TORTS § W. Page Keeton et al. eds., 5th ed
    • PROSSER AND KEETON ON THE LAW OF TORTS § 129, at 997 (W. Page Keeton et al. eds., 5th ed. 1984)
    • (1984) , vol.129
  • 8
    • 55349085796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U. ILL. L. REV., [hereinaf-ter Perry, Economic Bias]
    • Ronen Perry, The Economic Bias in Tort Law, 2008 U. ILL. L. REV. 1573, 1577-78 [hereinaf-ter Perry, Economic Bias].
    • (2008) The Economic Bias in Tort Law
    • Perry, R.1
  • 9
    • 78149305879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Scholars and courts have noted this puzzling dichotomy. See People Express Airlines, 495 A.2d at 109
  • 10
    • 78149343873 scopus 로고
    • Negligent and Economic Loss
    • P.S. Atiyah, Negligent and Economic Loss, 83 L.Q. REV. 248, 252 (1967)
    • (1967) L.Q. Rev. , vol.83
    • Atiyah, P.S.1
  • 11
  • 12
    • 78149328740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Barber Lines A/S v. M/V Donau Maru, 764 F.2d 50, 55 (1st Cir. 1985) (Breyer, J.) ("These considerations of administrability and disproportionality, offer plausible, though highly abstract, 'policy' support for the reluctance of the courts to impose tort liability for purely financial harm.").
  • 13
    • 27844483656 scopus 로고
    • Limitations on Liability for Economic Loss Caused by Negligence: A Pragmatic Ap-praisal
    • (explaining the rule as a "pragmatic objection")
    • Fleming James, Jr., Limitations on Liability for Economic Loss Caused by Negligence: A Pragmatic Ap-praisal, 25 VAND. L. REV. 43, 48 (1972) (explaining the rule as a "pragmatic objection").
    • (1972) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.25
    • James Jr., F.1
  • 14
    • 34249733901 scopus 로고
    • Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort: Another Look at Robins Dry Dock v. Flint
    • [hereinafter Goldberg, Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort] ("[D]octrine has been a significant factor in delimiting the boundaries.")
    • Cf. Victor P. Goldberg, Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort: Another Look at Robins Dry Dock v. Flint, 20 J. LEGAL STUD. 249, 275 (1991) [hereinafter Goldberg, Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort] ("[D]octrine has been a significant factor in delimiting the boundaries.").
    • (1991) J. Legal Stud. , vol.20
    • Goldberg Victor, P.1
  • 15
    • 78149351460 scopus 로고
    • 275 U.S
    • 275 U.S. 303, 304 (1927).
    • (1927)
  • 16
    • 78149322257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra Part I.A (discussing the fishermen exception).
  • 17
    • 78149354424 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James, supra note 5, at 45-46.
    • James1
  • 18
    • 4344615581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relational Economic Loss: An Integrated Economic Justification for the Exclusionary Rule
    • note
    • See Louisiana ex rel. Guste v. M/V Testbank, 752 F.2d 1019, 1023 (5th Cir. 1985) (en banc) (not-ing that the rule withstood "a sea of change in the tort law"). The rule also survived common law evolu-tion in England. Ronen Perry, Relational Economic Loss: An Integrated Economic Justification for the Exclusionary Rule, 56 RUTGERS L. REV. 711, 720 (2004) [hereinafter Perry, Relational Economic Loss].
    • (2004) Rutgers L. Rev. , vol.56
    • Perry, R.1
  • 19
    • 0036995042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comparative Economic Loss: Lessons from Case-Law-Focused "Middle Theory
    • Jane Stapleton, Comparative Economic Loss: Lessons from Case-Law-Focused "Middle Theory," 50 UCLA L. REV. 531, 536 (2002).
    • (2002) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.50
    • Stapleton, J.1
  • 22
    • 78149295086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Perry, Economic Bias, supra note 3, at 1585-1604.
    • Economic Bias , pp. 1585-1604
    • Perry1
  • 23
    • 0010997216 scopus 로고
    • Tort Recovery for Negligently Inflicted Economic Loss: A Reassessment
    • Robert L. Rabin, Tort Recovery for Negligently Inflicted Economic Loss: A Reassessment, 37 STAN. L. REV. 1513, 1522-26 (1985).
    • (1985) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.37
    • Rabin Robert, L.1
  • 25
    • 0012810049 scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Economic Loss in the Law of Torts
    • Mario J. Rizzo, A Theory of Economic Loss in the Law of Torts, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 281 (1982).
    • (1982) J. Legal Stud. , vol.11 , pp. 281
    • Rizzo Mario, J.1
  • 26
  • 27
    • 78149330582 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See In re Kinsman Transit Co., 388 F.2d 821, 824-25 (2d Cir. 1968) (noting reliance on "circum-locution" to decide cases)
    • (1968)
  • 28
    • 78149341335 scopus 로고
    • 523 F. (E.D. Va.) (noting lack of "any articulable reason for excluding any particular set of plaintiffs")
    • Pruitt v. Allied Chem. Corp., 523 F. Supp. 975, 980 (E.D. Va. 1981) (noting lack of "any articulable reason for excluding any particular set of plaintiffs").
    • (1981) Pruitt v. Allied Chem. Corp. , Issue.SUPPL.
  • 29
  • 30
    • 78149309076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In 2006, the, published a twenty-one article symposium on the field of economic torts
    • In 2006, the Arizona Law Review published a twenty-one article symposium on the field of economic torts.
    • Arizona Law Review
  • 31
    • 78149333869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 687 (2006)
    • (2006) Ariz. L. Rev , vol.48 , pp. 687
  • 32
    • 38049014426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner on Economic Loss in Tort: EVRA Corp. v. Swiss Bank
    • see also, (discussing how a recent Judge Posner opinion demonstrates that the economic loss rule is con-sistent with other tort doctrines)
    • see also Thomas J. Miles, Posner on Economic Loss in Tort: EVRA Corp. v. Swiss Bank, 74 U. CHI. L. REV. 1813 (2007) (discussing how a recent Judge Posner opinion demonstrates that the economic loss rule is con-sistent with other tort doctrines)
    • (2007) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 1813
    • Thomas, J.M.1
  • 33
    • 78149295086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing political underpinnings of economic loss doctrine)
    • Perry, Economic Bias, supra note 3 (discussing political underpinnings of economic loss doctrine)
    • Economic Bias
    • Perry1
  • 34
    • 78149302132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (proposing integrated eco-nomic justification for economic loss doctrine)
    • Perry, Relational Economic Loss, supra note 10 (proposing integrated eco-nomic justification for economic loss doctrine)
    • Relational Economic Loss
    • Perry1
  • 35
    • 78149341688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stapleton, (proposing that courts adhere to precise legal reasoning to create a high level of predictability in economic loss cases)
    • Stapleton, supra note 11 (proposing that courts adhere to precise legal reasoning to create a high level of predictability in economic loss cases).
  • 37
    • 84875501109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see generally 9, (Willem H. van Boom et al. eds.) (comparative study of the economic loss rule)
    • see generally 9 PURE ECONOMIC LOSS (Willem H. van Boom et al. eds., 2004) (comparative study of the economic loss rule)
    • (2004) PURE ECONOMIC LOSS
  • 39
    • 78149335961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recovery for Economic Loss in the European Union
    • Helmut Koziol, Recovery for Economic Loss in the European Union, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 871 (2006).
    • (2006) Ariz. L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 871
    • Koziol, H.1
  • 41
    • 0003849477 scopus 로고
    • (noting that the pace of industrialization accelerated in the mid-nineteenth century)
    • see DOUGLASS C. NORTH, THE ECONOMIC GROWTH OF THE UNITED STATES 1790-1860, at 204 (1961) (noting that the pace of industrialization accelerated in the mid-nineteenth century).
    • (1961) The Economic Growth Of The United States , vol.204 , pp. 1790-1860
    • Douglass, C.N.1
  • 42
    • 78149293237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Compare Byrd v. English, 43 S.E. 419 (Ga. 1903) (negligent severing of electrical cable on de-fendant's property causing electrical outage to plaintiff), with 532 Madison Ave. Gourmet Foods, Inc. v. Finlandia Ctr., Inc., 750 N.E.2d 1097 (N.Y. 2001) (negligent collapse of a building causing street clo-sure).
  • 43
    • 78149295614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 673 F.2d 951 (7th Cir. 1982) (Posner, J.) (failure to transmit electronic funds)
    • See, e.g., EVRA Corp. v. Swiss Bank Corp., 673 F.2d 951 (7th Cir. 1982) (Posner, J.) (failure to transmit electronic funds)
    • EVRA Corp. V. Swiss Bank Corp
  • 44
    • 78149308390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Huggins v. Citibank, N.A., 585 S.E.2d 275, 276 (S.C. 2003) (bank negligence leading to identity theft)
  • 45
    • 78149304721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • cf. Hedley Byrne Co. Ltd. v. Heller & Partners Ltd., [1964] A.C. 465, 467-69 (H.L. 1963) (bank misrepresentation concerning creditworthiness).
  • 46
    • 33750946541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Withering Away of Property: The Rise of the Internet Information Commons
    • (arguing that the Internet provides a flourishing infor-mation commons)
    • See John Cahir, The Withering Away of Property: The Rise of the Internet Information Commons, 24 OXFORD J. LEGAL STUD. 619, 637-41 (2004) (arguing that the Internet provides a flourishing infor-mation commons)
    • (2004) Oxford J. Legal Stud. , vol.24
    • Cahir, J.1
  • 47
    • 23844432009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Internet as Commons: The Issue of Access
    • (arguing that the Internet can be seen as a commons)
    • JoAnne Holman & Michael A. McGregor, The Internet as Commons: The Issue of Access, 10 COMM. L. & POL'Y 267, 281-87 (2005) (arguing that the Internet can be seen as a commons).
    • (2005) Comm. L. & Pol'y. , vol.10
    • Holman, J.1    McGregor Michael, A.2
  • 48
    • 78149320213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The liability on industry was a substantial factor in the development of tort law, FRIEDMAN
    • The liability on industry was a substantial factor in the development of tort law. FRIEDMAN, su-pra note 21, at 350-66
  • 50
    • 78149344955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tort Arbitrage
    • (arguing that negligence dominates today because it most preserves industry capital)
    • cf. Robert J. Rhee, Tort Arbitrage, 60 FLA. L. REV. 125, 180-81 (2008) (arguing that negligence dominates today because it most preserves industry capital).
    • (2008) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.60
    • Rhee Robert, J.1
  • 51
    • 78149300512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing the fishermen exception)
    • See infra Part I.A (discussing the fishermen exception).
    • , Issue.PART. I.A
  • 52
    • 78149297464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The fishermen cases are the most prominent gray area cases. The physical harms in these cases encompass both harm to private property of third parties and the commons. But other cases also fall into the gray area, and are explained by the theory advanced in this Article. For example, some plaintiffs have an action for economic loss from public nuisance, and these cases can be explained under the theory proposed in this Article. See infra Part III.A
  • 53
    • 78149337044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see, e.g., Masonite Corp. v. Steede, 23 So. 2d 756, 757-58 (Miss. 1945) (allowing owner of sporting rental and lodging business to recover for economic loss flowing from a public nuisance).
  • 55
    • 78149332394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see infra Part III.B.
  • 56
    • 78149344590 scopus 로고
    • note
    • People Express Airlines, Inc. v. Consol. Rail Corp., 495 A.2d 107, 109 (N.J. 1985) ("It is well-accepted that a defendant who negligently injures a plaintiff or his property may be liable for all prox-imately caused harm, including economic losses.").
    • (1985) Inc. V. Consol. Rail Corp , vol.495
  • 57
    • 78149332029 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Ultramares Corp. v. Touche, 174 N.E. 441, 448 (N.Y. 1931) (Cardozo, C.J.) (holding that accountant has no duty to creditors for negligent misrepresentation of company's financial state-ments).
    • (1931) Ultramares Corp. V. Touche , vol.174
  • 58
    • 78149349569 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Biakanja v. Irving, 320 P.2d 16, 19 (Cal. 1958) (holding that a notary public has a duty when drafting a will to intended beneficiaries of will)
    • (1958) Biakanja V. Irving , vol.320
  • 59
    • 78149333499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Glanzer v. Shepard, 135 N.E. 275, 277 (N.Y. 1922) (Cardozo, J.) (holding that a public weigher had a duty to the purchaser of beans when defendant was hired specifically to execute the transaction).
  • 60
    • 78149335202 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Seely v. White Motor Co., 403 P.2d 145, 147-48 (Cal. 1965) (holding that a plaintiff can recover lost profit under a breach of express warranty claim).
    • (1965)
  • 61
    • 78149305878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., In re Kinsman Transit Co., 388 F.2d 821, 825 (2d Cir. 1968) (holding that when a ship crashed into a bridge the defendant was not liable for lost profit of plaintiff who suffered no physical harm)
  • 62
    • 78149292477 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Neb. Innkeepers, Inc. v. Pittsburgh-Des Moines Corp., 345 N.W.2d 124, 126-27 (Iowa 1984) (holding that defendant was not liable for economic loss to local businesses resulting from damaged bridge)
    • (1984) Pittsburgh-Des Moines Corp , vol.345
  • 63
    • 78149336324 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rickards v. Sun Oil Co., 41 A.2d 267, 269-70 (N.J. 1945) (holding that the lost profits of local businesses were not proximately caused by the defendant's negligence that collapsed a bridge providing the only ingress and egress from island).
    • (1945)
  • 64
    • 78149348437 scopus 로고
    • Scholars have provided more comprehensive taxonomies, (2d ed.) (discussing vari-ous taxonomies)
    • Scholars have provided more comprehensive taxonomies. See BRUCE P. FELDTHUSEN, ECONOMIC NEGLIGENCE: THE RECOVERY OF PURE ECONOMIC LOSS 1-3 (2d ed. 1989) (discussing vari-ous taxonomies)
    • (1989) Economic Negligence: The Recovery of Pure Economic Loss , pp. 1-3
    • Bruce, P.F.1
  • 65
    • 34249750754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keep It Simple: An Explanation of the Rule of No Recovery for Pure Economic Loss
    • Anita Bernstein, Keep It Simple: An Explanation of the Rule of No Recovery for Pure Economic Loss, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 773, 782-83 (2006) (same)
    • (2006) Ariz. L. Rev. , vol.48
    • Bernstein, A.1
  • 69
    • 78149332749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Respecting Boundaries and the Economic Loss Rule in Tort
    • Robert L. Rabin, Respecting Boundaries and the Economic Loss Rule in Tort, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 857, 859 (2006)
    • (2006) Ariz. L. Rev. , vol.48
    • Rabin Robert, L.1
  • 70
    • 78149295088 scopus 로고
    • Economic Loss in American Tort Law: The Examples of J'Aire and of Products Liability
    • Gary T. Schwartz, Economic Loss in American Tort Law: The Examples of J'Aire and of Products Liability, 23 SAN DIEGO L. REV. 37, 38 (1986)
    • (1986) San Diego L. Rev. , vol.23
    • Schwartz Gary, T.1
  • 71
    • 78149331663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stapleton
    • Stapleton, supra note 11, at 534-35.
  • 72
    • 78149297113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Stapleton, supra note 11, at 561 ("U.S. case law on economic loss is still treated as falling in-to disparate fact-dictated pockets of liability.")
  • 73
    • 78149300893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Goldberg, Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort, supra note 6, at 251 (arguing that Robins "does not necessarily provide much of an insight into the myriad other problems classified under the heading of 'economic loss'").
    • Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort , pp. 251
  • 74
    • 78149352985 scopus 로고
    • U.S
    • 275 U.S. 303 (1927).
    • (1927) , vol.275 , pp. 303
  • 77
    • 78149332750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. at
    • Robins, 275 U.S. at 307.
    • , vol.275 , pp. 307
    • Robins1
  • 78
    • 78149297112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 309-10.
  • 79
    • 78149353361 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (citations omitted)
    • Id. at 308-09 (citations omitted).
  • 81
    • 78149300140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 725-26
  • 82
    • 78149315323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see, e.g., Burgess v. M/V Tamano, 370 F. Supp. 247, 250 n.2 (S.D. Me. 1973). Robins was technically an admiralty case, but its influence on the common law is unquestionable.
  • 84
    • 78149340964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., J'Aire Corp. v. Gregory, 598 P.2d 60, 63-64 (Cal. 1979) (upholding lost profit claim of a lessee restaurant against a contractor for negligent delays in its remodeling of a local airport).
  • 85
    • 78149320212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (criticizing J'Aire as "strained" reasoning)
    • But see Rabin, supra note 14, at 1514 n.3 (criticizing J'Aire as "strained" reasoning)
    • , Issue.3 , pp. 1514
    • Rabin1
  • 86
    • 78149313465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (arguing that J'Aire was wrongly decided)
    • Schwartz, supra note 35, at 40 (arguing that J'Aire was wrongly decided).
    • Schwartz1
  • 87
    • 78149295616 scopus 로고
    • A.2d 107 (N.J.)
    • 495 A.2d 107 (N.J. 1985).
    • (1985) , vol.495
  • 88
    • 78149292476 scopus 로고
    • Id. at 109.
    • (1985) , pp. 109
  • 89
    • 78149334851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 116.
  • 90
    • 78149293238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rabin, supra note 35, at 858.
    • Rabin1
  • 91
    • 78149317254 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It appears that only the Alaska Supreme Court has followed People Express and allowed recovery for pure economic loss.
  • 93
    • 78149334850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("The bulk of economic-loss case law repudiates People Ex-press and J'Aire.")
    • See Bernstein, supra note 34, at 791 ("The bulk of economic-loss case law repudiates People Ex-press and J'Aire.")
    • Bernstein1
  • 94
    • 78149329831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 35, at, ("People Express. stands as a lonely outpost.")
    • Rabin, supra note 35, at 858 ("People Express. stands as a lonely outpost.").
    • Rabin1
  • 95
    • 78149352170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Louisiana ex rel. Guste v. M/V Testbank, 752 F.2d 1019, 1023 (5th Cir. 1985) (en banc) ("Retention of this conspicuous bright-line rule. is strong testament both to the rule's utility and to the absence of a more 'conceptually pure' substitute." (citations omitted)).
  • 98
    • 78149291000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bishop, supra note 15, at 25-26
    • Bishop1
  • 99
    • 0003233309 scopus 로고
    • Recovery for Economic Loss Following the Exxon Valdez Oil Spill
    • [hereinafter Goldberg, Exxon Valdez]
    • Victor P. Goldberg, Recovery for Economic Loss Following the Exxon Valdez Oil Spill, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 4-7 (1994) [hereinafter Goldberg, Exxon Valdez]
    • (1994) J. Legal Stud. , vol.23 , pp. 4-7
    • Goldberg Victor, P.1
  • 102
    • 78149352595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rabin, supra note 14, at 1535 n.72
    • , Issue.72 , pp. 1535
    • Rabin1
  • 103
    • 78149343171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rabin, supra note 16, at 298-99
    • Rabin1
  • 104
    • 78149354067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Casebooks also frequently acknowledge the fishermen exception
    • Stapleton, supra note 11, at 567-70. Casebooks also frequently acknowledge the fishermen exception.
    • Stapleton1
  • 107
    • 78149324843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., M/V Testbank, 752 F.2d at 1027 n.10
    • M/V Testbank , vol.752 , Issue.10 , pp. 1027
  • 108
    • 78149338610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • id. at 1034 (Williams, J., concurring).
  • 109
    • 78149338609 scopus 로고
    • Defen-dants seem to readily concede the question of liability, 523 F. (E.D. Va.)
    • Defen-dants seem to readily concede the question of liability. Pruitt v. Allied Chem. Corp., 523 F. Supp. 975, 978 (E.D. Va. 1981).
    • (1981) Pruitt V. Allied Chem. Corp , Issue.SUPPL
  • 110
    • 78149328350 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Fifth Circuit's reservation of the issue concerning fishermen's right to recover lost catch in M/V Testbank will prove to be important. On April 20, 2010, Deepwater Horizon, an off-shore oil rig operated by BP plc, exploded and thereafter continuously spilled oil into the Gulf of Mex-ico. As of the final editing of this Article by the author, July 12, 2010, the leak has not been contained. This disaster is probably the worst oil spill affecting the United States, and when the final assessment is made the catastrophe will most probably far exceed the Exxon Valdez in environmental harm and liabili-ty. On June 16, 2010, following a meeting with President Barack Obama, BP announced a commitment of $20 billion toward a compensation fund. Press Release, BP, BP Establishes $20 Billion Claims Fund for Deepwater Horizon Spill and Outlines Dividend Decisions, (June 16, 2010), available at http://www.bp.com/genericarticle.do?categoryId=2012968&contentId=706 2966.
    • (2010)
  • 111
    • 78149295615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Fishermen in the ju-risdictions covered by the Fifth and Eleventh Circuits, states abutting the Gulf of Mexico, will surely claim their share of compensation from the fund. See infra notes 67-70 and accompanying text (discuss-ing the law in the Eleventh Circuit).
  • 112
    • 78149297111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In re Exxon Valdez, 270 F.3d 1215, 1225 (9th Cir. 2001) (awarding fishermen $287 million in prospective catch with additional $5 billion in punitive damages). After the Exxon Valdez oil spill, Congress regulated the liability of oil spills for vessels and facilities. A federal statute recognizes "[d]amages for loss of subsistence use of natural resources, which shall be recoverable by any claimant who so uses natural resources which have been injured, destroyed, or lost, without regard to the owner-ship or management of the resources." 33 U.S.C. § 2702(b)(2)(C) (2006) (emphasis added). This pro-vision obviously covers fishermen's rights to lost catch.
    • (2001) , vol.270
    • Valdez, E.1
  • 113
    • 78149328739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 9 & infra note 280 and accompanying text.
  • 115
    • 78149340963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra notes 140-142 and accompanying text.
  • 116
    • 78149356308 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The following case law focuses on federal cases. But the protection of fishermen's prospective profit absent an accompanying harm to their property or person is not limited to federal cases. State cases based on negligence and nuisance claims have also held for fishermen. See, e.g., Masonite Corp. v. Steede, 23 So. 2d 756 (Miss. 1945) (en banc)
    • (1945) Masonite Corp. V. Steede , vol.23 , pp. 756
  • 117
    • 78149344601 scopus 로고
    • (N.C.)
    • Hampton v. N.C. Pulp Co., 27 S.E.2d 538 (N.C. 1943)
    • (1943) Hampton V. N.C. Pulp Co , vol.27 , pp. 538
  • 119
    • 78149327517 scopus 로고
    • (Wash.)
    • Morris v. Graham, 47 P. 752 (Wash. 1897).
    • (1897) Morris V. Graham , vol.47 , pp. 752
  • 120
    • 78149343160 scopus 로고
    • 209 F.2d, (9th Cir.)
    • 209 F.2d 178, 179 (9th Cir. 1953).
    • (1953)
  • 121
    • 78149350159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (citing cases)
    • Id. at 179-80 (citing cases).
  • 122
    • 78149297462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In an earlier decision, the Ninth Circuit had invoked Robins to deny lost profit claims of fishermen. See Borcich v. Ancich, 191 F.2d 392, 396-97 (9th Cir. 1951). But the Carbone court overruled the prior precedent. 209 F.2d at 183.
  • 123
    • 78149336323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • F.2d
    • Carbone, 209 F.2d at 182.
    • Carbone , vol.209 , pp. 182
  • 124
    • 78149351816 scopus 로고
    • 501 F.2d, (9th Cir.)
    • 501 F.2d 558, 559-60 (9th Cir. 1974).
    • (1974)
  • 125
    • 78149329484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 570.
  • 126
    • 78149298228 scopus 로고
    • (11th Cir.)
    • 733 F.2d 813, 815 (11th Cir. 1984).
    • (1984) , vol.733
  • 127
    • 78149290653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 820.
  • 128
    • 78149335960 scopus 로고
    • There is some doubt whether Miller Industries is still good law in light of, U.S
    • There is some doubt whether Miller Industries is still good law in light of East River Steamship Corp. v. Transamerica Delaval, Inc., 476 U.S. 858 (1986).
    • (1986) East River Steamship Corp. V. Transamerica Delaval, Inc , vol.476 , pp. 858
  • 129
    • 78149344954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eurocopter Deutschland, GMBH, F.3d, (5th Cir.) ("Miller is also seemingly no longer good law.")
    • See Mem'l Hermann Healthcare Sys. Inc. v. Eurocopter Deutschland, GMBH, 524 F.3d 676, 679 n.2 (5th Cir. 2008) ("Miller is also seemingly no longer good law.").
    • (2008) Mem'l Hermann Healthcare Sys. Inc. V , vol.524 , Issue.2
  • 130
    • 78149333109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In East River, the Supreme Court held that a manufacturer has no duty under tort law to prevent a product from injuring itself. 476 U.S. at 871. The Court did not reach the issue of whether admiralty law would recognize a tort claim for lost profit. Id. at 871 n.6. The Court stated that manufacturers cannot be held liable for "all foreseeable claims for purely economic loss." Id. at 874 (citing Robins Dry Dock & Repair Co. v. Flint, 275 U.S 303, 309 (1927)). This is the general rule, but the Court did not address whether the manufacturer has a tort duty to third parties. Such tort duty would not be derivative of the contract claim. Accordingly, the rule regarding fishermen in Miller Industries may still be good law in the Eleventh Circuit.
  • 131
    • 78149334245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • F.3d, (4th Cir.)
    • 131 F.3d 389, 390 (4th Cir. 1997).
    • (1997) , vol.131
  • 132
    • 78149349568 scopus 로고
    • 262 F (D. Md.), aff'd 384 F.2d 998 (4th Cir. 1967)
    • Henderson v. Arundel Corp., 262 F. Supp. 152, (D. Md. 1966), aff'd 384 F.2d 998 (4th Cir. 1967).
    • (1966) Henderson V. Arundel Corp , Issue.SUPPL. , pp. 152
  • 134
    • 78149303243 scopus 로고
    • F.2d, (9th Cir.)
    • Union Oil Co. v. Oppen, 501 F.2d 558, 563 (9th Cir. 1974)
    • (1974) Union Oil Co. V. Oppen , vol.501
  • 136
    • 78149340962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • infra Part III.A.
  • 137
    • 78149299789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This reasoning has been called "bizarre
    • This reasoning has been called "bizarre." Stapleton, supra note 11, at 567.
    • Stapleton , pp. 567
  • 138
    • 78149345699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The following authors'dialogue between Aaron Twerski and James Henderson in their casebook illustrates perhaps in an amusing way the essential problem
    • The following authors'dialogue between Aaron Twerski and James Henderson in their casebook illustrates perhaps in an amusing way the essential problem:
  • 139
    • 78149309455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Aaron: But what if he had burned me out-he would have to pay me lost profits then, wouldn't he?
  • 140
    • 78149314979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Jim: Not exactly. He would have to pay you the value of the Deli he destroyed, part of which would reflect its capacity to earn profits. But then, he destroyed your "property," after all. Maybe that's another way of explaining the "no recovery" rule for pure economic loss-you don't have a property interest in the expectation of future profits, apart from your property interest in the Deli, itself.
  • 141
    • 78149312210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Aaron: Then why do fishermen recover when fishing grounds are damaged? They don't own the fish 'til they catch them.
  • 142
    • 78149297845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Jim: They have a "quasi-property interest" in the fish, I suppose. Same with the airline in People Express-they had a "quasi-property interest" in the operation of their terminal facility.
  • 143
    • 78149323016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Aaron: And you, my friend, are left with a "quasi-theory." To get Judge Henderson's attention, all I have to do is assert a "quasi-property interest" in the uninterrupted operation of my Deli. I didn't realize until this moment how susceptible to legal fictions you are.
  • 145
    • 78149331652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (denying recovery for owner of a delicatessen who suffered economic loss when a nearby build-ing collapse closed the street)
    • See, e.g., 532 Madison Ave. Gourmet Foods, Inc. v. Finlandia Ctr., Inc., 750 N.E.2d 1097 (N.Y. 2001) (denying recovery for owner of a delicatessen who suffered economic loss when a nearby build-ing collapse closed the street).
    • (2001) Madison Ave. Gourmet Foods, Inc. V. Finlandia Ctr., Inc , vol.750 , pp. 532
  • 146
    • 78149305877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James, supra note 5, at 48
    • James1
  • 147
    • 78149331278 scopus 로고
    • note
    • see Louisiana ex rel. Guste v. M/V Testbank, 752 F.2d 1019, 1028-29 (5th Cir. 1985) (en banc) (considering "pragmatic" limitations)
    • (1985)
  • 148
    • 78149300127 scopus 로고
    • Protected Interests and Undertakings in the Law of Negligence
    • [hereinafter Perry, Protected Interests] (observing that the standard explanation "is pragmatic in character")
    • Stephen R. Perry, Protected Interests and Undertakings in the Law of Negligence, 42 U. TORONTO L.J. 247, 262 (1992) [hereinafter Perry, Protected Interests] (observing that the standard explanation "is pragmatic in character").
    • (1992) U. Toronto L.J. , vol.42
    • Perry Stephen, R.1
  • 149
    • 78149342818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing the theories of William Bishop and Mario Rizzo)
    • See infra notes 97-106 (discussing the theories of William Bishop and Mario Rizzo).
  • 151
    • 78149304722 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Atiyah, supra note 4, at 270. See, e.g., Libbey v. Hampton Water Works Co., 389 A.2d 434, 435 (N.H. 1978) (imposing liability on water company for negligent act would create "indefinitely extended scope of liability").
    • (1985) People Express Airlines, Inc. V. Consol. Rail. Corp , vol.495
    • Atiyah1
  • 152
    • 78149355195 scopus 로고
    • Barber Lines A/S v. M/V Donau Maru, 764 F.2d 50, 54 (1st Cir.) (Breyer, J.)
    • Barber Lines A/S v. M/V Donau Maru, 764 F.2d 50, 54 (1st Cir. 1985) (Breyer, J.).
    • (1985)
  • 153
    • 78149286869 scopus 로고
    • Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort: Another Look at Robins Dry Dock v. Flint
    • Rabin, supra note 14, at 1531-32.
    • (1991) J. Legal Stud. , vol.14 , pp. 1531-1532
    • Rabin1
  • 154
    • 78149292466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See M/V Testbank, 752 F.2d at 1021 ("[W]ithout this limitation foreseeability loses much of its ability to function as a rule of law.").
  • 155
    • 78149288696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("Foreseeability proves too much, as has been frequently demonstrated.")
    • Rabin, supra note 14, at 1526 ("Foreseeability proves too much, as has been frequently demonstrated.").
    • Rabin1
  • 156
    • 78149352976 scopus 로고
    • (2d Cir.)
    • See In re Kinsman Transit Co., 388 F.2d 821, 825 n.8 (2d Cir. 1968).
    • (1968) Kinsman Transit Co , vol.388 , Issue.8
  • 158
    • 84858033056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Principled Solution for Negligent Infliction of Emotional Distress Claims
    • (arguing that foreseeability is insufficient to invoke duty in emo-tional distress cases)
    • See Robert J. Rhee, A Principled Solution for Negligent Infliction of Emotional Distress Claims, 36 ARIZ. ST. L.J. 805, 836-42 (2004) (arguing that foreseeability is insufficient to invoke duty in emo-tional distress cases).
    • (2004) ARIZ. ST. L.J. , vol.36 , pp. 836-842
    • Rhee Robert, J.1
  • 159
    • 0043245453 scopus 로고
    • Palsgraf Revisited
    • ("These are shifting sands, and no fit foundation. There is a duty if the court says there is a duty.")
    • See William L. Prosser, Palsgraf Revisited, 52 MICH. L. REV. 1, 15 (1953) ("These are shifting sands, and no fit foundation. There is a duty if the court says there is a duty.").
    • (1953) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.52 , Issue.1 , pp. 15
    • Prosser William, L.1
  • 160
    • 78149310007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Louisiana ex rel. Guste v. M/V Testbank, 752 F.2d 1019, 1029 (5th Cir. 1985) (en banc).
  • 161
    • 78149300128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rabin, supra note 14, at 1534.
    • Rabin1
  • 162
    • 78149319833 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Barber Lines A/S v. M/V Donau Maru, 764 F.2d 50, 54 (1st Cir. 1985) (Breyer, J.).
    • (1985)
  • 163
    • 78149342060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 54-55.
  • 164
    • 78149290270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see Rabin, supra note 35, at 862 (stating that courts must sort out an "exceedingly fine and elaborate network of interdependencies").
    • Rabin1
  • 165
    • 78149308027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • M/V Testbank, 752 F.2d at 1028-29.
    • M/V Testbank , vol.752 , pp. 1028-1029
  • 166
    • 34249718634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Common-Law Economic Torts: An Economic and Legal Analysis
    • Richard A. Posner, Common-Law Economic Torts: An Economic and Legal Analysis, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 735, 737 (2006).
    • (2006) Ariz. L. Rev. , vol.48
    • Posner Richard, A.1
  • 167
    • 78149347680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing the fishermen exception)
    • See EPSTEIN, supra note 51, at 606.
    • , Issue.PART. I.A , pp. 606
    • Epstein1
  • 168
    • 78149328349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LANDES & POSNER, supra note 51, at 251-55 & n.48.
    • , Issue.48 , pp. 251-255
    • Landes1    Posner2
  • 170
    • 78149342436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Goldberg, Exxon Valdez, su-pra note 51, at 11-14 & n.49.
    • Exxon Valdez , Issue.49 , pp. 11-14
    • Goldberg1
  • 173
    • 78149286478 scopus 로고
    • Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort: Another Look at Robins Dry Dock v. Flint
    • Rabin, Bishop's and Rizzo's ideas are widely taught to law students
    • Rabin, supra note 14, at 1535-36 n.72. Bishop's and Rizzo's ideas are widely taught to law students.
    • (1991) J. Legal Stud. , vol.20 , Issue.72 , pp. 1535-1536
    • Rabin1
  • 175
    • 78149299425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comparative Economic Loss: Lessons from Case-Law-Focused Middle Theory
    • TWERSKI & HENDERSON, supra note 19, at 359 n.25.
    • (2002) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.50 , Issue.25 , pp. 359
    • Twerski1    Henderson2
  • 176
    • 78149320935 scopus 로고
    • Bishop, supra note 15, at 4.
    • (1927) , Issue.4
    • Bishop1
  • 177
    • 78149291788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11.
  • 178
    • 78149287602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Bishop clarifies that many of his assumptions are "an empirical question" and that "financial losses are only poorly correlated with social cost."
  • 179
    • 27744512259 scopus 로고
    • Economic Loss: A Reply to Professor Rizzo
    • W. Bishop, Economic Loss: A Reply to Professor Rizzo, 2 OXFORD J. LEGAL STUD. 207, 207 (1982).
    • (1982) Oxford J. Legal Stud. , vol.2
    • Bishop, W.1
  • 180
    • 78149340406 scopus 로고
    • Bishop, supra note 15, at 11.
    • (1927) , pp. 11
    • Bishop1
  • 181
    • 78149354423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 13.
  • 182
    • 78149335201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 17.
  • 183
    • 78149356689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rizzo, supra note 16, at 282.
    • Rizzo1
  • 184
    • 78149309454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 283.
  • 185
    • 78149307641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rizzo was not the first to argue that the rule channels claims into physical loss claims.
  • 186
    • 78149336320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Atiyah, supra note 4, at 274 ("[T]he law should try to channel all the claims through the person who has suffered the physical damage."). Atiyah, however, concludes that such "channeling" would be unsatis-factory and arbitrary.
    • Atiyah1
  • 187
    • 78149313463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rhee, (discussing the instrumental problems surrounding emotion-al distress claims)
    • See Rhee, supra note 88, at 836-42 (discussing the instrumental problems surrounding emotion-al distress claims).
  • 188
    • 78149323025 scopus 로고
    • (9th Cir.)
    • See Union Oil Co. v. Oppen, 501 F.2d 558, 568-69 (9th Cir. 1974)
    • (1974) Union Oil Co. V. Oppen , vol.501
  • 189
    • 78149331662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rabin, supra note 14, at 1522-25
    • Rabin1
  • 190
    • 34249676529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Recovery in Tort for Pure Economic Loss
    • Eileen Silverstein, On Recovery in Tort for Pure Economic Loss, 32 U. MICH. J.L. REFORM 403, 419 (1999).
    • (1999) U. Mich. J.L. Reform , vol.32
    • Silverstein, E.1
  • 191
    • 78149344590 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Compare People Express Airlines, Inc. v. Consol. Rail. Corp., 495 A.2d 107, 110 (N.J. 1985) (pure economic loss case) ("These concerns include the fear of fraudulent claims, mass litigation, and limitless liability, or liability out of proportion to the defendant's fault."), with Gottshall v. Consol. Rail Corp., 988 F.2d 355, 366 (3d Cir. 1993), rev'd by Consol. Rail Corp. v. Gottshall, 512 U.S. 530 (1994) (emotional distress case) ("[W]e adopted the policy considerations. [those being] a need to prevent incalculable and potentially unlimited damages, a flood of litigation, and fraud.").
    • (1985) Inc. V. Consol. Rail. Corp. , vol.495
  • 192
    • 78149314601 scopus 로고
    • See supra note 1 and infra note 110
    • See supra note 1 and infra note 110.
    • (1856) Conn. Mut. Life Ins. , vol.265 , pp. 270
  • 193
    • 78149341687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rhee, supra note 88, at 813
    • Rhee1
  • 194
    • 78149314204 scopus 로고
    • (H.L.)
    • see, e.g., Lynch v. Knight, (1861) 11 Eng. Rep. 854, 863 (H.L.).
    • (1861) Eng. Rep. , vol.11
    • Knight1    Lynch2
  • 195
    • 78149316866 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (describing various rules and jurisdictional dispersion of rules)
    • See Rhee, supra note 88, at 816-23 (describing various rules and jurisdictional dispersion of rules).
    • Rhee1
  • 197
    • 78149316154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing this distinction)
    • See Atiyah, supra note 4, at 262-64 (discussing this distinction)
    • Atiyah1
  • 198
    • 78149352157 scopus 로고
    • (discussing cases in emotional distress claims using this distinction)
    • see also Rhee, supra note 88, at 859-60 (discussing cases in emotional distress claims using this distinction).
    • (1985) , pp. 859-860
    • Rhee1
  • 199
    • 78149342814 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Haft v. Lone Palm Hotel, 478 P.2d 465, 475 (Cal. 1970) (shifting burden of proof on the issue of causation to defendants in negligence action when requiring plaintiff to prove proximate causation would advantage the defendant)
    • (1970) Haft V. Lone Palm Hotel , vol.478
  • 200
    • 78149292837 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Byrne v. Boadle, (1863) 159 Eng. Rep. 299, 300 (Exch. Div.) (officially instituting the doctrine of res ipsa loquitur when breach is obvious but impossible to prove)
    • (1863) Eng. Rep. , vol.159
    • Boadle1    Byrne2
  • 201
    • 78149297110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Probability, Policy, and the Problem of Reference Class
    • note
    • see also Robert J. Rhee, Probability, Policy, and the Problem of Reference Class, 11 INT'L J. EVIDENCE & PROOF 286, 290-91 (2007) (discussing the problem of systemic error in tort law and the law's "nor-mative correction" of this problem through special doctrines).
    • (2007) Int'L J. Evidence & Proof. , vol.11
    • Rhee Robert, J.1
  • 202
    • 67949084993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward Procedural Optionality: Private Ordering of Public Adjudication
    • See Robert J. Rhee, Toward Procedural Optionality: Private Ordering of Public Adjudication, 84 N.Y.U. L. REV. 514, 561 (2009).
    • (2009) N.Y.U. L. REV. , vol.84
    • Rhee Robert, J.1
  • 207
    • 78149317586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. ("Policy-driven line-drawing is to an extent arbitrary because, wherever the line is drawn, invariably it cuts off liability to persons who foreseeably might be plaintiffs.").
  • 208
    • 78149305513 scopus 로고
    • See Rhee, supra note 88, at 806-07.
    • (1985) , pp. 806-807
    • Rhee1
  • 209
    • 78149306918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Silverstein, supra note 108, at 429.
    • Silverstein1
  • 210
    • 0039703071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (ex-panded ed.) (examining the shifting and varied ideas underpinning tort law as developed over time)
    • See generally G. EDWARD WHITE, TORT LAW IN AMERICA: AN INTELLECTUAL HISTORY (ex-panded ed. 2003) (examining the shifting and varied ideas underpinning tort law as developed over time).
    • (2003) Tort Law in America: An Intellectual History
    • Edward White, G.1
  • 212
    • 78149351043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N.E.2d, N.Y
    • 750 N.E.2d 1097, 1100 (N.Y. 2001).
    • (2001) , vol.750
  • 213
    • 78149296692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bishop, supra note 15, at 5-11.
    • Bishop1
  • 214
    • 78149304720 scopus 로고
    • A.2d, (N.J.). This fact pattern of access cutoff occurs in other cases as well
    • 41 A.2d 267 (N.J. 1945). This fact pattern of access cutoff occurs in other cases as well.
    • (1945) , vol.41 , pp. 267
  • 215
    • 78149295086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing political underpinnings of economic loss doctrine)
    • See supra note 33.
    • Economic Bias
    • Perry1
  • 216
    • 78149345318 scopus 로고
    • Weller & Co. v. Foot & Mouth Disease Research Inst
    • (refusing economic loss recovery for cattle auctioneer for losses caused by virus escape from research institute)
    • Cf. Weller & Co. v. Foot & Mouth Disease Research Inst., (1966) 1 Q.B. 569, 570 (refusing economic loss recovery for cattle auctioneer for losses caused by virus escape from research institute).
    • (1966) Q.B. , vol.1
  • 217
    • 78149331287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bishop, supra note 15, at 13.
    • Bishop1
  • 218
    • 78149334467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N.E.2d at
    • 750 N.E.2d at 1099.
    • , vol.750 , pp. 1099
  • 219
    • 78149352592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Bishop's theory has been roundly criticized by others.
  • 220
    • 78149306560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Schwartz, supra note 12, at 128
    • Schwartz1
  • 221
    • 78149340960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rabin, supra note 14, at 1536 n.72
    • , Issue.72 , pp. 1536
    • Rabin1
  • 222
    • 0010960512 scopus 로고
    • The Economic Loss Problem: A Comment on Bishop
    • Mario J. Rizzo, The Economic Loss Problem: A Comment on Bishop, 2 OXFORD J. LEGAL STUD. 197 (1982)
    • (1982) Oxford J. Legal Stud. , vol.2 , pp. 197
    • Rizzo Mario, J.1
  • 223
    • 78149302132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (summarizing the criticisms)
    • see also Perry, Relational Economic Loss, supra note 10, at 738-45 (summarizing the criticisms).
    • Relational Economic Loss , pp. 738-745
    • Perry1
  • 224
    • 78149342811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (rebutting Ra-bin's critique of Bishop's theory)
    • But see LANDES & POSNER, supra note 51, at 252-53 (rebutting Ra-bin's critique of Bishop's theory).
    • Landes1    Posner2
  • 228
    • 78149304362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Like Bishop's theory, Rizzo's theory has been criticized.
  • 229
    • 78149313107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rabin, supra note 14, at 1535 n.72
    • , Issue.72 , pp. 1535
    • Rabin1
  • 230
    • 78149320206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (summarizing criti-cisms)
    • see also Relational Economic Loss, supra note 10, at 777-81 (summarizing criti-cisms).
    • Relational Economic Loss , pp. 777-781
  • 231
    • 78149333867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These cases are frequently cited in scholarship and casebooks.
  • 232
    • 78149296696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., FARNSWORTH & GRADY, supra note 51, at 281-82
    • Farnsworth1    Grady2
  • 233
    • 78149319098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LANDES & POSNER, supra note 51, at 251-54
    • Landes1    Posner2
  • 235
    • 78149335957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • n.72
    • Perry, supra note 14, at 1528 n.47, 1535 n.72
    • , vol.1528 , Issue.47 , pp. 1535
    • Perry1
  • 236
    • 78149317973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rizzo, supra note 16, at 301.
    • Rizzo1
  • 237
    • 78149324149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robins Dry Dock & Repair Co. v. Flint, 275 U.S. 303, 309 (1927) (stating that "no au-thority need be cited" to justify the pure economic loss rule).
  • 238
    • 78149322612 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To keep this condition somewhat realistic at least, we assume that there is not perfect informa-tion as to all other factors of outcome, such as judicial outcomes.
  • 239
    • 78149289072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The pricing of insurance premiums is instructive. The premium is calculated as: P = E(S) + k + R, where E(S) represents the mathematical expectation of claims, k is the operating expenses, and R is a risk premium that allows for unforeseen deviations in the claims amount.
  • 241
    • 78149354816 scopus 로고
    • (9th Cir.)
    • 501 F.2d 558 (9th Cir. 1974)
    • (1974) , vol.501 , pp. 558
  • 242
    • 78149355575 scopus 로고
    • see supra text accompanying note 63.
    • (1945)
  • 243
    • 78149344599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Barber Lines A/S v. M/V Donau Maru, 764 F.2d 50, 54-55 (1st Cir. 1985) (Breyer, J.) (ar-guing that contractual risk allocation may be more efficient)
  • 244
    • 78149349567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • EVRA Corp. v. Swiss Bank Corp., 673 F.2d 951, 957-59 (7th Cir. 1982) (Posner, J.) (arguing that the plaintiff was in a better position to measure the risk and take precautions against economic loss)
  • 245
    • 78149346080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see Miles, supra note 19 (analyzing Posn-er's opinion in Swiss Bank).
  • 246
    • 78149320208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Effect of Risk on Legal Valuation
    • (discussing effect of uncertainty on valuation)
    • See generally Robert J. Rhee, The Effect of Risk on Legal Valuation, 78 U. COLO. L. REV. 193 (2007) (discussing effect of uncertainty on valuation)
    • (2007) U. Colo. L. Rev. , vol.78 , pp. 193
    • Rhee Robert, J.1
  • 247
    • 78149304366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Price Theory of Legal Bargain-ing: An Inquiry into the Selection of Settlement and Litigation Under Uncertainty
    • (discussing information asymmetry and related risk premiums)
    • Robert J. Rhee, A Price Theory of Legal Bargain-ing: An Inquiry into the Selection of Settlement and Litigation Under Uncertainty, 56 EMORY L.J. 619 (2006) (discussing information asymmetry and related risk premiums).
    • (2006) Emory L.J. , vol.56 , pp. 619
    • Rhee Robert, J.1
  • 248
    • 78149295086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (doctrine is "irrelevant")
    • See Perry, Economic Bias, supra note 3, at 1616 (doctrine is "irrelevant")
    • Economic Bias , pp. 1616
    • Perry1
  • 249
    • 78149307640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Union Oil Co. v. Oppen holds "no general interest")
    • Rabin, supra note 14, at 1535 n.72 (Union Oil Co. v. Oppen holds "no general interest").
    • , Issue.72 , pp. 1535
    • Rabin1
  • 250
    • 78149320209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (fishermen have "quasi-property interest" in the bounties of the sea)
    • See TWERSKI & HENDERSON, supra note 19, at 365 (fishermen have "quasi-property interest" in the bounties of the sea)
    • Twerski1    Henderson2
  • 251
    • 0035565441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Modernizing Public Nuisance: Solving the Paradox of the Spe-cial Injury Rule
    • (preclusion would result in "unfairness")
    • Denise Antolini, Modernizing Public Nuisance: Solving the Paradox of the Spe-cial Injury Rule, 28 ECOLOGY L.Q. 755, 773 n.65 (2001) (preclusion would result in "unfairness")
    • (2001) Ecology L.Q. , vol.28 , Issue.65
    • Antolini, D.1
  • 252
    • 84937325805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Too Pragmatic by Half
    • ("[C]onvenience favors allowing actions by immediate parties with large stakes, such as fishermen.")
    • Richard A. Epstein, Too Pragmatic by Half, 109 YALE L.J. 1639, 1654 (2000) ("[C]onvenience favors allowing actions by immediate parties with large stakes, such as fishermen.")
    • (2000) YALE L.J. , vol.109
    • Epstein Richard, A.1
  • 253
    • 78149328738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (fishermen had a "reasonably foreseeable, special connection" to the sea)
    • Stapleton, supra note 11, at 568 (fishermen had a "reasonably foreseeable, special connection" to the sea).
    • , vol.568
    • Stapleton1
  • 254
    • 78149300893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("The case for compensating the future losses [of fishermen] is much weaker.")
    • See Goldberg, Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort, supra note 6, at 273 ("The case for compensating the future losses [of fishermen] is much weaker.").
    • Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort , pp. 273
    • Goldberg1
  • 255
    • 78149286883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rizzo, supra note 16, at 298-99.
    • Rizzo1
  • 256
    • 78149322611 scopus 로고
    • (citing Union Oil Co. v. Oppen, 501 F.2d 558 (9th Cir.))
    • Bishop, supra note 15, at 25-26 (citing Union Oil Co. v. Oppen, 501 F.2d 558 (9th Cir. 1974))
    • (1974) , pp. 25-26
    • Bishop1
  • 257
    • 78149302515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (agreeing with Bishop's theory)
    • see also LANDES & POSNER, supra note 51, at 251-52 (agreeing with Bishop's theory).
    • Landes1    Posner2
  • 258
    • 78149290652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LANDES & POSNER, supra note 51, at 252.
    • , Issue.PART. I.A , pp. 252
    • Landes1    Posner2
  • 259
    • 78149310372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 252 n.50
    • , Issue.50 PART. I.A , pp. 252
    • Landes1    Posner2
  • 260
    • 78149304367 scopus 로고
    • ("Presumably, sportsfishermen share the same entitlement to legal redress for damage to the Bay's ecol-ogy.")
    • see also Pruitt v. Allied Chem. Corp., 523 F. Supp. 975, 978 (D. Va. 1981) ("Presumably, sportsfishermen share the same entitlement to legal redress for damage to the Bay's ecol-ogy.").
    • (1981) Pruitt V. Allied Chem. Corp. , vol.523 , Issue.SUPPL.
  • 261
    • 78149287974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bishop, supra note 15, at 25-26.
    • Bishop1
  • 262
    • 0001394870 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Theory of Property Rights
    • generally, (exploring different types of property ownership rights, including communal ownership)
    • See generally Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 AM. ECON. REV. 347 (1967) (exploring different types of property ownership rights, including communal ownership).
    • (1967) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.57 , pp. 347
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 263
    • 78149312215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bishop, supra note 15, at 25-26.
    • Bishop1
  • 264
    • 78149292474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., In re Exxon Valdez, 270 F.3d 1215, 1223, 1225 (9th Cir. 2001) (Exxon spent over $2 billion in cleanup of Prince William Sound, settled $900 million with Alaska and the United States to restore the environment, and was fined $125 million)
    • (2001)
  • 265
    • 78149332391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (providing liability for "removal costs" incurred in an oil spill)
    • 33 U.S.C. § 2702(a) (2006) (providing liability for "removal costs" incurred in an oil spill).
    • (2006)
  • 266
    • 78149335956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The government as plaintiff is a familiar concept. See, e.g., United States v. Bestfoods, (action against defendant for environmental cleanup under CERCLA)
    • The government as plaintiff is a familiar concept. See, e.g., United States v. Bestfoods, 524 U.S. 51, 57-58 (1998) (action against defendant for environmental cleanup under CERCLA).
    • (1998)
  • 267
    • 78149335588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • But see Exxon Valdez, 270 F.3d at 1221 ("This is a case about commercial fishing. The ver-dict in this case was for damage to economic expectations for commercial fishermen.").
  • 268
    • 78149325321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Bishop, supra note 15, at 13 ("But what exactly is the social cost of an accident is a very complex matter. The answer depends upon innumerable particular facts of interacting markets.").
    • Bishop1
  • 269
    • 78149306917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwartz, supra note 12, at 128.
    • Schwartz1
  • 270
    • 78149318714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("The so-called pragmatic con-cerns. [are] just the surface symptoms of an underlying concern along these lines.")
    • Perry, Protected Interests, supra note 80, at 263, 266 ("The so-called pragmatic con-cerns. [are] just the surface symptoms of an underlying concern along these lines.").
    • Protected Interests
    • Perry1
  • 271
    • 78149311474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Palsgraf v. Long Island R. Co., 162 N.E. 99, 99 (N.Y. 1928) ("Proof of negligence in the air, so to speak, will not do." (quoting SIR FREDERICK POLLOCK, TORTS 455 (11th ed. 1920)) (internal quo-tation marks omitted)).
  • 272
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost
    • See R.H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1, 2 (1960).
    • (1960) J.L. & Econ. , vol.3
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 273
    • 78149293996 scopus 로고
    • A Return to Principles of Corrective Justice in Deciding Economic Loss Cases
    • But see Andrew W. McThenia & Joseph E. Ulrich, A Return to Principles of Corrective Justice in Deciding Economic Loss Cases, 69 VA. L. REV. 1517 (1983).
    • (1983) Va. L. Rev. , vol.69 , pp. 1517
    • McThenia Andrew, W.1    Ulrich Joseph, E.2
  • 276
    • 78149290651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("[B]usiness risk management is concerned with possible reductions in business value from any source.")
    • SCOTT E. HARRINGTON & GREGORY R. NIEHAUS, RISK MANAGEMENT AND INSURANCE 4 (2d ed. 2004) ("[B]usiness risk management is concerned with possible reductions in business value from any source.").
    • (2004) Niehaus, Risk Management and Insurance , vol.4
    • Scott, E.H.1    Gregory, R.2
  • 278
    • 78149343872 scopus 로고
    • G.S. Rasmussen & Assocs., (9th Cir.)
    • See G.S. Rasmussen & Assocs., Inc. v. Kalitta Flying Serv., Inc., 958 F.2d 896, 903 (9th Cir. 1992).
    • (1992) Inc. V. Kalitta Flying Serv., Inc
  • 279
    • 78149297109 scopus 로고
    • Kaiser Aetna v. United States, 444 U.S
    • See Kaiser Aetna v. United States, 444 U.S. 164, 176 (1979)
    • (1979)
  • 280
    • 0037678339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property and the Right to Exclude
    • Thomas W. Merrill, Property and the Right to Exclude, 77 NEB. L. REV. 730, 730 (1998).
    • (1998) Neb. L. Rev. , vol.77
    • Merrill Thomas, W.1
  • 281
    • 78149306428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Knight notes that ownership "consists essential-ly of the combination of the rights of control and of usufruct." KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 352. Stephen Perry argues that the distinction between pure and consequential economic loss is not arbitrary because the harm invoked by the consequential economic loss cases "is the loss of use of the property." Perry, Protected Interests, supra note 80, at 269. The loss of use of property, however, cannot be the distinc-tion as this would entail contractual rights seen in Robins.
  • 282
    • 78149308733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra note 179 and accompanying text.
  • 283
    • 84979188687 scopus 로고
    • The Nature of the Firm
    • See R.H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 ECONOMICA 386, 390-91 (1937).
    • (1937) Economica , vol.4
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 284
    • 78149321308 scopus 로고
    • (D. Me.)
    • 370 F. Supp. 247, 248-49 (D. Me. 1973).
    • (1973) , vol.370 , Issue.SUPPL.
  • 285
    • 78149338607 scopus 로고
    • Id. at 249-50.
    • (1973) , vol.370 , Issue.SUPPL. , pp. 249-250
  • 286
    • 78149287612 scopus 로고
    • Id. at 250
    • (1973) , vol.370 , Issue.SUPPL. , pp. 250
  • 289
    • 78149332041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 251.
  • 290
  • 291
    • 78149316880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Other cases have recognized a fishermen's "special interest" in the public right to fishing and thus their right to recover economic loss. See, e.g., Columbia River Fishermen's Protective Union v. City of St. Helens, 87 P.2d 195, 197 (Or. 1939).
  • 292
    • 78149289539 scopus 로고
    • 172 23 So. 2d 756 (Miss. 1945).
    • (1945) , pp. 756
  • 293
    • 78149287972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 758. The point here is that the "fishermen" exception is not an exception for a special oc-cupational class but is a part of a class of cases with a common principle. The fishermen cases are prominent because these cases most commonly present the fact pattern that invokes the principle.
  • 294
    • 78149288693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 757-58.
  • 295
    • 78149303609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 758.
  • 297
    • 78149301765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This concept is the basis of the prevailing economic theory of the firm, which views the firm as a nexus of contracts among persons owning inputs of production.
  • 299
    • 44649197264 scopus 로고
    • Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure
    • Michael C. Jensen & William H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, 3 J. FIN. ECON. 305, 311 (1976).
    • (1976) J. Fin. Econ. , vol.3
    • Jensen Michael, C.1    Meckling William, H.2
  • 300
    • 78149349181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 306 (residual income belongs to the owner of property as property rent).
  • 301
    • 78149331289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "The theory of the income capitalization approach is based on the premise that value is equal to the present value of the cash flow and reversionary value the property will produce over a reasonable holding (ownership) period."
  • 302
    • 78149320944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This method is the primary value indicator for commercial assets
    • JAMES R. HITCHNER, FINANCIAL VALUATION: APPLICATIONS AND MODELS 352 (2d ed. 2006). This method is the primary value indicator for commercial assets.
    • (2006) Financial Valuation: Applications and Models , vol.352
    • James, R.H.1
  • 303
    • 78149296695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The suggestion is not that the actual market is perfectly competitive, but simply that contract spreads on rentals, like other arbitrage opportunities, are hard to find.
  • 304
    • 78149303251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Goldberg, Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort, supra note 6, at 252. The parties agreed to a rent of £250 per month. Id. This price was well below the market price. Id. The plaintiff chartered the ship in 1915 for twenty-six months at a rate of £11,200 per month, and the ship was rechartered to another party for nearly £16,995 per month for a sixteen-month term beginning on August 1, 1917.
  • 305
    • 78149356688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 281-82, 311.
    • Knight1
  • 306
    • 78149295984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Market participants are not helpless in the face of fortune's winds. The charterer could have taken a number of steps to hedge this risk: for example, entering into forward contracts with subcharter-ers to lock in prices, or, less likely, a derivative type wager on the forward prices of shipping contracts. Such contracts have existed for centuries.
  • 307
    • 78149286882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See ARISTOTLE, POLITICS, bk. I, ch. 11, reprinted in THE BASIC WORKS OF ARISTOTLE 1142 (Richard McKeon ed. 2001) (describing the use of option contracts in the olive oil market). Alternatively, if war was the principal driver of price, the charterer could have entered into a wager on war's end or continuance, which would have imperfectly hedged the risk of an adverse future price movement. These steps would not secure prospective profit because such hedging is always associated with a cost. There is not only the obvious transaction cost associated with hedging, but also we cannot ignore the fundamental nature of the transaction, namely, the charterer must assume an adverse economic consequence of a forward rate swap if the rates increase.
  • 308
    • 78149309075 scopus 로고
    • ("Their loss arose only through their contract with the owners.")
    • 275 U.S. 303, 308 (1927) ("Their loss arose only through their contract with the owners.").
    • (1927)
  • 311
    • 78149324841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This classic treatise has been called "the first work of any importance, and in any field of study, that deals explicitly with decision-making under conditions of uncertainty."
  • 313
    • 78149345322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Knight's theory remains a vital subject of academic inquiry.
  • 314
    • 84977355938 scopus 로고
    • Frank Knight on Risk, Un-certainty, and the Firm: A New Interpretation
    • See Richard N. Langlois & Metin M. Cosgel, Frank Knight on Risk, Un-certainty, and the Firm: A New Interpretation, 31 ECON. INQUIRY 456 (1993)
    • (1993) Econ. Inquiry , vol.31
    • Langlois Richard, N.1    Cosgel Metin, M.2
  • 316
    • 77957255616 scopus 로고
    • The Profit Concept and Theory: A Restatement
    • J. Fred Weston, The Profit Concept and Theory: A Restatement, 62 J. POL. ECON. 152 (1954).
    • (1954) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.62 , pp. 152
    • Fred Weston, J.1
  • 318
    • 84896515917 scopus 로고
    • Noise
    • (posit-ing that a stock market is impossible without uncertainty)
    • see also Fischer Black, Noise, 41 J. FIN. 529, 530 (1986) (posit-ing that a stock market is impossible without uncertainty).
    • (1986) J. Fin. , vol.41
    • Black, F.1
  • 319
    • 84995186518 scopus 로고
    • Portfolio Selection
    • Harry Markowitz, Portfolio Selection, 7 J. FIN. 77, 77 (1952).
    • (1952) J. Fin. , vol.7
    • Markowitz, H.1
  • 321
    • 78149344598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Even supposedly risk-neutral corporations buy in-surance.
  • 322
    • 78149344224 scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Economic Loss in the Law of Torts
    • Rhee, supra note 25, at 153
    • (1982) J. Legal Stud. , vol.11 , pp. 153
    • Rhee1
  • 323
    • 78149306916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (explaining why corporations purchase insurance)
    • see also HARRINGTON & NIEHAUS, supra note 159, at 171-74 (explaining why corporations purchase insurance)
    • Harrington1    Niehaus2
  • 325
    • 78149340055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 285 ("The presence of true profit, therefore, depends on an absolute uncertainty in the estimation of the value of judgment, or on the absence of the requisite organization for combining a sufficient number of instances to secure certainty through consolidation."). Knight defines standard business usage of profit as "the entrepreneur's net income, what remains out of the gross proceeds of the business after paying the hired labor and capital at the agreed rates, determined by mar-ket competition."
    • Knight1
  • 326
    • 0040751636 scopus 로고
    • Profit and Entrepreneurial Functions
    • Frank H. Knight, Profit and Entrepreneurial Functions, 2 J. ECON. HIST. 126, 127 (Supp. 1942)
    • (1942) J. Econ. Hist. , vol.2 , Issue.SUPPL.
    • Knight Frank, H.1
  • 327
    • 78149329829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 280, 284 (defining profit as the residual income after the payment to all factors of production). Knight distinguishes this general understanding of profit from "pure profit," which also deducts the "going rate" wages of the entrepreneur were he to rent his labor. Knight, Profit and Entrepreneurial Functions, supra, at 127.
  • 328
    • 78149327907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 284.
    • Knight1
  • 329
    • 78149310017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra notes 181~183.
  • 330
    • 78149334848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Knight commented that entrepreneurs have "an irrationally high confidence in their own good fortune."
  • 331
    • 78149351055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 366.
    • Knight1
  • 332
    • 78149309074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Adam Smith similarly observed that overconfidence "is an ancient evil."
  • 334
    • 78149348101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As a result of this overconfidence, Knight believes that "busi-ness as a whole suffers a loss."
  • 335
    • 78149288692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 365.
    • Knight1
  • 336
    • 78149342434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 78, 86.
    • Knight1
  • 337
    • 78149352984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 82.
  • 338
    • 78149289537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Knight, supra note 191, at 127 ("[I]t will be evident to anyone with a rudimentary under-standing of economic processes and analysis that profit (always in the sense of pure profit) would be ab-sent under the conditions of equilibrium with perfect competition'.")
    • See Knight, supra note 191, at 127 ("[I]t will be evident to anyone with a rudimentary under-standing of economic processes and analysis that profit (always in the sense of pure profit) would be ab-sent under the conditions of equilibrium with perfect competition'.").
  • 339
    • 78149311857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 185-186 and accompanying text.
  • 340
    • 78149337910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 231.
    • Knight1
  • 341
    • 78149342070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 199, 259.
  • 342
    • 78149312605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 237-38.
  • 343
    • 78149287971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Markowitz, supra note 189, at 91
    • Markowitz1
  • 344
    • 78149309686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT, (calling uncertainty "evil")
    • see also KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 347 (calling uncertainty "evil").
  • 345
    • 78149310371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HARRINGTON & NIEHAUS
    • See HARRINGTON & NIEHAUS, supra note 159, at 179-87, 195
  • 347
    • 78149319096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Telephone interview with Barry Bablin, Senior Vice President, Cas. & Actuarial Servs., Farm Family Cas. Ins. Co. (Feb. 17, 2009). Bablin suggested that a policy for business interruption for a cov-ered loss of another person's property is not prevalent. Such risks are difficult to price and premiums would not be price effective for policyholders. If such a market for pure economic loss exists, he sug-gested that it would be found in the specialized excess and surplus lines. Accord Telephone interview with Steven Sachs, Managing Dir., Nat'l Real Estate Practice, Hilb Rogal & Hobbs (Feb. 10, 2009) (confirming broadly Bablin's points).
  • 348
    • 78149338278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economic Loss Rule and Liability Insurance
    • See Ellen S. Pryor, The Economic Loss Rule and Liability Insurance, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 905, 912 (2006).
    • (2006) Ariz. L. Rev. , vol.48
    • Pryor Ellen, S.1
  • 350
    • 78149321662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 87 and accompanying text.
  • 351
    • 78149323024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Pryor, supra note 206, at 908 ("On the supply side, combining coverage for pure economic losses into the same coverage as accidental bodily harm would be difficult.").
  • 353
    • 35349027428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Terrorism Risk in a Post-9/11 Economy: The Convergence of Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government Action
    • (arguing that economic infeasibility of premium arising from high capital cost is the problem of insuring catastrophic risk)
    • see also Robert J. Rhee, Terrorism Risk in a Post-9/11 Economy: The Convergence of Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government Action, 37 ARIZ. ST. L.J. 435, 474-77 (2005) (arguing that economic infeasibility of premium arising from high capital cost is the problem of insuring catastrophic risk).
    • (2005) ARIZ. ST. L.J , vol.37
    • Rhee Robert, J.1
  • 354
    • 78149307638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Absent an insurable interest, an insurance contract is void as a wagering contract
    • Absent an insurable interest, an insurance contract is void as a wagering contract.
  • 357
  • 358
    • 78149327526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 3 COUCH ON INSURANCE, supra note 212, § 41:11, at
    • 3 COUCH ON INSURANCE, supra note 212, § 41:11, at 21-22.
  • 359
    • 78149351054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 26
  • 360
    • 78149334255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Secura Ins. Co. v. Pioneer State Mut. Ins. Co., 470 N.W.2d 415, 415-16 (Mich. Ct. App. 1991) (leasehold is not an insurable interest).
  • 361
    • 78149352983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Interestingly, the deli in 532 Madison Avenue achieved a $100,000 settlement for business inter-ruption with its insurer though it did not suffer a physical loss. Interview with Ms. Cho, in her store at 532 Madison Avenue (Feb. 27, 2009) (full name not given). Cho indicated that most other businesses that suffered economic loss did not recover from their insurers.
  • 363
    • 78149301764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The loading cost of insurance is cheaper than the cost of litigation.
  • 364
    • 78149293993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rhee, supra note 25, at 159 n.159, 164-65
    • , Issue.159 , pp. 164-165
    • Rhee1
  • 365
    • 78149286881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Barber Lines A/S v. M/V Do-nau Maru, 764 F.2d 50, 54 (1st Cir. 1985) (Breyer, J.)
  • 366
    • 78149293995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James, supra note 5, at 52.
    • James1
  • 367
    • 78149346941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (noting the insurability problem)
    • See Rabin, supra note 14, at 1537 (noting the insurability problem)
    • Rabin1
  • 368
    • 78149340404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • supra note 205 (describing the absence of a general market for pure economic loss coverage)
  • 369
    • 78149340054 scopus 로고
    • (discussing the problem of finding an insurable interest in factual
    • see also ROBERT E. KEETON & ALAN I. WIDISS, INSURANCE LAW § 3.4(a)(5), at 168-72 (West 1988) (discussing the problem of finding an insurable interest in factual pecuniary expectancies). The economist Robert Shiller notes that insurance removes only a small slice of the potential risks facing most people, and that the most important risks, such as a market decline in home value and the economic value of one's occupation, cannot be insured against or hedged.
    • (1988) Insurance Law , pp. 168-172
    • Robert, E.K.1    Alan, I.W.2
  • 371
    • 78149349566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 204 and accompanying text. Economists have argued that Knight's distinction between risk and uncertainty really refers to insurable and uninsurable risk. See, e.g., LeRoy & Singell, supra note 187, at 394.
  • 372
    • 78149299437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT
    • See KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 252-54.
  • 373
    • 78149337909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Jensen & Meckling, supra note 177, at 311 ("The private corporation or firm. is also cha-racterized by the existence of divisible residual claims on the assets and cash flows of the organiza-tion.").
  • 374
    • 0000589270 scopus 로고
    • Agency Problems and Residual Claims
    • ("Common stock allows residual risk to be spread across many residual clai-mants who individually choose the extent to which they bear risk and who can diversify across organiza-tions offering such claims.")
    • See Eugene F. Fama & Michael C. Jensen, Agency Problems and Residual Claims, 26 J.L. & ECON. 327, 329 (1983) ("Common stock allows residual risk to be spread across many residual clai-mants who individually choose the extent to which they bear risk and who can diversify across organiza-tions offering such claims.").
    • (1983) J.L. & ECON , vol.26
    • Fama Eugene, F.1    Jensen Michael, C.2
  • 375
    • 78149325320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Residual risk is "the difference between stochastic inflows of resources and promised payments to agents. "
  • 379
    • 78149330195 scopus 로고
    • note
    • This inquiry concerning uncertainty and the law is not limited to tort law. The law is generally biased toward adhering to the principle of no arbitrage in economic transactions. Business risk cannot be eliminated without cost or manipulation. The most obvious adoption of this principle is the law pro-hibiting riskless profit through price fixing and insider trading. See KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 334 (de-scribing problem of managers using inside information). The tentacles of this principle reach further. A transaction between capital creditor and issuer is strictly enforced even though an unforeseen contingen-cy creates a harsh, even unfair, circumstance because the transaction is a party's commitment to a par-ticular view of outcome, which the law does not rearrange per contract doctrine. See Sharon Steel Corp. v. Chase Manhattan Bank, N.A., 691 F.2d 1039, 1053 (2d Cir. 1982)
    • (1982)
  • 380
    • 78149305876 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Metro. Life Ins. Co. v. RJR Na-bisco, Inc., 716 F. Supp. 1504, 1518 (S.D.N.Y. 1989). In corporate affairs, the overwhelming bias is toward respecting the reality that the engagement of enterprise is risky.
    • (1989)
  • 381
    • 3142686274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Business Judgment Rule as Abstention Doctrine
    • See Stephen M. Bainbridge, The Business Judgment Rule as Abstention Doctrine, 57 VAND. L. REV. 83, 110-17 (2004).
    • (2004) VAND. L. REV , vol.57 , Issue.83 , pp. 110-117
    • Bainbridge Stephen, M.1
  • 382
    • 78149320589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The business judgment rule provides a virtually impenetrable legal shield against liability so long as the manager acted in good faith.
  • 383
    • 22944470814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sacrificing Corporate Profits in the Public Interest
    • Einer Elhauge, Sacrificing Corporate Profits in the Public Interest, 80 N.Y.U. L. REV. 733, 770 (2005)
    • (2005) N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.80 , Issue.733 , pp. 770
    • Elhauge, E.1
  • 384
    • 84898970892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Ethics, Agency, and the Theory of the Firm
    • see also Robert J. Rhee, Corporate Ethics, Agency, and the Theory of the Firm, 3 J. BUS. & TECH. L. 309, 320 (2008).
    • (2008) J. BUS. & TECH. L , vol.3 , Issue.309 , pp. 320
    • Rhee Robert, J.1
  • 385
    • 78149311472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although the stupid, negligent, or unlucky manager can impose great economic havoc on creditors and shareholders, the law prohibits retroactive legal correction of a bad or stupid business decision, no less a fortuitous mishap.
  • 386
    • 78149344597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., In re The Walt Disney Co. Deriv-ative Litig., 906 A.2d 27 (Del. 2006) (finding decision to give poorly performing manager $130 million severance payout protected by business judgment rule)
    • (2006)
  • 387
    • 78149348810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kamin v. Am. Express Co., 383 N.Y.S.2d 807 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1976) (finding decision to distribute stocks and thereby forego approximately $8 million in potential tax savings is protected by business judgment rule).
  • 388
    • 78149332746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT, (emphasis added)
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 356 (emphasis added).
  • 389
    • 78149292162 scopus 로고
    • Perry
    • Perry, Economic Bias, supra note 3, at 1609.
    • (1609) Economic Bias
  • 390
    • 78149286880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1606.
  • 391
    • 78149304011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1608.
  • 392
    • 78149343870 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Perry adds, "I hesitate to attribute to common-law judges any intention to widen so-cioeconomic gaps." Id. at 1609.
    • (1609)
  • 393
    • 78149309685 scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1607.
    • (1607)
  • 394
    • 78149331288 scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1604.
    • (1604)
  • 395
  • 396
    • 78149334468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 437.
  • 397
    • 78149352982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 432.
  • 398
    • 78149331659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 437.
  • 400
    • 78149329479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 264
  • 401
    • 78149291787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Home Office v. Dorset Yacht Co., Ltd., [1970] A.C. 1004, 1027 (H.L.) (Atkin, L.) ("[F]or one thing it is often caused by deliberate action. Competition involves traders being entitled to damage their rivals'interests by promoting their own.").
  • 402
    • 78149318714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perry
    • Perry, Protected Interests, supra note 80, at 266.
    • Protected Interests , pp. 266
  • 403
    • 78149354421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 267.
  • 404
    • 78149340594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Rhee, supra note 25, at 170-82 (arguing that the dominance of negligence as the standard in accident law is the result of "a compromise within the broader political economy").
  • 405
    • 78149314977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Based on this theory, it would appear that the New Jersey Supreme Court, the author of People Express, which radically departed from the general rule of Robins, would be the sole dissident and guar-dian of egalitarian sentiments.
  • 406
    • 0010367396 scopus 로고
    • Tort Law and the Economy in Nineteenth-Century America: A Reinterpretation
    • note
    • But see Gary T. Schwartz, Tort Law and the Economy in Nineteenth-Century America: A Reinterpretation, 90 YALE L.J. 1717, 1720 (1981) (observing that even early com-mon law courts displayed an "impressive sternness to major industries and that tort law exhibited a keen concern for victim welfare").
    • (1981) YALE L.J , vol.90
    • Schwartz Gary, T.1
  • 407
    • 78149339319 scopus 로고
    • note
    • MacPherson v. Buick Motor Co., 111 N.E. 1050, 1053 (N.Y. 1916) (Cardozo, J.).
    • (1916)
  • 408
    • 78149300510 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Greenman v. Yuba Power Prod., Inc., 377 P.2d 897, 900-01 (Cal. 1963) (Traynor, J.).
    • (1963)
  • 409
    • 78149288343 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sindell v. Abbott Labs., 607 P.2d 924, 936-38 (Cal. 1960).
    • (1960)
  • 410
    • 78149312604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "[N]egligently harming another is morally less reprehensible than doing so intentionally, and economic interests are not generally protected against intentional interference." Perry, Protected Inter-ests, supra note 80, at 265.
  • 411
    • 78149349179 scopus 로고
    • See Palsgraf v. Long Island R.R. Co., 162 N.E. 99, 101 (N.Y.)
    • See Palsgraf v. Long Island R.R. Co., 162 N.E. 99, 101 (N.Y. 1928).
    • (1928)
  • 413
    • 78149289916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This comment should not be construed as a complete explanation for why tort law provides compensation for physical losses. That inquiry is beyond the scope of this Article. The point is simply that the most obvious factors of production are property and human capital.
  • 414
    • 78149288341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An element of insurability is the absence or mitigation of a moral hazard.
  • 415
    • 78149293993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rhee, supra note 25, at 159 n.159, 164-65
    • , Issue.159 , pp. 164-165
    • Rhee1
  • 416
    • 78149354813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Barber Lines A/S v. M/V Donau Maru, 764 F.2d 50, 54 (1st Cir. 1985) (Breyer, J.).
  • 417
    • 78149320588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 235.
  • 418
    • 78149325686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Atiyah, supra note 4, at 271-73 (discussing the problem of large scale wealth transfers if the law eliminates the rule of no recovery for pure economic loss).
  • 419
    • 78149300892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Barber Lines, 764 F.2d at 55 (noting "inaccessibility of the empirical information needed to confirm or invalidate" the policy considerations).
  • 420
    • 78149290999 scopus 로고
    • Robins Dry Dock & Repair Co. v. Flint, 275 U.S. 303, 309
    • Robins Dry Dock & Repair Co. v. Flint, 275 U.S. 303, 309 (1927).
    • (1927)
  • 421
    • 78149330194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although it is not within the scope of this Article to engage in comparative analyses of econo-mies and rules of law, we can speculate, consistent with the thesis here, that societies with weaker com-mitment to private arrangement of the economic organization would show a greater tendency to recognize pure economic loss as a viable cause of action. In this regard, the observation that civil law jurisdictions such as France may be more accommodating of these claims than Anglo-American juris-dictions is consistent with this speculation.
  • 422
    • 78149295086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Perry, Economic Bias, supra note 3, at 1617-20
    • Economic Bias , pp. 1617-1620
    • Perry1
  • 423
    • 78149320206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perry, ("It would be fair to say that the prospects of liability for relational loss are higher in France than in England.")
    • see also Perry, Relational Economic Loss, supra note 10, at 729 ("It would be fair to say that the prospects of liability for relational loss are higher in France than in England.").
    • Relational Economic Loss , pp. 729
  • 424
    • 78149295086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perry
    • Perry, Economic Bias, supra note 3, at 1607-09.
    • Economic Bias , pp. 1607-1609
    • Perry1
  • 425
    • 78149306913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 299.
  • 426
    • 78149347328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The suggestion is not that wealth is a superior value to some other value such as welfare. The author punts this complex discourse to philosophers and economists.
  • 427
    • 0001347311 scopus 로고
    • Is Wealth a Value?
    • Compare, (arguing wealth maximization fails as a normative theory of social good)
    • Compare Ronald M. Dworkin, Is Wealth a Value?, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 191 (1980) (arguing wealth maximization fails as a normative theory of social good).
    • (1980) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.9 , pp. 191
    • Dworkin Ronald, M.1
  • 428
    • 0346808403 scopus 로고
    • Wealth Maximization as a Normative Principle
    • (arguing wealth maximization combines the problems of both utilitarianism and Pareto superiority)
    • and Anthony T. Kronman, Wealth Maximization as a Normative Principle, 9 J. LEGAL. STUD. 227 (1980) (arguing wealth maximization combines the problems of both utilitarianism and Pareto superiority).
    • (1980) J. LEGAL. STUD , vol.9 , pp. 227
    • Kronman Anthony, T.1
  • 429
    • 33646512584 scopus 로고
    • The Value of Wealth: A Comment on Dworkin and Kronman
    • (defending the normative usefulness of wealth maximization)
    • with Richard A. Posner, The Value of Wealth: A Comment on Dworkin and Kronman, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 243 (1980) (defending the normative usefulness of wealth maximization).
    • (1980) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.9
    • Posner Richard, A.1
  • 430
    • 78149289915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Consider for example the following passage from a public nuisance case involving fishermen's right to recover lost profit:
  • 431
    • 78149303607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We do not think this is merely to prevent the common shame of the extinction of an interesting type of river fauna in our time, or for the sole benefit of the owners of exclusive fisheries. In fact, perhaps the largest beneficiaries of these laws are those engaged in the business of fishing in common fisheries. The great fisheries on the Columbia River and of Alaska so conducted are so extensive that their products are found at one time or another on every table in the country.
  • 432
    • 78149317970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Hampton v. N.C. Pulp Co., 27 S.E. 538, 546 (N.C. 1943).
  • 433
    • 78149314220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KNIGHT
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 307.
  • 434
    • 78149346940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 350.
  • 435
    • 78149301623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Perry concedes that this exception is "inconsistent with my hypothesis."
  • 437
    • 78149306425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • But he also argues that the exception is "theoretically irrelevant."
  • 438
    • 78149339317 scopus 로고
    • Ames v. Union Ry
    • Ames v. Union Ry., 117 Mass. 541, 541 (1875)
    • (1875) , vol.117
  • 439
    • 78149351051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mattingly v. Sheldon Jackson Coll., 743 P.2d 356, 361-62 (Alaska 1987) (noting old common law rule allowing recovery to employers)
    • see also Mattingly v. Sheldon Jackson Coll., 743 P.2d 356, 361-62 (Alaska 1987) (noting old common law rule allowing recovery to employers).
  • 440
    • 78149331286 scopus 로고
    • Tullidge v. Wade, (K.B.)
    • Tullidge v. Wade, (1769) 95 Eng. Rep. 909, 909-10 (K.B.).
    • (1769) Eng. Rep. , vol.95 , Issue.909 , pp. 909-910
  • 441
    • 78149294706 scopus 로고
    • Liability to Master for Negligent Harm to Servant
    • Warren A. Seavey, Liability to Master for Negligent Harm to Servant, 1956 WASH. U. L.Q. 309, 310.
    • (1956) WASH. U. L.Q
    • Seavey Warren, A.1
  • 442
    • 78149339690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Chelsea Moving & Trucking Co. v. Ross Towboat Co., 182 N.E. 477 (Mass. 1932). See generally Seavey, supra note 266, at 310-11 (arguing contractual liability theories have overtaken property liability theories in master-servant relationships).
  • 443
    • 78149316503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Seavey, supra note 266, at 310 ("It is equally clear that a servant no longer regards himself as his master's man, but as an independent person who can bargain effectually. [T]he bond is primarily contractual with rights and duties in many cases spelled out in great detail.").
  • 444
    • 78149311855 scopus 로고
    • See Mattingly, 743 P.2d at 362 (Alaska)
    • See Mattingly, 743 P.2d at 362 (Alaska 1987)
    • (1987)
  • 445
    • 78149346078 scopus 로고
    • Phoenix Prof'l Hockey Club, Inc. v. Hirmer, 502 P.2d 164, (Ariz.)
    • Phoenix Prof'l Hockey Club, Inc. v. Hirmer, 502 P.2d 164, 164-65 (Ariz. 1972)
    • (1972) , pp. 164-165
  • 446
    • 78149312602 scopus 로고
    • Snow v. West, 440 P.2d
    • Snow v. West, 440 P.2d 864, 865 (Or. 1968)
    • (1968)
  • 447
    • 78149309071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Atiyah, supra note 4, at 271-73 (analyzing reasons why employer should not recover economic loss resulting from an em-ployee's injury)
  • 448
    • 78149316165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Seavey, supra note 266, at 311 ("The modern authority [permitting recovery], howev-er, is so slight as to be almost non-existent.").
  • 449
    • 78149313846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra Part III.A.
  • 450
    • 78149306426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 301-02 ("[T]he wages of labor are in fact generally a fair approx-imation to a guaranteed contractual return.").
  • 451
    • 78149318347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See generally Rhee, supra note 88 (proposing a principled basis of liability for negligent inflic-tion of emotional distress).
  • 452
    • 78149304010 scopus 로고
    • Union Oil Co. v. Oppen, 501 F.2d 558, 570 (9th Cir.)
    • Union Oil Co. v. Oppen, 501 F.2d 558, 570 (9th Cir. 1974).
    • (1974)
  • 453
    • 78149297456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Yarmouth Sea Prods. Ltd. v. Scully, 131 F.3d 389, 398 (4th Cir. 1997).
    • (1997)
  • 454
    • 78149343867 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Miller Indus. v. Caterpillar Tractor Co., 733 F.2d 813, 820 (11th Cir. 1984).
    • (1984)
  • 455
    • 78149337551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, a partner is not entitled to compensation for services performed for the partnership. UNIFORM PARTNERSHIP ACT § 401(h) (1997).
    • (1997)
  • 456
    • 78149325319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A mere interest in profit does not, however, create an ownership interest in an enterprise.
  • 457
    • 78149332030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Partnership Tax Allocations and the Inter-nalization of Tax-Item Transactions
    • note
    • See Bradley T. Borden, Partnership Tax Allocations and the Inter-nalization of Tax-Item Transactions, 59 S.C. L. REV. 297, 313 (2008) ("The payment from the property owner to the service provider will be compensation for services regardless of the mode of determining the amount of the compensation.")
    • (2008) S.C. L. REV , vol.59
    • Borden Bradley, T.1
  • 458
    • 84936194550 scopus 로고
    • The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration
    • note
    • Sanford J. Grossman & Oliver D. Hart, The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration, 94 J. POL. ECON. 691, 694 (1986) ("A firm may pay another firm or person by the piece or a fixed amount (salary), irrespective of the ownership of the machines.").
    • (1986) J. POL. ECON , vol.94
    • Grossman Sanford, J.1    Hart Oliver, D.2
  • 459
    • 78149290283 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Borcich v. Ancich, 191 F.2d 392, 393 (9th Cir. 1951) (noting action as "for wages and main-tenance"), overruled by Carbone v. Ursich, 209 F.2d 178 (9th Cir. 1953)
    • (1953)
  • 460
    • 78149351052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Goldberg, Recovery for Pure Economic Loss in Tort, supra note 6, at 274 ("[T]he fishermen's share is primarily compensation for la-bor not yet performed-that is, it is a substitute for future wages.").
  • 461
    • 78149317969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See HENRY HANSMANN, THE OWNERSHIP OF ENTERPRISE 11 (1996) ("A firm's 'owners'. are those persons who share two formal rights: the right to control the firm and the right to appropriate the firm's profits, or residual earnings.")
    • (1996) , vol.11
  • 462
    • 78149344595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • KNIGHT, supra note 28, at 280 ("That is, in a sense, the entre-preneur's income is not 'determined'at all; it is' what is left'after the others are 'determined.'").
  • 463
    • 78149305509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Yarmouth, 131 F.3d at 398 (distinguishing fishermen on "lay" agreements from salaried dredge workers).
  • 464
    • 78149303606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henderson v. Arundel Corp., 262 F. Supp. 152, 160 (D. Md. 1966), aff'd 384 F.2d 998 (4th Cir. 1967) (finding no exception for salaried dredge workers)
    • Henderson v. Arundel Corp., 262 F. Supp. 152, 160 (D. Md. 1966), aff'd 384 F.2d 998 (4th Cir. 1967) (finding no exception for salaried dredge workers)
  • 465
    • 78149315319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Casado v. Schooner Pilgrim, Inc., 171 F. Supp. 78, 79 (D. Mass. 1959) (providing no recovery for sailors who "had no actual contracts for sea duty").
  • 466
    • 78149296691 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Mair v. Wood, (1948) S.C. 83, 85 (1st Div. 1947) (Cooper, L.)
    • (1947)
  • 467
    • 78149304718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Parker v. Walker, 1961 S.L.T. 252, 254 (O.H.) (characterizing enterprise between ship owner and fishermen as a "joint adven-ture").
  • 468
    • 78149355573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Carbone, 209 F.2d at 179.
  • 469
    • 78149296338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Yarmouth Sea Prods. Ltd. v. Scully, 131 F.3d 389, 398 (4th Cir. 1997).
    • (1997)
  • 470
    • 78149299787 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Miller Indus. v. Caterpillar Tractor Co., 733 F.2d 813, 820 (11th Cir. 1984).
    • (1984)
  • 471
    • 78149347691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, in Carbone v. Ursich, the lay agreement gave the fishermen sixty-one percent of proceeds after specified expenses. 209 F.2d at 179.
  • 472
    • 78149294350 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 182
  • 473
    • 78149325318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Pruitt v. Allied Chem. Corp., 523 F. Supp. 975, 978 (E.D. Va. 1981) ("The entitlement given these fishermen presumably arises from what might be called a constructive property interest in the Bay's harvestable species.").
  • 474
    • 78149288690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Carbone, 209 F.2d at 180 & n.3 (citing Taber v. Jenny, 23 F. Cas. 605 (D. Mass. 1856) (No. 13,720)).
  • 475
    • 78149342809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taber, 23 F. Cas. at
    • Taber, 23 F. Cas. at 608-09.
  • 476
    • 78149343512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (emphasis added)
    • Id. at 608 (emphasis added).
  • 477
    • 78149310014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Subsequently in Robins, Holmes rejected the Second Circuit's use of a trust analogy to provide the plaintiff remedy against the defendant dry dock. See Robins Dry Dock & Repair Co. v. Flint, 275 U.S. 303, 309 (1927), rev'g The Bjornefjord, 271 F. 682 (2d Cir. 1921).
  • 478
    • 78149303250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Miller Indus. v. Caterpillar Tractor Co., 733 F.2d 813, 820 (11th Cir. 1984) (footnote omitted).
  • 479
    • 78149350157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Perry, Relational Economic Loss, supra note 10, at 786. Notwithstanding this observation, Perry argues that fishermen should not be allowed to recover for their loss because "no rational distinction can be made between the interests of fishermen and the interests of other victims (such as fish restaurants, bait shops, tourist guides, hotels, and other businesses in the area)."
  • 480
    • 78149302875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Union Oil Co. v. Oppen, 501 F.2d 558, 570 (9th Cir. 1974) (emphasis added).
  • 481
    • 78149329467 scopus 로고
    • Atiyah, supra note 4, at 256 n.26 (citing Parker v. Walker, S.L.T. 252 (O.H.)
    • Atiyah, supra note 4, at 256 n.26 (citing Parker v. Walker, (1961) S.L.T. 252 (O.H.)
    • (1961)
  • 482
    • 78149348089 scopus 로고
    • Mair v. Wood, S.C. 83 (1st Div. 1947)
    • Mair v. Wood, (1948) S.C. 83 (1st Div. 1947)
    • (1948)
  • 483
    • 78149314599 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Main v. Leask, (1910) S.C. 772 (2d Div.)). Atiyah disapproves of the outcome of these cases because they seem irreconcilable with the time charter cases like Robins. Id. As discussed, however, there is a significant difference between contractual arrangements to rent property, where risk and return are contractually fixed, and arrangements to form a business association, where business risk is allocated through a profit share arrangement among owners. See supra Part III.A.
    • (1910)
  • 484
    • 78149310370 scopus 로고
    • (1910) S.C. at 772.
    • (1910) , pp. 772
  • 485
    • 78149314219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 778-79 (Ardwall, L.) (emphasis added). This interpretation of the fishermen exception is also supported by the law of partnership, which provides a more accurate economic account than tort law's property-centric focus. A partnership is an independent economic entity distinct from its partners.
  • 486
    • 78149304009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • UNIFORM PARTNERSHIP ACT § 201(a) (1997). By sharing profit, fishermen are closer to partners in a joint venture than employees, independent contractors, or renters.
    • (1997)
  • 487
    • 78149317253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. § 101(6) (defining a partnership as "an association of two or more persons to carry on as co-owners a business for profit")
  • 488
    • 78149337907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also id. § 202(c)(3) ("A person who receives a share of the profits of a business is presumed to be a partner in the business."). Specifically, they resemble service partners. It is unclear whether the fishermen in these cases were partners for the purpose of partnership law, and the point may be speculative if the theory was not pursued, but the point is that economically the venture is owned by them.
  • 489
    • 78149338277 scopus 로고
    • Main, (1910) S.C. at 778-79.
    • (1910) , pp. 778-779
    • Main1
  • 490
    • 78149319448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oppen
    • Oppen, 501 F.2d at 570.
  • 491
    • 78149290998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Such disparity of economic outcome during a common venture has long been recognized by common law judges:
  • 492
    • 78149294349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The owner [of the ship] would at least get compensation to the extent of the value of his ship, with interest at 5 per cent from the date when she was lost; but the fishermen whom he employed on the footing that they were to share the profits of the fishing would not participate in that compensa-tion, and would, if the defenders'contention were well founded, get nothing at all except compen-sation for the loss of their personal effects.
  • 493
    • 78149336655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Burgess v. M/V Tamano, 370 F. Supp. 247, 250 (D. Me. 1973) (internal quotation marks omit-ted).
  • 494
    • 78149325685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
  • 495
    • 78149304008 scopus 로고
    • Columbia River Fishermen's Protective Union v. City of St. Helens, 87 P.2d
    • Columbia River Fishermen's Protective Union v. City of St. Helens, 87 P.2d 195, 197-98 (Or. 1939).
    • (1939)
  • 496
    • 78149304717 scopus 로고
    • See Masonite Corp. v. Steede, 23 So. 2d, (Miss)
    • See Masonite Corp. v. Steede, 23 So. 2d 756, 758 (Miss. 1945)
    • (1945)
  • 497
    • 78149314218 scopus 로고
    • Hampton v. N.C. Pulp Co., 27 S.E, (N.C.)
    • Hampton v. N.C. Pulp Co., 27 S.E. 538, 546 (N.C. 1943).
    • (1943)
  • 498
    • 78149329094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 269.
  • 499
    • 78149334466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Main, (1910) S.C. at 777 (Salvesen, L.) ("The ordinary crew of a trading vessel may have no difficulty in obtaining employment in other ships when the one in which they were engaged is sunk in a collision. ").
  • 500
    • 78149355572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Burgess v. Florence Nightingale Hosp., [1955] 1 Q.B
    • But see Burgess v. Florence Nightingale Hosp., [1955] 1 Q.B. 349, 357.
  • 501
    • 78149354065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • However, a business can protect itself through a key-person life insurance, and thus there are some ways in which this risk can be reduced.
  • 502
    • 78149322256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, in 532 Madison Avenue, the employees of the deli could not claim for economic loss against the negligent construction company because they may have been laid off. 750 N.E.2d 1097 (N.Y. 2001).
    • (2001)
  • 503
    • 78149332039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. MODEL BUS. CORP. ACT § 10.01(b) (2003) (providing that a shareholder "does not have a vested property right resulting from any provision in the articles of incorporation")
    • (2003)
  • 504
    • 78149333497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Grimes v. Donald, 673 A.2d 1207, 1213 (Del. 1996) (shareholders permitted to bring direct claims).
  • 505
    • 78149344223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • EASTERBROOK & FISCHEL, supra note 112, at 12
  • 506
    • 78149305147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Coase, supra note 164, at 390-91.
  • 507
    • 78149353359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 122(2)
    • DEL. CODE ANN. Tit , vol.8 , Issue.2 , pp. 122
  • 508
    • 78149319094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Bird v. Wilmington Soc'y of Fine Arts, 43 A.2d 476, 484 (Del. 1945) (corporation is distinct from its shareholders).
  • 509
    • 0347765234 scopus 로고
    • Defense of the Shareholder Wealth Maximization Norm: A Reply to Professor Green
    • note
    • See Stephen M. Bainbridge, In Defense of the Shareholder Wealth Maximization Norm: A Reply to Professor Green, 50 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 1423, 1428 (1993) (arguing that the "nexus of contracts" theory of the firm rejects the proposition that a corporation can be owned)
    • (1993) WASH. & LEE L. REV , vol.50
    • Bainbridge Stephen, M.1
  • 510
    • 0036655428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bad and Not-So-Bad Arguments for Shareholder Primacy
    • ("A lawyer would know that the shareholders do not, in fact, own the corporation.")
    • Lynn A. Stout, Bad and Not-So-Bad Arguments for Shareholder Primacy, 75 S. CAL. L. REV. 1189, 1191 (2002) ("A lawyer would know that the shareholders do not, in fact, own the corporation.")
    • (2002) S. CAL. L. REV , vol.75
    • Stout Lynn, A.1
  • 511
    • 77954191494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Specific Investment: Explaining Anomalies in Corporate Law
    • note
    • see also Margaret M. Blair & Lynn A. Stout, Specific Investment: Explaining Anomalies in Corporate Law, 31 J. CORP. L. 719, 728 (2006) ("The claim that shareholders are 'principals'and directors are' agents'contradicts the realities of cor-porate law.").
    • (2006) J. CORP. L , vol.31
    • Blair Margaret, M.1    Stout Lynn, A.2
  • 512
    • 0012872139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Essential Role of Organizational Law
    • generally
    • See generally Henry Hansmann & Reinier Kraakman, The Essential Role of Organizational Law, 110 YALE L.J. 387 (2000).
    • (2000) YALE L.J , vol.110 , pp. 387
    • Hansmann, H.1    Kraakman, R.2
  • 513
    • 78149302512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 266-267 and accompanying text.
  • 514
    • 78149351815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The loss of the Internet for a significant period may result mostly in a transfer payment for cer-tain activities such as selling books, which are sold through other distribution channels. However, since we do not expect the loss of the Internet (vis-à-vis ordinary use limitations) anytime soon, this hypothet-ical may perhaps be academic.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.