메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 9, Issue 2, 2010, Pages 213-244

The market, competition, and equality

Author keywords

Determinants of income inequality; Economic justice; Kinds of redistribution; Shaping markets; Theories of competition

Indexed keywords


EID: 77951922565     PISSN: 1470594X     EISSN: 17413060     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1177/1470594X09359148     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (15)

References (102)
  • 1
    • 77951920033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Pareto efficiency is to be distinguished from x-efficiency, which focuses on the relation of inputs and output in economic production. A system of production is x-efficient if it produces maximum output with a given quantity of inputs, in other words, if it minimizes waste.
  • 2
    • 39449125904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Survey Article: Justice in Production
    • A notable exception is a recent article by Nien-Hê Hsieh, who analyses normative questions related to the nature of work under capitalist institutions as well as to the participation of the worker in the governance of these institutions. See
    • A notable exception is a recent article by Nien-Hê Hsieh, who analyses normative questions related to the nature of work under capitalist institutions as well as to the participation of the worker in the governance of these institutions. See Nien-Hê Hsieh, 'Survey Article: Justice in Production', Journal of Political Philosophy 16 (2008).
    • (2008) Journal of Political Philosophy , pp. 16
    • Nien-Hê, H.1
  • 3
    • 77951882801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • One of the few passages in which John Rawls, for example, even mentions this issue remains superficial as to how the influence of competition on distribution actually works: 'Inequality can be wrong or unjust in itself whenever society makes use of fair procedures. Two examples are: fair, that is, open and workably competitive markets; and fair political elections. In these cases a certain equality, or a wellmoderated inequality, is a condition of economic and political justice. Monopoly and its kindred are to be avoided, not simply for their bad effects, among them inefficiency, but also because without a special justification they make markets unfair.'
  • 5
    • 77951905190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Ronald Dworkin's 'equality of resources' is another example. The feature of the market that is relevant for Dworkin and captured in his auction of clamshells among the shipwreck survivors is that the price mechanism coordinates people's preferences by making individuals pay for the opportunity costs their choices impose on others. This mechanism only works well in the absence of market failure, and the validity of Dworkin's argument is therefore confined to a hypothetical, perfectly competitive market. The distributive issues that arise when we depart from this benchmark model, and when the level of competition varies, are not addressed by Dworkin's analysis.
  • 6
    • 0000791830 scopus 로고
    • What is Equality? Part 2: Equality of Resources
    • See, in particular
    • See Ronald Dworkin, 'What is Equality? Part 2: Equality of Resources', Philosophy and Public Affairs 10 (1981): 285-9 in particular.
    • (1981) Philosophy and Public Affairs , vol.10 , pp. 285-9
    • Dworkin, R.1
  • 7
    • 77951916233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Liberal egalitarians, for instance, hold that the distribution of talent is arbitrary from a moral point of view and that its impact on the distribution of income should be mitigated in some way. To put such an approach into practice, one needs to be able to trace income inequality to its various determinants. Economists call this the 'decomposition' of income inequality. For a classic, technical article on inequality decomposition,
  • 8
    • 0001735723 scopus 로고
    • Inequality Decomposition by Population Subgroups
    • see
    • see Anthony F. Shorrocks, 'Inequality Decomposition by Population Subgroups', Econometrica 52 (1984): 1369-85.
    • (1984) Econometrica , vol.52 , pp. 1369-85
    • Shorrocks, A.F.1
  • 9
    • 77951928660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • In contrast to ex post and ex ante redistribution, which ultimately also rely on institutions, the idea of process redistribution as employed here construes institutions more narrowly. As will become clear further down, process redistribution operates through the dynamics of market interaction itself, whereas ex post and ex ante redistribution are grafted on to this interaction with a view to modifying its results. I deliberately avoid using the label 'procedural redistribution' to preempt confusion with the notion of procedural justice in political philosophy.
  • 10
    • 77951936245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • For instance, I bracket considerations regarding the extent to which a particular job bears risks (for example, firemen). Other determinants of wages and, a fortiori, of income inequality could be added to Table 1, but are not necessary for the argument of this article.
  • 11
    • 77951892102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Obviously, the entries in Table 1 by no means claim to be complete. Other contributions to economic theory and to the literature on theories of justice may be added to the classification. All I claim is that they conform to the soon-to-beidentified pattern of the table.
  • 12
    • 77951901920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Treating normative principles and policy instruments as if they were part of one and the same category might strike some readers as inappropriate. However, I choose this approach here in order to reflect the different points of emphasis in economics and political philosophy respectively. Note also that these two different levels of abstraction can be bridged by either giving examples for concrete policies that implement the principles put forward by philosophers or by inquiring into the principles that underpin policy proposals by economists. For example, an instance of a policy in line with an egalitarian theory of education is a school system that streams pupils according to skill level relatively late - this is one of the features of the Finnish school system, and it is often invoked as an important factor in explaining the high average scores of Finnish children in cross-country comparisons of educational achievement.
  • 13
    • 77951903159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, OECD, press release, URL (consulted 2 December)
    • See OECD, press release, URL (consulted 2 December 2009): http://www.oecd.org/document/22/0,3343,en_2649_34487_39713238_1_1_1_1,00.html.
    • (2009)
  • 14
    • 77951890346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Vice versa, moving from policy to principle, one way of justifying a progressive fiscal policy is a principle of fair equality of opportunity.
  • 15
    • 77951908511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Of course, a progressive fiscal policy reduces income inequalities in general and not only those due to differential skills. But one plausible justification of a progressive fiscal policy appeals to this wage determinant in particular.
  • 16
    • 33744781188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On this issue, see for instance, (New York and Princeton, NJ: Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton University Press)
    • On this issue, see for instance Samuel Bowles, Herbert Gintis and Melissa Osborne Groves, Unequal Chances: Family Background and Economic Success (New York and Princeton, NJ: Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton University Press, 2005).
    • (2005) Unequal Chances: Family Background and Economic Success
    • Bowles, S.1    Gintis, H.2    Groves, M.O.3
  • 17
    • 22944478662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Can We Discern the Effect of Globalization on Income Distribution? Evidence from Household Surveys
    • See for instance
    • See for instance Branko Milanovic, 'Can We Discern the Effect of Globalization on Income Distribution? Evidence from Household Surveys', World Bank Economic Review 19 (2005): 21-44.
    • (2005) World Bank Economic Review , vol.19 , pp. 21-44
    • Milanovic, B.1
  • 19
    • 0031412535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Globalization and Inequality, Past and Present
    • See
    • See Jeffrey G. Williamson, 'Globalization and Inequality, Past and Present', World Bank Research Observer 2 (1997): 117-35.
    • (1997) World Bank Research Observer , vol.2 , pp. 117-35
    • Williamson, J.G.1
  • 20
    • 77951905569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • That said, they are usually thought of as lease payments for the use of crown land rather than as a tax.
  • 21
    • 33748938739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Benefits of Cooperation
    • Joseph Heath, 'The Benefits of Cooperation', Philosophy and Public Affairs 4 (2006): 313-51.
    • (2006) Philosophy and Public Affairs , vol.4 , pp. 313-51
    • Heath, J.1
  • 22
    • 77951911385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The First Fundamental Theorem states, conversely, that any outcome of a perfectly competitive market will be Pareto optimal.
  • 23
    • 84959674689 scopus 로고
    • The Moral Standing of the Market
    • Compare
    • Compare Amartya Sen, 'The Moral Standing of the Market', Social Philosophy and Policy 2 (1985): 11.
    • (1985) Social Philosophy and Policy , vol.2 , pp. 11
    • Sen, A.1
  • 24
    • 77951924772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I would like to thank, for alerting me to the expression
    • I would like to thank Daniel Hausman for alerting me to the expression 'shaping markets'.
    • Shaping Markets
    • Hausman, D.1
  • 25
    • 0002563875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutions and Their Design
    • edited by Robert E. Goodin (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
    • Robert E. Goodin, 'Institutions and Their Design', in The Theory of Institutional Design, edited by Robert E. Goodin (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996), p. 7.
    • (1996) The Theory of Institutional Design , pp. 7
    • Goodin, R.E.1
  • 26
    • 77951930327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • This is why the policies listed in the bottom right-hand cell of Table 1 are in square brackets. They are, of course, part and parcel of economic analysis, but always from an efficiency perspective rather than informed by a concern with distribution.
  • 27
    • 77951935121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See also n. 5.
  • 28
    • 0040972807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What is Equality? Part 2: Equality of Resources
    • Compare, for instance, Rawls, Justice as Fairness: A Restatement, para. 49, in particular
    • Compare, for instance, Rawls, Justice as Fairness: A Restatement, para. 49 or Dworkin, 'What is Equality? Part 2: Equality of Resources', pp. 323-34 in particular.
    • Dworkin1
  • 29
    • 0004340089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • eventually turns to a progressive income tax to implement his ideal of, In this sense, his approach could also be listed in the ex post redistribution column of Table 1
    • Eventually turns to a progressive income tax to implement his ideal of 'equality of resources'. In this sense, his approach could also be listed in the ex post redistribution column of Table 1.
    • Equality of Resources
  • 30
    • 0003988298 scopus 로고
    • Compare, (Cambridge, MA: Blackwell)
    • Compare Hillel Steiner, An Essay on Rights (Cambridge, MA: Blackwell, 1994).
    • (1994) An Essay on Rights
    • Steiner, H.1
  • 31
    • 77951903742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Left-libertarian theories such as Steiner's do not fall under the umbrella of liberal egalitarianism, but they import certain elements from liberal egalitarian thought.
  • 32
    • 0006534873 scopus 로고
    • Competing Justifications of Basic Income
    • These are the elements that preoccupy us here. For arguments in favor of a basic income, see, (London: Verso)
    • These are the elements that preoccupy us here. For arguments in favor of a basic income, see Philippe van Parijs, 'Competing Justifications of Basic Income', in Arguing for Basic Income: Ethical Foundations for a Radical Reform (London: Verso, 1992).
    • (1992) Arguing For Basic Income: Ethical Foundations For a Radical Reform
    • van Parijs, P.1
  • 33
    • 0141463602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Defending Liberalism in Education Theory
    • See
    • See Harry Brighouse and Adam Swift, 'Defending Liberalism in Education Theory', Journal of Education Policy 4 (2003): 355-73.
    • (2003) Journal of Education Policy , vol.4 , pp. 355-373
    • Brighouse, H.1    Swift, A.2
  • 34
    • 0004238625 scopus 로고
    • (New York: Basic Books), Ch. 8
    • Michael Walzer, Spheres of Justice (New York: Basic Books, 1983), Ch. 8.
    • (1983) Spheres of Justice
    • Walzer, M.1
  • 35
    • 77956285247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a classic illustration of this tension, see Rawls's discussion of the family in Rawls, para. 50
    • For a classic illustration of this tension, see Rawls's discussion of the family in Rawls, Justice as Fairness: A Restatement, para. 50.
    • Justice As Fairness: A Restatement
  • 36
    • 77951914915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Philosophie de la fiscalité pour une économie mondialisée
    • Philippe van Parijs, 'Philosophie de la fiscalité pour une économie mondialisée', Archives de philosophie de droit 46 (2002): 329-48.
    • (2002) Archives De Philosophie De Droit , vol.46 , pp. 329-348
    • van Parijs, P.1
  • 37
    • 77951931210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The examples taken from Van Parijs in the 'process redistribution' column of Table 1 are descriptive rather than normative. They depict how redistribution actually takes place rather than how it should take place.
  • 38
    • 77951907306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • In fact, as Julian LeGrand convincingly argues, economic efficiency does not represent a social objective in its own right at all, but is only of instrumental value in promoting other goals such as the maximization of social welfare or economic growth.
  • 39
    • 84930559860 scopus 로고
    • Justice Versus Efficiency: The Elusive Trade-Off
    • See
    • See Julian LeGrand, 'Justice Versus Efficiency: The Elusive Trade-Off', Ethics 3 (1990): 554-68.
    • (1990) Ethics , vol.3 , pp. 554-568
    • Legrand, J.1
  • 40
    • 84979188687 scopus 로고
    • The Nature of the Firm
    • The reason why these suppliers take the form of firms rather than individuals has been elucidated by Ronald Coase, who put forward the idea that assembling a productive venture under the umbrella of a firm allows a significant lowering of transaction costs, See
    • The reason why these suppliers take the form of firms rather than individuals has been elucidated by Ronald Coase, who put forward the idea that assembling a productive venture under the umbrella of a firm allows a significant lowering of transaction costs. See Ronald Coase, 'The Nature of the Firm', Economica 1 (1937): 386-405.
    • (1937) Economica , vol.1 , pp. 386-405
    • Coase, R.1
  • 41
    • 77951894190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • I thank François Claveau for making me realize the importance of the distinction between output and input markets for my argument.
  • 42
    • 77951885421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • If not exhaustive, I believe these roles to represent the categories most important to a distributive analysis of competition.
  • 43
    • 17144425956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perfectly and Imperfectly Competitive Markets
    • See, edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman (London: Macmillan)
    • See John Roberts, 'Perfectly and Imperfectly Competitive Markets', in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman (London: Macmillan, 1998), p. 838.
    • (1998) The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics , pp. 838
    • Roberts, J.1
  • 44
    • 77951911084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Returns to scale are increasing when, upon an increase of all the inputs to production, output increases more that proportionately. A proportionate increase corresponds to constant returns to scale. A less than proportionate increase corresponds to diminishing returns to scale. It is important to distinguish increasing returns in this sense from increasing returns as understood by classical economists such as Adam Smith. Smith emphasized the network effects that arise from the division of labor in society and the specialization it entails. The more specialized a society, the higher individual productivity, and the bigger the cooperative surplus, that is, the extra output produced thanks to the division of labor.
  • 45
    • 62449111974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributive Lessons from Division of Labour
    • As in the case of increasing returns to scale, the neglect of network effects has important normative consequences - I discuss these in, However, I choose to bracket them for the purposes of the present article
    • As in the case of increasing returns to scale, the neglect of network effects has important normative consequences - I discuss these in Peter Dietsch, 'Distributive Lessons from Division of Labour', Journal of Moral Philosophy 1 (2008): 96-117. However, I choose to bracket them for the purposes of the present article.
    • (2008) Journal of Moral Philosophy , vol.1 , pp. 96-117
    • Dietsch, P.1
  • 48
    • 77951881938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Another way to express the idea of deadweight loss is to look at it as the consumer and producer surplus foregone by moving from qc to qm. Areas A + B measure the consumer surplus foregone, whereas C - A represents the producer surplus foregone. The net 'deadweight' loss therefore amounts to B + C.
  • 49
    • 77951918830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • I do not discuss the cases of oligopoly or duopoly here.
  • 52
    • 33644923054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also, (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press)
    • See also Russell Hardin, Indeterminacy and Society (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003), p. 18.
    • (2003) Indeterminacy and Society , pp. 18
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 54
    • 11744288988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contestable Markets
    • edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman (London: Macmillan)
    • Robert D. Willig, 'Contestable Markets', in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman (London: Macmillan, 1998), p. 618.
    • (1998) The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics , pp. 618
    • Willig, R.D.1
  • 55
    • 77951884849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Some economists will criticize my use of the neoclassical analysis of competition in this section as misleading. All the theories of competition discussed here, so their objection will run, rely on a static rather than dynamic conception of efficiency, which tells us very little about how real economies work.
  • 56
    • 0034966910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is Competition Such a Good Thing? Static Efficiency Versus Dynamic Efficiency
    • For an eloquent formulation of this position, see
    • For an eloquent formulation of this position, see Mark Blaug, 'Is Competition Such a Good Thing? Static Efficiency Versus Dynamic Efficiency', Review of Industrial Organization 19 (2001): 37-48.
    • (2001) Review of Industrial Organization , vol.19 , pp. 37-48
    • Blaug, M.1
  • 57
    • 77951901044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • This is a forceful objection. However, it does not undermine the basic claim of this article that theories of distributive justice as well as institutional design should take into account the distributive consequences of competition. What it does show is that there are various ways to conceptualize competition. Trying to arbitrate between these here would take us too far into economic history.
  • 58
    • 77951916232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I borrow this example from
    • I borrow this example from Willig, 'Contestable Markets', p. 622.
    • Contestable Markets , pp. 622
    • Willig1
  • 59
    • 77951929253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • I should add that price is not the only variable through which various degrees of competition affect the consumer. Competitive pressures, or the lack thereof, also have an impact on the rate of innovation as well as on the quality of products available for purchase. One might think, for instance, that more intense competition increases the pressure to innovate on the one hand, while reducing the resources potentially available for research and development on the other. For simplicity's sake, I bracket these considerations here.
  • 60
    • 77951921443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Measuring the distributive impact of competition in terms of other focal variables altogether, such as social primary goods or capabilities, is possible. However, it is both more complicated and less relevant in the present context, where income distribution is my primary focus.
  • 61
    • 77951893864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • They will use the additional disposable income either to shift more of their consumption to the now cheaper good (substitution effect) or buy more of other goods they are now able to afford (income effect).
  • 62
    • 77951904024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • For example, one might say international air travel has been made accessible to lower-income segments of the population by the rise of low-fare airlines.
  • 63
    • 77951899556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The change in consumer surplus is only an exact measure of the change in utility if the consumer's utility function is quasi-linear. A quasi-linear utility function is one that is linear in one of its arguments (goods). In other words, the demand for that good is insensitive to changes in income.
  • 64
    • 0004263651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, For simplicity's sake, I assume quasi-linear utility functions here
    • See Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics, pp. 63, 247-8. For simplicity's sake, I assume quasi-linear utility functions here.
    • Intermediate Microeconomics
    • Varian1
  • 65
    • 77951935120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • One principal reason is the problem of expensive tastes. Imagine that the only way for X to be minimally happy is to consume caviar and champagne all day, whereas Y will be pretty happy even on a much less fancy diet. It seems unreasonable to think that justice requires us to subsidize X's expensive tastes.
  • 66
    • 0009388941 scopus 로고
    • What is equality? Part 1: Equality of welfare
    • See, for instance
    • See, for instance, Ronald Dworkin, 'What is Equality? Part 1: Equality of Welfare', Philosophy and Public Affairs 3 (1981): pp. 228-40).
    • (1981) Philosophy and Public Affairs , vol.3 , pp. 228-40
    • Dworkin, R.1
  • 67
    • 77951904330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • hough a substantial portion of these is no doubt due to advances in technology, it is safe to assume that increased competition due to the deregulation of these markets has also played a significant role. Note that deregulation and privatization are by no means coextensive.
  • 68
    • 77951896466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Scenario 1 is also the context in which two economists, Christian Broda and John Romalis, have recently argued that the prices of goods consumed by the poor in the USA have risen more slowly than prices of goods consumed by the rich and that, as a result, the rise in US inequality has been smaller than is usually assumed. According to the authors, the reason for this development lies in the fact that the poor tend to consume more nondurable goods such as clothing, footwear, and toiletries, the relative prices of which have fallen thanks to cheap Chinese imports.
  • 69
    • 55349144783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inequality and prices: Does China benefit the poor in America?
    • See, working paper, URL (consulted 2 December)
    • See Christian Broda and John Romalis, 'Inequality and Prices: Does China Benefit the Poor in America?', working paper, URL (consulted 2 December 2009): http://www.freit.org/EIIE/2008/SubmittedPapers/John_Romalis.pdf.
    • (2009)
    • Broda, C.1    Romalis, J.2
  • 70
    • 77951916801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • While it may be true that traditional inequality measures have neglected this phenomenon, I disagree that it necessarily follows that inequality has been overstated. After all, the long-term goal of the poor is to shift some of their spending from nondurable goods to services, that is, toward a spending pattern more like that of the rich. As long as the price inflation of the latter outpaces the growth in disposable income, attaining this goal becomes less likely. In this sense, inequality could even be said to increase.
  • 71
    • 77951922691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • I would like to thank Joseph Heath for drawing my attention to this aspect, and for pointing out the potentially progressive impact of price discrimination discussed later in the article.
  • 72
    • 77951912309 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • As in the previous section, this question can be addressed using different focal variables. I will limit myself to the impact of price discrimination on disposable income.
  • 73
    • 33847710020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, (Oxford: Oxford University Press)
    • See Andrew Glyn, Capitalism Unleashed (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006), p. 191.
    • (2006) Capitalism Unleashed , pp. 191
    • Glyn, A.1
  • 74
    • 77951920291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Given the enormous and increasing wealth held offshore and therefore hidden from the fiscal authorities, these numbers might even underestimate the share of capital.
  • 75
    • 33645560098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the so-called 'tax gap', see for instance, (London: Tax Justice Network)
    • On the so-called 'tax gap', see for instance Richard Murphy, Tax Us If You Can (London: Tax Justice Network, 2005).
    • (2005) Tax Us If You Can
    • Murphy, R.1
  • 76
    • 0037331911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Income inequality in the Unites States, 1913-98
    • For the former, see, For the latter
    • For the former, see Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, 'Income Inequality in the Unites States, 1913-98', Quarterly Journal of Economics 1 (2003): 1-39. For the latter.
    • (2003) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.1 , pp. 1-39
    • Piketty, T.1    Saez, E.2
  • 79
    • 0036002283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Self-ownership and the property in the person: Democratization and a tale of two concepts
    • On the idea of renting labor, see for instance
    • On the idea of renting labor, see for instance Carole Pateman, 'Self-Ownership and the Property in the Person: Democratization and a Tale of Two Concepts', Journal of Political Philosophy 1 (2002): 20-53.
    • (2002) Journal of Political Philosophy , vol.1 , pp. 20-53
    • Pateman, C.1
  • 80
    • 77951883968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The following examples are taken from Andrew Glyn's book Capitalism Unleashed in which he documents the shift in power from labor to capital since the 1960s.
  • 81
    • 77951890067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Not all the manifestations of this shift are financial. Workers in liberal economies in particular have seen their hours increase. Besides, competition might 'force' companies to make only minimal efforts to comply with health and safety regulations, which can be another way of saying that the interests of the shareholder trump those of the worker. Finally, some critics have suggested that capitalist competition renders many forms of work less meaningful and intra-firm relations even more hierarchical; for a lucid discussion of these concerns, see Hsieh, 'Survey Article: Justice in Production'.
  • 82
    • 77951901919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See the itemized list above (p. 229).
  • 83
    • 77951922396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • I borrow this term from Van Parijs, 'Philosophie de la fiscalité pour une économie mondialisée'. 'Internal' redistribution, for lack of a better term, is an imperfect translation of the French term 'redistribution implicite'. See also redistribution within the firm or within the family in Part I and Table 1.
  • 84
    • 59149084643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a recent analysis of the effect of technological change on inequality, see, (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press)
    • For a recent analysis of the effect of technological change on inequality, see Gilles Saint-Paul, Innovation and Inequality: How Does Technical Progress Affect Workers? (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2008).
    • (2008) Innovation and Inequality: How Does Technical Progress Affect Workers?
    • Saint-Paul, G.1
  • 85
    • 33847710020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of these trends in practice, see for instance
    • For a discussion of these trends in practice, see for instance Glyn, Capitalism Unleashed, pp. 107-13.
    • Capitalism Unleashed , pp. 107-113
    • Glyn1
  • 86
    • 77951922692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Two of the most widely held positions are as follows. Some commentators believe that high executive salaries serve an important function as incentives. Especially when ownership and control are separated, as they are for the model of the shareholder-owned company that dominates our economy, high and performancerelated executive salaries can help align the interests of management with those of the owners. For evidence supporting this hypothesis.
  • 87
    • 0000207706 scopus 로고
    • Executive compensation structure, ownership, and firm performance
    • see for example
    • see for example Hamid Mehran, 'Executive Compensation Structure, Ownership, and Firm Performance', Journal of Financial Economics 2 (1995): 163-84.
    • (1995) Journal of Financial Economics , vol.2 , pp. 163-184
    • Mehran, H.1
  • 88
    • 77951890945 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Others believe that high executive paychecks are the result of shortcomings in corporate governance that have enabled managers to influence how much they take home.
  • 90
    • 77951909608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Savers, by definition, are capital owners.
    • Savers1
  • 91
    • 77951882800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • For simplicity's sake, I set aside rent as a separate category of return on capital.
  • 92
    • 77951897105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • This is true at least for the period prior to the financial crises of 2008.
    • (2008)
  • 94
    • 77951910209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • As in the case for workers, one should add that while profits have increased, so has their volatility. At first glance, one might think that capital owners are better equipped to deal with this volatility than workers, since their capital income is rarely their only source of income. However, workers are also affected by this volatility in profits through the investments made by their pension funds. The impact of the corporate scandal at Enron on its employees is instructive here.
  • 95
    • 77951913718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The ratio of property income (dividends, interest and rent) to labor income (wages and self-employment income) rose from about 15% in the USA in 1979 to 18% in 2002 and from 7% to 12% in France.'
  • 96
    • 77951913719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, Note
    • See ibid., p. 170.
  • 97
    • 77951889212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Although wealth inequalities today are lower than 50 years ago, Förster and d'Ercole show that in the rich OECD countries, the top 20 percent of the population still receive 53 percent of property income.
  • 98
    • 29144490017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Income Distribution and Poverty in OECD Countries in the Second Half of the 1990s
    • See, Working Papers, No. 22
    • See Michael F. F̈rster and Marco Mira d'Ercole, 'Income Distribution and Poverty in OECD Countries in the Second Half of the 1990s', OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers, No. 22 (2005).
    • (2005) Oecd Social, Employment and Migration
    • F̈rster, M.F.1    D'Ercole, M.M.2
  • 99
    • 77951894189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Opening the Big Box: Measuring the Wal-Mart Effect
    • See, for instance, 23 February
    • See, for instance, The Economist, 'Opening the Big Box: Measuring the Wal-Mart Effect', 23 February 2006.
    • (2006) The Economist
  • 101
    • 77951907632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • on perfect competition and monopoly: 'Counting both the firm and the consumer, it is not clear whether competition or monopoly will be a "better" arrangement. It appears that one must make a value judgment about the relative welfare of consumers and the owners of firms. However. one can argue against monopoly on grounds of efficiency alone.' Austrian economics may provide a more helpful perspective in this regard. Schumpeter's notion of creative destruction, for instance, could be interpreted as requiring certain inequalities in the short term in order to raise both the quantity and the quality of products and services in the long term.
  • 102
    • 77951932897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert E. Goodin (editor), (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, especially)
    • See Robert E. Goodin (editor), The Theory of Institutional Design (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996), pp. 24-30 especially.
    • (1996) The Theory of Institutional Design , pp. 24-30


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.