메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 11, Issue 1, 2010, Pages

Central bank transparency: Causes, consequences and updates

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77649169753     PISSN: None     EISSN: 15653404     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.2202/1565-3404.1237     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (34)

References (53)
  • 2
    • 77649127166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WILLIAM GREIDER, SECRETS OF THE TEMPLE: HOW THE FEDERAL RESERVE RUNS THE COUNTRY (1987).
    • See WILLIAM GREIDER, SECRETS OF THE TEMPLE: HOW THE FEDERAL RESERVE RUNS THE COUNTRY (1987).
  • 3
    • 84983958104 scopus 로고
    • A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model, 91
    • Robert Barro & Roger Gordon, A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model, 91 J. POL. ECON. 589 (1983).
    • (1983) J. POL. ECON , vol.589
    • Barro, R.1    Gordon, R.2
  • 4
    • 0012034141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Adopt Transparency? The Publication of Central Bank Forecasts
    • See, e.g, July, unpublished manuscript, on file with the University of Cambridge
    • See, e.g., Petra M. Geraats, Why Adopt Transparency? The Publication of Central Bank Forecasts (July 2002) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the University of Cambridge);
    • (2002)
    • Geraats, P.M.1
  • 5
    • 0036864181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Central Bank Transparency, 112
    • at
    • Petra M. Geraats, Central Bank Transparency, 112 ECON. J., at F532 (2002).
    • (2002) ECON. J
    • Geraats, P.M.1
  • 6
    • 0006260747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory, 115
    • See
    • See Richard Clarida, Jordi Gali & Mark Gertler, Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory, 115 Q.J. ECON. 147 (2000);
    • (2000) Q.J. ECON , vol.147
    • Clarida, R.1    Gali, J.2    Gertler, M.3
  • 7
    • 77649167771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Larence J. Christiano & Christopher Gust, The Expectations Trap, ECON. PERSP. (Fed. Reserve Bank of Chi.), Q. II, 2000, at 21, available at http://www.chicagofed.org/publications/ economicperspectives/2000/2qep2.pdf.
    • Larence J. Christiano & Christopher Gust, The Expectations Trap, ECON. PERSP. (Fed. Reserve Bank of Chi.), Q. II, 2000, at 21, available at http://www.chicagofed.org/publications/ economicperspectives/2000/2qep2.pdf.
  • 8
    • 0009903373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Faust and Svensson consider a model in which the public attempts to infer whether or not the central bank is serious about limiting inflation from information on policy outcomes. Its inferences are imperfect because of unanticipated policy-implementation errors that the public is incompletely able to observe. Greater transparency about economic conditions thus enables agents to infer the central bank's preferences more accurately. In turn, this gives the monetary authority an incentive to build a reputation for valuing price stability. The private sector becomes more sensitive to unanticipated policy responses and actions, attenuating the incentive for the central bank to engage in them. The result is thus greater sensitivity of inflation expectations to policy actions, less benefit to the central bank for fueling inflation, and less inflationary bias. In this way, increased transparency about control errors improves social welfare. Greater transparency about the central bank's objecti
    • Faust and Svensson consider a model in which the public attempts to infer whether or not the central bank is serious about limiting inflation from information on policy outcomes. Its inferences are imperfect because of unanticipated policy-implementation errors that the public is incompletely able to observe. Greater transparency about economic conditions thus enables agents to infer the central bank's preferences more accurately. In turn, this gives the monetary authority an incentive to build a reputation for valuing price stability. The private sector becomes more sensitive to unanticipated policy responses and actions, attenuating the incentive for the central bank to engage in them. The result is thus greater sensitivity of inflation expectations to policy actions, less benefit to the central bank for fueling inflation, and less inflationary bias. In this way, increased transparency about control errors improves social welfare. Greater transparency about the central bank's objectives may be more of a mixed blessing in this framework. In addition to reducing uncertainty about future inflation and output, which would, all other things equal, be welfare-improving, transparency about objectives removes the central bank's incentive to curtail inflation in order to signal its type, which could be welfare-reducing. See Jon Faust & Lars Svensson, Transparency and Credibility: Monetary Policy with Unobservable Goals, 42 INT'L ECON. REV. 369 (2001).
  • 9
    • 77649171367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moreover, while observers may never have been exactly ignorant about the influence of monetary policy over economic and financial conditions, it was less fully appreciated than today, when traders hold their collective breath on the days when the central bank announces its interest-rate decision. And where the extent of the franchise and of political contestability was limited, there was no more need for the central bank to be democratically accountable than any other branch of government
    • Moreover, while observers may never have been exactly ignorant about the influence of monetary policy over economic and financial conditions, it was less fully appreciated than today, when traders hold their collective breath on the days when the central bank announces its interest-rate decision. And where the extent of the franchise and of political contestability was limited, there was no more need for the central bank to be democratically accountable than any other branch of government.
  • 10
    • 0013082741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Morris and Shin illustrate the point in a model in which individual welfare depends not just on the state of the world, but on the actions of other individuals there exists a coordination externality, Starting from a position where both private and public information are imperfect, they show that greater precision of public information can lead individuals to attach inadequate weight to private information. In the absence of coordination motives, the precision attached to the public and private signals will be commensurate with their relative precision. When coordination motives are present, however, agents attach greater weight to the public signal, since they know this to be common information. But since the public signal is noisy, this weight on the public signal may be suboptimal from a social-welfare point of view; agents may be led to coordinate on the basis of an inefficient equilibrium. The more precise the private information, the more likely this adverse outcome is to ensue
    • Morris and Shin illustrate the point in a model in which individual welfare depends not just on the state of the world, but on the actions of other individuals (there exists a coordination externality). Starting from a position where both private and public information are imperfect, they show that greater precision of public information can lead individuals to attach inadequate weight to private information. In the absence of coordination motives, the precision attached to the public and private signals will be commensurate with their relative precision. When coordination motives are present, however, agents attach greater weight to the public signal, since they know this to be common information. But since the public signal is noisy, this weight on the public signal may be suboptimal from a social-welfare point of view; agents may be led to coordinate on the basis of an inefficient equilibrium. The more precise the private information, the more likely this adverse outcome is to ensue. See Stephen Morris & Hyun Shin, The Social Value of Public Information, 92 AM. ECON. REV. 1521 (2002);
  • 11
    • 33645367011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stephen Morris & Hyun Shin, Central Bank Transparency and the Signal Value of Prices, [2005] 2 BROOKINGS PAPERS ECON. AACTIVITY 1.
    • Stephen Morris & Hyun Shin, Central Bank Transparency and the Signal Value of Prices, [2005] 2 BROOKINGS PAPERS ECON. AACTIVITY 1.
  • 12
    • 77649125898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus, some critics of the European Central Bank, whose transnational status, embedded in an international treaty, makes it difficult for national politicians to sanction those responsible for its policy, question whether policy transparency provides adequate political accountability
    • Thus, some critics of the European Central Bank, whose transnational status, embedded in an international treaty, makes it difficult for national politicians to sanction those responsible for its policy, question whether policy transparency provides adequate political accountability.
  • 13
    • 77649117043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sirkka Hamalainen, The ECB's Monetary Policy - Accountability, Transparency and Communication (Sept. 14, 2001) (speech delivered to the Conference on Old Age, New Economy, and Central Banking), available at http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2001/html/sp010914.en.html for an early statement to this effect.
    • See Sirkka Hamalainen, The ECB's Monetary Policy - Accountability, Transparency and Communication (Sept. 14, 2001) (speech delivered to the Conference on Old Age, New Economy, and Central Banking), available at http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2001/html/sp010914.en.html for an early statement to this effect.
  • 14
    • 77649098676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrew Clare & Roger Courtenay, Assessing the Impact of Macroeconomic News Announcements on Securities Prices Under Different Monetary Policy Regimes (Bank of Eng., Working Paper No. 125, 2001).
    • Andrew Clare & Roger Courtenay, Assessing the Impact of Macroeconomic News Announcements on Securities Prices Under Different Monetary Policy Regimes (Bank of Eng., Working Paper No. 125, 2001).
  • 15
    • 77649114540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carin A.B. van der Cruijsen, Sylvester C.W. Eijffinger & Lex H. Hoogduin, Optimal Central Bank Transparency (June 2008) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the De Nederlandsche Bank, Tilberg University and University of Amsterdam).
    • Carin A.B. van der Cruijsen, Sylvester C.W. Eijffinger & Lex H. Hoogduin, Optimal Central Bank Transparency (June 2008) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the De Nederlandsche Bank, Tilberg University and University of Amsterdam).
  • 16
    • 77649103484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charles Goodhart, Monetary Transmission Lags and the Formulation of the Policy Decision on Interest Rates, FED. RES. BANK ST. LOUIS REV., July/Aug. 2001, at 165.
    • Charles Goodhart, Monetary Transmission Lags and the Formulation of the Policy Decision on Interest Rates, FED. RES. BANK ST. LOUIS REV., July/Aug. 2001, at 165.
  • 17
    • 77649149825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some central banks go partway toward indicating the prospective future path of interest rates; the Federal Reserve, for example, regularly signals its bias toward future interest-rate increases or reductions by issuing a balance of risks statement
    • Some central banks go partway toward indicating the prospective future path of interest rates; the Federal Reserve, for example, regularly signals its "bias" toward future interest-rate increases or reductions by issuing a "balance of risks" statement.
  • 20
    • 77649107364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mishkin, supra note 15
    • Mishkin, supra note 15.
  • 21
    • 32144438376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Transparent Are Central Banks?, 22 EUR
    • Sylvester Eijffinger & Petra Geraats, How Transparent Are Central Banks?, 22 EUR. J. POL. ECON. 1 (2006).
    • (2006) J. POL. ECON , vol.1
    • Eijffinger, S.1    Geraats, P.2
  • 22
    • 77649147827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The overall index thus runs from 0 to 15. Adopting the same criteria used by these previous investigators has the advantage of facilitating comparisons across studies and frees us of any suspicion that we have constructed our measures so as to maximize or minimize the impact of transparency.
    • The overall index thus runs from 0 to 15. Adopting the same criteria used by these previous investigators has the advantage of facilitating comparisons across studies and frees us of any suspicion that we have constructed our measures so as to maximize or minimize the impact of transparency.
  • 23
    • 17644411371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An earlier study by Bini-Smaghi and Gros also considered 15 aspects of central bank transparency, although they considered only four central banks. See Lorenzo Bini-Smaghi & Daniel Gros, Is the ECB Sufficiently Accountable and Transparent, European Network of Econ. Policy Research Inst, Working Paper No. 7, 2001, De Haan, Amtenbrink and Waller developed a similar index for six countries, while De Haan and Amtembrink apply a similar approach to 15 countries. See Jakob De Haan, Fabian Amtenbrink & Sandra Waller, The Transparency and Credibility of the European Central Bank, 42 J. COMMON MKT. STUD. 775 (2004);
    • An earlier study by Bini-Smaghi and Gros also considered 15 aspects of central bank transparency, although they considered only four central banks. See Lorenzo Bini-Smaghi & Daniel Gros, Is the ECB Sufficiently Accountable and Transparent? (European Network of Econ. Policy Research Inst., Working Paper No. 7, 2001). De Haan, Amtenbrink and Waller developed a similar index for six countries, while De Haan and Amtembrink apply a similar approach to 15 countries. See Jakob De Haan, Fabian Amtenbrink & Sandra Waller, The Transparency and Credibility of the European Central Bank, 42 J. COMMON MKT. STUD. 775 (2004);
  • 24
    • 77649111329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jakob De Haan & Fabian Amtenbrink, A Non-Transparent European Central Bank: Who Is to Blame? (May 2002) (unpublished manuscript, presented at the Bank of England to the conference on Monetary Policy Transparency). Siklos expands coverage to twenty central banks, all from advanced industrial countries.
    • Jakob De Haan & Fabian Amtenbrink, A Non-Transparent European Central Bank: Who Is to Blame? (May 2002) (unpublished manuscript, presented at the Bank of England to the conference on Monetary Policy Transparency). Siklos expands coverage to twenty central banks, all from advanced industrial countries.
  • 25
    • 77649127165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PIERRE SIKLOS, THE CHANGING FACE OF CENTRAL BANKING: EVOLUTIONARY TRENDS SINCE WORLD WAR II (2002). The most comprehensive previous study in terms of country coverage is Fry et al., although they construct indices only for 1998.
    • See PIERRE SIKLOS, THE CHANGING FACE OF CENTRAL BANKING: EVOLUTIONARY TRENDS SINCE WORLD WAR II (2002). The most comprehensive previous study in terms of country coverage is Fry et al., although they construct indices only for 1998.
  • 26
    • 77649156899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Maxwell Fry et al., Key Issues in the Choice of a Monetary Policy Framework, in MONETARY POLICY FRAMEWORKS IN A GLOBAL CONTEXT 1 (Lavan Mahadeva & Gabriel Sterne eds., 2000).
    • See Maxwell Fry et al., Key Issues in the Choice of a Monetary Policy Framework, in MONETARY POLICY FRAMEWORKS IN A GLOBAL CONTEXT 1 (Lavan Mahadeva & Gabriel Sterne eds., 2000).
  • 27
    • 77649138980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adding this time dimension was particularly challenging, since many central bank websites describe current practice, but not that of prior years. For that we had to rely mainly on published documents. We were able to access a relatively complete run of these on the basis of holdings in the University of California and Joint IMF-World Bank libraries. We are grateful to the staff of the Joint Bank-Fund library for granting us access to their collection
    • Adding this time dimension was particularly challenging, since many central bank websites describe current practice, but not that of prior years. For that we had to rely mainly on published documents. We were able to access a relatively complete run of these on the basis of holdings in the University of California and Joint IMF-World Bank libraries. We are grateful to the staff of the Joint Bank-Fund library for granting us access to their collection.
  • 28
    • 77649085209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is the vast majority of central banks in the world (recall that there are more countries than there are central banks, given the existence of monetary unions, countries that have unilaterally adopted the currencies of other countries, etc, A subsequent study by Crowe and Meade constructs measures of transparency very similar to our own, but only since 2000 and for a much smaller (37 country) sample (their purpose being to compare measures of central bank transparency and independence, See Christopher Crowe & Ellen Meade, Central Bank Independence and Transparency: Evolution and Effectiveness Int'l Monetary Fund, Working Paper No. 08/119, 2008
    • This is the vast majority of central banks in the world (recall that there are more countries than there are central banks, given the existence of monetary unions, countries that have unilaterally adopted the currencies of other countries, etc.). A subsequent study by Crowe and Meade constructs measures of transparency very similar to our own, but only since 2000 and for a much smaller (37 country) sample (their purpose being to compare measures of central bank transparency and independence). See Christopher Crowe & Ellen Meade, Central Bank Independence and Transparency: Evolution and Effectiveness (Int'l Monetary Fund, Working Paper No. 08/119, 2008).
  • 29
    • 77649147828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Among the omissions are Bolivia, Ecuador, Chad, Iran, and Afghanistan. We are aware that this creates a form of sampling bias: we tend to oversample more transparent central banks. Although econometric corrections for this bias (involving strong assumptions) do exist, we have not implemented these yet. Our defense is that the number of consequential omissions is relatively slight
    • Among the omissions are Bolivia, Ecuador, Chad, Iran, and Afghanistan. We are aware that this creates a form of sampling bias: we tend to oversample more transparent central banks. Although econometric corrections for this bias (involving strong assumptions) do exist, we have not implemented these yet. Our defense is that the number of consequential omissions is relatively slight.
  • 30
    • 77649159827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Up from 47 in 1998
    • Up from 47 in 1998.
  • 31
    • 77649108694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • -2006 being the most recent year for which all the ancillary variables are currently available.
    • -2006 being the most recent year for which all the ancillary variables are currently available.
  • 32
    • 0041738311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carmen Reinhart, Kenneth Rogoff & Miguel Savastano, Debt Intolerance, [2003] 1 BROOKINGS PAPERS ECON. ACTIVITY 1;
    • Carmen Reinhart, Kenneth Rogoff & Miguel Savastano, Debt Intolerance, [2003] 1 BROOKINGS PAPERS ECON. ACTIVITY 1;
  • 33
    • 33745959564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barry Eichengreen & Raul Razo-Garcia, The International Monetary System in the Last and Next 20 Years, 21 ECON. POL'Y 393 (2006).
    • Barry Eichengreen & Raul Razo-Garcia, The International Monetary System in the Last and Next 20 Years, 21 ECON. POL'Y 393 (2006).
  • 35
    • 77649140930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where we use variables from the Polity database, we are forced to end the analysis in 2004.
    • Where we use variables from the Polity database, we are forced to end the analysis in 2004.
  • 36
    • 77649173685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Readers may be concerned that the exchange rate regime is endogenous, that countries with experience with monetary policy transparency may be better able to operate regimes of greater flexibility. In the event, dropping the exchange-rate regime leaves the other results unchanged
    • Readers may be concerned that the exchange rate regime is endogenous - that countries with experience with monetary policy transparency may be better able to operate regimes of greater flexibility. In the event, dropping the exchange-rate regime leaves the other results unchanged.
  • 37
    • 77649146838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The other variables do not approach statistical significance at conventional confidence levels. For what they are worth, the point estimates suggest that central banks of countries with better developed financial markets tend to be more transparent. Similarly, central banks of countries with a history of inflation tend to be more transparent, presumably as part of a credibility-building strategy. This is not something that might have been anticipated from the contrast between transparency in advanced and developing countries
    • The other variables do not approach statistical significance at conventional confidence levels. For what they are worth, the point estimates suggest that central banks of countries with better developed financial markets tend to be more transparent. Similarly, central banks of countries with a history of inflation tend to be more transparent, presumably as part of a credibility-building strategy. This is not something that might have been anticipated from the contrast between transparency in advanced and developing countries.
  • 38
    • 77649155853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When we include multiple political variables, it is voice and accountability and government efficiency that are most often significant at standard confidence levels
    • When we include multiple political variables, it is voice and accountability and government efficiency that are most often significant at standard confidence levels.
  • 39
    • 77649164480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that the polity variable in the final column is the difference between democracy and autocracy
    • Note that the "polity" variable in the final column is the difference between "democracy" and "autocracy."
  • 40
    • 77649130338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political transparency also appears to decline with financial depth, which is not a pattern for which we have an immediate explanation. Interestingly, other components such as economic and procedural transparency are positively associated with financial depth, as can be seen from the corresponding tables
    • Political transparency also appears to decline with financial depth, which is not a pattern for which we have an immediate explanation. Interestingly, other components such as economic and procedural transparency are positively associated with financial depth, as can be seen from the corresponding tables.
  • 41
    • 77649145517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The standard Hausman and Breusch-Pagan tests reject random effects and simple pooling in favor of fixed effects (the Hausman test statistic is reported at the foot of the tables). See also the further discussion below.
    • The standard Hausman and Breusch-Pagan tests reject random effects and simple pooling in favor of fixed effects (the Hausman test statistic is reported at the foot of the tables). See also the further discussion below.
  • 42
    • 77649091704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mishkin, supra note 15
    • Mishkin, supra note 15.
  • 43
    • 77649120066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But not between the level of inflation and transparency. See Maria Demertzis & Andrew Hughes Hallett, Central Bank Transparency in Theory and Practice, (Jan. 2003) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Netherlands Bank and Vanderbilt University).
    • But not between the level of inflation and transparency. See Maria Demertzis & Andrew Hughes Hallett, Central Bank Transparency in Theory and Practice, (Jan. 2003) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Netherlands Bank and Vanderbilt University).
  • 44
    • 21244501699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gregory Mankiw, Ricardo Reis & Justin Wolfers, Disagreement About Inflation Expectations, 2003 NAT 'L BUREAU ECON. RES. MACROECONOMICSANN. 209 (2004);
    • Gregory Mankiw, Ricardo Reis & Justin Wolfers, Disagreement About Inflation Expectations, 2003 NAT 'L BUREAU ECON. RES. MACROECONOMICSANN. 209 (2004);
  • 46
    • 77649133584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Refet Gurkaynak, Andrew Levin & Eric Swanson, Inflation Targeting and the Anchoring of Long-Run Inflation Expectations: International Evidence from Daily Bond Yield Data (June 2005) (unpublished manuscript, prepared for the Riksbank Workshop on Inflation Targeting, Stockholm) (on file with authors).
    • Refet Gurkaynak, Andrew Levin & Eric Swanson, Inflation Targeting and the Anchoring of Long-Run Inflation Expectations: International Evidence from Daily Bond Yield Data (June 2005) (unpublished manuscript, prepared for the Riksbank Workshop on Inflation Targeting, Stockholm) (on file with authors).
  • 47
    • 77649112760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Results using alternative instrument lists are discussed below and are available from the authors on request
    • Results using alternative instrument lists are discussed below and are available from the authors on request.
  • 48
    • 77649138663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Though the confidence level in question depends on which specific controls are included or excluded
    • Though the confidence level in question depends on which specific controls are included or excluded.
  • 49
    • 77649146366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The squared term, like the level, is constructed from the fitted value of transparency derived from the first-stage regression
    • The squared term, like the level, is constructed from the fitted value of transparency derived from the first-stage regression.
  • 50
    • 77649090172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If the coefficients are taken literally, they suggest that the benefits in terms of reducing inflation variability dissipate and inflation variability begins to rise with transparency when the index for the latter exceeds five, a suspiciously low threshold. Thus we do not want to push these particular point estimates too far
    • If the coefficients are taken literally, they suggest that the benefits in terms of reducing inflation variability dissipate and inflation variability begins to rise with transparency when the index for the latter exceeds five, a suspiciously low threshold. Thus we do not want to push these particular point estimates too far.
  • 51
    • 77649133585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Van der Cruijsen et al., supra note 12.
    • Van der Cruijsen et al., supra note 12.
  • 52
    • 77649100155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The versions of the equation run with instruments are again estimated by GMM. The two-stage least squares version simply applying the instruments to transparency yields the same results
    • The versions of the equation run with instruments are again estimated by GMM. The two-stage least squares version simply applying the instruments to transparency yields the same results.
  • 53
    • 77649173686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The coefficient on the fifth component enters with a t-statistic of 4.2. None of the other coefficients have t's in excess of one.
    • The coefficient on the fifth component enters with a t-statistic of 4.2. None of the other coefficients have t's in excess of one.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.