메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 6, Issue 3, 2010, Pages 521-594

Innovation spillovers and the "dirt road" Fallacy: The intellectual bankruptcy of banning optional transactions for enhanced delivery over the internet

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77956920105     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: 17446422     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhq003     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (18)

References (186)
  • 1
    • 0040927565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Internet Under Siege
    • Lawrence Lessig, The Internet Under Siege, 127 FOREIGN POL'Y 56, 56 (2001)
    • (2001) Foreign Pol'y , vol.127 , Issue.56 , pp. 56
    • Lessig, L.1
  • 3
    • 77956929052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congress Must Keep Broadband Competition Alive
    • Oct. 18
    • Lawrence Lessig, Congress Must Keep Broadband Competition Alive, FIN.TIMES, Oct. 18, 2006.
    • (2006) Fin. Times
    • Lessig, L.1
  • 4
    • 33846797209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • No Tolls on the Internet
    • June 8, at A23
    • Lawrence Lessig & Robert W. McChesney, No Tolls on the Internet, WASH. POST, June 8, 2006, at A23.
    • (2006) Wash. Post
    • Lessig, L.1    McChesney, R.W.2
  • 5
    • 77956939275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Net Neutrality, 109th Cong., 2d Sess. 59 (testimony of Lawrence Lessig), available at
    • Net Neutrality, Hearing before the Sen. Comm. on Commerce, Science, and Transportation, 109th Cong., 2d Sess. 59 (2006) (testimony of Lawrence Lessig), available at http://www.lessig.org/blog/archives/Lessig_Testimony_2.pdf.
    • (2006) Hearing before the Sen. Comm. on Commerce, Science, and Transportation
  • 6
    • 29244458515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Network Neutrality, Broadband Discrimination
    • Tim Wu, Network Neutrality, Broadband Discrimination, 2 J. TELECOMM. & HIGH TECH. L. 141 (2003).
    • (2003) J. Telecomm. & High Tech. L. , vol.2 , Issue.141
    • Wu, T.1
  • 7
    • 34548290442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Towards an Economic Framework for Network Neutrality Regulation
    • See Barbara van Schewick, Towards an Economic Framework for Network Neutrality Regulation, 5 J. TELECOMM. & HIGH TECH. L. 329 (2007).
    • (2007) J. Telecomm. & High Tech. L. , vol.5 , pp. 329
    • van Schewick, B.1
  • 8
    • 31744452370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond Network Neutrality
    • Christopher S. Yoo, Beyond Network Neutrality, 19 HARV. J.L. & TECH. 1 (2005).
    • (2005) Harv. J.L. & Tech. , vol.19 , pp. 1
    • Yoo, C.S.1
  • 9
    • 31844445493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Network Neutrality and the Economics of Congestion
    • Christopher S. Yoo, Network Neutrality and the Economics of Congestion,95 GEO. L.J. 1847 (2006).
    • (2006) Geo. L.J. , vol.95 , pp. 1847
    • Yoo, C.S.1
  • 10
    • 33846828281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Consumer-Welfare Approach to Network Neutrality Regulation of the Internet
    • 349, available at
    • See J. Gregory Sidak, A Consumer-Welfare Approach to Network Neutrality Regulation of the Internet, 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 349, 349 (2006), available at http://www.criterioneconomics.com/pdfs/A_Consumer_Welfare_Approach_to_Network_Neutrality_Regulation_of_the_Internet.pdf
    • (2006) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.2 , pp. 349
    • Gregory Sidak, J.1
  • 11
    • 77956908054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Net Neutrality, Hearing before the Sen. Comm. on Commerce, Science, and Transportation, 109th Cong., 2d Sess. 59 (2006) (testimony of J. Gregory Sidak) [hereinafter Sidak 2006 Senate Te s t i m o n y] (listing six essential characteristics of communications networks that rendered regulation unnecessary and likely harmful to investment and innovation incentives among network operators: the substantial sunk investments required to build networks, economies of scale, economies of scope, differential pricing, two-sided demand, and the susceptibility of networks to congestion)
  • 14
    • 77956918084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • ("It bears repeating that the stakeholders whose interests should weigh most heavily in the deliberations of policy makers are consumers, not any particular constituency of competitors.").
  • 15
    • 77956943128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Preserving the Open Internet; Broadband Industry Practices, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52, ¶¶ 60-80 (2009) [hereinafter Network Neutrality NPRM].
  • 18
    • 77956934757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FT.COM, Oct. 27, available at
    • See Richard A. Epstein, Net Neutrality at the Crossroads, FT.COM, Oct. 27, 2009, available at http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/d9611768-c310-11de-8eca-00144feab49a.html?nclick_check=1.
    • (2009) Net Neutrality at the Crossroads
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 20
    • 42449121926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hold Off on Net Neutrality
    • Jan. 19, at A19
    • David Farber & Michael Katz, Hold Off on Net Neutrality, WASH.POST, Jan. 19, 2007, at A19.
    • (2007) Wash. post
    • Farber, D.1    Katz, M.2
  • 21
    • 77956899668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Broadbandits
    • Aug. 12, at A9, available at
    • See Thomas W. Hazlett, Broadbandits, WALL ST. J., Aug. 12, 2006, at A9, available at http://online.wsj.com/article/SB115533922506533851-search.html.
    • (2006) Wall St. J.
    • Hazlett, T.W.1
  • 22
    • 63749124016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Network Neutrality and the False Promise of Zero-Price Regulation
    • See C. Scott Hemphill, Network Neutrality and the False Promise of Zero-Price Regulation, 25 YALE J. ON REG. 135 (2008).
    • (2008) Yale J. on Reg. , vol.25 , pp. 135
    • Scott Hemphill, C.1
  • 23
    • 77956894207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statement of Alfred E. Kahn, Robert Julius Thorne Professor of Political Economy
    • (delivered Feb. 13), (Feb. 21, 2007 rev.)
    • See Alfred E. Kahn, Statement of Alfred E. Kahn, Robert Julius Thorne Professor of Political Economy, Emeritus, Cornell University, before the FTC Workshop on Broadband Connectivity Competition Policy, (delivered Feb. 13, 2007), http://www.ftc.gov/opp/workshops/broadband/presentations/kahn.pdf (Feb. 21, 2007 rev.).
    • (2007) Emeritus, Cornell University, before the FTC Workshop on Broadband Connectivity Competition Policy
    • Kahn, A.E.1
  • 25
    • 77956910655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Father of the Internet Warns Against Net Neutrality
    • Jan. 18, (last visited Mar. 10, 2010) ("Robert Kahn, the most senior figure in the development of the internet, has delivered a strong warning against 'Net Neutrality' legislation")
    • see also Andrew Orlowski, Father of the Internet Warns Against Net Neutrality, THE REGISTER, Jan. 18, 2007, http://www.theregister.co.uk/2007/01/18/kahn_net_neutrality_warning/ (last visited Mar. 10, 2010) ("Robert Kahn, the most senior figure in the development of the internet, has delivered a strong warning against 'Net Neutrality' legislation.").
    • (2007) The register
    • Orlowski, A.1
  • 26
    • 77956945538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52 (filed with the FCC on behalf of Verizon Jan. 14)
    • See Michael L. Katz, Maximizing Consumer Benefits from Broadband, GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52 (filed with the FCC on behalf of Verizon Jan. 14, 2010).
    • (2010) Maximizing Consumer Benefits from Broadband
    • Katz, M.L.1
  • 27
    • 70249116113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antecedents to Net Neutrality
    • See Bruce M. Owen, Antecedents to Net Neutrality, 30 REG. 14 (2007).
    • (2007) Reg , vol.30 , pp. 14
    • Owen, B.M.1
  • 28
    • 58149331588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Local Broadband Access: Primum Non Nocere or Primum Processi? A Property Rights Approach
    • (Thomas M. Lenard & Randolph J. May eds)
    • Bruce M. Owen & Gregory L. Rosston, Local Broadband Access: Primum Non Nocere or Primum Processi? A Property Rights Approach, in NET NEUTRALITY OR NET NEUTERING: SHOULD BROADBAND INTERNET SERVICES BE REGULATED? 163 (Thomas M. Lenard & Randolph J. May eds., 2006).
    • (2006) Net Neutrality or Net Neutering: should Broadband Internet Services be Regulated? , vol.163
    • Owen, B.M.1    Rosston, G.L.2
  • 29
    • 77956912782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Antitrust Analysis of the Case for Wireless Network Neutrality
    • Discussion Paper No. 08-040, July
    • See Gregory L. Rosston & Michael D. Topper, An Antitrust Analysis of the Case for Wireless Network Neutrality (Stanford Inst. for Econ. Policy Research, Discussion Paper No. 08-040, July 2009)
    • (2009) Stanford Inst. for Econ. Policy Research
    • Rosston, G.L.1    Topper, M.D.2
  • 30
    • 77956905292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Declaration of Marius Schwartz, In the Matter of Preserving the Open Internet, Broadband Industry Practices, GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52 (filed with the FCC on behalf of AT&T Jan. 14) [hereinafter Schwartz Declaration]
    • See Declaration of Marius Schwartz, In the Matter of Preserving the Open Internet, Broadband Industry Practices, GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52 (filed with the FCC on behalf of AT&T Jan. 14, 2010) [hereinafter Schwartz Declaration].
    • (2010)
  • 32
    • 33846682514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comments on Network Neutrality
    • This list is only partial
    • See Leonard Waverman, Comments on Network Neutrality, 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON 475 (2006). This list is only partial.
    • (2006) J. Competition L. & Econ , vol.2 , pp. 475
    • Waverman, L.1
  • 33
    • 77956897348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52 (filed with the FCC on behalf of Verizon Jan. 14)
    • See, e.g., Michael D. Topper, Broadband Competition and Network Neutrality Regulation, GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52 (filed with the FCC on behalf of Verizon Jan. 14, 2010)
    • (2010) Broadband Competition and Network Neutrality Regulation
    • Topper, M.D.1
  • 34
    • 77956899946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • available at, (last visited Mar. 10, 2010)
    • Gerald Faulhaber, David Farber, Michael Katz & Christopher Yoo, Common Sense on Net Neutrality (2006), available at http://www.interesting-people.org/archives/interesting-people/200606/msg00014.html (last visited Mar. 10, 2010)
    • (2006) Common Sense on Net Neutrality
    • Faulhaber, G.1    Farber, D.2    Katz, M.3    Yoo, C.4
  • 35
    • 77956892535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spreading the Broadband Revolution
    • Oct. 21, at A13
    • William E. Kennard, Spreading the Broadband Revolution, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 21, 2006, at A13.
    • (2006) N.Y. Times
    • Kennard, W.E.1
  • 36
    • 77956906890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Net Neutrality Debate Sets Out a False Choice
    • June 12, 2006, available at, (last visited Mar. 10)
    • Robert Pepper, Net Neutrality Debate Sets Out a False Choice, NETWORK WORLD, June 12, 2006, available at http://www.networkworld.com/columnists/2006/061206-net-neutrality-no.html (last visited Mar. 10, 2010).
    • (2010) Network World
    • Pepper, R.1
  • 37
    • 77956941363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Faulhaber and Farber observe that, "during ten years of experience without network neutrality regulations, there are just two incidents (the tiresomely familiar Madison River and Comcast cases) of any actual misbehavior by broadband ISPs."
  • 39
    • 65049089532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Benefits and Risks of Mandating Network Neutrality, and the Quest for a Balanced Policy
    • See, e.g., Jon M. Peha, The Benefits and Risks of Mandating Network Neutrality, and the Quest for a Balanced Policy,1 INT'L J. COMM. 644 (2007).
    • (2007) Int'l J. comm. , vol.1 , pp. 644
    • Peha, J.M.1
  • 40
    • 76349105744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Network Neutrality: Regulating with More Questions than Answers
    • Howard A. Shelanksi, Network Neutrality: Regulating with More Questions than Answers,6J.TELECOMM.&HIGH TECH. L. 23 (2007).
    • (2007) J. Telecomm. & High Tech. L. , vol.6 , pp. 23
    • Shelanksi, H.A.1
  • 41
    • 27744476355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Modularity, Vertical Integration, and Open Access Policies: Towards a Convergence of Antitrust and Regulation in the Internet Age
    • Joseph Farrell & Phil Weiser, Modularity, Vertical Integration, and Open Access Policies: Towards a Convergence of Antitrust and Regulation in the Internet Age, 17 HARV. J.L. & TECH. 85 (2003).
    • (2003) Harv. J.L. & Tech. , vol.17 , pp. 85
    • Farrell, J.1    Weiser, P.2
  • 42
    • 75749131593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Subsidizing Creativity Through Network Design: Zero Pricing and Net Neutrality
    • ("network management and quality of service inherently requires some form of packet discrimination or content co-location, and are practices with which we do not necessarily take issue")
    • See, e.g., Robin S. Lee & Tim Wu, Subsidizing Creativity Through Network Design: Zero Pricing and Net Neutrality, 23 J. ECON.PERSP. 61, 73-74 (2009) ("network management and quality of service inherently requires some form of packet discrimination or content co-location, and are practices with which we do not necessarily take issue").
    • (2009) J. Econ.Persp. , vol.23 , Issue.61 , pp. 73-74
    • Lee, R.S.1    Wu, T.2
  • 43
    • 77956923430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dkt. 07-52 (Apr. 17, 2008) (testimony of Lawrence Lessig), available at Testifying @ FCC @ Stanford, Lessig Blog (posted Apr. 18), [hereinafter Lessig 2008 FCC Testimony]
    • Second En Banc Hearing on Broadband Network Management Practices before the FCC, Dkt. 07-52 (Apr. 17, 2008) (testimony of Lawrence Lessig), available at Testifying @ FCC @ Stanford, Lessig Blog (posted Apr. 18, 2008), http://lessig.org/blog/2008/04/testifying_fcc_stanford. html [hereinafter Lessig 2008 FCC Testimony].
    • (2008) Second En Banc Hearing on Broadband Network Management Practices before the FCC
  • 44
    • 77956941288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • FCC, Policy Statement, Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet over Wireline Facilities, CC Dkt. No. 02-33, Review of Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broadband Telecommunications Services, CC Dkt. No. 01-337, Computer III Further Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review-Review of Computer III and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, CC Dkt. Nos. 95-20, 98-10, Inquiry Concerning High-Speed Access to the Internet over Cable and Other Facilities, Internet over Cable Declaratory Ruling, GN Dkt. No. 00-185, Appropriate Regulatory Treatment for Broadband Access to the Internet over Cable Facilities, CS Dkt. No. 02-52, 20 F.C.C. Rcd. 14,986 ¶ 4 (2005).
  • 45
    • 77956918634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Seeking to "encourage broadband deployment and preserve and promote the open and interconnected nature of the public Internet," the FCC declared that consumers possess entitlements "to access the lawful Internet content of their choice," "to run applications and use services of their choice, subject to the needs of law enforcement," "to connect their choice of legal devices that do not harm the network," and to benefit from "competition among network providers, application and service providers, and content providers."
  • 46
    • 77956908610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • But see Comcast Corp. v. FCC, No. 08-1291 (D.C. Cir. Apr. 6, 2010) (depriving FCC of authority to enforce Internet policy statement).
  • 47
    • 77956936874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The "nondiscrimination" rule can best be regarded as a "no priority access fee" rule. Nevertheless, in what follows, we will use the FCC's "nondiscrimination" language.
  • 48
    • 77956908323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Nicholas Economides, Why Imposing New Tolls on Third-Party Content and Applications Threatens Innovation and Will Not Improve Broadband Providers' Investments, GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52 (filed with the FCC on behalf of Google Jan. 14, 2010) [hereinafter Economides, Imposing New Tolls on Third-Party Content].
  • 49
    • 77956927396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Christiaan Hogendorn, Spillovers and Network Neutrality, GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52 (filed with the FCC on behalf of Google Jan. 2010).
  • 52
    • 14844352207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deploying Diffserv in Backbone Networks for Tight SLA Control
    • (Jan.-Feb)
    • see also Clarence Filsfils & John Evans, Deploying Diffserv in Backbone Networks for Tight SLA Control, IEEE INTERNET COMPUTING 58 (Jan.-Feb. 2005).
    • (2005) IEEE Internet Computing , vol.58
    • Filsfils, C.1    Evans, J.2
  • 53
    • 0016059991 scopus 로고
    • A Protocol for Packet Network Intercommunication
    • Vinton G. Cerf & Robert E. Kahn, A Protocol for Packet Network Intercommunication, 22 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON COMM. 637 (1974).
    • (1974) IEEE Transactions on Comm , vol.22 , pp. 637
    • Cerf, V.G.1    Kahn, R.E.2
  • 54
    • 77956915783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • IBM Global Technologies, (Oct.), available at
    • IBM Global Technologies, Business Benefits of Converged Communications (Oct. 2006), available at http://www-935.ibm.com/services/uk/igs/pdf/converged-communications-pov_ 0906.pdf.
    • (2006) Business Benefits of Converged Communications
  • 55
    • 77956907169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comments of Google Inc., GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52, at 35 (filed with the FCC Jan. 14) [hereinafter Google Comments]
    • Comments of Google Inc., In the Matter of Preserving the Open Internet, Broadband Industry Practices, GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52, at 35 (filed with the FCC Jan. 14, 2010) [hereinafter Google Comments].
    • (2010) In the Matter of Preserving the Open Internet, Broadband Industry Practices
  • 56
    • 77956941287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • IEEE, Dec. 2008, available at, (last visited Mar. 11)
    • See, e.g., A Fairer Faster Internet Protocol, IEEE, Dec. 2008, available at http://spectrum.ieee.org/telecom/standards/a-fairer-faster-internet-protocol (last visited Mar. 11, 2010).
    • (2010) A Fairer Faster Internet Protocol
  • 57
    • 0001073135 scopus 로고
    • The Use of Knowledge in Society
    • Friedrich A. Hayek, The Use of Knowledge in Society, 35 AM. ECON. REV. 519 (1945).
    • (1945) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.35 , pp. 519
    • Hayek, F.A.1
  • 58
    • 77956929345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • One example of enhanced end-to-end delivery is virtual private networks (VPN) service, which businesses commonly use to enable employees to connect to the enterprise's network from offsite
  • 59
    • 77956898246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Connect:Direct® Over a VPN Connection, AT&T Virtual Private Networks
    • See, e.g., Connect:Direct® Over a VPN Connection, http://www22.verizon.com/wholesale/lsp/connguide/1,5133,4-East-Billing-dialup,00.html; AT&T Virtual Private Networks, http://www.business.att.com/enterprise/Portfolio/vpn-services-enterprise/.
  • 60
    • 77956179642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FCC, [hereinafter National Broadband Plan] ("Networks, devices and applications drive each other in a virtuous cycle. If networks are fast, reliable and widely available, companies produce more powerful, more capable devices to connect to those networks. These devices, in turn, encourage innovators and entrepreneurs to develop exciting applications and content. These new applications draw interest among end users, bring new users online and increase use among those who already subscribe to broadband services. This growth in the broadband ecosystem reinforces the cycle, encouraging service providers to boost the speed, functionality and reach of their networks")
    • See FCC, CONNECTING AMERICA: THE NATIONAL BROADBAND PLAN 15 (2010) [hereinafter NATIONAL BROADBAND PLAN] ("Networks, devices and applications drive each other in a virtuous cycle. If networks are fast, reliable and widely available, companies produce more powerful, more capable devices to connect to those networks. These devices, in turn, encourage innovators and entrepreneurs to develop exciting applications and content. These new applications draw interest among end users, bring new users online and increase use among those who already subscribe to broadband services. This growth in the broadband ecosystem reinforces the cycle, encouraging service providers to boost the speed, functionality and reach of their networks.").
    • (2010) Connecting America: The National Broadband Plan , vol.15
  • 61
    • 77956932420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The FCC may be proposing to allow ISPs to provide CDN-like QoS services to content providers. If so, clarification of that policy, together with a clear explanation of why prioritized or enhanced delivery by an ISP should be treated differently, would be welcome.
  • 62
    • 77956914487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Comments of the Ass'n for Competitive Tech., In the Matter of Preserving the Open Internet, Broadband Industry Practices, GN Dkt. No. 09-191, WC Dkt. No. 07-52, at 13-20 (filed with the FCC Jan. 14, 2010) [hereinafter ACT Comments].
  • 63
    • 77956918369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • About ACT, ACT
    • About ACT, ACT, http://www.actonline.org/na/about/.
  • 64
    • 77956915479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • These business models are often called "freemium business models."
  • 65
    • 77952581340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Business Models, Business Strategy and Innovation
    • 178
    • See David J. Teece, Business Models, Business Strategy and Innovation, 43 LONG RANGE PLANNING 172, 178 (2010).
    • (2010) Long Range Planning , vol.43 , pp. 172
    • Teece, D.J.1
  • 66
    • 77956935884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Although large content and applications developers can purchase local caching services such as those provided by Akamai to enhance their applications' QoS, many small developers may lack the scale to purchase such services efficiently or may prefer the functionalities that ISPs could offer
  • 67
    • 77956944475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Morgan Reed, Executive Director, Ass'n for Competitive Tech., Statements at the Information Technology & Innovation Foundation Panel Discussion, Preserving the Open Internet: Is a Consensus Emerging? (Feb. 23), available at
    • See Morgan Reed, Executive Director, Ass'n for Competitive Tech., Statements at the Information Technology & Innovation Foundation Panel Discussion, Preserving the Open Internet: Is a Consensus Emerging? (Feb. 23, 2010), available at http://www.itif.org/index.php?id=335.
    • (2010)
  • 68
    • 0042844539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Persistent Heterogeneity and Sustainable Innovation
    • See, e.g., Anne Marie Knott, Persistent Heterogeneity and Sustainable Innovation, 24 STRATEGIC MGMT. J. 687 (2003).
    • (2003) Strategic MGMT. J. , vol.24 , pp. 687
    • Knott, A.M.1
  • 69
    • 0035351895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demand Heterogeneity and Technology Evolution: Implications for Product and Process Innovation
    • 612
    • See, e.g., Ron Adner & Daniel Levinthal, Demand Heterogeneity and Technology Evolution: Implications for Product and Process Innovation, 47 MGMT.SCI. 611, 612 (2001) (concluding that "[i]n a heterogeneous demand environment, early technological development is motivated by the drive to meet market requirements").
    • (2001) MGMT. Sci. , vol.47 , pp. 611
    • Adner, R.1    Levinthal, D.2
  • 70
    • 77956938016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The "long tail" is the concept that businesses target multiple niche markets instead of trying to achieve a few mass-market hits
  • 72
    • 33746659458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From Niches to Riches: Anatomy of the Long Tail
    • Erik Brynjolfsson, Yu Jeffrey Hu & Michael D. Smith, From Niches to Riches: Anatomy of the Long Tail, 47 MIT SLOAN MGMT. REV. 66 (2006).
    • (2006) MIT Sloan MGMT. Rev. , vol.47 , pp. 66
    • Brynjolfsson, E.1    Hu, Y.J.2    Smith, M.D.3
  • 73
    • 77956941647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Pareto efficient outcome is one resulting in an "[a]llocation of goods in which no one can be made better off unless someone else is made worse off." (6th ed)
    • A Pareto efficient outcome is one resulting in an "[a]llocation of goods in which no one can be made better off unless someone else is made worse off." ROBERT S. PINDYCK &DANIEL L. RUBINFELD, MICROECONOMICS 584 (6th ed. 2005).
    • (2005) Microeconomics , vol.584
    • Pindyck, R.S.1    Rubinfeld, D.L.2
  • 74
    • 33846819331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Platform Markets
    • See, e.g., David S. Evans, The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Platform Markets, 20 YALE J. on REG. 325 (2003).
    • (2003) Yale J. on Reg. , vol.20
    • Evans, D.S.1
  • 75
    • 1942479042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets
    • Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 4 J. EUR. ECON. ASS'N 990 (2003).
    • (2003) J. Eur. Econ. Ass'n , vol.4 , pp. 990
    • Rochet, J.-C.1    Tirole, J.2
  • 76
    • 84878850517 scopus 로고
    • Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and Economic Perspectives
    • The seminal article on two-sided markets is
    • The seminal article on two-sided markets is William F. Baxter, Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and Economic Perspectives, 26 J.L. & ECON. 541 (1983).
    • (1983) J.L. & Econ. , vol.26 , pp. 541
    • Baxter, W.F.1
  • 77
    • 77956898245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Dep't of Justice, Yahoo! Inc. and Google Inc. Abandon Their Advertising Agreement (Nov. 5), (reporting Google's 70 percent market share in both the Internet search advertising and Internet search syndication markets)
    • See Press Release, Dep't of Justice, Yahoo! Inc. and Google Inc. Abandon Their Advertising Agreement (Nov. 5, 2008), http://www.justice.gov/opa/pr/2008/November/08-at-981.html (reporting Google's 70 percent market share in both the Internet search advertising and Internet search syndication markets)
    • (2008)
  • 78
    • 77956932707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Yahoo!, Yahoo! and Microsoft to Implement Search Alliance (Feb. 18), As of December 2009, Google had 67.3 percent of the Internet search market, compared with 65.4 percent in November 2009. Don Reisinger, Google Rules Search in December
    • Press Release, Yahoo!, Yahoo! and Microsoft to Implement Search Alliance (Feb. 18, 2010), http://finance.yahoo.com/news/Yahoo-and-Microsoft-to-bw-2356666634.html?x=0. As of December 2009, Google had 67.3 percent of the Internet search market, compared with 65.4 percent in November 2009. Don Reisinger, Google Rules Search in December
    • (2010)
  • 79
    • 77956919494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bing Drops, CNET News, Jan. 13, (citing The Nielson Company)
    • Bing Drops, CNET NEWS, Jan. 13, 2010, http://news.cnet.com/8301-13506_3-10434099-17.html (citing The Nielson Company).
    • (2010)
  • 80
    • 77956894731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Spillovers, known more generally in economics as externalities, are benefits (or detriments) that accrue as unpriced side effects of other actions of an individual or firm. Spillovers are ubiquitous. For example, a beekeeper who keeps bees for their honey confers an external benefit on nearby farmers because the bees pollinate the surrounding crops. The farmer does not pay the beekeeper, but nonetheless benefits from the presence of his bees-thus, the beekeeper is the source of a positive spillover.
  • 81
    • 0006778780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (3d, The McGraw Hill Companies, Inc)
    • MICHAEL L. KATZ & HARVEY S. ROSEN, MICROECONOMICS 398 (3d, The McGraw Hill Companies, Inc., 1998).
    • (1998) Microeconomics , vol.398
    • Katz, M.L.1    Rosen, H.S.2
  • 82
    • 77956910654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • We note also that the redistribution alternative is a taking of private property for what is ostensibly, but not obviously, a public purpose. Consequently, it raises a Fifth Amendment question of whether the taking is made with or without just compensation.
  • 83
    • 77956904498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See U.S. CONST., amend. V.
  • 86
    • 77956906428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Room, (last visited Feb. 16)
    • Press Room, Facebook Factsheet, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/press/info.php?timeline#!/press/info.php?factsheet (last visited Feb. 16, 2010).
    • (2010) Facebook Factsheet, Facebook
  • 87
    • 77956927395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • TM Report, Data: Thomson Reuters (Jan. 22), available at
    • TM REPORT, DATA: THOMSON REUTERS (Jan. 22, 2010), available at http://www.nvca.org/index.php?option=com_docman&task=cat_view&gid=57&Itemid=317.
    • (2010)
  • 88
    • 0034553083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Assessing the Contribution of Venture Capital to Innovation
    • Samuel Kortum & Josh Lerner, Assessing the Contribution of Venture Capital to Innovation, 31 RAND J. ECON. 674 (2000).
    • (2000) Rand J. Econ. , vol.31 , pp. 674
    • Kortum, S.1    Lerner, J.2
  • 89
    • 77956894461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PricewaterhouseCoopers/National Venture Capital Ass'n, Investment by Industry Q1 1995-Q4 2009, (Jan. 22), available at
    • TM REPORT, DATA: THOMSON REUTERS (Jan. 22, 2010), available at http://www.nvca.org/index.php?option=com_docman&task=cat_view&gid=57&Itemid=317.
    • (2010) TM Report, Data: Thomson Reuters
  • 90
    • 84963082747 scopus 로고
    • The General Theory of the Second Best
    • See R.G. Lipsey & Kelvin Lancaster, The General Theory of the Second Best, 24 REV. ECON. STUD. 11 (1956).
    • (1956) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.24 , pp. 11
    • Lipsey, R.G.1    Lancaster, K.2
  • 92
    • 77956909207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • (emphasis added). Although the authors have attempted to excuse network neutrality from the implications of their findings, their arguments are unpersuasive. Dismissing spillover benefits from network infrastructure innovation as "not known or even knowable," and claiming that optional QoS transactions would reduce innovation on the content side and that "application-level innovation may be more important than encouraging additional innovation in the network itself.".
  • 93
    • 77956929625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See GOOGLE INC., ANNUAL REPORT (FORM 10-K), at 35 item 6 (Feb. 12, 2010), available at http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1288776/000119312510030774/d10k.htm [hereinafter GOOGLE FORM 10-K 2009] (reporting $23.7 billion in revenues for the year ending December 31, 2009). Advertising revenues constituted 99 percent of Google's revenues in 2007, and 97 percent in 2008 and 2009
  • 94
    • 77956910947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • (reporting $2.8 billion in R&D costs in 2009, up from $0.6 billion in 2005)
  • 95
    • 77956927983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • GOOGLE INC., REGISTRATION STATEMENT (FORM S-1), at 64 (Apr. 29, 2004), available at http://www. sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1288776/000119312504073639/ds1.htm (last visited Feb. 22, 2010) ("We strive to hire the best computer scientists and engineers to help us solve very significant challenges across systems design, artificial intelligence, machine learning, data mining, networking, software engineering, testing, distributed systems, cluster design and other areas. We work hard to provide an environment where these talented people can have fulfilling jobs.... We employ technology whenever possible to increase the efficiency of our business and to improve the experience we offer our users.").
  • 98
    • 77956916330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Northwestern Law & Economics Research Paper No. 03-16) ("those with the most extensive demands will if necessary pay for so much of it that those with less extensive demands lose interest in having more. Those with inframarginal demands value the good-perhaps they enjoy few things more keenly-but they are satiated before their preferences have any impact on optimal provision.") (citations omitted)
    • See David D. Haddock, Irrelevant Internalities, Irrelevant Externalities, and Irrelevant Anxieties 1, 20 (Northwestern Law & Economics Research Paper No. 03-16, 2003) ("those with the most extensive demands will if necessary pay for so much of it that those with less extensive demands lose interest in having more. Those with inframarginal demands value the good-perhaps they enjoy few things more keenly-but they are satiated before their preferences have any impact on optimal provision.") (citations omitted).
    • (2003) Irrelevant Internalities, Irrelevant Externalities, and Irrelevant Anxieties , vol.1 , pp. 20
    • Haddock, D.D.1
  • 99
    • 77956893914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Efficiency Risks of Network Neutrality Rules
    • available at, (last visited Mar. 25, 2010)
    • George S. Ford, Thomas Koutsky & Lawrence J. Spiwak, The Efficiency Risks of Network Neutrality Rules 4 (Phoenix Center Policy Bull. No. 16, 2006), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=925347&download=yes (last visited Mar. 25, 2010).
    • (2006) Phoenix Center Policy Bull , vol.4 , Issue.16
    • Ford, G.S.1    Koutsky, T.2    Spiwak, L.J.3
  • 100
    • 73049099380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Broadband Internet Access
    • Daniel F. Spulber & Christopher S. Yoo, Rethinking Broadband Internet Access, 22 HARV. J.L. & TECH. 1, 52 (2008).
    • (2008) Harv. J.L. & Tech. , vol.22 , Issue.1 , pp. 52
    • Spulber, D.F.1    Yoo, C.S.2
  • 101
    • 77956897614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See John Horrigan, Home Broadband Adoption 2009, PEW INTERNET &AMERICAN LIFE PROJECT 7 (32 percent of American dial-up users said that broadband prices would have to fall for them to switch to broadband; 20 percent said nothing would get them to switch; 17 percent cited availability as the obstacle to switching, 16 percent said they did not know what would get them to switch; and 13 percent cited some other reason)
  • 102
    • 0347722915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cyberjam: The Law and Economics of Internet Congestion of the Telephone Network
    • J. Gregory Sidak & Daniel F. Spulber, Cyberjam: The Law and Economics of Internet Congestion of the Telephone Network, 21 HARV. J. L. & PUB.POL'Y 327 (1998).
    • (1998) Harv. J. L. & Pub.Pol'y , vol.21 , pp. 327
    • Gregory Sidak, J.1    Spulber, D.F.2
  • 103
    • 77956940086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Apple Inc., iPhone 3G on Sale Tomorrow (July 10, 2008), (last visited Mar. 26)
    • Press Release, Apple Inc., iPhone 3G on Sale Tomorrow (July 10, 2008), http://www.apple.com/pr/library/2008/07/10iphone.html (last visited Mar. 26, 2010).
    • (2010)
  • 104
    • 77956923168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Apple Inc., Apple's App Store Downloads Top 1.5 Billion in First Year (July 14)
    • Press Release, Apple Inc., Apple's App Store Downloads Top 1.5 Billion in First Year (July 14, 2008), http://www.apple.com/pr/library/2009/07/14apps.html.
    • (2008)
  • 105
    • 77956902510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Press Release, Apple Inc., iPad Available in U.S. on April 3 (Mar. 5, 2010), (last visited Mar. 22)
    • See Press Release, Apple Inc., iPad Available in U.S. on April 3 (Mar. 5, 2010), http://www.apple.com/pr/library/2010/03/05ipad.html (last visited Mar. 22, 2010).
    • (2010)
  • 106
    • 77956897347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Hogendorn argues that network operators would "block or degrade certain services in violation of ICE" because: (1) they seek to "charge different prices to different customers in order to increase profits;" (2) they want to "make it harder for other firms to enter the market;" (3) "there may be bargaining problems that prevent internalization;" (4) "firms may not fully realize the benefits of all externalities;" or (5) "if Internet applications have other spillover benefits, it may make it easier to capture (but in the process reduce) those spillovers."
  • 108
    • 0038320372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The New Economy and Ubiquitous Competitive Price Discrimination: Identifying Defensible Criteria of Market Power
    • 662
    • See William J. Baumol & Daniel G. Swanson, The New Economy and Ubiquitous Competitive Price Discrimination: Identifying Defensible Criteria of Market Power, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 661, 662 (2003).
    • (2003) Antitrust L.J. , vol.70 , pp. 661
    • Baumol, W.J.1    Swanson, D.G.2
  • 109
    • 85022000243 scopus 로고
    • Price Discrimination and Social Welfare
    • See also Hal R. Varian, Price Discrimination and Social Welfare, 75 AM. ECON. REV. 870 (1985).
    • (1985) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 870
    • Varian, H.R.1
  • 110
    • 0000381850 scopus 로고
    • Price Discrimination
    • 599. (Richard Schmalensee & Robert Willig, eds., Elsevier Science Publishers B.V)
    • Hal R. Varian, Price Discrimination, in HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 597, 599 (Richard Schmalensee & Robert Willig, eds., Elsevier Science Publishers B.V. 1989).
    • (1989) Handbook of Industrial Organization , pp. 597
    • Varian, H.R.1
  • 111
    • 0001104079 scopus 로고
    • Output and Welfare Implications of Monopolistic Third-Degree Price Discrimination
    • See also Richard Schmalensee, Output and Welfare Implications of Monopolistic Third-Degree Price Discrimination, 71 AM. ECON. REV. 242 (1981).
    • (1981) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 242
    • Schmalensee, R.1
  • 112
    • 0011421429 scopus 로고
    • Third-Degree Price Discrimination and Output: Generalizing a Welfare Result
    • Marius Schwartz, Third-Degree Price Discrimination and Output: Generalizing a Welfare Result, 80 AM. ECON. REV. 1259 (1990).
    • (1990) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 1259
    • Schwartz, M.1
  • 113
    • 77956896801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Farrell and Weiser cite Microsoft-which "exposes many of its application programming interfaces (APIs) to independent developers, spending money and resources to cooperate with complementary (applications) providers"-and Intel as examples
  • 114
    • 0035583308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal-Why Aspen and Kodak Are Misguided
    • 667
    • Dennis W. Carlton, A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal-Why Aspen and Kodak Are Misguided, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 659, 667 (2001).
    • (2001) Antitrust L.J. , vol.68 , pp. 659
    • Carlton, D.W.1
  • 115
    • 77956892244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Madison River Commc'n, L.L.C. and Affiliated Companies, 4, 295 (Enforcement Bureau, Mar. 3)
    • In re Madison River Commc'n, L.L.C. and Affiliated Companies, 20 F.C.C. Rcd. 4, 295 (Enforcement Bureau, Mar. 3, 2005).
    • (2005) F.C.C. Rcd. , vol.20
  • 116
    • 77956940085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • In re Formal Complaint of Free Press and Public Knowledge Against Comcast Corporation for Secretly Degrading Peer-to-Peer Applications, Broadband Industry Practices Petition of Free Press et al. for Declaratory Ruling that Degrading an Internet Application Violates the FCC's Internet Policy Statement and Does Not Meet an Exception for "Reasonable Network Management," 23 F.C.C. Rcd. 13,028 (2008), vacated, Comcast Corp. v. FCC, No. 08-1291 (D.C. Cir. Apr. 6, 2010).
  • 117
    • 77956922876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • It is important to recognize that all regulation is costly-both in terms of the direct costs of enforcement and in terms of the potentially damaging effects on incentives to invest and innovate. Daniel Spulber and Christopher Yoo observe that government-imposed solutions often fall short of efficient outcomes, even when they are implemented to correct a market failure.
  • 118
    • 77956915313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Not only can a regulatory access regime harm allocative efficiency if access prices are set at inefficient levels, regulation can also harm dynamic efficiency by causing investment incentives to fall below efficient levels and by creating de facto entry barriers
  • 119
    • 31844436631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Network Regulation: The Many Faces of Access
    • 675
    • Daniel F. Spulber & Christopher S. Yoo, Network Regulation: The Many Faces of Access,1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 635, 675 (2005).
    • (2005) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.1 , pp. 635
    • Spulber, D.F.1    Yoo, C.S.2
  • 120
    • 77956920639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Fox TV Stations, Inc. v. FCC, 280 F.3d 1027, 1051 (D.C. Cir. 2002), in which it addressed the FCC's proposal to institute new nondiscrimination regulation for cable, the D.C. Circuit Court said: "[T]he Commission has not shown a substantial enough probability of discrimination to deem reasonable a prophylactic rule as broad as the cross-ownership ban, especially in light of the already extant conduct rules.
  • 121
    • 77956901155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • A single incident since the must-carry rules were promulgated-and one that seems to have been dealt with adequately under those rules-is just not enough to suggest an otherwise significant problem."
  • 122
    • 77956943949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Craig Moffett et al., Bernstein Research, Broadband: Are We Reaching Saturation?, at 4, at exhibit 2 (reporting monthly churn rates for cable broadband at 2.4 to 3 percent).
  • 123
    • 77956921758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Contrary to the claims of some, in industries with a large proportion of fixed costs, supramarginal cost pricing does not indicate any market failure or the presence of market power
  • 124
    • 85048160949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Power in U.S. Broadband Services
    • Paper Series No. 09-69, Nov)
    • Thomas W. Hazlett & Dennis L. Weisman, Market Power in U.S. Broadband Services 8 (Geo. Mason U. Law and Econ. Research Paper Series No. 09-69, Nov. 2009).
    • (2009) Geo. Mason U. Law and Econ. Research , vol.8
    • Hazlett, T.W.1    Weisman, D.L.2
  • 125
    • 32944462707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Fallacies Encountered in the Law of Antitrust: Illustrations from Australia and New Zealand
    • see also David J. Teece & Christopher Pleatsikas, Economic Fallacies Encountered in the Law of Antitrust: Illustrations from Australia and New Zealand, 9 TRADE PRAC. L.J. 73 (2001).
    • (2001) Trade Prac. L.J. , vol.9 , pp. 73
    • Teece, D.J.1    Pleatsikas, C.2
  • 126
    • 77956927072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The FCC acknowledged this point in its recently released National Broadband Plan: "Building broadband networks-especially wireline-requires large fixed and sunk investments. Consequently, the industry will probably always have a relatively small number of facilities-based carriers, at least for wireline service."
  • 127
    • 77956913935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • However, the FCC continued, "the lack of a large number of wireline, facilities-based providers does not necessarily mean competition among broadband providers is inadequate."
  • 128
    • 33645578475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When Can Regulation Defer to Competition for Constraining Market Power?: Complements and Critical Elasticities
    • 102
    • Dennis L. Weisman, When Can Regulation Defer to Competition for Constraining Market Power?: Complements and Critical Elasticities, 2J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 101, 102 (2006).
    • (2006) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.2 , pp. 101
    • Weisman, D.L.1
  • 129
    • 77956893072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Top 23 U.S. ISPs by Subscriber: Q2 2008, ISP Planet, Dec. 2
    • Alex Goldman, Top 23 U.S. ISPs by Subscriber: Q2 2008, ISP PLANET, Dec. 2, 2008, http://www.isp-planet.com/research/rankings/usa.html).
    • (2008)
    • Goldman, A.1
  • 131
    • 0002104252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mitigating Procurement Hazards in the Context of Innovation
    • See also John M. de Figueredo & David J. Teece, Mitigating Procurement Hazards in the Context of Innovation, 5 INDUS. & CORP. CHANGE 537 (1996).
    • (1996) Indus. & Corp. Change , vol.5 , pp. 537
    • de Figueredo, J.M.1    Teece, D.J.2
  • 135
    • 77956914486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Although Hogendorn does not discuss explicitly the vertical foreclosure argument, his second proposed exception to ICE is a vertical foreclosure argument, as explained in Part III
  • 136
    • 0003227340 scopus 로고
    • Nonprice Anticompetitive Behavior by Dominant Firms Toward the Producers of Complementary Products
    • (Franklin M. Fisher ed)
    • See, e.g., Janusz A. Ordover, Alan O. Sykes & Robert D. Willig, Nonprice Anticompetitive Behavior by Dominant Firms Toward the Producers of Complementary Products, in ANTITRUST AND REGULATION: ESSAYS IN MEMORY OF JOHN J. MCGOWAN 119 (Franklin M. Fisher ed., 1985).
    • (1985) Antitrust and Regulation: Essays in Memory of John J. Mcgowan , vol.119
    • Ordover, J.A.1    Sykes, A.O.2    Willig, R.D.3
  • 137
    • 0000211369 scopus 로고
    • Tying, Foreclosure, and Exclusion
    • 838
    • See also Michael D. Whinston, Tying, Foreclosure, and Exclusion, 80 AM. ECON. REV. 837, 838 (1990).
    • (1990) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 837
    • Whinston, M.D.1
  • 138
    • 77956925383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • For a further critique of van Schewick's exceptions, see Testimony of George S. Ford, Ph.D., Chief Economist, Phoenix Center for Advanced Legal & Economic Public Policy Studies, Before the Federal Communications Commission Open Meeting on Network Neutrality and Broadband Network Management, Stanford University, at 19-20 (Apr. 17, 2008).
  • 139
    • 77956935323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., iPhone Dev. Center, (last visited Mar. 11)
    • See, e.g., iPhone Dev. Center, http://developer.apple.com/iphone/index.action (last visited Mar. 11, 2010).
    • (2010)
  • 140
    • 77956909823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Apple's App Store Downloads Top Three Billion, Apple, (Jan. 5), available at
    • Apple's App Store Downloads Top Three Billion, Apple, (Jan. 5, 2010), available at http://www.apple.com/pr/library/2010/01/05appstore.html.
    • (2010)
  • 142
    • 0002119982 scopus 로고
    • Patterns of Industrial Innovation
    • See William J. Abernathy & James M. Utterback, Patterns of Industrial Innovation, 80 TECH. REV. 40 (1978).
    • (1978) Tech. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 40
    • Abernathy, W.J.1    Utterback, J.M.2
  • 143
    • 0002578120 scopus 로고
    • The Evolution of New Industries and the Determinants of Market Structure
    • See, e.g., Steven Klepper & Elizabeth Grady, The Evolution of New Industries and the Determinants of Market Structure, 21 RAND J. ECON. 27 (1990).
    • (1990) Rand J. Econ. , vol.21
    • Klepper, S.1    Grady, E.2
  • 144
    • 33744492239 scopus 로고
    • Innovation, Competition, and Industry Structure
    • James M. Utterback & Fernando Suarez, Innovation, Competition, and Industry Structure, 22 RES. POL'Y 1 (1993).
    • (1993) Res. Pol'y , vol.22 , pp. 1
    • Utterback, J.M.1    Suarez, F.2
  • 145
    • 0002844271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dynamics and Evolution of Industries
    • Franco Malerba & Luigi Orsenigo, The Dynamics and Evolution of Industries, 5 INDUS. & CORP. CHANGE 51 (1996).
    • (1996) Indus. & Corp. Change , vol.5 , pp. 51
    • Malerba, F.1    Orsenigo, L.2
  • 146
    • 49349126835 scopus 로고
    • Monopoly and Product Quality
    • Michael Mussa & Sherwin Rosen, Monopoly and Product Quality,18 J. ECON. THEORY 301 (1978).
    • (1978) J. Econ. Theory , vol.18 , pp. 301
    • Mussa, M.1    Rosen, S.2
  • 147
    • 0001673646 scopus 로고
    • Monopoly with Incomplete Information
    • Eric Maskin & John Riley, Monopoly with Incomplete Information, 15 RAND J. ECON 171 (1984).
    • (1984) Rand J. Econ , vol.15 , pp. 171
    • Maskin, E.1    Riley, J.2
  • 149
    • 85022000243 scopus 로고
    • Price Discrimination and Social Welfare
    • Hal Varian, Price Discrimination and Social Welfare, 75 AM. ECON. REV. 870 (1985)).
    • (1985) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 870
    • Varian, H.1
  • 150
    • 77956916905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See, e.g., Press Release, AT&T, AT&T to Invest More Than $17 Billion in 2009 to Drive Economic Growth (Mar. 10, 2009), available at http://www.att.com/gen/press-room?pid=4800&cdvn=news&newsarticleid=26597&mapcode=
  • 151
    • 77956913371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Press Release, Verizon, Verizon's $17 Billion Network Investment in 2009 Pays Off (Dec. 29, 2009), available at http://newscenter.verizon.com/press-releases/verizon/2009/verizons-17-billion-network.html. In addition, AT&T's triple-play platform is all-IP and already involves prioritization of voice and video packets.
  • 152
    • 77956908053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See, e.g., FCC Fifth Report, Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced Telecommunications Capability to All Americans in a Reasonable and Timely Fashion, 23 F.C.C. Rcd. 9,651 ¶ 74 (2008) (telecommunications industry planned to spend $50 billion in capital expenditures in 2008 and 2009)
  • 153
    • 77956906889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • NCTA, Industry Data, http://www.ncta.com/Statistics.aspx (citing that more than 120 million homes have access to cable broadband service and industry capital investments of $161.2 billion since 1996).
  • 154
    • 77956893071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Linda Haugsted, Turtles that Win the Race: Comcast's 'Slowskys' Back Cable Modems Via TV Spots, Multichannel News, June 22, available at
    • See Linda Haugsted, Turtles that Win the Race: Comcast's 'Slowskys' Back Cable Modems Via TV Spots, MULTICHANNEL NEWS, June 22, 2006, available at http://www.multichannel.com/article/CA6336326.html.
    • (2006)
  • 155
    • 77956899358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lance Whitney, U.S. Broadband Speeds Rise in 2009,CNET News, Feb. 10
    • Lance Whitney, U.S. Broadband Speeds Rise in 2009,CNET NEWS, Feb. 10, 2010, http://news.cnet.com/8301-1023_3-10450784-93.html?tag=mncol.
    • (2010)
  • 156
    • 77956926788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verizon, FiOS Internet, Plans, (last visited Feb. 18)
    • Verizon, FiOS Internet, Plans, http://www22.verizon.com/Residential/FiOSInternet/Plans/Plans.htm (last visited Feb. 18, 2010).
    • (2010)
  • 157
    • 77956910101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chloe Albanesius, Comcast Rolling Out 'Xfinity' Brand to 11 Markets, PCMAG.COM, Feb. 4
    • See Chloe Albanesius, Comcast Rolling Out 'Xfinity' Brand to 11 Markets, PCMAG.COM, Feb. 4, 2010, http://www.pcmag.com/article2/0,2817,2358807,00.asp.
    • (2010)
  • 158
    • 77956941286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • ISPs are not entitled, under Title II of the Communications Act or other law, to file tariffs for delivering packets over their broadband networks. Consequently, ISPs have no ability to act like a "terminating access monopoly" that threatens not to deliver traffic to its customers unless its posted price is paid. To the contrary, ISPs exchange broadband Internet traffic through peering and transiting agreements that are voluntarily negotiated on commercial terms.
  • 161
    • 0013115995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prisoner's Dilemma
    • 974, (John Eatwell, Murray Milgate & Peter Newman, eds., Macmillan 1987) ("Perhaps the most interesting result of Prisoner's Dilemma experiments with iterated play is that even if the number of iterations to be played is known to both subjects, nevertheless a tacit agreement to cooperate is often achieved.")
    • Anatol Rapoport, Prisoner's Dilemma, in 3 THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY of ECONOMICS 973, 974 (John Eatwell, Murray Milgate & Peter Newman, eds., Macmillan 1987) ("Perhaps the most interesting result of Prisoner's Dilemma experiments with iterated play is that even if the number of iterations to be played is known to both subjects, nevertheless a tacit agreement to cooperate is often achieved.").
    • The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics , vol.3 , pp. 973
    • Rapoport, A.1
  • 162
    • 77956919203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • In a traditional prisoner's dilemma framework, prosecutors offer two prisoners the option of confessing to a crime (defecting) or staying silent (cooperating with the other prisoner), offering leniency if a prisoner "turns state's evidence" by confessing and implicating his colleague, and threatening to "throw the book" at a prisoner if he stays silent while his partner confesses. Each prisoner finds it worthwhile to confess, which makes the prisoners themselves worse off than they would have been if both had remained silent. But to say that such an outcome is "inefficient" ignores the interests of society in inducing criminals to confess to (and pay for) their crimes.
  • 164
    • 77956903672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A "Principled" Approach to the Design of Telecommunications Policy
    • (forthcoming)
    • Dennis L. Weisman, A "Principled" Approach to the Design of Telecommunications Policy, 6 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. (forthcoming 2010).
    • (2010) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.6
    • Weisman, D.L.1
  • 165
    • 77956932974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • During 2009, Akamai's share price increased almost 70 percent, or more than double the increase of the market index
  • 166
    • 77956905044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Yahoo! Finance, Akamai Technologies Inc. (AKAM): Historical Prices, (last visited Mar. 25)
    • See Yahoo! Finance, Akamai Technologies Inc. (AKAM): Historical Prices, http://finance.yahoo.com/q/hp?s=AKAM (last visited Mar. 25, 2010).
    • (2010)
  • 167
    • 77956941646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • At the same time, Akamai achieved a 31.9 percent share of professional video views.
  • 168
    • 77956899667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See AccuStream Research, CDN Account Growth at 23.3% in 2009,WIRELESS NEWS, 2009.
  • 169
    • 77956942525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (NET Institute, Working Paper No. 08-03, Sept), available at
    • Jay Pil Choi & Byung-Cheol Kim, Net Neutrality and Investment Incentives (NET Institute, Working Paper No. 08-03, Sept. 2008), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers. cfm?abstract_id=1285639#
    • (2008) Net Neutrality and Investment Incentives
    • Choi, J.P.1    Kim, B.-C.2
  • 170
    • 77956904497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Economides actually cites the Choi-Kim article for this point (he lists the Economides-Tåg article in his bibliography, but does not cite it for this point), as well as two other articles, by Lee and Wu and Peha. A review of the last two papers shows that Economides has seriously mischaracterized their results. Contrary to Economides' contention, Lee and Wu assert that "the impact [of allowing termination fees] on the marginal incentive to invest is indeterminate."
  • 171
    • 77956939274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • A careful reading of Peha indicates that he does not express any opinion as to whether total ISP investment would be greater or less with the option of business-to-business transactions for QoS than under a "nondiscrimination" regime. He does not develop any formal model and does not make any predictions, other than to say that "if network operators were prohibited from this practice [of 'intentionally degrad[ing] QOS for some traffic, even when there is excess capacity to provide excellent QOS'], they might have incentive not to increase the capacity of the network."
  • 172
    • 77956929045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • It may well be true that different content providers who offer similar types of offerings (for example, different Internet search providers) may have similar QoS needs, though that is itself open to question (for example, some content providers may have self-provided enhanced delivery or contracted with CDN providers, although their competitors may not have). But that would not eliminate the fact that the Internet involves many different types of packets with very different QoS needs.
  • 173
    • 77956917174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Economides and Tåg initially assume that there is a single "monopoly" ISP (they then extend the model to a "duopoly" model), that there are two content providers who "are independent monopolists, each in its own markets, and therefore do not compete with one another", and that ISPs charge content providers a "lump sum fee... to gain access to users."
  • 174
    • 77956905285 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Moreover, the level of investment per se is economically less significant than the effect of the combination of investment and prioritization rules on the effective delivery speed of different classes of traffic. Suppose, for example, that with the option of business-to-business QoS transactions, ISPs have an incentive to allocate resources to packets that are more valuable and/or more time-sensitive and away from packets that are less valuable and/or less time sensitive. Holding total resources constant, such a resource allocation rule will increase in consumer welfare relative to an alternative allocation rule that treats all packets equally.
  • 175
    • 77956918073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • (citing Jules Dupuit, De la Mesure de L'Utilité des Travaux Publics, ANNALES DES PONTS ET CHAUSSÉES (2d Ser.) 8 (1844), translated as Jules Dupuit, On the Measurement of the Utility of Public Works, 2INT'L ECON. PAPERS 83 (1952) (trans. R.H. Barback). The correct citation for this quote is Jules Dupuit, De l'Influence des Péages sur l'Utilitié des Voies de Communication,ANNALES DES PONTS ET CHAUSSÉES (2d Ser.) 17 (1849), translated as Jules Dupuit, On Tolls and Transport Charges,11INT'L ECON.PAPERS 7 (1962) (trans. Elizabeth Henderson)).
  • 177
    • 77956934467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • In addition, capital markets are available to place cash-poor companies with good business plans on a par with cash-rich companies
  • 178
    • 77956929623 scopus 로고
    • New York Trust Co. v. Eisner, 256 U.S. 345, 349 (Holmes, J.)
    • New York Trust Co. v. Eisner, 256 U.S. 345, 349 (1921) (Holmes, J.).
    • (1921)
  • 179
    • 77956925372 scopus 로고
    • Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain, and France
    • (Cambridge Univ. Press)
    • See FRANK DOBBIN, FORGING INDUSTRIAL POLICY: THE UNITED STATES, BRITAIN, AND FRANCE in the RAILWAY AGE 114 (Cambridge Univ. Press 1994).
    • (1994) Railway Age , vol.114
    • Dobbin, F.1
  • 180
    • 77956893902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Development of the British Railway Carriage
    • See, e.g., The Development of the British Railway Carriage, Bluebell Railway Preservation Society, http://www.bluebell-railway.co.uk/~zhaa009/bb/car_fs1.html.
    • Bluebell Railway Preservation Society
  • 183
    • 17144378140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why the Economy Reflects the Polity: Early Rail Policy in Britain, France, and the United States
    • 413, (Mark Granovetter & Richard Swedberg eds., Westview Press)
    • Frank Dobbin, Why the Economy Reflects the Polity: Early Rail Policy in Britain, France, and the United States, in 2 THE SOCIOLOGY of ECONOMIC LIFE 401, 413 (Mark Granovetter & Richard Swedberg eds., Westview Press 2001).
    • (2001) The Sociology of Economic Life , vol.2 , pp. 401
    • Dobbin, F.1
  • 185
    • 77956944216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • We believe that this assumption makes it unlikely that the Deneckere-McAfee damaged-goods model is particularly relevant to the Internet, as typically one would expect that it would be more costly for an ISP to supply higher QoS to a content provider than it would be to supply a lower QoS, especially if one measures cost in terms of opportunity cost rather than only out-of-pocket cost
  • 186
    • 77956929883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Moreover, the proposition that firms generally charge higher prices for products that are more costly to supply than for products that are less costly to supply is both uncontroversial and not a cause for policy concern


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.