메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 84, Issue 5, 2009, Pages 1222-1291

Existing uses and the limits of land use regulations

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 70450239866     PISSN: 00287881     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (35)

References (562)
  • 1
    • 84869675071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Hooper v. City of St. Paul, 353 N.W.2d 138, 140 (Minn. 1984) referring to "constitutional protection afforded existing uses"
    • See, e.g., Hooper v. City of St. Paul, 353 N.W.2d 138, 140 (Minn. 1984) (referring to "constitutional protection afforded existing uses"
  • 2
    • 70450229347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing County of Freeborn v. Claussen, 203 N.W.2d 323, 325 (Minn. 1972)
    • citing County of Freeborn v. Claussen, 203 N.W.2d 323, 325 (Minn. 1972)
  • 3
    • 70450250899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 325 (Minn. 1972)
    • 325 (Minn. 1972).
  • 4
    • 84869682520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rudolf Steiner Fellowship Found, v. De Luccia, 685 N.E.2d 192, 197 (N.Y. 1997) (Bellacosa, J., dissenting) "It is the law of this state that nonconforming uses or structures, in existence when a zoning ordinance is enacted, are, as a general rule, constitutionally protected and will be permitted to continue, notwithstanding the contrary provisions of the ordinance."
    • Rudolf Steiner Fellowship Found, v. De Luccia, 685 N.E.2d 192, 197 (N.Y. 1997) (Bellacosa, J., dissenting) ("It is the law of this state that nonconforming uses or structures, in existence when a zoning ordinance is enacted, are, as a general rule, constitutionally protected and will be permitted to continue, notwithstanding the contrary provisions of the ordinance." (
  • 5
    • 70450240403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing People v. Miller, 106 N.E.2d 34, 35 (N.Y. 1952)
    • citing People v. Miller, 106 N.E.2d 34, 35 (N.Y. 1952)
  • 6
    • 70450231273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 106 N.E.2d 34, 35 (N.Y. 1952)
    • 106 N.E.2d 34, 35 (N.Y. 1952)
  • 7
    • 84869671443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harbison v. City of Buffalo, 152 N.E.2d 42, 44 (N.Y. 1958) ("When zoning ordinances are initially adopted to limit permissible uses of property, or when property is rezoned ... to prevent uses of property previously allowed, a degree of protection is constitutionally required to be given owners of property then using their premises in a manner forbidden by the ordinance.")
    • Harbison v. City of Buffalo, 152 N.E.2d 42, 44 (N.Y. 1958) ("When zoning ordinances are initially adopted to limit permissible uses of property, or when property is rezoned ... to prevent uses of property previously allowed, a degree of protection is constitutionally required to be given owners of property then using their premises in a manner forbidden by the ordinance.");
  • 8
    • 84869671444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Snake River Brewing Co. v. Town of Jackson, 39 P.3d 397, 403 (Wyo. 2002) ("When a zoning ordinance is enacted, it cannot outlaw previously existing non-conforming uses. This right to continue a non-conforming use is a vested property right, protected by statute, and by both federal and state constitutions." (citations and internal quotation marks omitted)).
    • Snake River Brewing Co. v. Town of Jackson, 39 P.3d 397, 403 (Wyo. 2002) ("When a zoning ordinance is enacted, it cannot outlaw previously existing non-conforming uses. This right to continue a non-conforming use is a vested property right, protected by statute, and by both federal and state constitutions." (citations and internal quotation marks omitted)).
  • 9
    • 70450286873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For discussion of these doctrines, see infra Part I.
    • For discussion of these doctrines, see infra Part I.
  • 10
    • 70450234297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some specific doctrines related to existing uses have received serious study, however. For example, the doctrines governing the treatment of prior nonconforming uses, which are the subject of Part I.B, infra, have received significant attention.
    • Some specific doctrines related to existing uses have received serious study, however. For example, the doctrines governing the treatment of prior nonconforming uses, which are the subject of Part I.B, infra, have received significant attention.
  • 11
    • 84869671445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. ch. 4OA, § 6 (West 2004) (forbidding zoning ordinances to apply to structures "lawfully in existence or lawfully begun" before first notice of new law, but requiring their application to "any change or substantial extension of such use");
    • See, e.g., MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. ch. 4OA, § 6 (West 2004) (forbidding zoning ordinances to apply to structures "lawfully in existence or lawfully begun" before first notice of new law, but requiring their application to "any change or substantial extension of such use");
  • 12
    • 84869684601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N.J. STAT. ANN. § 40:550-68 (West 2008) ("Any nonconforming use or structure existing at the time of the passage of an ordinance may be continued upon the lot or in the structure so occupied and any such structure may be restored or repaired in the event of partial destruction thereof.");
    • N.J. STAT. ANN. § 40:550-68 (West 2008) ("Any nonconforming use or structure existing at the time of the passage of an ordinance may be continued upon the lot or in the structure so occupied and any such structure may be restored or repaired in the event of partial destruction thereof.");
  • 13
    • 84869679220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rourke v. Rothman, 859 N.E.2d 821, 822 n.5 (Mass. 2007) (citing statute that "sets the floor for 'grandfather' protection in local zoning bylaws")
    • Rourke v. Rothman, 859 N.E.2d 821, 822 n.5 (Mass. 2007) (citing statute that "sets the floor for 'grandfather' protection in local zoning bylaws");
  • 14
    • 84869684598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Ferraro v. Bd. of Zoning Adjustment, 970 So. 2d 299, 310 (Ala. Civ. App. 2007) ("Generally, nonconforming uses of property are 'grandfathered' under zoning ordinances and not lost unless the owner abandons that use.")
    • see also Ferraro v. Bd. of Zoning Adjustment, 970 So. 2d 299, 310 (Ala. Civ. App. 2007) ("Generally, nonconforming uses of property are 'grandfathered' under zoning ordinances and not lost unless the owner abandons that use.");
  • 15
    • 84869671441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Manhattan, Inc. v. Shelby County, No. W2006-02017-COA-R3-CV, 2008 WL 639791, at *7 (Tenn. Ct. App. Mar. 11, 2008) (noting that local zoning ordinances "specifically permit a lawful use in existence at the time of any zoning change to continue after the change, i.e., 'grandfathered' nonconforming use, with certain restrictions").
    • Manhattan, Inc. v. Shelby County, No. W2006-02017-COA-R3-CV, 2008 WL 639791, at *7 (Tenn. Ct. App. Mar. 11, 2008) (noting that local zoning ordinances "specifically permit a lawful use in existence at the time of any zoning change to continue after the change, i.e., 'grandfathered' nonconforming use, with certain restrictions").
  • 16
    • 70450247823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ex parte Ala. Alcoholic Beverage Control Bd., 819 So. 2d 50, 52-53 (Ala. 2001) (upholding Control Board's denial of expansion of nonconforming use but recognizing store as valid nonconforming use allowed to operate)
    • See Ex parte Ala. Alcoholic Beverage Control Bd., 819 So. 2d 50, 52-53 (Ala. 2001) (upholding Control Board's denial of expansion of nonconforming use but recognizing store as valid nonconforming use allowed to operate);
  • 17
    • 84869684599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brewster v. Fayette County Bd. of County Comm'rs, No. W2003-01842-COA-R3-CV, 2005 WL 873224, at *1 (Tenn. Ct. App. Apr. 14, 2005) (holding that previously "grandfathered" grocery store on property could not reopen without demonstrating continuous use of property). This rule is subject to various techniques - like amortization - that local governments can, in fact, use to eliminate existing uses. See infra Part I.B (discussing amortization).
    • Brewster v. Fayette County Bd. of County Comm'rs, No. W2003-01842-COA-R3-CV, 2005 WL 873224, at *1 (Tenn. Ct. App. Apr. 14, 2005) (holding that previously "grandfathered" grocery store on property could not reopen without demonstrating continuous use of property). This rule is subject to various techniques - like amortization - that local governments can, in fact, use to eliminate existing uses. See infra Part I.B (discussing amortization).
  • 18
    • 70450265443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a more emotional example, consider a co-op board seeking to enforce a new nopets policy. There is little doubt in most jurisdictions that such policies are permissible prospectively, but it is another matter entirely to apply the policy against existing pets.
    • For a more emotional example, consider a co-op board seeking to enforce a new nopets policy. There is little doubt in most jurisdictions that such policies are permissible prospectively, but it is another matter entirely to apply the policy against existing pets.
  • 19
    • 70450242700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Winston Towers 200 Ass'n v. Saverio, 360 So. 2d 470, 470-71 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1978) (holding invalid attempt to fine condo owner for keeping puppy of dog grandfathered into co-op's no-pet policy)
    • See, e.g., Winston Towers 200 Ass'n v. Saverio, 360 So. 2d 470, 470-71 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1978) (holding invalid attempt to fine condo owner for keeping puppy of dog grandfathered into co-op's no-pet policy),
  • 21
    • 84869671442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Young v. Savinon, 492 A.2d 385, 390 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 1985) (invalidating no-pets provision in lease renewal as applied to existing dogs). For a particularly funny examination of no-pet policies, see The Daily Show with Jon Stewart: Rent Claws (Comedy Central television broadcast Mar. 29, 2004), available at
    • Young v. Savinon, 492 A.2d 385, 390 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 1985) (invalidating no-pets provision in lease renewal as applied to existing dogs). For a particularly funny examination of no-pet policies, see The Daily Show with Jon Stewart: Rent Claws (Comedy Central television broadcast Mar. 29, 2004), available at http://www. thedailyshow.com/video/index.jhtml?title=rent- claws&videoId=124322.
  • 22
    • 33947630415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 7 §41.01 [2], If the goal of [zoning] regulations was to ensure uniformity of all uses in a particular district, dissimilar existing uses would detract from that purpose as much as new uses.
    • See 7 PATRICK J. ROHAN, ZONING AND LAND USE CONTROLS §41.01 [2], at 41-47 (2009) ("If the goal of [zoning] regulations was to ensure uniformity of all uses in a particular district, dissimilar existing uses would detract from that purpose as much as new uses.");
    • (2009) Zoning And Land Use Controls , pp. 41-47
    • Rohan, P.J.1
  • 23
    • 34250306774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Local Property Law: Adjusting the Scale of Property Protection
    • 940 The extent of existing development in developed cities means that changes in applicable zoning must either include an enormous number of nonconforming uses-potentially undermining the efficacy of the zoning regime-or come with some plan for eliminating the nonconforming uses over time.
    • Christopher Serkin, Local Property Law: Adjusting the Scale of Property Protection, 107 COLUM. L. REV. 883, 940 (2007) ("The extent of existing development in developed cities means that changes in applicable zoning must either include an enormous number of nonconforming uses-potentially undermining the efficacy of the zoning regime-or come with some plan for eliminating the nonconforming uses over time.");
    • (2007) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.107 , pp. 883
    • Serkin, C.1
  • 24
    • 84869684596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Cohen v. Duncan, No. Civ.A.2002-599, Civ.A.2001-380, 2004 WL 1351155, at *15 (R.I. Super. Ct. June 9, 2004) ("The restrictive provisions of the ordinance properly recognize that 'nonconforming uses are a thorn in the side of proper zoning and should not be perpetuated any longer than necessary.'" (second alteration in original) (internal citation omitted)).
    • see also Cohen v. Duncan, No. Civ.A.2002-599, Civ.A.2001-380, 2004 WL 1351155, at *15 (R.I. Super. Ct. June 9, 2004) ("The restrictive provisions of the [ordinance properly recognize that '[nonconforming uses are a thorn in the side of proper zoning and should not be perpetuated any longer than necessary.'" (second alteration in original) (internal citation omitted)).
  • 25
    • 84869671436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court originally justified zoning as separating incompatible neighbors, noting that a "nuisance may be merely a right thing in the wrong place, like a pig in the parlor instead of the barnyard." Vill. of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365, 388 (1926)
    • The Supreme Court originally justified zoning as separating incompatible neighbors, noting that a "nuisance may be merely a right thing in the wrong place, like a pig in the parlor instead of the barnyard." Vill. of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365, 388 (1926);
  • 26
    • 0347798692 scopus 로고
    • The Impact of Variances: A Study of Statewide Zoning
    • see also 771-72 describing use of variances as "especially dangerous because they jeopardize zoning's primary purpose: separating incompatible land uses
    • see also David P. Bryden, The Impact of Variances: A Study of Statewide Zoning, 61 MINN. L. REV. 769, 771-72 (1977) (describing use of variances as "especially dangerous because they jeopardize zoning's primary purpose: separating incompatible land uses").
    • (1977) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 769
    • Bryden, D.P.1
  • 27
    • 70450233482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra note 40 and Part IV.A (discussing transitions literature). Academic writing on legal transitions has tended to focus both on changes in tax rules and on changes in property rules, with the latter squarely implicating the Takings Clause and the extent of protection from regulatory change.
    • See infra note 40 and Part IV.A (discussing transitions literature). Academic writing on legal transitions has tended to focus both on changes in tax rules and on changes in property rules, with the latter squarely implicating the Takings Clause and the extent of protection from regulatory change.
  • 29
    • 84934564251 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of Legal Transitions
    • 517 discussing changes to property rules
    • Louis Kaplow, An Economic Analysis of Legal Transitions, 99 HARV. L. REV. 509, 517 (1986) (discussing changes to property rules).
    • (1986) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 509
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 30
    • 37749039804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grandfathering and Environmental Regulation: The Law and Economics of New Source Review
    • See generally, e.g., discussing harms of grandfather clauses in recent legislation.
    • See generally, e.g., Jonathan Remy Nash & Richard L. Revesz, Grandfathering and Environmental Regulation: The Law and Economics of New Source Review, 101 Nw. U. L. EV. 1677 (2007) (discussing harms of grandfather clauses in recent legislation).
    • (2007) Nw. U. L. Ev. , vol.101 , pp. 1677
    • Nash, J.R.1    Revesz, R.L.2
  • 31
    • 70450258512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1729 (discussing how Bush administration policies exacerbated this problem).
    • See id. at 1729 (discussing how Bush administration policies exacerbated this problem).
  • 32
    • 84869671434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 42 U.S.C. §§ 7401-7671q (2006).
    • 42 U.S.C. §§ 7401-7671q (2006).
  • 33
    • 84869671438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 42 U.S.C. § 7411(a)(3) (2006) (defining stationary source). Existing uses are subject only to state implementation of ambient air quality requirements and not to the stricter emissions reduction requirements for new sources, which are set by the federal government.
    • 42 U.S.C. § 7411(a)(3) (2006) (defining stationary source). Existing uses are subject only to state implementation of ambient air quality requirements and not to the stricter emissions reduction requirements for new sources, which are set by the federal government.
  • 35
    • 84869679215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 42 U.S.C. § 7411(a)(2), (4) (2006) (defining new source as any source "the construction or modification of which is commenced after publication of regulations" and defining modification as "any physical change in, or change in method of operation of, a stationary source which increases the amount of air pollutant emitted"). This is like the converse of the vested rights doctrine, discussed in Part LC, infra.
    • 42 U.S.C. § 7411(a)(2), (4) (2006) (defining new source as any source "the construction or modification of which is commenced after publication of regulations" and defining modification as "any physical change in, or change in method of operation of, a stationary source which increases the amount of air pollutant emitted"). This is like the converse of the vested rights doctrine, discussed in Part LC, infra.
  • 36
    • 84869671431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 33 U.S.C. §§ 1251-1387 (2006).
    • 33 U.S.C. §§ 1251-1387 (2006).
  • 37
    • 84869688736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 33 U.S.C. § 1316(d);
    • 33 U.S.C. § 1316(d);
  • 38
    • 70450241601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also supra note 10, at discussing grandfathering provisions in Clean Water Act
    • see also Nash & Revesz, supra note 10, at 1728-1729 (discussing grandfathering provisions in Clean Water Act).
    • Nash1    Revesz2
  • 39
    • 0000967070 scopus 로고
    • If Your Grandfather Could Pollute, so Can You: Environmental "Grandfather Clauses " and Their Role in Environmental Inequity
    • See 132-33 & nn.8-15 providing examples of grandfather clauses from various legal contexts;
    • See Heidi Gorovitz Robertson, If Your Grandfather Could Pollute, So Can You: Environmental "Grandfather Clauses " and Their Role in Environmental Inequity, 45 CATH. U. L. REV. 131, 132-33 & nn.8-15 (1995) (providing examples of grandfather clauses from various legal contexts);
    • (1995) CATH. U. L. REV. , vol.45 , pp. 131
    • Robertson, H.G.1
  • 40
    • 47749108284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Optimal Change, Past Behavior, and Grandfathering
    • 69-70 same.
    • Steven Shavell, On Optimal Change, Past Behavior, and Grandfathering, 37 J. LEGAL STUD. 37, 69-70 (2008) (same).
    • (2008) J. Legal Stud. , vol.37 , pp. 37
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 41
    • 84869684594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 42 U.S.C. § 12101-12213 (2006).
    • 42 U.S.C. § 12101-12213 (2006).
  • 42
    • 84869671430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 28 C.F.R. § 36.304 (2008) implementing Title III of Americans with Disabilities Act; requiring existing buildings to "remove architectural barriers in existing facilities" but only "where such removal is readily achievable, i.e., easily accomplishable and able to be carried out without much difficulty or expense"
    • See 28 C.F.R. § 36.304 (2008) (implementing Title III of Americans with Disabilities Act; requiring existing buildings to "remove architectural barriers in existing facilities" but only "where such removal is readily achievable, i.e., easily accomplishable and able to be carried out without much difficulty or expense");
  • 43
    • 70450273138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal Implications of the Americans with Disabilities Act on Recreation Services: Changing Guidelines, Structures, and Attitudes in Accommodating Guests with Disabilities
    • see also 235 describing application of ADA to new and existing facilities
    • see also John Grady & Damon Andrew, Legal Implications of the Americans with Disabilities Act on Recreation Services: Changing Guidelines, Structures, and Attitudes in Accommodating Guests with Disabilities, 13 J. LEGAL ASPECTS SPORT 231, 235 (2003) (describing application of ADA to new and existing facilities).
    • (2003) J. Legal Aspects Sport , vol.13 , pp. 231
    • Grady, J.1    Andrew, D.2
  • 44
    • 84869688734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 16 U.S.C. §§ 1131-1136 (2006).
    • 16 U.S.C. §§ 1131-1136 (2006).
  • 45
    • 0025616107 scopus 로고
    • Livestock in Wilderness: A Review and Forecast
    • See 858 A short-lived proposal to eliminate existing grazing, made during the initial legislative process, was only an anomaly in an otherwise continuous history of grandfathering most grazing management structures and practices as acceptable nonconforming uses in wilderness.
    • See Mitchel P. McClaran, Livestock in Wilderness: A Review and Forecast, 20 ENVTL. L. 857, 858 (1990) ("A short-lived proposal to eliminate existing grazing, made during the initial legislative process, was only an anomaly in an otherwise continuous history of grandfathering most grazing management structures and practices as acceptable nonconforming uses in wilderness.").
    • (1990) Envtl. L. , vol.20 , pp. 857
    • McClaran, M.P.1
  • 46
    • 84869690130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Property Rights Protection Act
    • See § 70.001 West
    • See Bert J. Harris, Jr., Private Property Rights Protection Act, FLA. STAT. ANN. § 70.001 (West 2006);
    • (2006) Fla. Stat. Ann.
    • Harris Jr., B.J.1
  • 47
    • 1842819108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1999 Update on the Bert J. Harris Private Property Rights Protection
    • see also discussing application of and alternatives to Florida statute
    • see also Nicole S. Sayfie & Ronald L. Weaver, 1999 Update on the Bert J. Harris Private Property Rights Protection, 73 FLA. B.J. 49 (1999) (discussing application of and alternatives to Florida statute).
    • (1999) Fla. B.J. , vol.73 , pp. 49
    • Sayfie, N.S.1    Weaver, R.L.2
  • 48
    • 84869682320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FLA. STAT. ANN. § 70.001(2) (emphasis added). The statute defines an existing use, in relevant part, as "an actual, present use or activity on the real property ... or such reasonably foreseeable, nonspeculative land uses which are suitable for the subject real property and compatible with adjacent land uses."
    • FLA. STAT. ANN. § 70.001(2) (emphasis added). The statute defines an existing use, in relevant part, as "an actual, present use or activity on the real property ... or such reasonably foreseeable, nonspeculative land uses which are suitable for the subject real property and compatible with adjacent land uses."
  • 49
    • 84869664959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 70.001(3)(b).
    • Id. § 70.001(3)(b).
  • 50
    • 70450268253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, Montana voters passed by referendum a law eliminating the use of open pit mining with a cyanide reagent, but it grandfathered existing mines that already had a permit.
    • For example, Montana voters passed by referendum a law eliminating the use of open pit mining with a cyanide reagent, but it grandfathered existing mines that already had a permit.
  • 51
    • 68949208703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See § 82-4-390 In 1980, Arizona adopted a new law governing the use of groundwater that explicitly grandfathered existing uses of groundwater.
    • See MONT. CODE ANN. § 82-4-390 (2007). In 1980, Arizona adopted a new law governing the use of groundwater that explicitly grandfathered existing uses of groundwater.
    • (2007) Mont. Code Ann.
  • 52
    • 0347306537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See § 45-462 The right to withdraw or receive and use groundwater pursuant to this article is a grandfathered right.
    • See ARIZ. REV. STAT. ANN. § 45-462 (2003) ("The right to withdraw or receive and use groundwater pursuant to this article is a grandfathered right.").
    • (2003) Ariz. Rev. Stat. Ann.
  • 53
    • 84869672036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robertson, supra note 17, at 132 (discussing grandfather clauses and observing that "when a tough new law is proposed, affected industry lobbyists fight, often successfully, to exempt the existing industry from the new, presumably more stringent requirements"). But
    • See Robertson, supra note 17, at 132 (discussing grandfather clauses and observing that "when a tough new law is proposed, affected industry lobbyists fight, often successfully, to exempt the existing industry from the new, presumably more stringent requirements"). But
  • 54
    • 70450237639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elizabeth Bogley Roth, Environmental Considerations in Hydroelectric Licensing
    • cf. Elizabeth Bogley Roth, Environmental Considerations in Hydroelectric Licensing:
  • 55
    • 84869682322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • California v. FERC (Dynamo Pond), 23 ENVTL. L. 1165, 1183 (1993) ("One possible, but unarticulated, reason for the grandfather clause might be that Congress felt a hydroelectric license represents some sort of property right.").
    • California v. FERC (Dynamo Pond), 23 ENVTL. L. 1165, 1183 (1993) ("One possible, but unarticulated, reason for the grandfather clause might be that Congress felt a hydroelectric license represents some sort of property right.").
  • 56
    • 70450228146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This point is considered in detail in Part III.D, infra.
    • This point is considered in detail in Part III.D, infra.
  • 57
    • 70450229342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Those doctrines are the subject of Part I, infra.
    • Those doctrines are the subject of Part I, infra.
  • 58
    • 84869664956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Vill. of Valatie v. Smith, 632 N.E.2d 1264, 1266-1267 (N.Y. 1994) "Though the amortization period is typically discussed in terms of protecting the owners' financial interests, it serves more generally to protect 'an individual's interest in maintaining the present use' of the property."
    • See Vill. of Valatie v. Smith, 632 N.E.2d 1264, 1266-1267 (N.Y. 1994) ("Though the amortization period is typically discussed in terms of protecting the owners' financial interests, it serves more generally to protect 'an individual's interest in maintaining the present use' of the property."
  • 59
    • 70450225345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • quoting Modjeska Sign Studios, Inc. v. Berle, 373 N.E.2d 255, 261 (N.Y. 1977)
    • (quoting Modjeska Sign Studios, Inc. v. Berle, 373 N.E.2d 255, 261 (N.Y. 1977))).
  • 60
    • 70450253156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of amortization, see infra Part I.B.
    • For a discussion of amortization, see infra Part I.B.
  • 61
    • 84869672033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Mayor and Council of New Castle v. Rollins Outdoor Adver., Inc., 475 A.2d 355, 359 (Del. 1984) (holding that "reasonable, required amortization of such nonconforming uses as sign boards may be accomplished with due process of law, and that such form of regulation does not necessarily constitute a compensable taking")
    • See, e.g., Mayor and Council of New Castle v. Rollins Outdoor Adver., Inc., 475 A.2d 355, 359 (Del. 1984) (holding that "reasonable, required amortization of such nonconforming uses as sign boards may be accomplished with due process of law, and that such form of regulation does not necessarily constitute a compensable taking");
  • 62
    • 70450273140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Friends of East Fork v. Clark County, No. 33422-4-II, 2006 WL 1745032, at *1 n.l (Wash. Ct. App. June 27, 2006) Lawful nonconforming uses may continue but, subject to constitutional limits, the government may regulate or even terminate the use after a period of nonuse or a reasonable amortization period that allows the owner to recoup on investment.
    • Friends of East Fork v. Clark County, No. 33422-4-II, 2006 WL 1745032, at *1 n.l (Wash. Ct. App. June 27, 2006) ("Lawful nonconforming uses may continue but, subject to constitutional limits, the government may regulate or even terminate the use after a period of nonuse or a reasonable amortization period that allows the owner to recoup on investment.").
  • 63
    • 70450268255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These include, notably, the vested rights doctrine and the nuisance exception, both of which are discussed at length in Part I.C-D, infra.
    • These include, notably, the vested rights doctrine and the nuisance exception, both of which are discussed at length in Part I.C-D, infra.
  • 64
    • 70450255909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Sterngass v. Woodbury, 433 F. Supp. 2d 351, 355 (S.D.N.Y. 2006) His only right is to continue a pre-existing non-conforming use, without expansion or change.
    • See, e.g., Sterngass v. Woodbury, 433 F. Supp. 2d 351, 355 (S.D.N.Y. 2006) ("His only right is to continue a pre-existing non-conforming use, without expansion or change.");
  • 65
    • 84869672027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dublin v. Finkes, 615 N.E.2d 690, 692 (Ohio Ct. App. 1992) (finding that federal and state constitutions both "recognize a right to continue a given use of real property if such use is already in existence at the time of the enactment of a land use regulation forbidding or restricting the land use in question")
    • Dublin v. Finkes, 615 N.E.2d 690, 692 (Ohio Ct. App. 1992) (finding that federal and state constitutions both "recognize a right to continue a given use of real property if such use is already in existence at the time of the enactment of a land use regulation forbidding or restricting the land use in question");
  • 66
    • 70450253993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State v. Thomasson, 378 P.2d 441, 443 (Wash. 1963) [W]e have recognized that property owners are not without some rights in the continuance of a legitimate business on their property despite a change in zoning.
    • State v. Thomasson, 378 P.2d 441, 443 (Wash. 1963) ("[W]e have recognized that property owners are not without some rights in the continuance of a legitimate business on their property despite a change in zoning.").
  • 67
    • 70450261371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., City of Annapolis v. Waterman, 745 A.2d 1000, 1015 (Md. 2000) [I]nsofar as the ordinance required the reduction, removal, or destruction of existing property at the owners' expense, it was a taking ....
    • See, e.g., City of Annapolis v. Waterman, 745 A.2d 1000, 1015 (Md. 2000) ("[I]nsofar as the ordinance required the reduction, removal, or destruction of existing property at the owners' expense, it was a taking ....");
  • 68
    • 84869682527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Terminals Equip. Co. v. City & County of San Francisco, 270 CaI. Rptr. 329, 335 (CaI. Ct. App. 1990) rejecting takings claim because regulation was "only operating to restrict new uses of the subject [p]roperty, not to eliminate existing ones"
    • see also Terminals Equip. Co. v. City & County of San Francisco, 270 CaI. Rptr. 329, 335 (CaI. Ct. App. 1990) (rejecting takings claim because regulation was "only operating to restrict new uses of the subject [p]roperty, not to eliminate existing ones");
  • 69
    • 70450286048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taylor v. Zoning Bd. of Appeals, 783 A.2d 526, 531 (Conn. App. Ct. 2001) The right to continue an established nonconforming use of one's property is securely grounded, both in statutes and in previous decisions of this court and our Supreme Court.
    • Taylor v. Zoning Bd. of Appeals, 783 A.2d 526, 531 (Conn. App. Ct. 2001) ("The right to continue an established nonconforming use of one's property is securely grounded, both in statutes and in previous decisions of this court and our Supreme Court.").
  • 70
    • 70450279567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Penn Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104, 124 (1978).
    • Penn Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104, 124 (1978).
  • 71
    • 70450279568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 136.
    • Id. at 136.
  • 72
    • 70450240401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wensmann Realty, Inc. v. City of Eagan, 734 N.W.2d 623, 638 (Minn. 2007) (holding that owner of option to purchase golf course had no reasonable investmentbacked expectations to support claim that city's denial of amendment to comprehensive plan to permit residential development of property constituted taking)
    • See, e.g., Wensmann Realty, Inc. v. City of Eagan, 734 N.W.2d 623, 638 (Minn. 2007) (holding that owner of option to purchase golf course had no reasonable investmentbacked expectations to support claim that city's denial of amendment to comprehensive plan to permit residential development of property constituted taking);
  • 73
    • 84869682528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumers Union of U.S., Inc. v. State, 840 N.E.2d 68, 103 (N.Y. 2005) ("The word 'investment' may seem awkward in discussing the expectations of a not-for-profit entity, but I think the meaning of 'investment-backed expectations' in this context is simply [claimant's] reasonable expectations as to the future use of [its] property."). The evolution of Penn Central's investment-backed expectations prong is discussed in Daniel R. Mandelker, The Notice Rule in Investment-Backed Expectations, in TAKING SIDES ON TAKINGS ISSUES: PUBLIC AND PRIVATE PERSPECTIVES 21, 21-29 (Thomas E. Roberts ed., 2002).
    • Consumers Union of U.S., Inc. v. State, 840 N.E.2d 68, 103 (N.Y. 2005) ("The word 'investment' may seem awkward in discussing the expectations of a not-for-profit entity, but I think the meaning of 'investment-backed expectations' in this context is simply [claimant's] reasonable expectations as to the future use of [its] property."). The evolution of Penn Central's investment-backed expectations prong is discussed in Daniel R. Mandelker, The Notice Rule in Investment-Backed Expectations, in TAKING SIDES ON TAKINGS ISSUES: PUBLIC AND PRIVATE PERSPECTIVES 21, 21-29 (Thomas E. Roberts ed., 2002).
  • 74
    • 70450256540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124 describing multifactor test for takings liability
    • Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124 (describing multifactor test for takings liability).
  • 75
    • 70450258511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the Due Process Clause, see infra Part U.C.
    • For a discussion of the Due Process Clause, see infra Part U.C.
  • 76
    • 70450243591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The other possible justifications for existing use protection considered in this Article include the endowment effect, political economy, waste prevention, owner expectations, and the stability of the status quo. See infra Part III.
    • The other possible justifications for existing use protection considered in this Article include the endowment effect, political economy, waste prevention, owner expectations, and the stability of the status quo. See infra Part III.
  • 77
    • 84917293747 scopus 로고
    • Natural Preservation and the Race to Develop
    • See, e.g., 677-95 describing how natural preservation regulation encourages development
    • See, e.g., David A. Dana, Natural Preservation and the Race To Develop, 143 U. PA. L. REV. 655, 677-95 (1995) (describing how natural preservation regulation encourages development);
    • (1995) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.143 , pp. 655
    • Dana, D.A.1
  • 78
    • 70450226186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kaplow, supra note 9, at 527-31 analyzing risks and incentives created by government regulation
    • Kaplow, supra note 9, at 527-31 (analyzing risks and incentives created by government regulation);
  • 79
    • 70450261370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 104-15 discussing norm against nominally retroactive taxes and implications of this norm
    • see also SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 104-15 (discussing norm against nominally retroactive taxes and implications of this norm);
  • 80
    • 0042195345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Givings
    • 582-84 illustrating effect of future regulatory takings on investment decisions
    • Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, Givings, 111 YALE L.J. 547, 582-84 (2001) (illustrating effect of future regulatory takings on investment decisions);
    • (2001) Yale L.J. , vol.111 , pp. 547
    • Bell, A.1    Parchomovsky, G.2
  • 81
    • 0346703088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Changes, Anticipations, Reparations
    • exploring incentives created by changes in law
    • Saul Levmore, Changes, Anticipations, Reparations, 99 COLUM. L. REV. 1657 (1999) (exploring incentives created by changes in law);
    • (1999) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 1657
    • Levmore, S.1
  • 82
    • 47749112976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal Transitions, Rational Expectations, and Legal Process
    • 216-18 arguing for transition policies for regulatory takings of private property as type of "government-provided insurance".
    • Kyle D. Logue, Legal Transitions, Rational Expectations, and Legal Process, 13 J. Co.N'iEMP. LEGAL ISSUES 211, 216-18 (2003) (arguing for transition policies for regulatory takings of private property as type of "government-provided insurance").
    • (2003) J. Co.N'iemp. Legal Issues , vol.13 , pp. 211
    • Logue, K.D.1
  • 83
    • 0346158837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Genealogy of Moral Hazard
    • For a leading account of moral hazard, see generally Moral hazard in the land use context is considered in detail in Part IV.A, infra.
    • For a leading account of moral hazard, see generally Tom Baker, On the Genealogy of Moral Hazard, 75 TEX. L. REV. 237 (1996). Moral hazard in the land use context is considered in detail in Part IV.A, infra.
    • (1996) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 237
    • Baker, T.1
  • 84
    • 70450285154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.
    • See infra Part II.
  • 85
    • 70450261369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The list is not exhaustive. The protection of existing uses is found in other areas too. According to a leading casebook, for example, local governments may be more likely to grant variances for structures that already exist than for those yet to be built.
    • The list is not exhaustive. The protection of existing uses is found in other areas too. According to a leading casebook, for example, local governments may be more likely to grant variances for structures that already exist than for those yet to be built.
  • 86
    • 84869682529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ELLICKSON & BEEN, supra note 6, at 293 ("PJeople who built first and sought variances later were more successful in obtaining variances than those who proceeded lawfully.").
    • See ELLICKSON & BEEN, supra note 6, at 293 ("[PJeople who built first and sought variances later were more successful in obtaining variances than those who proceeded lawfully.").
  • 87
    • 84869672028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STANDARD STATE ZONING ENABLING ACT (Advisory Comm. on Zoning, U.S. Dep't of Commerce 1926), available at
    • STANDARD STATE ZONING ENABLING ACT (Advisory Comm. on Zoning, U.S. Dep't of Commerce 1926), available at http://myapa.planning.org/growingsmart/pdf/ SZEnabling Actl926.pdf [hereinafter SZEA];
  • 88
    • 0347605627 scopus 로고
    • Deregulating Land Use: An Alternative Free Enterprise Development System
    • see 58 finding that "most zoning ordinances" either completely or partially exempt "land uses that predate the ordinance" and remarking that "there was some feeling on the part of the drafters of the SZEA that any attempt to apply zoning to existing land uses and structures without compensation would have been found unconstitutional". The issue goes back further than that.
    • see Douglas W. Kmiec, Deregulating Land Use: An Alternative Free Enterprise Development System, 130 U. PA. L. REV. 28, 58 (1981) (finding that "most zoning ordinances" either completely or partially exempt "land uses that predate the ordinance" and remarking that "there was some feeling on the part of the drafters of the SZEA that any attempt to apply zoning to existing land uses and structures without compensation would have been found unconstitutional"). The issue goes back further than that.
    • (1981) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.130 , pp. 28
    • Kmiec, D.W.1
  • 89
    • 70450228470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The famous case Hadacheck v. Sebastian, involving a municipality eliminating an existing use, dates back to 1915. 239 U.S. 394 (1915).
    • The famous case Hadacheck v. Sebastian, involving a municipality eliminating an existing use, dates back to 1915. 239 U.S. 394 (1915).
  • 90
    • 1142276558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Legislative Requirement that Zoning and Land Use Controls Be Consistent with an Independently Adopted Local Comprehensive Plan: A Model Statute
    • 297
    • Stuart Meek, The Legislative Requirement that Zoning and Land Use Controls Be Consistent with an Independently Adopted Local Comprehensive Plan: A Model Statute, 3 WASH. U. J.L. & POI.'Y 295, 297 (2000).
    • (2000) Wash. U. J.L. & Poi.'y , vol.3 , pp. 295
    • Meek, S.1
  • 91
    • 70450277189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The SZEA itself provides: 3. Modify this standard act as little as possible.-It was prepared with a full knowledge of the decisions of the courts in every case in which zoning acts have been under review, and has been carefully checked with reference to sub- sequent decisions. A safe course to follow is to make only those changes necessary to have the act conform to local legislative customs and modes of expression.
    • The SZEA itself provides: 3. Modify this standard act as little as possible.-It was prepared with a full knowledge of the decisions of the courts in every case in which zoning acts have been under review, and has been carefully checked with reference to sub- sequent decisions. A safe course to follow is to make only those changes necessary to have the act conform to local legislative customs and modes of expression.
  • 92
    • 70450286872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SZEA, supra note 43, at 1.
    • SZEA, supra note 43, at 1.
  • 93
    • 0042577441 scopus 로고
    • Planning and Dealing: Piecemeal Land Controls as a Problem of Local Legitimacy
    • 848 &
    • Carol M. Rose, Planning and Dealing: Piecemeal Land Controls as a Problem of Local Legitimacy, 71 CAL. L. REV. 837, 848 & n.29 (1983).
    • (1983) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.71 , Issue.29 , pp. 837
    • Rose, C.M.1
  • 94
    • 70450233483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SZEA, supra note 43, at 2.
    • SZEA, supra note 43, at 2.
  • 95
    • 70450268252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The zoning enabling acts of Illinois, Kansas, Massachusetts, New Hampshire, Ohio, and Wisconsin provided that zoning could not apply to existing uses.
    • The zoning enabling acts of Illinois, Kansas, Massachusetts, New Hampshire, Ohio, and Wisconsin provided that zoning could not apply to existing uses.
  • 96
    • 70450249241 scopus 로고
    • Comment, Retroactive Zoning Ordinances
    • See 735 & citing statutes. But see MARC: A. WEISS, THE RISE OF THE COMMUNITY BUILDERS: THE AMERICAN REAL ESTATE INDUSTRY AND URBAN LAND PLANNING 81 (1987) describing Los Angeles ordinance predating zoning that permitted application of land use restrictions to existing businesses.
    • See Comment, Retroactive Zoning Ordinances, 39 YALE L.J. 735, 735 & n.6 (1930) (citing statutes). But see MARC: A. WEISS, THE RISE OF THE COMMUNITY BUILDERS: THE AMERICAN REAL ESTATE INDUSTRY AND URBAN LAND PLANNING 81 (1987) (describing Los Angeles ordinance predating zoning that permitted application of land use restrictions to existing businesses).
    • (1930) Yale L.J. , vol.39 , Issue.6 , pp. 735
  • 97
    • 70450284376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Jones v. City of Los Angeles, 295 P. 14, 18-19, 22 (Cal. 1930) striking down ordinance and citing, inter alia, A.C. Blumenthal & Co. v. Cryer, 236 P. 216 (CaI. Dist. Ct. App. 1925), Frank J. Durkin Lumber Co. v. Fitzsimmons, 147 A. 555, 558 (N.J. 1929)
    • See, e.g., Jones v. City of Los Angeles, 295 P. 14, 18-19, 22 (Cal. 1930) (striking down ordinance and citing, inter alia, A.C. Blumenthal & Co. v. Cryer, 236 P. 216 (CaI. Dist. Ct. App. 1925), Frank J. Durkin Lumber Co. v. Fitzsimmons, 147 A. 555, 558 (N.J. 1929),
  • 98
    • 0040392309 scopus 로고
    • Constitutionality of Zoning
    • 853
    • Alfred Bettman, Constitutionality of Zoning, 37 HARV. L. REV. 834, 853 (1924), and
    • (1924) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.37 , pp. 834
    • Bettman, A.1
  • 99
    • 70450239575 scopus 로고
    • City Planning and Restrictions on the Use of Property
    • 628
    • J.S. Young, City Planning and Restrictions on the Use of Property, 9 MINN. L. REV. 593, 628 (1925)).
    • (1925) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.9 , pp. 593
    • Young, J.S.1
  • 100
    • 70450281395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 295 P. 14 (1930)
    • 295 P. 14 (1930).
  • 101
    • 70450225346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 15.
    • Id. at 15.
  • 102
    • 70450230441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 17.
    • Id. at 17.
  • 103
    • 70450265287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 19.
    • Id. at 19.
  • 104
    • 70450255077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 22.
    • Id. at 22.
  • 105
    • 70450228472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bd. of County Comm'rs v. Petsch, 109 N.W.2d 388, 390 (Neb. 1961)
    • Bd. of County Comm'rs v. Petsch, 109 N.W.2d 388, 390 (Neb. 1961);
  • 106
    • 70450231267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lochner, Liberty, Property, and Human Rights
    • see also 459-60 & finding in Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365 (1926), "some slight suggestion that failure to grandfather existing uses when enacting a new zoning provision might be a problem"
    • see also Wayne McCormack, Lochner, Liberty, Property, and Human Rights, 1 N.Y.U. J.L. & LIBERTY 432, 459-60 & n.153 (2005) (finding in Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365 (1926), "some slight suggestion that failure to grandfather existing uses when enacting a new zoning provision might be a problem").
    • (2005) N.Y.U. J.L. & Liberty , vol.1 , Issue.153 , pp. 432
    • McCormack, W.1
  • 107
    • 70450242701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Bettman, supra note 49, at 853 noting that application of zoning to existing uses would present same constitutional problem as retroactive laws more generally
    • See, e.g., Bettman, supra note 49, at 853 (noting that application of zoning to existing uses would present same constitutional problem as retroactive laws more generally);
  • 108
    • 70450271543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Young, supra note 49, at 628 Retroactive zoning is not to be recommended except in very unusual cases [when] public protection imperatively demands it.
    • Young, supra note 49, at 628 ("Retroactive zoning is not to be recommended except in very unusual cases [when] public protection imperatively demands it.").
  • 109
    • 70450256539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comment, supra note 48, at 737
    • Comment, supra note 48, at 737;
  • 110
    • 70349516069 scopus 로고
    • Zoning Legislation
    • see also 174-175 The Standard Act does not declare that the zoning ordinances shall not be retroactive. . . . [B]ut the practice would cause many cases of individual hardship if tried in a comprehensively zoned city which would result in raising the issue of the constitutionality of zoning in general.
    • see also Newman F. Baker, Zoning Legislation, 11 CORNELL L.Q. 164, 174-175 (1926) ("The Standard Act does not declare that the zoning ordinances shall not be retroactive. . . . [B]ut the practice would cause many cases of individual hardship if tried in a comprehensively zoned city which would result in raising the issue of the constitutionality of zoning in general.").
    • (1926) Cornell L.Q. , vol.11 , pp. 164
    • Baker, N.F.1
  • 111
    • 84869682299 scopus 로고
    • Elimination of Nonconformities: The Case of Voluntary Discontinuance
    • See 160 defining nonconforming use as "the lawful use of a building or premises, existing at the time of the adoption or amendment of a zoning ordinance, although such use does not conform to the provisions of the ordinance" (quoting Wis. STAT. § 62.23(7)(h) (1988)). Courts and particularly commentators distinguish between nonconforming structures and nonconforming uses, although essentially the same reasoning applies to both.
    • See Eric J. Strauss & Mary M. Giese, Elimination of Nonconformities: The Case of Voluntary Discontinuance, 25 UKB. LAW. 159, 160 (1993) (defining nonconforming use as "the lawful use of a building or premises, existing at the time of the adoption or amendment of a zoning ordinance, although such use does not conform to the provisions of the ordinance" (quoting Wis. STAT. § 62.23(7)(h) (1988))). Courts and particularly commentators distinguish between nonconforming structures and nonconforming uses, although essentially the same reasoning applies to both.
    • (1993) Ukb. Law. , vol.25 , pp. 159
    • Strauss, E.J.1    Giese, M.M.2
  • 112
    • 70450232408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 161.
    • See id. at 161.
  • 113
    • 84869682516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See City of Los Angeles v. A.I. Gage, 274 P.2d 34, 40 (Cal. Dist. Ct. App. 1954) ("Until recently zoning ordinances have made no provision for any systematic and comprehensive elimination of the nonconforming use. The expectation seems to have been that existing nonconforming uses would be of little consequence and that they would eventually disappear. The contrary appears to be the case." (internal citations omitted))
    • See City of Los Angeles v. A.I. Gage, 274 P.2d 34, 40 (Cal. Dist. Ct. App. 1954) ("Until recently zoning ordinances have made no provision for any systematic and comprehensive elimination of the nonconforming use. The expectation seems to have been that existing nonconforming uses would be of little consequence and that they would eventually disappear. The contrary appears to be the case." (internal citations omitted));
  • 114
    • 70450253992 scopus 로고
    • The Reasonableness of Amortization Periods for Nonconforming Uses- Balancing the Private Interest and the Public Welfare
    • 99-100 noting that courts also believed that nonconforming uses would die out and that courts have often assumed, where ordinance did not specify, that ordinance did not apply retroactively
    • Osborne M. Reynolds, Jr., The Reasonableness of Amortization Periods for Nonconforming Uses- Balancing the Private Interest and the Public Welfare, 34 WASH. U. J. URB. & CONTEMP. L. 99, 99-100 (1988) (noting that courts also believed that nonconforming uses would die out and that courts have often assumed, where ordinance did not specify, that ordinance did not apply retroactively).
    • (1988) Wash. U. J. Urb. & Contemp. L. , vol.34 , pp. 99
    • Reynolds Jr., O.M.1
  • 115
    • 70450259408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Varadarajan, supra note 13, at 2556 Zoning regulators believed that these restrictions would cause the gradual disappearance of such nonconforming uses.
    • See Varadarajan, supra note 13, at 2556 ("Zoning regulators believed that these restrictions would cause the gradual disappearance of such nonconforming uses.");
  • 116
    • 70450252868 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Huntington Props., LLC v. Currituck County, 569 S.E.2d 695, 700 (N.C. Ct. App. 2002) Moreover, 'non-conforming uses are not favored by the law. Most zoning schemes foresee elimination of non-conforming uses either by amortization, or attrition or other means.
    • see also Huntington Props., LLC v. Currituck County, 569 S.E.2d 695, 700 (N.C. Ct. App. 2002) ("Moreover, 'non-conforming uses are not favored by the law. Most zoning schemes foresee elimination of non-conforming uses either by amortization, or attrition or other means.'"
  • 117
    • 70450235066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • quoting CG & T Corp. v. Bd. of Adjustment, 411 S.E.2d 655, 659-60 (N.C. Ct. App. 1992). This view traditionally justifies laws limiting improvements or expansions of nonconforming uses.
    • (quoting CG & T Corp. v. Bd. of Adjustment, 411 S.E.2d 655, 659-60 (N.C. Ct. App. 1992))). This view traditionally justifies laws limiting improvements or expansions of nonconforming uses.
  • 118
    • 84869664949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., County Council v. E.L. Gardner, Inc., 443 A.2d 114, 119 (Md. 1982) (recognizing that "the purpose of such restrictions is to achieve the ultimate elimination of nonconforming uses through economic attrition and physical obsolescence").
    • See, e.g., County Council v. E.L. Gardner, Inc., 443 A.2d 114, 119 (Md. 1982) (recognizing that "the purpose of such restrictions is to achieve the ultimate elimination of nonconforming uses through economic attrition and physical obsolescence").
  • 119
    • 70450258510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Reynolds, supra note 59, at 109 Nonconforming uses thrived due to the protection from new competition given them by the zoning laws.
    • See Reynolds, supra note 59, at 109 ("[Nonconforming uses thrived due to the protection from new competition given them by the zoning laws.");
  • 120
    • 70450265445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strauss & Giese, supra note 58, at 163 Unfortunately, nonconforming uses were not phased out because the restriction on the development of similar uses in the area created a virtual monopoly, which allowed the nonconforming use to flourish.
    • Strauss & Giese, supra note 58, at 163 ("Unfortunately, nonconforming uses were not phased out because the restriction on the development of similar uses in the area created a virtual monopoly, which allowed the nonconforming use to flourish.").
  • 121
    • 70450229341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These include precluding any expansion of a nonconforming use and terminating a nonconforming use if the use is abandoned, changed, or destroyed.
    • These include precluding any expansion of a nonconforming use and terminating a nonconforming use if the use is abandoned, changed, or destroyed.
  • 122
    • 70450280564 scopus 로고
    • Amortization of Legal Land Use Nonconformities as Regulatory Takings: An Uncertain Future
    • See 39-41 summarizing early approaches to eliminating existing uses
    • See Craig A. Peterson & Claire McCarthy, Amortization of Legal Land Use Nonconformities as Regulatory Takings: An Uncertain Future, 35 WASH. U. J. URB. & CONTEMP. L. 37, 39-41 (1989) (summarizing early approaches to eliminating existing uses);
    • (1989) Wash. U. J. Urb. & Contemp. L. , vol.35 , pp. 37
    • Peterson, C.A.1    McCarthy, C.2
  • 123
    • 70450228144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Reynolds, supra note 59, at 101-04 describing limitations on growth and repair
    • see also Reynolds, supra note 59, at 101-04 (describing limitations on growth and repair);
  • 124
    • 70450279566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strauss & Giese, supra note 58, at 163-167 summarizing all available methods
    • Strauss & Giese, supra note 58, at 163-167 (summarizing all available methods).
  • 125
    • 70450261365 scopus 로고
    • Annotation, Alteration, Extension, Reconstruction, or Repair of Nonconforming Structure or Structure Devoted to Nonconforming Use as Violation of Zoning Ordinance
    • For a summary and analysis of these rules, see 4th
    • For a summary and analysis of these rules, see Eunice A. Eichelberger, Annotation, Alteration, Extension, Reconstruction, or Repair of Nonconforming Structure or Structure Devoted to Nonconforming Use as Violation of Zoning Ordinance, 63 A.L.R. 4th 275 (1988).
    • (1988) A.L.R. , vol.63 , pp. 275
    • Eichelberger, E.A.1
  • 126
    • 70450233485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Peterson & McCarthy, supra note 62, at 37 [S]tate courts have generally upheld amortization provisions since the 1950s.
    • See Peterson & McCarthy, supra note 62, at 37 ("[S]tate courts have generally upheld amortization provisions since the 1950s.");
  • 127
    • 70450258509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reynolds, supra note 59, at 109 [M]ost courts held that amortization provisions are valid if they are reasonable in nature. This is currently the majority view in America. The actual use of amortization may be quite limited, however.
    • Reynolds, supra note 59, at 109 ("[M]ost courts held that amortization provisions are valid if they are reasonable in nature. This is currently the majority view in America."). The actual use of amortization may be quite limited, however.
  • 128
    • 70450281386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Methods of Determining Amortization Periods for Non-conforming Uses
    • See 216 A survey of 489 cities showed that, although planners in 159 cities had access to amortization programs, only 27 cities had actually used them.
    • See Margaret Collins, Methods of Determining Amortization Periods for Non-conforming Uses, 3 WASH. U. J.L. & POL'Y 215, 216 (2000) ("A survey of 489 cities showed that, although planners in 159 cities had access to amortization programs, only 27 cities had actually used them.").
    • (2000) Wash. U. J.L. & Pol'y , vol.3 , pp. 215
    • Collins, M.1
  • 129
    • 70450227285 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collins, supra note 64, at 216. Amortization is related to the depreciation of an asset for tax purposes
    • explaining various depreciation methods
    • Collins, supra note 64, at 216. Amortization is related to the depreciation of an asset for tax purposes. See id. at 223-224 (explaining various depreciation methods).
    • See Id. at , pp. 223-224
  • 130
    • 70450279563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., City of Oakbrook Terrace v. Suburban Bank & Trust Co., 845 N.E.2d 1000, 1011 (111. App. Ct. 2006) holding that municipal ordinance providing amortization period for nonconforming signs violated State Eminent Domain Act, which required just compensation
    • See, e.g., City of Oakbrook Terrace v. Suburban Bank & Trust Co., 845 N.E.2d 1000, 1011 (111. App. Ct. 2006) (holding that municipal ordinance providing amortization period for nonconforming signs violated State Eminent Domain Act, which required just compensation);
  • 131
    • 70450286870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hoffmann v. Kinealy, 389 S.W.2d 745, 753 (Mo. 1965) Of course, every comprehensive zoning ordinance limits and thereby regulates the use of property prospectively. But we cannot embrace the doctrine espoused by advocates of the amortization technique that there is no material distinction between regulating the future use of property and terminating pre-existing lawful nonconforming uses.
    • Hoffmann v. Kinealy, 389 S.W.2d 745, 753 (Mo. 1965) ("Of course, every comprehensive zoning ordinance limits and thereby regulates the use of property prospectively. But we cannot embrace the doctrine espoused by advocates of the amortization technique that there is no material distinction between regulating the future use of property and terminating pre-existing lawful nonconforming uses.");
  • 132
    • 70450279565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PA Nw. Distribs., Inc. v. Zoning Hearing Bd., 584 A.2d 1372, 1376 (Pa. 1991) holding that amortization provisions are unconstitutional because they take property without just compensation
    • PA Nw. Distribs., Inc. v. Zoning Hearing Bd., 584 A.2d 1372, 1376 (Pa. 1991) (holding that amortization provisions are unconstitutional because they take property without just compensation).
  • 133
    • 70450259407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Bd. of Zoning Appeals v. Leisz, 702 N.E.2d 1026, 1032 (Ind. 1998) holding that amortization provisions that require owner to discontinue nonconforming use after certain period of time are not per se unconstitutional
    • See, e.g., Bd. of Zoning Appeals v. Leisz, 702 N.E.2d 1026, 1032 (Ind. 1998) (holding that amortization provisions that require owner to discontinue nonconforming use after certain period of time are not per se unconstitutional);
  • 134
    • 70450273987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trip Assoes, v. Mayor and City Council of Baltimore, 898 A.2d 449, 457 (Md. 2006) So long as it provides for a reasonable relationship between the amortization and the nature of the nonconforming use, an ordinance prescribing . . . amortization is not unconstitutional.
    • Trip Assoes, v. Mayor and City Council of Baltimore, 898 A.2d 449, 457 (Md. 2006) ("So long as it provides for a reasonable relationship between the amortization and the nature of the nonconforming use, an ordinance prescribing . . . amortization is not unconstitutional.");
  • 135
    • 84869672021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Red Roof Inns, Inc. v. City of Ridgeland, 797 So. 2d 898, 902 (Miss. 2001)"The weight of authority supports the conclusion that a reasonable amortization provision would not be unconstitutional." (citation omitted). The inquiry into duration is also a source of controversy, with some courts holding that amortization must be sufficiently long to allow the value of the buildings on the property to depreciate fully, and others holding that the adequacy of the duration must be evaluated by comparing the burden to the property owner with the burden to the public of allowing the use to continue.
    • Red Roof Inns, Inc. v. City of Ridgeland, 797 So. 2d 898, 902 (Miss. 2001) ("The weight of authority supports the conclusion that a reasonable amortization provision would not be unconstitutional." (citation omitted)). The inquiry into duration is also a source of controversy, with some courts holding that amortization must be sufficiently long to allow the value of the buildings on the property to depreciate fully, and others holding that the adequacy of the duration must be evaluated by comparing the burden to the property owner with the burden to the public of allowing the use to continue.
  • 136
    • 84869672022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare Lone v. Montgomery County, 584 A.2d 142, 153 (Md. Ct. Spec. App. 1991) ("We hold that the ten-year amortization period in the case at bar is reasonable because within that time, the multi-family housing owners could recoup any lost investment. . . .")
    • Compare Lone v. Montgomery County, 584 A.2d 142, 153 (Md. Ct. Spec. App. 1991) ("We hold that the ten-year amortization period in the case at bar is reasonable because within that time, the multi-family housing owners could recoup any lost investment. . . ."),
  • 137
    • 70450253989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • with Modjeska Sign Studios, Inc. v. Berle, 373 N.E.2d 255, 262 (N. Y. 1977) If an owner can show that the loss he suffers as a result of the removal of a nonconforming use at the expiration of an amortization period is so substantial that it outweighs the public benefit gained by the legislation, then the amortization period must be held unreasonable.
    • with Modjeska Sign Studios, Inc. v. Berle, 373 N.E.2d 255, 262 (N. Y. 1977) ("If an owner can show that the loss he suffers as a result of the removal of a nonconforming use at the expiration of an amortization period is so substantial that it outweighs the public benefit gained by the legislation, then the amortization period must be held unreasonable.").
  • 138
    • 70450249240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Reynolds, supra note 59, at 108 describing constitutional concern about duration of amortization period.
    • Cf. Reynolds, supra note 59, at 108 (describing constitutional concern about duration of amortization period).
  • 139
    • 70450258508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Collins, supra note 64.
    • See generally Collins, supra note 64.
  • 140
    • 70450241600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Modjeska Sign Studios, 373 N.E.2d at 262 In essence, however, we believe the critical question which must be asked is whether the public gain achieved by the exercise of the police power outweighs the private loss suffered by owners of nonconforming uses.
    • See Modjeska Sign Studios, 373 N.E.2d at 262 ("In essence, however, we believe the critical question which must be asked is whether the public gain achieved by the exercise of the police power outweighs the private loss suffered by owners of nonconforming uses.");
  • 141
    • 84869682308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collins, supra note 64, at 217 The process of determining amortization periods is ... a balancing tesť weighing the private cost against the public gain.
    • Collins, supra note 64, at 217 ("The process of determining amortization periods is ... a balancing tesť weighing the private cost against the public gain.").
  • 142
    • 70450238506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Peterson & McCarthy, supra note 62, at 72-79 applying Penn Central test to as applied challenge to amortization provisions
    • But see Peterson & McCarthy, supra note 62, at 72-79 (applying Penn Central test to as applied challenge to amortization provisions).
  • 143
    • 70450256532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lingle v. Chevron, 544 U.S. 528, 540 (2005) describing due process test. In fact, if the test for amortization of prior existing uses is not more protective than substantive due process, it threatens to become superfluous. In a dissenting opinion, a judge on the Washington Court of Appeals recognized this point: The majority's flaw is its failure to make the distinction between continuation of a nonconforming use which is exempt from police power regulation on the one hand, and imposition of the police power without exemption, subject only to the usual requirements of due process, on the other. If the latter be the rule, the nonconforming use doctrine is robbed of its reason for existence, and is no more than the usual due process test.
    • See Lingle v. Chevron, 544 U.S. 528, 540 (2005) (describing due process test). In fact, if the test for amortization of prior existing uses is not more protective than substantive due process, it threatens to become superfluous. In a dissenting opinion, a judge on the Washington Court of Appeals recognized this point: The majority's flaw is its failure to make the distinction between continuation of a nonconforming use which is exempt from police power regulation on the one hand, and imposition of the police power without exemption, subject only to the usual requirements of due process, on the other. If the latter be the rule, the nonconforming use doctrine is robbed of its reason for existence, and is no more than the usual due process test.
  • 144
    • 70450240400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rhod-A-Zalea & 35th, Inc. v. Snohomish County, 959 P.2d 1024, 1036 (Wash. 1988) en bancSanders, J., dissenting
    • Rhod-A-Zalea & 35th, Inc. v. Snohomish County, 959 P.2d 1024, 1036 (Wash. 1988) (en banc) (Sanders, J., dissenting).
  • 145
    • 70450264186 scopus 로고
    • Estoppel, and the Land Development Process
    • 660-61 Early cases and treatises contain numerous admonitions based on reasons at once philosophical, practical, and legal that zoning must be prospective in nature. The assumption has not changed dramatically and continues to be of paramount importance in many modern land regulatory statutes.
    • Richard B. Cunningham & David H. Kremer, Vested Rights, Estoppel, and the Land Development Process, 29 HASTINGS L.J. 623, 660-61 (1978) ("Early cases and treatises contain numerous admonitions based on reasons at once philosophical, practical, and legal that zoning must be prospective in nature. The assumption has not changed dramatically and continues to be of paramount importance in many modern land regulatory statutes.");
    • (1978) Hastings L.J. , vol.29 , pp. 623
    • Cunningham, R.B.1    Kremer, D.H.2    Rights, V.3
  • 146
    • 84869664948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peterson & McCarthy, supra note 62, at 39 finding that "pre-existing uses and aspects of development are always to some extent 'grandfathered'"
    • Peterson & McCarthy, supra note 62, at 39 (finding that "pre-existing uses and aspects of development are always to some extent 'grandfathered'");
  • 147
    • 70450229340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reynolds, supra note 59, at 104 Supporters of [amortization] have generally agreed that constitutional limitations, or considerations of fairness require that existing uses be allowed to continue until the user has had a reasonable opportunity to amortize his investment. footnotes omittedinternal quotation marks omitted
    • Reynolds, supra note 59, at 104 ("Supporters of [amortization] have generally agreed that constitutional limitations, or considerations of fairness require that existing uses be allowed to continue until the user has had a reasonable opportunity to amortize his investment." (footnotes omitted) (internal quotation marks omitted)).
  • 148
    • 70450279564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cunningham & Kremer, supra note 71, at 625-626 summarizing vested rights doctrine
    • See Cunningham & Kremer, supra note 71, at 625-626 (summarizing vested rights doctrine).
  • 149
    • 70450279562 scopus 로고
    • For a typical hypothetical raising this problem, see introducing book with stylized hypothetical of developer affected by zoning regulations passed after significant investment
    • For a typical hypothetical raising this problem, see CHARLES L. SIEMON ET AL., VESTED RIGHTS 2 (1982) (introducing book with stylized hypothetical of developer affected by zoning regulations passed after significant investment).
    • (1982) Vested Rights , pp. 2
    • Siemon, C.L.1
  • 150
    • 70450232403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Quest for the Best Test to Vest: Washington's Vested Rights Doctrine Beats the Rest
    • See generally 1069-71 endorsing Washington State's vested rights rule in part because it provides "date certain" when development rights will vest
    • See generally Gregory Overstreet & Diana M. Kirchheim, The Quest for the Best Test To Vest: Washington's Vested Rights Doctrine Beats the Rest, 23 SEATILE U. L. REV. 1043, 1069-71 (2000) (endorsing Washington State's vested rights rule in part because it provides "date certain" when development rights will vest);
    • (2000) Seatile U. L. Rev. , vol.23 , pp. 1043
    • Overstreet, G.1    Kirchheim, D.M.2
  • 151
    • 33847133031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Searching for Certainty: Virginia's Evolutionary Approach to Vested Rights
    • describing complex history of vested rights issue in Virginia
    • E.A. Prichard & Gregory A. Riegle, Searching for Certainty: Virginia's Evolutionary Approach to Vested Rights, 7 GEO. MASON L. REV. 983 (1999) (describing complex history of vested rights issue in Virginia).
    • (1999) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.7 , pp. 983
    • Prichard, E.A.1    Riegle, G.A.2
  • 152
    • 84869682307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Trans-Oceanic Oil Corp. v. City of Santa Barbara, 194 P.2d 148, 152 (CaI. Dist. Ct. App. 1948) holding that valid permit "ripens into
    • See, e.g., Trans-Oceanic Oil Corp. v. City of Santa Barbara, 194 P.2d 148, 152 (CaI. Dist. Ct. App. 1948) (holding that valid permit "ripens into a vested property right which may not be taken from him against his will other than by proceedings in eminent domain with the payment of just compensation"). According to Black's Law Dictionary, a vested right is "[a] right that so completely and definitely belongs to a person that it cannot be impaired or taken away without the person's consent." BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY 1349 (8th ed. 2004).
  • 153
    • 70450239576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 623 A.2d 1296 (Md. 1993).
    • 623 A.2d 1296 (Md. 1993).
  • 154
    • 70450250068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1301.
    • Id. at 1301.
  • 155
    • 70450231595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1297 The developer's vested rights argument ultimately rests on a single footing, one that was placed in the ground ... for a proposed column at a proposed outside corner of a proposed portico.
    • Id. at 1297 ("The developer's vested rights argument ultimately rests on a single footing, one that was placed in the ground ... for a proposed column at a proposed outside corner of a proposed portico.").
  • 156
    • 70450234294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1298-1299
    • Id. at 1298-1299
  • 157
    • 70450256538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1298-1299 n.3.
    • Id. at 1298-1299 n.3.
  • 158
    • 70450247818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1302.
    • Id. at 1302.
  • 159
    • 70450273991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Specifically, the court reinstated an administrative board's finding that development rights had not vested, holding: From the standpoint of a member of the general public who is either viewing the property from its boundaries or is consensually on the property, the footing is not so clearly the commencement of construction as to render the Board's finding to the contrary arbitrary, capricious or without substantial evidence on the entire record.
    • Specifically, the court reinstated an administrative board's finding that development rights had not vested, holding: From the standpoint of a member of the general public who is either viewing the property from its boundaries or is consensually on the property, the footing is not so clearly the commencement of construction as to render the Board's finding to the contrary arbitrary, capricious or without substantial evidence on the entire record.
  • 160
    • 70450235958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1305.
    • Id. at 1305.
  • 161
    • 70450246071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vesting Verities and the Development Chronology: A Gaping Disconnect?
    • See, e.g., 607 At least 30 state courts have used the issuance of a building permit as the principal benchmark for [vested rights], but virtually all of these courts also require that other actions be taken in reliance upon the permit, such as construction or expenditure of funds to implement the permit.
    • See, e.g., John J. Delaney, Vesting Verities and the Development Chronology: A Gaping Disconnect?, 3 WASH. U. J.L. & POL'Y 603, 607 (2000) ("At least 30 state courts have used the issuance of a building permit as the principal benchmark for [vested rights], but virtually all of these courts also require that other actions be taken in reliance upon the permit, such as construction or expenditure of funds to implement the permit.").
    • (2000) Wash. U. J.L. & Pol'y , vol.3 , pp. 603
    • Delaney, J.J.1
  • 162
    • 70450225344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Takings Clause, Version 2005: The Legal Process of Constitutional Property Rights
    • See 674 [T]he Supreme Court has typically, although not universally, allowed government to regulate broadly against nuisance activities and thereby lower private property value without compensation, especially where the regulation provided reciprocal benefits to the affected property owner.
    • See Mark Fenster, The Takings Clause, Version 2005: The Legal Process of Constitutional Property Rights, 9 U. PA. J. CONSI. L. 667, 674 (2007) ("[T]he Supreme Court has typically, although not universally, allowed government to regulate broadly against nuisance activities and thereby lower private property value without compensation, especially where the regulation provided reciprocal benefits to the affected property owner.");
    • (2007) U. Pa. J. Consi. L. , vol.9 , pp. 667
    • Fenster, M.1
  • 163
    • 70450284375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The New Nuisance: An Antidote to Wetland Loss, Sprawl, and Global Warming
    • 1195 In theory, traditional takings law has long recognized a nuisance exception under which landowners are not entitled to compensation when they are precluded from using their land to create a nuisance.
    • Christine A. Klein, The New Nuisance: An Antidote to Wetland Loss, Sprawl, and Global Warming, 48 B.C. L. REV. 1155, 1195 (2007) ("In theory, traditional takings law has long recognized a nuisance exception under which landowners are not entitled to compensation when they are precluded from using their land to create a nuisance.").
    • (2007) B.C. L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 1155
    • Klein, C.A.1
  • 164
    • 70450233484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 239 U.S. 394 (1915).
    • 239 U.S. 394 (1915).
  • 165
    • 70450228471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mugler v. Kansas, 123 U.S. 623 (1887), is similar, rejecting a constitutional challenge to prohibition in Kansas on the basis of a harm-prevention rationale. More perniciously, in 1911 the California Supreme Court upheld legislation eliminating 110 Chinese laundries on finding that they caused a harm.
    • Mugler v. Kansas, 123 U.S. 623 (1887), is similar, rejecting a constitutional challenge to prohibition in Kansas on the basis of a harm-prevention rationale. More perniciously, in 1911 the California Supreme Court upheld legislation eliminating 110 Chinese laundries on finding that they caused a harm.
  • 166
    • 70450267447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ex Parte Quong Wo, 118 P. 714 (Cal. 1911)
    • See Ex Parte Quong Wo, 118 P. 714 (Cal. 1911),
  • 167
    • 70450242702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • discussed in Young, supra note 49, at 627.
    • discussed in Young, supra note 49, at 627.
  • 168
    • 70450231596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comment, supra note 48, at 736-37
    • Comment, supra note 48, at 736-37 (
  • 169
    • 70450263325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing State v. McDonald, 121 So. 613 (La. 1929), and State ex rel Dema Realty Co. v. Jacoby, 123 So. 314 (La. 1929)
    • citing State v. McDonald, 121 So. 613 (La. 1929), and State ex rel Dema Realty Co. v. Jacoby, 123 So. 314 (La. 1929)).
  • 170
    • 70450253157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Boyd v. City of Sierra Madre, 183 P. 230 (Cal. 1919)
    • Boyd v. City of Sierra Madre, 183 P. 230 (Cal. 1919),
  • 171
    • 70450285155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • quoted in Young, supra note 49, at 616.
    • quoted in Young, supra note 49, at 616.
  • 172
    • 70450267450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 232 ellipsis in originalinternal quotation marks omitted
    • Id. at 232 (ellipsis in original) (internal quotation marks omitted).
  • 173
    • 70450268251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Goldblatt v. Hempstead, 369 U.S. 590 (1962) upholding regulation banning excavations below water table despite effect of eliminating gravel mining operation in existence for thirty years
    • See, e.g., Goldblatt v. Hempstead, 369 U.S. 590 (1962) (upholding regulation banning excavations below water table despite effect of eliminating gravel mining operation in existence for thirty years);
  • 174
    • 70450273988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dep't of Agric. & Consumer Servs. v. Polk, 568 So. 2d 35 (FIa. 1990) holding that destruction of trees exhibiting bacterial disease did not constitute taking
    • Dep't of Agric. & Consumer Servs. v. Polk, 568 So. 2d 35 (FIa. 1990) (holding that destruction of trees exhibiting bacterial disease did not constitute taking);
  • 175
    • 84869682502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zeman v. City of Minneapolis, 552 N.W.2d 548, 555 (Minn. 1996) denying compensation where landlord's rental dwelling license was revoked after tenants received multiple disorderly conduct citations because ordinance "serves a public harm prevention purpose"
    • Zeman v. City of Minneapolis, 552 N.W.2d 548, 555 (Minn. 1996) (denying compensation where landlord's rental dwelling license was revoked after tenants received multiple disorderly conduct citations because ordinance "serves a public harm prevention purpose").
  • 176
    • 70450241598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Young, supra note 49, at 627 Some cities have made their ordinances retroactive for industries [that are] more or less offensive.
    • See Young, supra note 49, at 627 ("Some cities have made their ordinances retroactive for industries [that are] more or less offensive.");
  • 177
    • 70450260543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comment, supra note 48, at 737 It is a common occurrence, where there are zoning ordinances in effect, for the exclusions to begin with nuisances and near-nuisances, over which municipalities have always had extensive control. Moreover, Hadacheck triggered a backlash against Los Angeles's early twentieth-century land use regulations that applied to existing uses: Following Hadacheck, many land use statutes exempted existing uses.
    • Comment, supra note 48, at 737 ("It is a common occurrence, where there are zoning ordinances in effect, for the exclusions to begin with nuisances and near-nuisances, over which municipalities have always had extensive control."). Moreover, Hadacheck triggered a backlash against Los Angeles's early twentieth-century land use regulations that applied to existing uses: Following Hadacheck, many land use statutes exempted existing uses.
  • 178
    • 70450245190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WEISS, supra note 48, at 86.
    • WEISS, supra note 48, at 86.
  • 179
    • 70450248415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Sintra, Inc. v. City of Seattle, 829 P.2d 765, 773 (Wash. 1992) Regulations which enhance public interests, and go beyond preventing harmful activity, may constitute a taking. The regulatory scheme here goes beyond preventing harm.
    • See, e.g., Sintra, Inc. v. City of Seattle, 829 P.2d 765, 773 (Wash. 1992) ("[Regulations which enhance public interests, and go beyond preventing harmful activity, may constitute a taking. The regulatory scheme here goes beyond preventing harm.");
  • 180
    • 70450267448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1028-30 (1992) holding that regulations which prohibit all economically beneficial use of land are unconstitutional without compensation to burdened property owners unless that regulation is proscribing use under established property and nuisance principles
    • see also Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1028-30 (1992) (holding that regulations which prohibit all economically beneficial use of land are unconstitutional without compensation to burdened property owners unless that regulation is proscribing use under established property and nuisance principles);
  • 181
    • 70450235067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robinson v. City of Seattle, 830 P.2d 318, 328 (Wash. 1992) [I]f the regulation . . . goes beyond mere harm prevention to require a property owner to provide a public benefit, then that regulation is susceptible to a constitutional taking challenge.
    • Robinson v. City of Seattle, 830 P.2d 318, 328 (Wash. 1992) ("[I]f the regulation . . . goes beyond mere harm prevention to require a property owner to provide a public benefit, then that regulation is susceptible to a constitutional taking challenge.").
  • 182
    • 0347222484 scopus 로고
    • Responsibility, Causation, and the Harm-Benefit Line in Takings Jurisprudence
    • See, e.g., 475-78
    • See, e.g., Glynn S. Lunney, Jr., Responsibility, Causation, and the Harm-Benefit Line in Takings Jurisprudence, 6 FORDHAM ENVTL. L. REV. 433, 475-78 (1995);
    • (1995) Fordham Envtl. L. Rev. , vol.6 , pp. 433
    • Lunney Jr., G.S.1
  • 183
    • 84869682504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1024 observing that difference between preventing harm and conferring benefit is "often in the eye of the beholder
    • see also Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1024 (observing that difference between preventing harm and conferring benefit is "often in the eye of the beholder").
  • 184
    • 70450263326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 907 P.2d 1324 (Cal. 1996).
    • 907 P.2d 1324 (Cal. 1996).
  • 185
    • 70450228473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 1335
    • Id at 1335
  • 186
    • 70450246982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • quoting Edmonds v. Los Angeles County, 255 P.2d 772, 777 (Cal. 1953)
    • quoting Edmonds v. Los Angeles County, 255 P.2d 772, 777 (Cal. 1953)
  • 187
    • 70450273141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 188
    • 70450267449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing Penn Cent. Transp. Co. v. New York City, 438 U.S. 104, 125 (1978)
    • citing Penn Cent. Transp. Co. v. New York City, 438 U.S. 104, 125 (1978)
  • 189
    • 70450247816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 190
    • 70450231597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365 (1926)
    • citing Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365 (1926)).
  • 191
    • 70450237640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Euclid, 272 U.S. at 397.
    • Euclid, 272 U.S. at 397.
  • 192
    • 70450280565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Calvert v. County of Yuba, 145 Cal. App. 4th 613, 623 (2006)In light of the state and federal constitutional takings clauses, when zoning ordinances or similar land use regulations are enacted, they customarily exempt existing land uses (or amortize them over time) to avoid questions as to the constitutionality of their application to those uses.
    • See, e.g., Calvert v. County of Yuba, 145 Cal. App. 4th 613, 623 (2006) ("In light of the state and federal constitutional takings clauses, when zoning ordinances or similar land use regulations are enacted, they customarily exempt existing land uses (or amortize them over time) to avoid questions as to the constitutionality of their application to those uses.");
  • 193
    • 84869682497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prince George's County v. Sunrise Dev. Ltd. 623 A.2d 1296, 1303-04 (Md. 1993) stating, without elaboration, that vested rights doctrine has "constitutional foundation"
    • Prince George's County v. Sunrise Dev. Ltd. 623 A.2d 1296, 1303-04 (Md. 1993) (stating, without elaboration, that vested rights doctrine has "constitutional foundation").
  • 194
    • 70450230442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For other examples, see supra notes 1, 32, and 33.
    • For other examples, see supra notes 1, 32, and 33.
  • 195
    • 70450252864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Penn Coal, the case that famously identified the possibility of regulatory takings, was decided in 1922.
    • Penn Coal, the case that famously identified the possibility of regulatory takings, was decided in 1922.
  • 196
    • 70450278732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pa. Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393 (1922). The Supreme Court did not invalidate or even address the constitutionality of a land use regulation under the Takings Clause until Penn Central in 1978.
    • Pa. Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393 (1922). The Supreme Court did not invalidate or even address the constitutionality of a land use regulation under the Takings Clause until Penn Central in 1978.
  • 197
    • 70450273142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 438 U.S. 104 (1978).
    • See 438 U.S. 104 (1978).
  • 198
    • 33744747585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Police Power Revisited: Phantom Incorporation and the Roots of the Takings "Muddle,"
    • 838-851
    • Bradley C. Karkkainen, The Police Power Revisited: Phantom Incorporation and the Roots of the Takings "Muddle," 90 MINN. L. REV. 826, 838-851 (2006).
    • (2006) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.90 , pp. 826
    • Karkkainen, B.C.1
  • 199
    • 70450259406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See cases cited supra note 49.
    • See cases cited supra note 49.
  • 200
    • 84869672013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Hoffmann v. Kinealy, 389 S.W.2d 745, 754-55 (Mo. 1965) finding that elimina-tion of prior nonconforming use of land for open storage of lumber and other building materials and equipment would trigger takings liability under Missouri Constitution-"a taking not to be justified as an exercise of the police power which is always subject to, and may never transcend, constitutional rights and limitations"
    • E.g., Hoffmann v. Kinealy, 389 S.W.2d 745, 754-55 (Mo. 1965) (finding that elimina-tion of prior nonconforming use of land for open storage of lumber and other building materials and equipment would trigger takings liability under Missouri Constitution-"a taking not to be justified as an exercise of the police power which is always subject to, and may never transcend, constitutional rights and limitations");
  • 201
    • 70450267451 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PA Nw. Distribs., Inc. v. Zoning Hearing Bd., 584 A.2d 1372, 1376 (Pa. 1991) finding amortization of lawful preexisting use violative of Pennsylvania Constitution
    • PA Nw. Distribs., Inc. v. Zoning Hearing Bd., 584 A.2d 1372, 1376 (Pa. 1991) (finding amortization of lawful preexisting use violative of Pennsylvania Constitution);
  • 202
    • 70450280566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collins, supra note 64, at 217 The amortization technique, as applied to non-conforming uses, has been described as more of a postponement than a solution.
    • cf. Collins, supra note 64, at 217 ("The amortization technique, as applied to non-conforming uses, has been described as more of a postponement than a solution.");
  • 203
    • 70450257635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reynolds, supra note 59, at 105 & n.24 listing cases where court did not distinguish between immediate and delayed cessation
    • Reynolds, supra note 59, at 105 & n.24 (listing cases where court did not distinguish between immediate and delayed cessation).
  • 204
    • 84869682498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hoffmann, 389 S.W.2d at 753 stating that "no one has, as yet, been so brash as to contend that ... a pre-existing lawful nonconforming use might be terminated immediately
    • Hoffmann, 389 S.W.2d at 753 (stating that "no one has, as yet, been so brash as to contend that ... a pre-existing lawful nonconforming use might be terminated immediately
  • 205
    • 84869664939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and further arguing that "the contrary is implicit in the amortization technique itself which would validate a taking presently unconstitutional by the simple expedient of postponing such taking for a 'reasonable' time".
    • and further arguing that "the contrary is implicit in the amortization technique itself which would validate a taking presently unconstitutional by the simple expedient of postponing such taking for a 'reasonable' time").
  • 206
    • 70450235950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 584 A.2d at 1376 (finding amortization period violative of Pennsylvania Constitution)
    • See PA Nw. Distribs., 584 A.2d at 1376 (finding amortization period violative of Pennsylvania Constitution);
    • Pa Nw. Distribs.
  • 207
    • 84869682494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §622 & (collecting cases invalidating amortization rules under Takings Clause);
    • see also 83 AM. JUR. 2D Zoning and Planning §622 & n.5 (2003) (collecting cases invalidating amortization rules under Takings Clause);
    • (2003) 83 Am. Jur. 2D Zoning and Planning , Issue.5
  • 208
    • 70450264187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (same).
    • Reynolds, supra note 59, at 105-106 (same).
    • Supra Note , vol.59 , pp. 105-106
    • Reynolds1
  • 209
    • 84869672008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Concord Twp. v. Cornogg, 9 Pa. D. & C.2d 79, 86 (1956) (striking down zoning ordinance with amortization provision of six months on basis of constitutional ground "that no citizen can be deprived of his property without due process of law");
    • See, e.g., Concord Twp. v. Cornogg, 9 Pa. D. & C.2d 79, 86 (1956) (striking down zoning ordinance with amortization provision of six months on basis of constitutional ground "that no citizen can be deprived of his property without due process of law");
  • 210
    • 84869664937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Ailes v. Decatur County Area Planning Comm'n, 448 N.E.2d 1057, 1060 (Ind. 1983) ("[A]n ordinance prohibiting any continuation of an existing lawful use within a zoned area regardless of the length of time given to amortize that use is unconstitutional as the taking of property without due process of law and an unreasonable exercise of the police power.")
    • see also Ailes v. Decatur County Area Planning Comm'n, 448 N.E.2d 1057, 1060 (Ind. 1983) ("[A]n ordinance prohibiting any continuation of an existing lawful use within a zoned area regardless of the length of time given to amortize that use is unconstitutional as the taking of property without due process of law and an unreasonable exercise of the police power."),
  • 211
    • 70450258500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • overruled by Bd. of Zoning Appeals v. Leisz, 702 N.E.2d 1026 (Ind. 1998).
    • overruled by Bd. of Zoning Appeals v. Leisz, 702 N.E.2d 1026 (Ind. 1998).
  • 212
    • 70450250891 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Sun Oil Co. of Pa. v. City of Upper Arlington, 379 N.E.2d 266, 271 (Ohio Ct. App. 1977) (determining that amortization provisions are valid only where they eliminate nuisances)
    • See, e.g., Sun Oil Co. of Pa. v. City of Upper Arlington, 379 N.E.2d 266, 271 (Ohio Ct. App. 1977) (determining that amortization provisions are valid only where they eliminate nuisances);
  • 213
    • 70450260550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (describing Due Process protection).
    • see also Reynolds, supra note 59, at 108 (describing Due Process protection).
    • Supra Note , vol.59 , pp. 108
    • Reynolds1
  • 214
    • 84869682493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Modjeska Sign Studios, Inc. v. Berle, 373 N.E.2d 255, 262 (N.Y. 1977) (finding amortization reasonable only when "the public gain achieved ... outweighs the private loss suffered by owners of nonconforming uses")
    • See Modjeska Sign Studios, Inc. v. Berle, 373 N.E.2d 255, 262 (N.Y. 1977) (finding amortization reasonable only when "the public gain achieved ... outweighs the private loss suffered by owners of nonconforming uses");
  • 215
    • 84869682300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Austin v. Older, 278 N.W. 727, 730 (Mich. 1938) ("An ordinance requiring an immediate cessation of a nonconforming use may be held to be unconstitutional because it brings about a deprivation of property rights out of proportion to the public benefit obtained . ").
    • cf. Austin v. Older, 278 N.W. 727, 730 (Mich. 1938) ("An ordinance requiring an immediate cessation of a nonconforming use may be held to be unconstitutional because it brings about a deprivation of property rights out of proportion to the public benefit obtained . ").
  • 216
    • 70450226180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Outdoor Graphics, Inc. v. City of Burlington, 103 F.3d 690, 695 (8th Cir. 1996) (including benefits obtained during amortization period in regulatory takings analysis)
    • See, e.g., Outdoor Graphics, Inc. v. City of Burlington, 103 F.3d 690, 695 (8th Cir. 1996) (including benefits obtained during amortization period in regulatory takings analysis);
  • 217
    • 70450260546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing amortization as substitute for just compensation).
    • see also Varadarajan, supra note 13, at 2573-2576 (discussing amortization as substitute for just compensation).
    • Supra Note , vol.13 , pp. 2573-2576
    • Varadarajan1
  • 218
    • 70450235068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Naegele Outdoor Adver., Inc. v. City of Durham, 803 F. Supp. 1068, 1078 (M.D.N.C. 1992) (finding no taking because earnings during amortization period exceeded investment in property).
    • See Naegele Outdoor Adver., Inc. v. City of Durham, 803 F. Supp. 1068, 1078 (M.D.N.C. 1992) (finding no taking because earnings during amortization period exceeded investment in property).
  • 219
    • 70450284377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Temple Baptist Church, Inc. v. City of Albuquerque, 646 P.2d 565, 572 (N.M. 1982) (finding amortization period satisfied requirement of just compensation). In theory, one principal justification for amortization is that it is pegged to the useful economic life of the underlying structure. If the value of an asset has fully depreciated for tax purposes, then the courts will uphold its elimination without payment of just compensation.
    • E.g., Temple Baptist Church, Inc. v. City of Albuquerque, 646 P.2d 565, 572 (N.M. 1982) (finding amortization period satisfied requirement of just compensation). In theory, one principal justification for amortization is that it is pegged to the useful economic life of the underlying structure. If the value of an asset has fully depreciated for tax purposes, then the courts will uphold its elimination without payment of just compensation.
  • 221
    • 84869682297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Sand Key Assoes, v. Bd. of Trustees of Internal Improvement Trust Fund, 458 So. 2d 369, 370-71 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1984) ("Property rights are vested and cannot be taken away without just compensation.")
    • E.g., Sand Key Assoes, v. Bd. of Trustees of Internal Improvement Trust Fund, 458 So. 2d 369, 370-71 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1984) ("[Property rights are vested and cannot be taken away without just compensation.");
  • 222
    • 84869682298 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bye v. Giarrusso, 321 So. 2d 58, 60 (La. Ct. App. 1975) ("'[V]ested rights' shall not be divested except for purposes of public utility and then only on payment of just compensation." (quoting Quartemont v. Aroyelles Parish Police Jury, 228 So. 2d 199, 201 (La. Ct. App. 1969)))
    • Bye v. Giarrusso, 321 So. 2d 58, 60 (La. Ct. App. 1975) ("'[V]ested rights' shall not be divested except for purposes of public utility and then only on payment of just compensation." (quoting Quartemont v. Aroyelles Parish Police Jury, 228 So. 2d 199, 201 (La. Ct. App. 1969)));
  • 223
    • 84869672005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Padgett v. Mason County Zoning Comm'n, Nos. 236458, 236459, 2003 WL 22902878, at *5 (Mich. Ct. App. Dec. 9, 2003) ("[T]he prohibition of taking property without just compensation extends only to vested rights in property.").
    • Padgett v. Mason County Zoning Comm'n, Nos. 236458, 236459, 2003 WL 22902878, at *5 (Mich. Ct. App. Dec. 9, 2003) ("[T]he prohibition of taking property without just compensation extends only to vested rights in property.").
  • 224
    • 84869688824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("One common approach is to presume that a perfunctory reference to vested rights explains the legal theory involved and the reason for its application to the facts of the case.").
    • Others have noted the use of the phrase "vested rights" as a substitute for real analysis. See Cunningham & Kremer, supra note 71, at 628 ("One common approach is to presume that a perfunctory reference to vested rights explains the legal theory involved and the reason for its application to the facts of the case.").
    • Supra Note , vol.71 , pp. 628
    • Cunningham1    Kremer2
  • 225
    • 84869664934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Shrader v. United States, 38 Fed. Cl. 788, 796-97 (1997) "[Regarding a possible takings claim by Mr. Shrader, plaintiff's interests] . . . were neither vested rights, nor were they more than a 'mere expectancy, and therefore not entitled to protection as a property right.'"
    • See, e.g., Shrader v. United States, 38 Fed. Cl. 788, 796-97 (1997) ("[Regarding a possible takings claim by Mr. Shrader, plaintiff's interests] . . . were neither vested rights, nor were they more than a 'mere expectancy, and therefore not entitled to protection as a property right.'"
  • 226
    • 70450270652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting Alberico v. United States, 783 F.2d 1024, 1027 (Fed. Cir. 1986))
    • (quoting Alberico v. United States, 783 F.2d 1024, 1027 (Fed. Cir. 1986));
  • 227
    • 84869664935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Att'y Gen. v. Mich. Pub. Serv. Comm'n, 642 N.W.2d 691, 699 (Mich. Ct. App. 2002) "One who asserts an uncompensated taking claim must first establish that a vested property right is affected."
    • Att'y Gen. v. Mich. Pub. Serv. Comm'n, 642 N.W.2d 691, 699 (Mich. Ct. App. 2002) ("One who asserts an uncompensated taking claim must first establish that a vested property right is affected."
  • 228
    • 70450273146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting Fun 'N Sun RV, Inc. v. Michigan, 527 N.W.2d 468, 478 (Mich. 1994))
    • (quoting Fun 'N Sun RV, Inc. v. Michigan, 527 N.W.2d 468, 478 (Mich. 1994)));
  • 229
    • 84869682296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tracy v. City of Deshler, 568 N.W.2d 903, 907 (Neb. 1997) (contrasting "vested property right" with "mere privilege")
    • Tracy v. City of Deshler, 568 N.W.2d 903, 907 (Neb. 1997) (contrasting "vested property right" with "mere privilege");
  • 230
    • 70450248421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (distinguishing between privilege and right).
    • see also Cunningham & Kremer, supra note 71, at 639-40 (distinguishing between privilege and right).
    • Supra Note , vol.71 , pp. 639-640
    • Cunningham1    Kremer2
  • 231
    • 84869678305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("['Vested'] is frequently applied in a circular fashion to describe any interest that is protected by the law. Hence, to assert that a person has a vested right is merely to announce the conclusion that a court will protect that interest."). Any property right, not just a vested property right, is potentially protected by the Takings Clause.
    • In this sense, the term "vested right" is synonymous with the term "protected property interest" and, as such, its use is entirely circular. See Cunningham & Kremer, supra note 71, at 640 ("['Vested'] is frequently applied in a circular fashion to describe any interest that is protected by the law. Hence, to assert that a person has a vested right is merely to announce the conclusion that a court will protect that interest."). Any property right, not just a vested property right, is potentially protected by the Takings Clause.
    • Supra Note , vol.71 , pp. 640
    • Cunningham1    Kremer2
  • 232
    • 0009017757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recognizing vested development rights as protected property in fifth amendment due process and taking claims
    • ("In fact, many state courts use the words 'vested right' and 'property right' interchangeably.")
    • John J. Delaney & Emily J. Vaias, Recognizing Vested Development Rights as Protected Property in Fifth Amendment Due Process and Taking Claims, 49 WASH. U. J. URB. & CONTEMP. L. 27, 31 (1996) ("In fact, many state courts use the words 'vested right' and 'property right' interchangeably.") ;
    • (1996) 49 Wash. U. J. Urb. & Contemp. , vol.L. 27
    • Delaney, J.J.1    Vaias, E.J.2
  • 233
    • 84869676730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §150 ("For purposes of just compensation in an eminent-domain proceeding, 'property' includes every sort of interest the citizen may possess.").
    • cf. 26 AM. JUR. 2D Eminent Domain §150 (2004) ("For purposes of just compensation in an eminent-domain proceeding, 'property' includes every sort of interest the citizen may possess.").
    • (2004) 26 AM. Jur. 2D Eminent Domain
  • 234
    • 84869682487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Landgraf v. USA Film Prods., 511 U.S. 244, 266 (1994) ("The Fifth Amendment's Takings Clause prevents the Legislature (and other government actors) from depriving private persons of vested property rights except for a 'public use' and upon payment of 'just compensation.'")
    • See, e.g., Landgraf v. USA Film Prods., 511 U.S. 244, 266 (1994) ("The Fifth Amendment's Takings Clause prevents the Legislature (and other government actors) from depriving private persons of vested property rights except for a 'public use' and upon payment of 'just compensation.'");
  • 235
    • 70450286043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arrow of time: vested rights, zoning estoppel, and development agreements in Hawai'i
    • see also Kenneth R. Kupchak et al., Arrow of Time: Vested Rights, Zoning Estoppel, and Development Agreements in Hawai'i, 27 U. HAW. L. REV. 17, 38 (2004)
    • (2004) 27 U. Haw. L. Rev. , vol.17 , pp. 38
    • Kupchak, K.R.1
  • 236
    • 84869664929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting County of Kauai v. Pac. Standard Life Ins. Co., 653 P.2d 766, 780 & n.129 (Haw. 1982) and describing it as "equating establishing a vested right with establishing a regulatory taking");
    • (quoting County of Kauai v. Pac. Standard Life Ins. Co., 653 P.2d 766, 780 & n.129 (Haw. 1982) and describing it as "equating] establishing a vested right with establishing a regulatory taking");
  • 237
    • 33646547962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public rights, private rights, and statutory retroactivity
    • ("The vested label ⋯ often seems conclusory.").
    • Ann Woolhandler, Public Rights, Private Rights, and Statutory Retroactivity, 94 GEO. L.J. 1015, 1023-1024 (2006) ("The vested label ⋯ often seems conclusory.").
    • (2006) 94 Geo. L.J. , vol.1015 , pp. 1023-1024
    • Woolhandler, A.1
  • 238
    • 70450232404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • According to Cunningham and Kremer, "[t]he term instead should be recognized as the end product of a process that weighs and analyzes a private interest to determine whether it is of sufficient status to receive legal protection." Cunningham & Kremer, supra note 71, at 641.
    • Supra Note , vol.71 , pp. 641
    • Cunningham1    Kremer2
  • 239
    • 21344482123 scopus 로고
    • The historical framework for reviving constitutional protection for property and contract rights
    • For a historical explanation for the confusion about vested rights, see James L. Kainen, The Historical Framework for Reviving Constitutional Protection for Property and Contract Rights, 79 CORNELL L. REV. 87, 104-114 (1993).
    • (1993) 79 Cornell L. Rev. , vol.87 , pp. 104-114
    • Kainen, J.L.1
  • 240
    • 70450271538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003 (1992) (holding that regulation prohibiting building on beachfront lot, thus depriving landowner of virtually all economically viable use, constitutes compensable government taking).
    • See, e.g., Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003 (1992) (holding that regulation prohibiting building on beachfront lot, thus depriving landowner of virtually all economically viable use, constitutes compensable government taking).
  • 241
    • 84869682293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Colo. Ground Water Comm'n v. North Kiowa-Bijou Groundwater Mgmt. Dist., 77 P.3d 62, 81 (Colo. 2003) finding that plaintiff's groundwater right was vested right and "[a]s such it cannot be taken away by subsequent legislative action
    • See, e.g., Colo. Ground Water Comm'n v. North Kiowa-Bijou Groundwater Mgmt. Dist., 77 P.3d 62, 81 (Colo. 2003) (finding that plaintiff's groundwater right was vested right and "[a]s such it cannot be taken away by subsequent legislative action");
  • 242
    • 84869682292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • First of Am. Trust Co. v. Armstead, 664 N.E.2d 36, 40 (Ill. 1996) ("[T]his court has defined a vested right as an expectation that is so far perfected that it cannot be taken away by legislation.")
    • First of Am. Trust Co. v. Armstead, 664 N.E.2d 36, 40 (Ill. 1996) ("[T]his court has defined a vested right as an expectation that is so far perfected that it cannot be taken away by legislation.");
  • 243
    • 84869682294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Resolution Trust Corp. v. Fleischer, 892 P.2d 497, 501 (Kan. 1995) ("We, like many courts, have used the term 'vested rights' to describe rights which cannot be taken away by retroactive legislation.")
    • Resolution Trust Corp. v. Fleischer, 892 P.2d 497, 501 (Kan. 1995) ("We, like many courts, have used the term 'vested rights' to describe rights which cannot be taken away by retroactive legislation.");
  • 244
    • 84869682485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Powell v. Calvert County, 795 A.2d 96, 102 (Md. 2002) "[Vested rights] doctrine ⋯. rests upon the legal theory that when a property owner ⋯ completes substantial construction on [his] property, his right to complete and use that structure cannot be affected by any subsequent change of the applicable building or zoning regulations." (quoting Prince George's County v. Equitable Trust Co., 408 A.2d 737, 741 (Md. Ct. Spec. App. (1979))).
    • Powell v. Calvert County, 795 A.2d 96, 102 (Md. 2002) ("[Vested rights] doctrine ⋯. rests upon the legal theory that when a property owner ⋯ completes substantial construction on [his] property, his right to complete and use that structure cannot be affected by any subsequent change of the applicable building or zoning regulations." (quoting Prince George's County v. Equitable Trust Co., 408 A.2d 737, 741 (Md. Ct. Spec. App. (1979))).
  • 245
    • 0039581492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Entitlement to substantive due process: Old versus new property in land use regulation
    • (collecting cases demonstrating that municipality's revocation of building permit from property owner with vested right in permit constitutes violation of substantive due process)
    • See Daniel R. Mandelker, Entitlement to Substantive Due Process: Old Versus New Property in Land Use Regulation, 3 WASH. U. J.L. & POL'Y 61, 76 n.71 (2000) (collecting cases demonstrating that municipality's revocation of building permit from property owner with vested right in permit constitutes violation of substantive due process);
    • (2000) 3 Wash. U. J.L. & Pol'y , vol.61 , Issue.71 , pp. 76
    • Mandelker, D.R.1
  • 246
    • 84869682486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, e.g., Goldrush II v. City of Marietta, 482 S.E.2d 347, 358 (Ga. 1997) ("A property interest protected by the due process clauses of the federal and state constitutions meets our definition of 'vested rights.'")
    • see also, e.g., Goldrush II v. City of Marietta, 482 S.E.2d 347, 358 (Ga. 1997) ("A property interest protected by the due process clauses of the federal and state constitutions meets our definition of 'vested rights.'");
  • 247
    • 84869682295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hayes v. Howell, 308 S.E.2d 170, 175 (Ga. 1983) noting that "vested rights" is generally used to imply interests which "may not be interfered with by retrospective laws," which "it is proper for the state to recognize and protect, and of which the individual cannot be deprived arbitrarily without injustice."
    • Hayes v. Howell, 308 S.E.2d 170, 175 (Ga. 1983) (noting that "vested rights" is generally used to imply interests which "may not be interfered with by retrospective laws," which "it is proper for the state to recognize and protect, and of which the individual cannot be deprived arbitrarily without injustice."
  • 248
    • 70450264185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting Am. States Water Serv. Co. of Cal. v. Johnson, 88 P.2d 770, 774 (Cal. Dist. Ct. App. 1939))
    • (quoting Am. States Water Serv. Co. of Cal. v. Johnson, 88 P.2d 770, 774 (Cal. Dist. Ct. App. 1939)));
  • 249
    • 84869679719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("Some cases couch the constitutional purpose of the Washington rule in terms of how vesting provides citizens with 'fundamental fairness,' which is a due process concept.").
    • Overstreet & Kirchheim, supra note 74, at 1071-1072 ("Some cases couch the constitutional purpose of the Washington rule in terms of how vesting provides citizens with 'fundamental fairness,' which is a due process concept.").
    • Supra Note , vol.74 , pp. 1071-1072
    • Overstreet1    Kirchheim2
  • 250
    • 84869664928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Waikiki Marketplace Inv. Co. v. Honolulu, 949 P.2d 183, 193-94 (Haw. Ct. App. 1997) ("[D]ue process principles protect a property owner from having his or her vested property rights interfered with and preexisting lawful uses of property are generally considered to be vested rights that zoning ordinances may not abrogate." (citation omitted))
    • See, e.g., Waikiki Marketplace Inv. Co. v. Honolulu, 949 P.2d 183, 193-94 (Haw. Ct. App. 1997) ("[D]ue process principles protect a property owner from having his or her vested property rights interfered with and preexisting lawful uses of property are generally considered to be vested rights that zoning ordinances may not abrogate." (citation omitted));
  • 251
    • 84869671997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael Weimann Assoes. Gen. P'ship v. Town of Huntersville, 555 S.E.2d 342, 345 (N.C. Ct. App. 2001) ("At common law, the vested rights doctrine evolved as a balancing mechanism" between "the State's constitutional authority over land-use" and property owners' "constitutional entitlement to due process of law")
    • Michael Weimann Assoes. Gen. P'ship v. Town of Huntersville, 555 S.E.2d 342, 345 (N.C. Ct. App. 2001) ("At common law, the vested rights doctrine evolved as a balancing mechanism" between "the State's constitutional authority over land-use" and property owners' "constitutional entitlement to due process of law");
  • 252
    • 84869682484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weyerhaeuser v. Pierce County, 976 P.2d 1279, 1284 (Wash. Ct. App. 1999) ("The doctrine is based upon constitutional principles of fairness and due process, acknowledging that development rights are valuable and protected property interests.").
    • Weyerhaeuser v. Pierce County, 976 P.2d 1279, 1284 (Wash. Ct. App. 1999) ("The doctrine is based upon constitutional principles of fairness and due process, acknowledging that development rights are valuable and protected property interests.").
  • 253
    • 84869682904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing vested rights in land use). According to Kainen, whether a right has vested should not determine whether the right is subject to subsequent regulation. As he succinctly concludes, "Establishing that development expectations are 'vested rights' is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition to their constitutional protection."
    • Kainen, supra note 117, at 120-22 (discussing vested rights in land use). According to Kainen, whether a right has vested should not determine whether the right is subject to subsequent regulation. As he succinctly concludes, "Establishing that development expectations are 'vested rights' is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition to their constitutional protection."
    • Supra Note , vol.117 , pp. 120-122
    • Kainen1
  • 254
    • 70450243584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 122.
    • Id. at 122.
  • 255
    • 84869687919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 505 U.S. at 1029 ("[The limitation imposed by] regulations that prohibit all economically benficial use of land ⋯ must inhere in the title itself, in the restrictions that background principles of the State's law of property and nuisance already place upon land ownership.").
    • See, e.g., Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1029 ("[The limitation imposed by] regulations that prohibit all economically benficial use of land ⋯ must inhere in the title itself, in the restrictions that background principles of the State's law of property and nuisance already place upon land ownership.").
    • Lucas
  • 256
    • 70450268247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., City of Minot v. Freelander, 426 N.W.2d 556 (N.D. 1988) (holding that demolition of house to stop nuisance does not violate Takings Clause)
    • See, e.g., City of Minot v. Freelander, 426 N.W.2d 556 (N.D. 1988) (holding that demolition of house to stop nuisance does not violate Takings Clause);
  • 257
    • 70450246072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Just v. Marinette County, 201 N.W.2d 761 (Wis. 1972) (upholding wetlands regulation as preventing harm).
    • Just v. Marinette County, 201 N.W.2d 761 (Wis. 1972) (upholding wetlands regulation as preventing harm).
  • 258
    • 84869672000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Dep't of Agrie. & Consumer Servs. v. Polk, 568 So. 2d 35, 48 (Fla. 1990) (Barkett, J., concurring) ("Although this Court has applied the harm-benefit distinction to determine liability, I now believe that analysis is inappropriate in 'takings' cases." (citations omitted)). The relationship between the police power and the Takings Clause is enormously contested.
    • But see Dep't of Agrie. & Consumer Servs. v. Polk, 568 So. 2d 35, 48 (Fla. 1990) (Barkett, J., concurring) ("Although this Court has applied the harm-benefit distinction to determine liability, I now believe that analysis is inappropriate in 'takings' cases." (citations omitted)). The relationship between the police power and the Takings Clause is enormously contested.
  • 259
    • 0009627364 scopus 로고
    • The economics of public use
    • (discussing this relationship in context of Supreme Court efforts to define Takings Clause's 'public use' requirement)
    • See Thomas W. Merrill, The Economics of Public Use, 72 CORNELL L. REV. 61, 70 (1986) (discussing this relationship in context of Supreme Court efforts to define Takings Clause's 'public use' requirement);
    • (1986) 72 Cornell L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 70
    • Merrill, T.W.1
  • 260
    • 70450231598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public ruses, 2004
    • (discussing Merrill, supra, and arguing that if public use were coterminous with police power it would not eliminate compensation inquiry).
    • James E. Krier & Christopher Serkin, Public Ruses, 2004 MICH. ST. L. REV. 859, 862-63 (2004) (discussing Merrill, supra, and arguing that if public use were coterminous with police power it would not eliminate compensation inquiry).
    • (2004) Mich. St. L. Rev. , vol.859 , pp. 862-863
    • Krier, J.E.1    Serkin, C.2
  • 261
    • 70450265293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This assumes that existing uses are not eliminated through permanent physical occupations, proscribed in Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp., 458 U.S. 419, 421 (1982), nor eliminated through government exactions, the permissible limits of which are defined in
    • This assumes that existing uses are not eliminated through permanent physical occupations, proscribed in Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp., 458 U.S. 419, 421 (1982), nor eliminated through government exactions, the permissible limits of which are defined in
  • 262
    • 70450280573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dolan v. City of Tigard, 512 U.S. 374 (1994), and Nollan v. Cal. Coastal Comm'n, 483 U.S. 825 (1987).
    • Dolan v. City of Tigard, 512 U.S. 374 (1994), and Nollan v. Cal. Coastal Comm'n, 483 U.S. 825 (1987).
  • 263
    • 84869682482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 505 U.S. 1003, 1015 (1992) (deeming "categorical treatment appropriate ⋯ where regulation denies all economically beneficial or productive use of land").
    • 505 U.S. 1003, 1015 (1992) (deeming "categorical treatment appropriate ⋯ where regulation denies all economically beneficial or productive use of land").
  • 264
    • 70450247814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Penn Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104 (1978).
    • Penn Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104 (1978).
  • 265
    • 0347039857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.
    • Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1027.
    • Lucas , vol.505 , pp. 1027
  • 266
    • 10944239870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §3d ed. (discussing Lucas Court's emphasis on economically beneficial use of property).
    • See STEVEN J. EAGLE, REGULATORY TAKINGS §(3d ed. 2005) (discussing Lucas Court's emphasis on economically beneficial use of property).
    • (2005) Regulatory Takings
    • Eagle, S.J.1
  • 267
    • 0346409846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.
    • Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124.
    • Penn Central , vol.438 , pp. 124
  • 268
    • 84869689944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Character" as "Worthiness": A new meaning for penn central's third test?
    • Professor Eagle notes, however, that more recently, some courts have expanded the inquiry to include the purpose and benefits of the government action, specifically looking at whether the government regulation is retroactive or targeting an individual.
    • The third factor might also be relevant to this analysis, at least as interpreted by Professor Eagle. Traditionally, the character of the regulation implicated only a distinction between a physical invasion and regulation merely affecting economic interests. Steven J. Eagle, "Character" as "Worthiness": A New Meaning for Penn Central's Third Test?, 27 ZONING & PLANNING L. REP. 1, 2 (2004). Professor Eagle notes, however, that more recently, some courts have expanded the inquiry to include the purpose and benefits of the government action, specifically looking at whether the government regulation is retroactive or targeting an individual.
    • (2004) 27 Zoning & Planning L. Rep. , vol.1 , pp. 2
    • Eagle, S.J.1
  • 269
    • 70450241595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 4-5. This reading of the third Penn Central factor is very interesting but does not represent a consensus view of the content of the test.
    • Id. at 4-5. This reading of the third Penn Central factor is very interesting but does not represent a consensus view of the content of the test.
  • 270
    • 85045338255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Takings jurisprudence as three-tiered review
    • ("[T]he only clear case for a taking under Penn Central would be where the investment reflects actual development expenditures, such as constructing facilities or homes, rather than speculation on future uses.")
    • See Mark W. Cordes, Takings Jurisprudence as Three-Tiered Review, 20 J. NAT. RESOURCES & ENVTL. L. 1, 38 (2005) ("[T]he only clear case for a taking under Penn Central would be where the investment reflects actual development expenditures, such as constructing facilities or homes, rather than speculation on future uses.");
    • (2005) 20 J. Nat. Resources & Envtl. L. , vol.1 , pp. 38
    • Cordes, M.W.1
  • 271
    • 84869679897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Construing the canon: An exegesis of regulatory takings jurisprudence after Lingle v. Chevron
    • (identifying "subjective" aspects of investment-backed expectations, such as extent and characteristics of property owner's actual investment, and noting similarity to vested rights inquiry).
    • Michael B. Kent Jr., Construing the Canon: An Exegesis of Regulatory Takings Jurisprudence After Lingle v. Chevron, 16 N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. 63, 97-98 (2008) (identifying "subjective" aspects of investment-backed expectations, such as extent and characteristics of property owner's actual investment, and noting similarity to vested rights inquiry).
    • (2008) 16 N.Y.U. Envtl. L.J. , vol.63 , pp. 97-98
    • Kent Jr., M.B.1
  • 272
    • 70450278737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.
    • Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 115-116
    • Penn Central , vol.438 , pp. 115-116
  • 273
    • 70450265450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 116-118
    • Id. at 116-118
  • 274
    • 70450250072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 136.
    • Id. at 136.
  • 275
    • 70450255083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 276
    • 70450255081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • distinguishing Goldblatt v. Hempstead, 369 U.S. 590 (1962)
    • (distinguishing Goldblatt v. Hempstead, 369 U.S. 590 (1962),
  • 277
    • 70450225348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Miller v. Schoene, 276 U.S. 272 (1928)
    • Miller v. Schoene, 276 U.S. 272 (1928),
  • 278
    • 70450286045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Causby, 328 U.S. 256 (1946)
    • United States v. Causby, 328 U.S. 256 (1946),
  • 279
    • 70450237038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Griggs v. Allegheny County, 369 U.S. 84 (1962)
    • Griggs v. Allegheny County, 369 U.S. 84 (1962),
  • 280
    • 70450246985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hadacheck v. Sebastian, 239 U.S. 394 (1915).
    • and Hadacheck v. Sebastian, 239 U.S. 394 (1915)).
  • 281
    • 70450255082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. The Court's presumption about existing uses, however, may not be accurate. Existing uses can be speculative uses, and despite their lack of immediate utility or function they may simply be creative methods of land speculation. Parking lots in urban centers are one such example.
    • See id. The Court's presumption about existing uses, however, may not be accurate. Existing uses can be speculative uses, and despite their lack of immediate utility or function they may simply be creative methods of land speculation. Parking lots in urban centers are one such example.
  • 282
    • 84869679779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Remarks, random comments
    • ("Land in potentially lucrative and productive locations that is being kept in low-value parking lots is a symptom of land speculation: land remaining almost idle in hope that its very emptiness will increase its value to some future buyer.").
    • See Jane Jacobs, Remarks, Random Comments, 28 B.C. ENVIL. AFF. L. REV. 537, 541 (2001) ("Land in potentially lucrative and productive locations that is being kept in low-value parking lots is a symptom of land speculation: land remaining almost idle in hope that its very emptiness will increase its value to some future buyer.").
    • (2001) 28 B.C. Envil. Aff. L. Rev. , vol.537 , pp. 541
    • Jacobs, J.1
  • 283
    • 70450264184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 444 u.S. 164 (1979).
    • 444 u.S. 164 (1979).
  • 284
    • 0346409846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. (emphasis added).
    • Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124 (emphasis added).
    • Penn Central , vol.438 , pp. 124
  • 285
    • 70450232402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. (emphasis added). For further analysis of this transformation
    • Aetna, 444 U.S. at 175 (emphasis added). For further analysis of this transformation,
    • Aetna , vol.444 , pp. 175
  • 286
    • 70450253986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The regulatory takings notice rule
    • (characterizing transformation as move from subjective to objective standard).
    • see Steven J. Eagle, The Regulatory Takings Notice Rule, 24 U. HAW. L. REV. 533, 560 (2002) (characterizing transformation as move from subjective to objective standard).
    • (2002) 24 U. Haw. L. Rev. , vol.533 , pp. 560
    • Eagle, S.J.1
  • 287
    • 33646134138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Playing the expectations game: when are investment-backed land use expectations unreasonable in state courts?
    • ("Together, these decisions redirected the expectations inquiry away from the impact of regulation and toward the appropriateness of the landowners' land use expectations .")
    • See J. David Breemer, Playing the Expectations Game: When Are Investment-Backed Land Use Expectations (Unreasonable in State Courts?, 38 URB. LAW. 81, 85 (2006) ("Together, these decisions redirected the expectations inquiry away from the impact of regulation and toward the appropriateness of the landowners' land use expectations .");
    • (2006) 38 Urb. Law. , vol.81 , pp. 85
    • David Breemer, J.1
  • 288
    • 84869666792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("[T]he investment-backed expectations factor has become a shield for government that protects land use regulations from the Takings Clause."). The term "expectations" suffers from some of the same problems as "vested rights." "[C]ourts often use 'expectation' to refer to an interest less deserving of protection than a 'right.' By the same token, however, the Court has also used the word 'expectations' to refer to protected property interests."
    • Mandelker, supra note 36, at 21 ("[T]he investment-backed expectations factor has become a shield for government that protects land use regulations from the Takings Clause."). The term "expectations" suffers from some of the same problems as "vested rights." "[C]ourts often use 'expectation' to refer to an interest less deserving of protection than a 'right.' By the same token, however, the Court has also used the word 'expectations' to refer to protected property interests."
    • Supra Note , vol.36 , pp. 21
    • Mandelker1
  • 289
    • 70450266288 scopus 로고
    • Cornering the quark: Investment-backed expectations and economically viable uses in takings analysis
    • Lynda J. Oswald, Cornering the Quark: Investment-Backed Expectations and Economically Viable Uses in Takings Analysis, 70 WASH. L. REV. 91, 108 (1995).
    • (1995) 70 Wash. L. Rev. , vol.91 , pp. 108
    • Oswald, L.J.1
  • 290
    • 70450258499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing property owner's expectations as bound up with ability to anticipate future government regulation).
    • Cf. Oswald, supra note 141, at 111-112 (discussing property owner's expectations as bound up with ability to anticipate future government regulation).
    • Supra Note , vol.141 , pp. 111-112
    • Oswald1
  • 291
    • 84869671994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Nat'l Viatical, Inc. v. Oxendine, No.1:05-CV-3059-TWT, 2006 WL 1071839, at *4 (N.D. Ga. Apr. 20, 2006) (dismissing complaints based on allegations that statute lowered prices of life insurance policies on secondary market because plaintiff failed "to demonstrate how this regulation interferes with their reasonable investment-backed expectations");
    • See, e.g., Nat'l Viatical, Inc. v. Oxendine, No.1:05-CV-3059-TWT, 2006 WL 1071839, at *4 (N.D. Ga. Apr. 20, 2006) (dismissing complaints based on allegations that statute lowered prices of life insurance policies on secondary market because plaintiff failed "to demonstrate how this regulation interferes with their reasonable investment-backed expectations");
  • 292
    • 70450260551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peoples Super Liquor Stores, Inc. v. Jenkins, 432 F. Supp. 2d 200, 215-16 (D. Mass. 2006) (holding that prohibition against owning interest in more than three liquor stores did not interfere with franchisee's reasonable investment-backed expectations)
    • Peoples Super Liquor Stores, Inc. v. Jenkins, 432 F. Supp. 2d 200, 215-16 (D. Mass. 2006) (holding that prohibition against owning interest in more than three liquor stores did not interfere with franchisee's reasonable investment-backed expectations);
  • 293
    • 84869664921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bd. of Zoning Appeals v. Leisz, 702 N.E.2d 1026, 1030 (Ind. 1998) (noting that "the Supreme Court has 'uniformly rejected the proposition that diminution in property value, standing alone, can establish a taking'" and opining that "[i]n particular, the forfeiture of [plaintiff's] nonconforming use caused no interference with their reasonable investment-based expectations" (internal citation omitted)).
    • Bd. of Zoning Appeals v. Leisz, 702 N.E.2d 1026, 1030 (Ind. 1998) (noting that "the Supreme Court has 'uniformly rejected] the proposition that diminution in property value, standing alone, can establish a taking'" and opining that "[i]n particular, the forfeiture of [plaintiff's] nonconforming use caused no interference with their reasonable investment-based expectations" (internal citation omitted)).
  • 294
    • 84869676730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., §14 ("[I]nvestment-backed expectation must be reasonable.").
    • E.g., 26 AM. JUR. 2D Eminent Domain §14 (2004) ("[I]nvestment- backed expectation must be reasonable.").
    • (2004) 26 Am. Jur. 2D Eminent Domain
  • 295
    • 70450231268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 533 U.S. 606 (2001).
    • 533 U.S. 606 (2001).
  • 296
    • 84869682476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 626 (characterizing State's position as argument that "by prospective legislation the State can shape and define property rights and reasonable investment-backed expectations, and subsequent owners cannot claim any injury from lost value" because they "purchased or took title with notice of the limitation").
    • See id. at 626 (characterizing State's position as argument that "by prospective legislation the State can shape and define property rights and reasonable investment-backed expectations, and subsequent owners cannot claim any injury from lost value" because they "purchased or took title with notice of the limitation").
  • 297
    • 70450237040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 629-630
    • Id. at 629-630
  • 298
    • 84869682281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 634-36 (O'Connor, J., concurring) ("[T]he state of regulatory affairs at the time of acquisition is not the only factor that may determine the extent of investmentbacked expectations . Courts properly consider the effect of existing regulations under the rubric of investment-backed expectations in determining whether a compensable taking has occurred. As before, the salience of these facts cannot be reduced to any 'set formula.'").
    • See id. at 634-36 (O'Connor, J., concurring) ("[T]he state of regulatory affairs at the time of acquisition is not the only factor that may determine the extent of investmentbacked expectations . Courts properly consider the effect of existing regulations under the rubric of investment-backed expectations in determining whether a compensable taking has occurred. As before, the salience of these facts cannot be reduced to any 'set formula.'").
  • 299
    • 84869664919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 637 (Scalia, J., concurring) ("[T]he fact that a restriction existed at the time the purchaser took title .. . should have no bearing upon the determination of whether the restriction is so substantial as to constitute a taking.").
    • See id. at 637 (Scalia, J., concurring) ("[T]he fact that a restriction existed at the time the purchaser took title .. . should have no bearing upon the determination of whether the restriction is so substantial as to constitute a taking.").
  • 300
    • 84869682279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 641 (Stevens, J., dissenting in part) ("If the regulations imposed a compensable injury on anyone, it was on the owner of the property at the moment the regulations were adopted.").
    • See id. at 641 (Stevens, J., dissenting in part) ("If the regulations imposed a compensable injury on anyone, it was on the owner of the property at the moment the regulations were adopted.").
  • 301
    • 84869682280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Richard A. Epstein, Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council/ A Tangled Web of Expectations, 45 STAN. L. REV. 1369, 1370 (1993) (suggesting "investment-backed expectations" may be term excluding property received by gift)
    • See, e.g., Richard A. Epstein, Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council/ A Tangled Web of Expectations, 45 STAN. L. REV. 1369, 1370 (1993) (suggesting "investment-backed expectations" may be term excluding property received by gift);
  • 302
    • 70450277192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oswald, supra note 141, at 116-117
    • Supra Note , vol.141 , pp. 116-117
    • Oswald1
  • 303
    • 70450235073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (discussing Hodel v. Irving, 481 U.S. 704 (1987)).
    • (discussing Hodel v. Irving, 481 U.S. 704 (1987)).
  • 305
    • 84869679187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("All in all, we should be deeply suspicious of the phrase 'investment-backed expectations' because it is not possible to identify even the paradigmatic case of its use.").
    • See Epstein, supra note 151, at 1370 ("All in all, we should be deeply suspicious of the phrase 'investment-backed expectations' because it is not possible to identify even the paradigmatic case of its use.").
    • Supra Note , vol.151 , pp. 1370
    • Epstein1
  • 306
    • 84869663479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (examining history of investment-backed expectations). It appears that Professor Michelman was the first person to use the phrase, "investment- backed expectations" in the takings context.
    • See, e.g., Oswald, supra note 141, at 101-06 (examining history of investment-backed expectations). It appears that Professor Michelman was the first person to use the phrase, "investment-backed expectations" in the takings context.
    • Supra Note , vol.141 , pp. 101-106
    • Oswald1
  • 307
    • 0005359499 scopus 로고
    • Property, utility, and fairness: comments on the ethical foundations of "Just compensation" Law
    • He discussed the concept in the context of examining diminution in value.
    • Frank I. Michelman, Property, Utility, and Fairness: Comments on the Ethical Foundations of "Just Compensation" Law, 80 HARV. L. REV. 1165, 1213 (1967). He discussed the concept in the context of examining diminution in value.
    • (1967) 80 Harv. L. Rev. , vol.1165 , pp. 1213
    • Michelman, F.I.1
  • 308
    • 70450244121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1229-1234
    • Id. at 1229-1234
  • 309
    • 84869666351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("Trying to determine when land use expectations are reasonable in state courts is an experience akin to a dog chasing its own tail.")
    • See Breemer, supra note 141, at 82 ("Trying to determine when land use expectations are reasonable in state courts is an experience akin to a dog chasing its own tail.");
    • Supra Note , vol.141 , pp. 82
    • Breemer1
  • 310
    • 84869666380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("[C]ourts provide very little explanation for their holdings as to when it is and is not reasonable for a property owner to expect that she will be subject to uncompensated regulation in the future.").
    • see also, e.g., Dana, supra note 40, at 661 ("[C]ourts provide very little explanation for their holdings as to when it is and is not reasonable for a property owner to expect that she will be subject to uncompensated regulation in the future.").
    • Supra Note , vol.40 , pp. 661
    • Dana1
  • 311
    • 84869679187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("All in all, we should be deeply suspicious of the phrase 'investment-backed expectations' because it is not possible to identify even the paradigmatic case of its use.")
    • See Epstein, supra note 151, at 1370 ("All in all, we should be deeply suspicious of the phrase 'investment-backed expectations' because it is not possible to identify even the paradigmatic case of its use.");
    • Supra Note , vol.151 , pp. 1370
    • Epstein1
  • 312
    • 84869675465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("[T]he meaning of the phrase remains uncertain, rendering its effectiveness as a legal doctrine questionable at best.")
    • Oswald, supra note 141, at 107 ("[T]he meaning of the phrase remains uncertain, rendering its effectiveness as a legal doctrine questionable at best.");
    • Supra Note , vol.141 , pp. 107
    • Oswald1
  • 313
    • 84869668583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (citing sources and describing investment-backed expectations as "certainly the least understood" Penn Central factor).
    • see also Breemer, supra note 141, at 81-82 & n.6 (citing sources and describing investment-backed expectations as "certainly the least understood" Penn Central factor).
    • Supra Note , vol.141 , Issue.6 , pp. 81-82
    • Breemer1
  • 314
    • 84869688980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("Over the past sixteen years, the Supreme Court has increasingly committed itself to a regulatory takings analysis that focuses extensively, if not exclusively, upon the economic effects of the regulation upon the property owner.")
    • See Oswald, supra note 141, at 130 ("Over the past sixteen years, the Supreme Court has increasingly committed itself to a regulatory takings analysis that focuses extensively, if not exclusively, upon the economic effects of the regulation upon the property owner.");
    • Supra Note , vol.141 , pp. 130
    • Oswald1
  • 315
    • 0000598755 scopus 로고
    • Takings, private property, and public rights
    • ("[T]he criterion for recognizing a particular economic injury which follows from government action as a taking is the extent of economic loss.").
    • Joseph L. Sax, Takings, Private Property, and Public Rights, 81 YALE L.J. 149, 151 (1971) ("[T]he criterion for recognizing a particular economic injury which follows from government action as a taking is the extent of economic loss.").
    • (1971) 81 Yale L.J. , vol.149 , pp. 151
    • Sax, J.L.1
  • 316
    • 84869682249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Mayhew v. Town of Sunnyvale, 964 S.W.2d 922, 935 (Tex. 1998) (identifying focus of Penn Central as "the extent to which the regulation has interfered with distinct investment-backed expectations")
    • But see Mayhew v. Town of Sunnyvale, 964 S.W.2d 922, 935 (Tex. 1998) (identifying focus of Penn Central as "the extent to which the regulation has interfered with distinct investment-backed expectations");
  • 317
    • 84869683106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("[A]t least in the minds of some courts, 'investmentbacked expectations' would crowd out the other prongs of the three-factor test.").
    • Eagle, supra note 140, at 561 ("[A]t least in the minds of some courts, 'investmentbacked expectations' would crowd out the other prongs of the three-factor test.").
    • Supra Note , vol.140 , pp. 561
    • Eagle1
  • 318
    • 84869675510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (surveying cases and finding that "diminution in value must substantially exceed 50%, and should be closer to 90%, before any serious consideration is given of a taking").
    • What counts as too much has been a source of constant controversy, but the percentage diminution required appears to be quite high. Cordes, supra note 132, at 39 (surveying cases and finding that "diminution in value must substantially exceed 50%, and should be closer to 90%, before any serious consideration is given of a taking").
    • Supra Note , vol.132
    • Cordes1
  • 319
    • 70450234291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Before the regulation, the first lot might have been worth $1,000,000 and the second lot worth $250,000 (reflecting the absence of a building). After the regulation, they are both worth the same amount, say $ 50,000 (excepting the transition costs of removing the existing building, which this stylized hypothetical excludes, but which are considered in detail below). The diminution in value of the first lot is 95% and of the second is only 80%. Perversely, however, a regulation that has a fixed economic impact is more likely to be a taking when applied to undeveloped property because the denominator will be smaller; a regulation imposing a $50,000 loss may be a taking of property worth $60,000, but is unlikely to be a taking of property worth $200,000.
  • 320
    • 84869682446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Penn Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104, 130-131 (1978) ("In deciding whether a particular governmental action has effected a taking, this Court focuses [on] the parcel as a whole .").
    • See Penn Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104, 130-131 (1978) ("In deciding whether a particular governmental action has effected a taking, this Court focuses [on] the parcel as a whole .").
  • 321
    • 0005298486 scopus 로고
    • The liberal conception of property: cross currents in the jurisprudence of takings
    • ("This strategy I shall call 'conceptual severance.' It consists of delineating a property interest consisting of just what the government action has removed from the owner, and then asserting that that particular whole thing has been permanently taken.")
    • For a discussion of conceptual severance, see Margaret Jane Radin, The Liberal Conception of Property: Cross Currents in the Jurisprudence of Takings, 88 COLUM. L. REV. 1667, 1676 (1988) ("This strategy I shall call 'conceptual severance.' It consists of delineating a property interest consisting of just what the government action has removed from the owner, and then asserting that that particular whole thing has been permanently taken.");
    • (1988) 88 Colum. L. Rev. , vol.1667 , pp. 1676
    • Radin, M.J.1
  • 322
    • 0038172267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The global fifth amendment? NAFTA's investment protections and the misguided quest for an international "Regulatory Takings" Doctrine
    • (discussing Radin, supra).
    • see also Vicki Been & Joel C. Beauvais, The Global Fifth Amendment? NAFTA's Investment Protections and the Misguided Quest for an International "Regulatory Takings" Doctrine, 78 N.Y.U. L. REV. 30, 64 (2003) (discussing Radin, supra).
    • (2003) 78 N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.30 , pp. 64
    • Been, V.1    Beauvais, J.C.2
  • 323
    • 70450226179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michelman's article, usually cited for his proposed utilitarian formulation of takings liability, remains the single most influential article on the Takings Clause. A number of people have observed that it provided the blueprint for Penn Central.
    • Michelman, supra note 154, at 1233. Michelman's article, usually cited for his proposed utilitarian formulation of takings liability, remains the single most influential article on the Takings Clause. A number of people have observed that it provided the blueprint for Penn Central.
    • Supra Note , vol.154 , pp. 1233
    • Michelman1
  • 324
    • 84869671277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("Michelman's analysis clearly influenced Justice Brennan as he wrote the majority opinion in Penn Central.")
    • See Oswald, supra note 141, at 104 ("Michelman's analysis clearly influenced Justice Brennan as he wrote the majority opinion in Penn Central.");
    • Supra Note , vol.141 , pp. 104
    • Oswald1
  • 325
    • 84869675575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (describing Penn Central test as "created under the salutary
    • Radin, supra note 161, at 1684 (describing Penn Central test as "created under the salutary influence of Frank Michelman's famous article");
    • Supra Note , vol.161 , pp. 1684
    • Radin1
  • 326
    • 84869684636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The effect of palazzolo v. rhode island on the role of reasonable investment-backed expectations
    • in TAKING SIDES ON TAKINGS ISSUES: PUBLIC AND PRIVATE PERSPECTIVES, ("The Court relied heavily on Professor Frank Michelman's influential 1967 essay ⋯").
    • Gregory M. Stein, The Effect of Palazzolo v. Rhode Island on the Role of Reasonable Investment-Backed Expectations, in TAKING SIDES ON TAKINGS ISSUES: PUBLIC AND PRIVATE PERSPECTIVES, supra note 36, at 41-42 ("The Court relied heavily on Professor Frank Michelman's influential 1967 essay ⋯").
    • Supra Note , vol.36 , pp. 41-42
    • Stein, G.M.1
  • 327
    • 84869671949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Giovanella v. Conservation Comm'n of Ashland, 857 N.E.2d 451, 456 (Mass. 2006) ("When a court considers a large piece of land of which only a small portion has lost value due to regulation, it is less likely to conclude that a taking has occurred. If a court considers a smaller parcel of land, most of which has been affected by a regulation, then the economic impact is more likely to appear large enough to constitute a taking.")
    • See Giovanella v. Conservation Comm'n of Ashland, 857 N.E.2d 451, 456 (Mass. 2006) ("When a court considers a large piece of land of which only a small portion has lost value due to regulation, it is less likely to conclude that a taking has occurred. If a court considers a smaller parcel of land, most of which has been affected by a regulation, then the economic impact is more likely to appear large enough to constitute a taking.");
  • 328
    • 84869682441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also City of Coeur d'Alene v. Simpson, 136 P.3d 310, 319 (Idaho 2006) ("Courts typically reject the so-called 'conceptual severance' theory-the notion that whole units of property may be divided for the purpose of a takings claim.")
    • see also City of Coeur d'Alene v. Simpson, 136 P.3d 310, 319 (Idaho 2006) ("Courts typically reject the so-called 'conceptual severance' theory-the notion that whole units of property may be divided for the purpose of a takings claim.");
  • 329
    • 84869671950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Smith v. Town of Mendon, 822 N.E.2d 1214, 1220 n.12 (N.Y. 2004) (evaluating "effect of the government action on the value of the property as a whole, rather than ... its effect on discrete segments of the property")
    • Smith v. Town of Mendon, 822 N.E.2d 1214, 1220 n.12 (N.Y. 2004) (evaluating "effect of the government action on the value of the property as a whole, rather than ... its effect on discrete segments of the property");
  • 330
    • 84869682442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Machipongo Land & Coal Co. v. Commonwealth, 799 A.2d 751, 768 (Pa. 2002) (applying Penn Central's mandate to consider the "parcel as a whole").
    • Machipongo Land & Coal Co. v. Commonwealth, 799 A.2d 751, 768 (Pa. 2002) (applying Penn Central's mandate to consider the "parcel as a whole").
  • 331
    • 84869665213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. (focusing on "parcel as a whole")
    • See Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 131 (focusing on "parcel as a whole");
    • Penn Central , vol.438 , pp. 131
  • 332
    • 70450279558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also TahoeSierra Pres. Council, Inc. v. Tahoe Reg'l Planning Agency, 535 U.S. 302, 331 (2002) (rejecting temporal division of property)
    • see also TahoeSierra Pres. Council, Inc. v. Tahoe Reg'l Planning Agency, 535 U.S. 302, 331 (2002) (rejecting temporal division of property);
  • 333
    • 84869671945 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrus v. Allard, 444 U.S. 51, 65-66 (1979) ("At least where an owner possesses a full 'bundle' of property rights, the destruction of one 'strand' of the bundle is not a taking, because the aggregate must be viewed in its entirety.").
    • Andrus v. Allard, 444 U.S. 51, 65-66 (1979) ("At least where an owner possesses a full 'bundle' of property rights, the destruction of one 'strand' of the bundle is not a taking, because the aggregate must be viewed in its entirety.").
  • 334
    • 0036702595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Public use" and the original understanding of the socalled "Takings" Clause
    • ("[T]he idea that courts had the power to supervise legislative expropriations would have been unfamiliar to the members of the Congress who drafted the so-called Takings Clause.")
    • See Matthew P. Harrington, "Public Use" and the Original Understanding of the SoCalled "Takings" Clause,53 HASTINGS L.J.1245, 1247 (2002) ("[T]he idea that courts had the power to supervise legislative expropriations would have been unfamiliar to the members of the Congress who drafted the so-called Takings Clause.")
    • (2002) 53 Hastings L.J. , vol.1245 , pp. 1247
    • Harrington, M.P.1
  • 335
    • 84869682434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1057 n.23 (1992) ("James Madison, author of the Takings Clause, apparently intended it to apply only to direct, physical takings of property by the Federal Government"
    • see also Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1057 n.23 (1992) ("James Madison, author of the Takings Clause, apparently intended it to apply only to direct, physical takings of property by the Federal Government"
  • 336
    • 70450264179 scopus 로고
    • Note, the origins and original significance of the just compensation clause of the fifth amendment
    • (citing William Michael Treanor, Note, The Origins and Original Significance of the Just Compensation Clause of the Fifth Amendment, 94 YALE L.J. 694, 711 (1985))).
    • (1985) 94 Yale L.J. , vol.694 , pp. 711
    • Treanor, W.M.1
  • 337
    • 84869689745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "No taking without a touching?" Questions from an armchair originalist
    • (questioning historical accounts of Takings Clause).
    • But see Nicole Stelle Garnett, "No Taking Without a Touching?" Questions from an Armchair Originalist, 45 SAN DIEGO L. REV. 761, 762-764 (2008) (questioning historical accounts of Takings Clause).
    • (2008) 45 San Diego L. Rev. , vol.761 , pp. 762-764
    • Garnett, N.S.1
  • 338
    • 22744444519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The federalist dimension of regulatory takings jurisprudence
    • ("In addition to the Takings Clause, the [New York Court of Appeals] has also invoked substantive due process to protect landowners from actions by local zoning authorities.")
    • See Stewart E. Sterk, The Federalist Dimension of Regulatory Takings Jurisprudence, 114 YALE L.J. 203, 267 n.292 (2004) ("In addition to the Takings Clause, the [New York Court of Appeals] has also invoked substantive due process to protect landowners from actions by local zoning authorities.");
    • (2004) 114 Yale L.J. , vol.203 , Issue.292 , pp. 267
    • Sterk, S.E.1
  • 339
    • 84869676192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional protections of private property: Decoupling the takings and due process clauses
    • ("The Due Process Clauses provide protections against unfair laws, both those that take property as well as those that merely regulate it. The Due Process Clause, not the Takings Clause, protects citizens from state laws that are overbroad, arbitrary, insufficiently justified, or unfair.")
    • Mark Tunick, Constitutional Protections of Private Property: Decoupling the Takings and Due Process Clauses, 3 U. PA. J. CONSI. L. 885, 899 (2001) ("The Due Process Clauses provide protections against unfair laws, both those that take property as well as those that merely regulate it. The Due Process Clause, not the Takings Clause, protects citizens from state laws that are overbroad, arbitrary, insufficiently justified, or unfair.");
    • (2001) 3 U. Pa. J. Consi. L. , vol.885 , pp. 899
    • Tunick, M.1
  • 340
    • 0036011969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comment, land development, the graham doctrine, and the extinction of economic substantive due process
    • (noting in land use context alone "federal courts have allowed economic substantive due process ... to escape extinction (and in some instances even to flourish)")
    • Robert Ashbrook, Comment, Land Development, the Graham Doctrine, and the Extinction of Economic Substantive Due Process, 150 U. PA. L. REV. 1255, 1257 (2002) (noting in land use context alone "federal courts have allowed economic substantive due process ... to escape extinction (and in some instances even to flourish)");
    • (2002) 150 U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.1255 , pp. 1257
    • Ashbrook, R.1
  • 341
    • 84994195023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Winding toward the heart of the takings muddle: kelo, lingle, and public discourse about private property
    • (describing posl-Lingle "sequencing between the analyses under the two clauses, with substantive due process questions to be raised first and, assuming the statute in question withstands due process scrutiny (a safe assumption for economic regulation), takings scrutiny to follow").
    • see also Jane B. Baron, Winding Toward the Heart of the Takings Muddle: Kelo, Lingle, and Public Discourse About Private Property, 34 FORDHAM URB. L.J. 613, 640 (2007) (describing posl-Lingle "sequencing between the analyses under the two clauses, with substantive due process questions to be raised first and, assuming the statute in question withstands due process scrutiny (a safe assumption for economic regulation), takings scrutiny to follow").
    • (2007) 34 Fordham Urb. L.J. , vol.613 , pp. 640
    • Baron, J.B.1
  • 342
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (arguing for more frequent use of substantive due process analysis because of inadequacy of takings law).
    • See generally Mandelker, supra note 120 (arguing for more frequent use of substantive due process analysis because of inadequacy of takings law).
    • Supra Note , vol.120
    • Mandelker1
  • 343
    • 70450234288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 198 U.S. 45 (1905).
    • 198 U.S. 45 (1905).
  • 344
    • 33846063735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust and the supremacy clause
    • ("Judges across the ideological spectrum now try to outdo each other in denouncing Lochner, marking a broad consensus that principles whereby courts use federal law to cut down state economic regulation should not originate in the judicial branch.")
    • See Richard Squire, Antitrust and the Supremacy Clause, 59 STAN. L. REV. 77, 104 (2006) ("Judges across the ideological spectrum now try to outdo each other in denouncing Lochner, marking a broad consensus that principles whereby courts use federal law to cut down state economic regulation should not originate in the judicial branch.");
    • (2006) 59 Stan. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 104
    • Squire, R.1
  • 345
    • 84869669594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("Since the demise of Lochner, the Court has been reluctant to strike down economic legislation on due process grounds.").
    • Tunick, supra note 166, at 899 n.59 ("Since the demise of Lochner, the Court has been reluctant to strike down economic legislation on due process grounds.").
    • Supra Note , vol.166 , Issue.59 , pp. 899
    • Tunick1
  • 346
    • 84869682237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ferguson v. Skrupa, 372 U.S. 726, 729-731 (1963) ("It is now settled that States have power to legislate against what are found to be injurious practices in their internal commercial and business affairs, so long as their laws do not run afoul of some specific federal constitutional prohibition, or of some valid federal law." (internal quotation marks and citations omitted)).
    • See, e.g., Ferguson v. Skrupa, 372 U.S. 726, 729-731 (1963) ("It is now settled that States have power to legislate against what are found to be injurious practices in their internal commercial and business affairs, so long as their laws do not run afoul of some specific federal constitutional prohibition, or of some valid federal law." (internal quotation marks and citations omitted)).
  • 347
    • 70450235947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Marks v. City of Chesapeake, 883 F.2d 308, 313 (4th Cir. 1989) (holding that withholding permit for palm reading business is arbitrary and capricious and violates due process)
    • See, e.g., Marks v. City of Chesapeake, 883 F.2d 308, 313 (4th Cir. 1989) (holding that withholding permit for palm reading business is arbitrary and capricious and violates due process);
  • 348
    • 70450231601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sullivan v. Town of Salem, 805 F.2d 81, 85 (2d Cir. 1986) (holding that prohibiting occupancy of new home that meets building code violates due process)
    • Sullivan v. Town of Salem, 805 F.2d 81, 85 (2d Cir. 1986) (holding that prohibiting occupancy of new home that meets building code violates due process);
  • 349
    • 70450259396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Slow Return of Economic Substantive Due Process
    • (citing land use decisions)
    • see also Michael J. Phillips, The Slow Return of Economic Substantive Due Process, 49 SYRACUSE L. REV. 917, 927-36 (1999) (citing land use decisions);
    • (1999) 49 Syracuse L. Rev. , vol.917 , pp. 927-936
    • Phillips, M.J.1
  • 350
    • 84869677319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The new "Judicial federalism " before its time: A comprehensive review of economic substantive due process under state constitutional law since 1940 and the reasons for its recent decline
    • ("Instead of a deferential rational basis test, where the regulation at issue is heavily presumed to be constitutional, courts often apply a mere 'clear and convincing evidence' presumption when deciding land use zoning cases.").
    • Anthony B. Sanders, The New "Judicial Federalism " Before Its Time: A Comprehensive Review of Economic Substantive Due Process Under State Constitutional Law Since 1940 and the Reasons for Its Recent Decline, 55 AM. U. L. REV. 457, 469 (2005) ("Instead of a deferential rational basis test, where the regulation at issue is heavily presumed to be constitutional, courts often apply a mere 'clear and convincing evidence' presumption when deciding land use zoning cases.").
    • (2005) 55 Am. U. L. Rev. , vol.457 , pp. 469
    • Sanders, A.B.1
  • 351
    • 84869682431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lingle v. Chevron, 544 U.S. 528, 542 (2005) ("[A] regulation that fails to serve any legitimate governmental objective may be so arbitrary or irrational that it runs afoul of the Due Process Clause."). Other courts have made similar statements.
    • Lingle v. Chevron, 544 U.S. 528, 542 (2005) ("[A] regulation that fails to serve any legitimate governmental objective may be so arbitrary or irrational that it runs afoul of the Due Process Clause."). Other courts have made similar statements.
  • 352
    • 84869671941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., DeBlasio v. Zoning Bd. of Adjustment, 53 F.3d 592, 593 (3d Cir. 1995) ("[I]n the context of land use regulation, a property owner states a substantive due process claim where he or she alleges that the decision limiting the intended land use was arbitrarily or irrationally reached."). For further discussion of Lingle
    • See, e.g., DeBlasio v. Zoning Bd. of Adjustment, 53 F.3d 592, 593 (3d Cir. 1995) ("[I]n the context of land use regulation, a property owner states a substantive due process claim where he or she alleges that the decision limiting the intended land use was arbitrarily or irrationally reached."). For further discussion of Lingle,
  • 353
    • 31444445485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and accompanying text.
    • see infra notes 192-194 and accompanying text.
    • Infra Notes , pp. 192-194
  • 354
    • 70450270656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. (describing means-ends test).
    • See, e.g., Lingle, 544 U.S. at 541 (describing means-ends test).
    • Lingle , vol.544 , pp. 541
  • 355
    • 84869678025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("The precise legal standard varies by circuit. The District of Columbia Circuit merely requires a showing of 'grave unfairness.' More commonly, however, courts require some variation on arbitrariness and/or capriciousness." (footnotes omitted)).
    • See, e.g., Ashbrook, supra note 166, at 1260-1261 ("The precise legal standard varies by circuit. The District of Columbia Circuit merely requires a showing of 'grave unfairness.' More commonly, however, courts require some variation on arbitrariness and/or capriciousness." (footnotes omitted)).
    • Supra Note , vol.166 , pp. 1260-1261
    • Ashbrook1
  • 356
    • 33750503574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Intergovernmental liability rules
    • ("Courts deem [land use regulations] to be presumptively valid, and place the burden of proof on those making sustantive due process claims to show that the regulation is arbitrary and unreasonable.").
    • See, e.g., Amnon Lehavi, Intergovernmental Liability Rules, 92 VA. L. REV. 929, 937 (2006) ("Courts deem [land use regulations] to be presumptively valid, and place the burden of proof on those making sustantive due process claims to show that the regulation is arbitrary and unreasonable.").
    • (2006) 92 Va. L. Rev. , vol.929 , pp. 937
    • Lehavi, A.1
  • 357
    • 70450253163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Eger v. Levine, 545 N.Y.S.2d 618, 619 (App. Div. 1989) (finding denial of use variance to be irrational where use predated effective date of zoning ordinance). For an example of a court rejecting a due process challenge to a regulation eliminating an existing use
    • See, e.g., Eger v. Levine, 545 N.Y.S.2d 618, 619 (App. Div. 1989) (finding denial of use variance to be irrational where use predated effective date of zoning ordinance). For an example of a court rejecting a due process challenge to a regulation eliminating an existing use,
  • 358
    • 70450239583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Hartland Sportsman's Club, Inc. v. Town of Delafield, 35 F.3d 1198 (7th Cir. 1994).
    • see Hartland Sportsman's Club, Inc. v. Town of Delafield, 35 F.3d 1198 (7th Cir. 1994).
  • 359
    • 70450249236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and accompanying text (noting that original justification of zoning was to separate incompatible uses of property).
    • See supra note 8 and accompanying text (noting that original justification of zoning was to separate incompatible uses of property).
    • Supra Note , vol.8
  • 360
    • 70450285161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a fascinating and thoroughgoing analysis of this history, see Karkkainen, supra note 100, at 838-851
    • Supra Note , vol.100 , pp. 838-851
    • Karkkainen1
  • 361
    • 84869671937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Lincoln Trust Co. v. Williams Bldg. Corp., 128 N.E. 209, 210 (N.Y. 1920) ("In a great metropolis like New York, in which the public health, welfare, convenience, and common good are to be considered, I am of the opinion that the resolution was not an incumbrance, since, it was a proper exercise of the police power. The exercise of such power, within constitutional limitations, depends largely upon the discretion and good judgment of the municipal authorities ⋯ .");
    • See, e.g., Lincoln Trust Co. v. Williams Bldg. Corp., 128 N.E. 209, 210 (N.Y. 1920) ("In a great metropolis like New York, in which the public health, welfare, convenience, and common good are to be considered, I am of the opinion that the resolution was not an incumbrance, since, it was a proper exercise of the police power. The exercise of such power, within constitutional limitations, depends largely upon the discretion and good judgment of the municipal authorities ⋯ .");
  • 362
    • 70450261355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (describing relationship between police power and public use)
    • see also Merrill, supra note 124, at 69-70 (describing relationship between police power and public use);
    • Supra Note , vol.124 , pp. 69-70
    • Merrill1
  • 363
    • 84869667715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("The constitutional limitations upon eminent domain, such as the requirement that compensation be paid, have no relevance where an ordinance is an exercise of the police power.").
    • cf. Bettman, supra note 49, at 835 ("The constitutional limitations upon eminent domain, such as the requirement that compensation be paid, have no relevance where an ordinance is an exercise of the police power.").
    • Supra Note , vol.49 , pp. 835
    • Bettman1
  • 364
    • 70450235074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("Thus a legitimate exercise of the police power could never give rise to a compensable taking ." (footnote omitted)).
    • See Karkkainen, supra note 100, at 841 ("Thus a legitimate exercise of the police power could never give rise to a compensable taking ." (footnote omitted)).
    • Supra Note , vol.100 , pp. 841
    • Karkkainen1
  • 365
    • 84869666487 scopus 로고
    • In re opinion of the justices
    • Mass. ("An ordinance or by-law which segregates manufacturing and commercial buildings on the one side, from homes and residences on the other, is justified by the broad conceptions of the police power .").
    • See, e.g., In re Opinion of the Justices, 127 N.E. 525, 527 (Mass. 1920) ("An ordinance or by-law which segregates manufacturing and commercial buildings on the one side, from homes and residences on the other, is justified by the broad conceptions of the police power .").
    • (1920) 127 N.E. , vol.525 , pp. 527
  • 366
    • 84869682232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., City of Tucson v. Ariz. Mortuary, 272 P. 923, 927 (Ariz. 1928) (referring to Euclid and noting that ordinance is unconstitutional if it is "clearly arbitrary and unreasonable, and has not any substantial relation to the public health, safety, morals, or general welfare")
    • See, e.g., City of Tucson v. Ariz. Mortuary, 272 P. 923, 927 (Ariz. 1928) (referring to Euclid and noting that ordinance is unconstitutional if it is "clearly arbitrary and unreasonable, and has not any substantial relation to the public health, safety, morals, or general welfare");
  • 367
    • 84869682225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Longley v. Rumsey, 224 N.Y.S. 165, 167 (Sup. Ct. 1927) (holding zoning ordinance invalid because of its failure to act in accordance with comprehensive plan and "because of the arbitrary method by which the character of the so-called districts is determined")
    • Longley v. Rumsey, 224 N.Y.S. 165, 167 (Sup. Ct. 1927) (holding zoning ordinance invalid because of its failure to act in accordance with comprehensive plan and "because of the arbitrary method by which the character of the so-called districts is determined");
  • 368
    • 84869664880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Luse v. City of Dallas, 131 S.W.2d 1079, 1084 (Tex. Civ. App. 1939) (holding that, to be unconstitutional and therefore void, "[an] ordinance . must itself be clearly arbitrary, unreasonable and without any substantial relation to the public health, safety, morals, or general welfare")
    • Luse v. City of Dallas, 131 S.W.2d 1079, 1084 (Tex. Civ. App. 1939) (holding that, to be unconstitutional and therefore void, "[an] ordinance . must itself be clearly arbitrary, unreasonable and without any substantial relation to the public health, safety, morals, or general welfare");
  • 369
    • 84869671936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geisenfeld v. Vill. of Shorewood, 287 N.W. 683, 686 (Wis. 1939) (declaring ordinance "unconstitutional and void because 'clearly arbitrary and unreasonable, having no substantial relation to the public health, safety, morals, or general welfare'" (quoting Vill. of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365, 395 (1926))).
    • Geisenfeld v. Vill. of Shorewood, 287 N.W. 683, 686 (Wis. 1939) (declaring ordinance "unconstitutional and void because 'clearly arbitrary and unreasonable, having no substantial relation to the public health, safety, morals, or general welfare'" (quoting Vill. of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365, 395 (1926))).
  • 370
    • 84869664543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("[I]n actual practice in constitutional cases, 'reasonable' often signifies little more than that ... the balance of considerations of private and public interests has been fairly maintained.").
    • See Bettman, supra note 49, at 836 ("[I]n actual practice in constitutional cases, 'reasonable' often signifies little more than that ... the balance of considerations of private and public interests has been fairly maintained.").
    • Supra Note , vol.49 , pp. 836
    • Bettman1
  • 371
    • 70450235074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (defining content of due process review).
    • See Karkkainen, supra note 100, at 841-842 (defining content of due process review).
    • Supra Note , vol.100 , pp. 841-842
    • Karkkainen1
  • 372
    • 70450250073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and accompanying text.
    • See supra note 99 and accompanying text.
    • Supra Note , vol.99
  • 373
    • 70450231264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Penn Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104 (1978).
    • Penn Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104 (1978).
  • 374
    • 70450243577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The three-part ad hoc balancing test focuses on the diminution in value, the extent of interference with investment-backed expectations, and the character of the regulation. Id. at 124.
    • The three-part ad hoc balancing test focuses on the diminution in value, the extent of interference with investment-backed expectations, and the character of the regulation. Id. at 124.
  • 375
    • 70450229333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 447 U.S. 255 (1980), overruled in part by Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A. Inc., 544 U.S. 528, 540 (2005).
    • 447 U.S. 255 (1980), overruled in part by Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A. Inc., 544 U.S. 528, 540 (2005).
  • 376
    • 70450286864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 260 (citation omitted).
    • Id. at 260 (citation omitted).
  • 377
    • 84869676183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (arguing that "[c]onflation of substantive due process and Takings Clause doctrine muddled the 'takings' issue in multiple ways" and pointing to Agins as point of departure from proper takings jurisprudence)
    • See Karkkainen, supra note 100, at 883 (arguing that "[c]onflation of substantive due process and Takings Clause doctrine muddled the 'takings' issue in multiple ways" and pointing to Agins as point of departure from proper takings jurisprudence);
    • Supra Note , vol.100 , pp. 883
    • Karkkainen1
  • 378
    • 84869684049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The status of Nollan v. California coastal commission and Dolan v. City of Tigard after Lingle v. Chevron
    • ("[T]he Agins test is essentially a substantive due process inquiry⋯ .");
    • see also David L. Callies & Christopher T. Goodin, The Status of Nollan v. California Coastal Commission and Dolan v. City of Tigard After Lingle v. Chevron, 40 J. MARSHALL L. REV. 539, 557 (2007) ("[T]he Agins test is essentially a substantive due process inquiry⋯ .");
    • (2007) 40 J. Marshall L. Rev. , vol.539 , pp. 557
    • Callies, D.L.1    Goodin, C.T.2
  • 379
    • 33747709375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lingle's legacy: Untangling substantive due process from takings doctrine
    • (noting Supreme Court's reliance, in Agins, on "seminal due process cases")
    • Robert G. Dreher, Lingle's Legacy: Untangling Substantive Due Process from Takings Doctrine, 30 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 371, 372 (2006) (noting Supreme Court's reliance, in Agins, on "seminal due process cases");
    • (2006) 30 Harv. Envtl. L. Rev. , vol.371 , pp. 372
    • Dreher, R.G.1
  • 380
    • 84869671002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("[T]he Agins 'substantial advancement' test ⋯. mistook a substantive due process test for a takings test .").
    • Fenster, supra note 84, at 735 ("[T]he Agins 'substantial advancement' test ⋯. mistook a substantive due process test for a takings test .").
    • Supra Note , vol.84 , pp. 735
    • Fenster1
  • 381
    • 42649117758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The problem of equality in takings
    • (suggesting that Agins "substantially advances" language "formed the rhetorical basis for the suggestion in Nollan that Takings Clause-based review of the impact of regulation on property rights should be undertaken through some form of heightened scrutiny")
    • See Nestor M. Davidson, The Problem of Equality in Takings, 102 Nw. U. L. REV. 1, 16 (2008) (suggesting that Agins "substantially advances" language "formed the rhetorical basis for the suggestion in Nollan that Takings Clause-based review of the impact of regulation on property rights should be undertaken through some form of heightened scrutiny");
    • (2008) 102 Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.1 , pp. 16
    • Davidson, N.M.1
  • 382
    • 84869680680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (noting "errant language in Agins that imported Lochner-slyle heightened substantive due process review into modern takings law").
    • Karkkainen, supra note 100, at 828 (noting "errant language in Agins that imported Lochner-slyle heightened substantive due process review into modern takings law").
    • Supra Note , vol.100 , pp. 828
    • Karkkainen1
  • 383
    • 70450263328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a very good history of the relationship between takings law and substantive due process, see Dreher, supra note 189, at 373-387
    • Supra Note , vol.189 , pp. 373-387
    • Dreher1
  • 384
    • 70450247809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 544 U.S. 528 (2005). For more in-depth discussion of the line of cases resulting in Lingle
    • 544 U.S. 528 (2005). For more in-depth discussion of the line of cases resulting in Lingle,
  • 385
    • 70450256524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the doctrinal confusion that existed prior to Lingle
    • see generally Fenster, supra note 84. For a discussion of the doctrinal confusion that existed prior to Lingle,
    • Supra Note , vol.84
    • Fenster1
  • 386
    • 1842583483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LandUse litigation: Doctrinal confusion under the fifth and fourteenth amendments
    • see generally, for example, Thomas E. Roberts et al., LandUse Litigation: Doctrinal Confusion Under the Fifth and Fourteenth Amendments, 28 URB. LAW. 765 (1996).
    • (1996) 28 Urb. Law. , vol.765
    • Roberts, T.E.1
  • 387
    • 84869682415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. ("[A] regulation that fails to serve any legitimate governmental objective may be so arbitrary or irrational that it runs afoul of the Due Process Clause.").
    • See Lingle, 544 U.S. at 542 ("[A] regulation that fails to serve any legitimate governmental objective may be so arbitrary or irrational that it runs afoul of the Due Process Clause.").
    • Lingle , vol.544
  • 388
    • 84869664874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 542 ("In stark contrast to the three regulatory takings tests discussed above, the 'substantially advances' inquiry reveals nothing about the magnitude or character of the burden a particular regulation imposes upon private property rights.").
    • See id. at 542 ("In stark contrast to the three regulatory takings tests discussed above, the 'substantially advances' inquiry reveals nothing about the magnitude or character of the burden a particular regulation imposes upon private property rights.").
  • 389
    • 84869671932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (rev. ed. 1969) ("[A] retroactive law is truly a monstrosity.")
    • See, e.g., LON L. FULLER, THE MORALITY OF LAW 53 (rev. ed. 1969) ("[A] retroactive law is truly a monstrosity.");
    • The Morality of Law , vol.53
    • Fuller, L.L.1
  • 390
    • 70450235943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (arguing that retroactive legislation fails to give notice and therefore undermines free will and reliance necessary for social order)
    • DANIEL E. TROY, RETROACTIVE LEGISLATION 17-19 (1998) (arguing that retroactive legislation fails to give notice and therefore undermines free will and reliance necessary for social order);
    • (1998) Retroactive Legislation , vol.17 , pp. 19
    • Troy, D.E.1
  • 391
    • 0006671891 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Temporal limits on the legislative mandate: entrenchment and retroactivity
    • (referring to common assumption that "retroactive exercises of legislative power are incompatible with any fair and just system of government").
    • Julian N. Eule, Temporal Limits on the Legislative Mandate: Entrenchment and Retroactivity, 1987 AM. B. FOUND. RES. J. 379, 427 (referring to common assumption that "retroactive exercises of legislative power are incompatible with any fair and just system of government").
    • 1987 Am. B. Found. Res. J. , vol.379 , pp. 427
    • Eule, J.N.1
  • 392
    • 84869688913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("If every time a man relied on existing law in arranging his affairs, he were made secure against any change in legal rules, the whole body of our law would be ossified forever.").
    • See FULLER, supra note 195, at 60 ("If every time a man relied on existing law in arranging his affairs, he were made secure against any change in legal rules, the whole body of our law would be ossified forever.").
    • Supra Note , vol.195 , pp. 60
    • Fuller1
  • 393
    • 70450231602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (internal quotation marks omitted).
    • TROY, supra note 195, at 3 (internal quotation marks omitted).
    • Supra Note , vol.195 , pp. 3
    • Troy1
  • 394
    • 84869669140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §10, cl. 1 ("No State shall.⋯ pass any ⋯ Law impairing the Obligation of Contracts ."). Substantive due process analysis replaced an early natural rights treatment of retroactive legislation.
    • There are a variety of constitutional sources of antiretroactivity rules that apply to private law. The Contracts Clause prevents state government from interfering with existing contract rights (although often anemically). U.S. CONSI. art. I, §10, cl. 1 ("No State shall.⋯ pass any ⋯ Law impairing the Obligation of Contracts ."). Substantive due process analysis replaced an early natural rights treatment of retroactive legislation.
    • U.S. Consi. Art. I
  • 395
    • 84869687677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (noting that by 1880s, Supreme Court had begun using substantive due process "to implement many of its conceptions of natural justice"). Courts therefore reasoned that retroactive regulations, often described as those affecting vested rights, were unconstitutional under the Due Process Clause.
    • TROY, supra note 195, at 77 (noting that by 1880s, Supreme Court had begun using substantive due process "to implement many of its conceptions of natural justice"). Courts therefore reasoned that retroactive regulations, often described as those affecting vested rights, were unconstitutional under the Due Process Clause.
    • Supra Note , vol.195 , pp. 77
    • Troy1
  • 396
    • 70450238494 scopus 로고
    • See Comment, The Variable Quality of a Vested Right, summarizing due process cases and citing, inter alia
    • See Comment, The Variable Quality of a Vested Right, 34 YALE L.J. 303, 304 (1925) (summarizing due process cases and citing, inter alia,
    • (1925) 34 Yale L.J. , vol.303 , pp. 304
  • 397
    • 70450268243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Huffman v. Alderson's Adm'r, 9 W. Va. 616 (1876). In 1976, however, the Supreme Court refused to strike down an expressly retroactive law on due process grounds.
    • Huffman v. Alderson's Adm'r, 9 W. Va. 616 (1876)). In 1976, however, the Supreme Court refused to strike down an expressly retroactive law on due process grounds.
  • 398
    • 70450240389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Usery v. Turner Elkhorn Mining Co., 428 U.S. 1 (1976)
    • See Usery v. Turner Elkhorn Mining Co., 428 U.S. 1 (1976),
  • 399
    • 70450264176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 107 Nevertheless, substantive due process analysis still appears periodically in retroactivity analysis.
    • cited in TROY, supra note 195, at 38, 107 n.84. Nevertheless, substantive due process analysis still appears periodically in retroactivity analysis.
    • Supra Note , vol.195 , Issue.84 , pp. 38
    • Troy1
  • 400
    • 70450271531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, in Eastern Enters, v. Apfel, 524 U.S. 498 (1998), a plurality of the Supreme Court struck down a federal statute requiring coal com panies to fund retirement benefits for former coal miners. The Court could not agree on the constitutional analysis to apply. Four Justices believed the statute violated the Takings Clause. Id. at 522-38 (plurality opinion) (O'Connor, J., joined by Rehnquist, C.J., and Scalia and Thomas, JJ.). Justice Thomas suggested it also might violate the Ex Post Facto Clause. Id. at 538-39 (Thomas, J., concurring). Justice Kennedy believed the statute was unconstitutional but applied a due process analysis to reach his result. Id. at 547-50 (Kennedy, J., concurring in judgment and dissenting in part). The remaining four Justices voted to uphold the statute after applying the Due Process Clause. Id. at 556-58, 567-68 (Breyer, J., dissenting). Given the Supreme Court's fractured reasoning regarding retroactivity, it is perhaps not surprising that courts disagree about the source of the constitutional protection for existing uses. For a review of different constitutional prohibitions against retroactivity and their limitations, see Eule, supra note 195, at 427-34.
  • 401
    • 84925042474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Retroactivity and legal change: An equilibrium approach
    • 1067 see also Eule, supra note 195, at 435-36 (considering same example)
    • For example, if the government were to remove the home mortgage tax deduction it would have an enormous impact on the value of people's past investment decisions, even if the deduction were only repealed prospectively. Jill E. Fisch, Retroactivity and Legal Change: An Equilibrium Approach, 110 HARV. L. REV. 1055, 1067 (1997); see also Eule, supra note 195, at 435-36 (considering same example)
    • (1997) Harv. L. R , vol.110 , pp. 1055
    • Fisch, J.E.1
  • 402
    • 0345562962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax transitions, opportunistic retroactivity, and the benefits of government precommitment
    • Tax law provides a frequent source of discussion of retroactivity. See generally Kyle D. Logue, Tax Transitions, Opportunistic Retroactivity, and the Benefits of Government Precommitment, 94 MICH. L. REV. 1129 (1996) (arguing for transition relief in certain tax situations).
    • (1996) Mich. L. Rev , vol.94 , pp. 1129
    • Logue, K.D.1
  • 403
    • 77955528383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Takings and transitions
    • Fisch, supra note 199, at 1067-69; see SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 26 (identifying retroactive effect of "nominally prospective" changes); TROY, supra note 195, at 2 ("[A]lmost all legislation may be characterized as 'retroactive' [because] the operation of almost all legislation depends on antecedent facts."); see also FILLER, supra note 195, at 59-61 (discussing "the most difficult problem of all, that of knowing when an enactment should properly be regarded as retrospective"). This identification problem is particularly serious for land use regulations, because the land itself always preexists the regulation. L. 1
    • Fisch, supra note 199, at 1067-69; see SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 26 (identifying retroactive effect of "nominally prospective" changes); TROY, supra note 195, at 2 ("[A]lmost all legislation may be characterized as 'retroactive' [because] the operation of almost all legislation depends on antecedent facts."); see also FILLER, supra note 195, at 59-61 (discussing "the most difficult problem of all, that of knowing when an enactment should properly be regarded as retrospective"). This identification problem is particularly serious for land use regulations, because the land itself always preexists the regulation. See Holly Doremus, Takings and Transitions, 19 J. LAND USE & ENVTL. L. 1, 11-12 (2003) (arguing that "new property rules can never be wholly forward-looking," because while "they can be applied only to new activities, they can never be applied to new land").
    • (2003) J. Land Use & Envtl , vol.19 , pp. 11-12
    • Doremus, H.1
  • 404
    • 84869682213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fisch, supra note 199, at 1070 (explaining that describing "retroactivity as a spectrum or range of temporal options rather than as a binary construct provides a better description of the nature and consequences of legal change"); see also Logue, supra note 199, at 1133 ("Transition losses can occur whether the new tax law or new interpretation applies nominally retroactively or nominally prospectively")
    • See Fisch, supra note 199, at 1070 (explaining that describing "retroactivity as a spectrum or range of temporal options rather than as a binary construct provides a better description of the nature and consequences of legal change"); see also Logue, supra note 199, at 1133 ("Transition losses can occur whether the new tax law or new interpretation applies nominally retroactively or nominally prospectively").
  • 405
    • 84925905951 scopus 로고
    • Retroactive law
    • 383
    • See, e.g., Stephen R. Munzer, Retroactive Law, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 373, 383 (1977) (explaining that retroactivity may be either strong or weak and that "the difference lies in how the impact of a retroactive law on earlier acts in the period prior to its creation is understood");
    • (1977) J. Legal Stud. , vol.6 , pp. 373
    • Munzer, S.R.1
  • 406
    • 70450264177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. TROY, supra note 195, at 8
    • cf. TROY, supra note 195, at 8 (describing Justice Scalia as distinguishing between primary and secondary retroactivity, which "roughly correlate" with strong and weak retroactivity);
  • 407
    • 70450232397 scopus 로고
    • Constitutional and legislative considerations in retroactive lawmaking
    • 216
    • W. David Slawson, Constitutional and Legislative Considerations in Retroactive Lawmaking, 48 CAL. L. REV. 216, 216 (1960) ("[Retroactive] is used both (1) to describe the particular basis of selection for the direct imposition of legal effects and (2) as a description of particular kinds of effects which may occur when a new law is imposed on society.").
    • (1960) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 216
    • Slawson, D.W.1
  • 408
    • 70450279554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Munzer, supra note 202, at 383
    • Munzer, supra note 202, at 383.
  • 409
    • 84869671928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fisch, supra note 199, at 1084 ("It is typically thought that prospective laws are more fair and that retroactive laws are more efficient.")
    • See Fisch, supra note 199, at 1084 ("It is typically thought that prospective laws are more fair and that retroactive laws are more efficient.");
  • 410
    • 70450252855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rational retroactivity in a commercial context
    • 794
    • David Frisch, Rational Retroactivity in a Commercial Context, 58 ALA. L. REV. 765, 794 (2007) ("Traditional normative criticism of retroactivity has rested on two related assertions: Fairness mandates giving people the opportunity to know in advance what laws will govern their affairs and prohibits changing the rules in midstream, and retroactive laws defeat the legitimate expectations of the persons affected." (internal footnotes omitted));
    • (2007) Ala. L. Rev , vol.58 , pp. 765
    • Frisch, D.1
  • 411
    • 84869664865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Landgraf v. USA Film Prods., 511 U.S. 244, 265 (1994) ("[T]he presumption against retroactive legislation ... embodies a legal doctrine centuries older than our Republic. Elementary considerations of fairness dictate that individuals should have an opportunity to know what the law is and to conform their conduct accordingly; settled expectations should not be lightly disrupted." (internal footnote omitted))
    • see also Landgraf v. USA Film Prods., 511 U.S. 244, 265 (1994) ("[T]he presumption against retroactive legislation ... embodies a legal doctrine centuries older than our Republic. Elementary considerations of fairness dictate that individuals should have an opportunity to know what the law is and to conform their conduct accordingly; settled expectations should not be lightly disrupted." (internal footnote omitted)).
  • 412
    • 70450234283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See TROY, supra note 195, at 18-19 (arguing that notice is fundamental to fairness, rule of law, and moral choice)
    • See TROY, supra note 195, at 18-19 (arguing that notice is fundamental to fairness, rule of law, and moral choice);
  • 413
    • 84869682216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Fisch, supra note 199, at 1085 ("Notice enables people to predict the consequences of their transactions and increases the influence of legal rules upon primary conduct.")
    • see also Fisch, supra note 199, at 1085 ("Notice enables people to predict the consequences of their transactions and increases the influence of legal rules upon primary conduct.").
  • 414
    • 84869682411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fisch, supra note 199, at 1088 ("The view that the new rule improves the operative legal principles supports the application of that rule to as broad a class of cases as possible.")
    • See Fisch, supra note 199, at 1088 ("The view that the new rule improves the operative legal principles supports the application of that rule to as broad a class of cases as possible.").
  • 415
    • 84869682202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1089 ("The objectives of a new legal rule may also be undercut if people are able to avoid its application by rushing to complete transactions prior to enactment."). This is a familiar application of moral hazard and is considered in more detail in Part IV. A, infra. See Baker, supra note 40, at 239 ('"[M]oral hazard' refers to the tendency for insurance against loss to reduce incentives to prevent or minimize the cost of loss.")
    • Id. at 1089 ("The objectives of a new legal rule may also be undercut if people are able to avoid its application by rushing to complete transactions prior to enactment."). This is a familiar application of moral hazard and is considered in more detail in Part IV. A, infra. See Baker, supra note 40, at 239 ('"[M]oral hazard' refers to the tendency for insurance against loss to reduce incentives to prevent or minimize the cost of loss.");
  • 416
    • 34548760340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Size matters: Regulating nanotechnology
    • 401
    • Albert C. Lin, Size Matters: Regulating Nanotechnology, 31 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 349, 401 (2007) (defining moral hazard as "the temptation to behave differently because of the existence of insurance or other incentives").
    • (2007) Harv. Envtl. L. Rev. , vol.31 , pp. 349
    • Lin, A.C.1
  • 417
    • 84869682212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV.A; see also Kaplow, supra note 9, at 529 ("[T]he encouragement resulting from the assurance that compensation or other protection will be provided in the event of change results in overinvestment.")
    • See infra Part IV.A; see also Kaplow, supra note 9, at 529 ("[T]he encouragement resulting from the assurance that compensation or other protection will be provided in the event of change results in overinvestment.").
  • 418
    • 84869682409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Doremus, supra note 200, at 14 ("Changing the rules after people have adjusted their conduct on the basis of those rules often seems unfair, because we generally think that people are entitled to, and indeed should, govern their behavior according to the existing rules."); Frisch, supra note 204, at 765-66 (describing intuition that "there is something fundamentally unfair about government altering the rules that govern past conduct")
    • See Doremus, supra note 200, at 14 ("Changing the rules after people have adjusted their conduct on the basis of those rules often seems unfair, because we generally think that people are entitled to, and indeed should, govern their behavior according to the existing rules."); Frisch, supra note 204, at 765-66 (describing intuition that "there is something fundamentally unfair about government altering the rules that govern past conduct");
  • 419
    • 70450259395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Foreword: The dual dichotomy of retroactive lawmaking
    • 19
    • Matthew P. Harrington, Foreword: The Dual Dichotomy of Retroactive Lawmaking, 3 ROGER WILLIAMS U. L. REV. 19, 19 (1997) ("On the face of it, there is something unsettling about the possibility that lawmakers might change the rules whilst the game is in progress."). In a leading article, Joseph Singer offered an entire reliance-based theory of property law.
    • (1997) Roger Williams U. L. Rev. , vol.3
    • Harrington, M.P.1
  • 420
    • 84866252860 scopus 로고
    • The reliance interest in property
    • See generally Joseph William Singer, The Reliance Interest in Property, 40 STAN. L. REV. 611 (1988). It may be important to ask whether theories of reliance actually have any place in property law, but that question is far beyond the scope of this project.
    • (1988) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 611
    • Singer, J.W.1
  • 421
    • 84869664862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Kupchak et al., supra note 115, at 24 ("[T]he policy underlying zoning estoppel is two-fold: hold the government to its commitments, and treat property owners who rely fairly."). Zoning estoppel can be applied to prevent the government from changing zoning regulations on which a property owner has reasonably relied, but only if the government has given assurances that the zoning will not change. Id
    • See, e.g., Kupchak et al., supra note 115, at 24 ("[T]he policy underlying zoning estoppel is two-fold: hold the government to its commitments, and treat property owners who rely fairly."). Zoning estoppel can be applied to prevent the government from changing zoning regulations on which a property owner has reasonably relied, but only if the government has given assurances that the zoning will not change. Id.
  • 422
    • 84869671923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michelman, supra note 154, at 1233 ("[A] ban on potential uses not yet established may destroy market value as effectively as does a ban on activity already in progress.")
    • See Michelman, supra note 154, at 1233 ("[A] ban on potential uses not yet established may destroy market value as effectively as does a ban on activity already in progress.")
  • 423
    • 70450286037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This kind of example is common in the case law. See, e.g., Savvidis v. City of Norwalk, No. FSTCV054004143S, 2007 WL 2938522, at *4 (Conn. Super. Ct. Aug. 8, 2007) (granting writ of mandamus on behalf of property owners that spent significant sums on development in reliance on approval of zoning application)
    • This kind of example is common in the case law. See, e.g., Savvidis v. City of Norwalk, No. FSTCV054004143S, 2007 WL 2938522, at *4 (Conn. Super. Ct. Aug. 8, 2007) (granting writ of mandamus on behalf of property owners that spent significant sums on development in reliance on approval of zoning application).
  • 424
    • 84926275144 scopus 로고
    • The old-new division in risk regulation
    • 1065 contrasting consequences of regulation of new products versus regulation of existing products
    • Cf. Peter Huber, The Old-New Division in Risk Regulation, 69 VA. L. REV. 1025, 1065 (1983) (contrasting consequences of regulation of new products versus regulation of existing products).
    • (1983) Va. L. Rev. , vol.69 , pp. 1025
    • Huber, P.1
  • 425
    • 84869664863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 23 ("People tend to over-weight out-of-pocket costs relative to pure opportunity costs such as foregone gains. . . . Accordingly, out-of-pocket losses and those that result in a perceived transaction loss may tend to be more salient than others . . . .")
    • See SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 23 ("People tend to over-weight out-of-pocket costs relative to pure opportunity costs such as foregone gains. . . . Accordingly, out-of-pocket losses and those that result in a perceived transaction loss may tend to be more salient than others . . . .").
  • 426
    • 10044298804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The endowment effect and legal analysis
    • 1228 "[P]eople tend to value goods more when they own them than when they do not."
    • See Russell Korobkin, The Endowment Effect and Legal Analysis, 97 Nw. U. L. REV. 1227, 1228 (2003) ("[P]eople tend to value goods more when they own them than when they do not.").
    • (2003) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.97 , pp. 1227
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 427
    • 70450241587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 23 (discussing endowment effects)
    • See generally SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 23 (discussing endowment effects);
  • 428
    • 84936526580 scopus 로고
    • Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the coase theorem
    • Daniel Kahneman et al., Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem, 98 J. POL. ECON. 1325 (1990) (demonstrating experimentally that endowment effect persists even in market setting with opportunities to learn).
    • (1990) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.98 , pp. 1325
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 429
    • 43749092173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Land assembly districts
    • 1479-80
    • See Michael Heller & Rick Hills, Land Assembly Districts, 121 HARV. L. REV. 1465, 1479-80 (2008) (discussing endowment effects and noting that "[h]umans have a wellverified psychological inclination to value their current endowments more than identical items that they currently lack but could purchase");
    • (2008) Harv. L. Rev , vol.121 , pp. 1465
    • Heller, M.1    Hills, R.2
  • 430
    • 70450268242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kahneman et al., supra note 215 (making same point)
    • Kahneman et al., supra note 215 (making same point).
  • 431
    • 0346785701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Remedies and the psychology of ownership
    • 1558 "[S]ubjects actually have to feel and touch [the object] to make it theirs-the right to [an object is] not endowed
    • See Jeffrey J. Rachlinski & Forest Jourden, Remedies and the Psychology of Ownership, 51 VAND. L. REV. 1541, 1558 (1998) ("[S]ubjects actually have to feel and touch [the object] to make it theirs-the right to [an object is] not endowed.");
    • (1998) Vand. L. Rev , vol.51 , pp. 1541
    • Rachlinski, J.J.1    Jourden, F.2
  • 432
    • 70450286038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also id. at 1559 (describing further psychological study)
    • see also id. at 1559 (describing further psychological study);
  • 433
    • 84869682407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Doremus, supra note 200, at 23 ("The [endowment] effect does not seem to attach to expectations. The right to collect a commodity does not give as strong an effect as even brief possession of the commodity itself. . . .")
    • Doremus, supra note 200, at 23 ("The [endowment] effect does not seem to attach to expectations. The right to collect a commodity does not give as strong an effect as even brief possession of the commodity itself. . . .").
  • 434
    • 0032257831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The effect of ownership history on the valuation of objects
    • See Michael A. Strahilevitz & George Lowenstein, The Effect of Ownership History on the Valuation of Objects, 25 J. OF CONSUMER RESEARCH 276 (1998) (publishing findings from studies showing endowment effect increasing over time). Responding to this same phenomenon, some have proposed increasing compensation for condemnation the longer property has been owned by the condemnee.
    • (1998) J. of Consumer Research , vol.25 , pp. 276
    • Strahilevitz, M.A.1    Lowenstein, G.2
  • 435
    • 70449371664 scopus 로고
    • Identifying intense preferences
    • 1391
    • See, e.g., Mo. ANN. STAT. §523.039(3) (West. 2009) (offering higher compensation for properties held by same family for fifty or more years), cited in Daphna Lewinsohn-Zamir, Identifying Intense Preferences, 94 CORNELL. L. REV. 1391, 1409 n.88;
    • (1409) Cornell. L. Rev. , vol.94 , Issue.88
    • Lewinsohn-Zamir, D.1
  • 436
    • 33746148137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eminent domain and the sanctity of the home
    • John Fee, Eminent Domain and the Sanctity of the Home, 81 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 783, 814-17 (2006) ("For example, eminent domain law might require government to pay homeowners market value plus X percent of the home's market value, where X depends on how long the owner has lived in the home."). It may, however, be difficult to move from controlled psychological experiments involving tangible and low-value property to real property.
    • (2006) Notre Dame L. Rev. , vol.81-783 , pp. 814-817
    • Fee, J.1
  • 437
    • 22444452514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The future of behavioral economic analysis of law
    • Comment, 1768-71
    • See Jennifer Arlen, Comment, The Future of Behavioral Economic Analysis of Law, 51 VAND. L. REV. 1765, 1768-71 (1998) ("The classic experiment illustrating the endowment effect involved Cornell coffee mugs.").
    • (1998) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 1765
    • Arlen, J.1
  • 438
    • 0001417422 scopus 로고
    • The path of the law
    • 477
    • O.W. Holmes, The Path of the Law, 10 HARV. L. REV. 457, 477 (1897).
    • (1897) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.10 , pp. 457
    • Holmes, O.W.1
  • 439
    • 70450244114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In support of this intuition, Daniel Troy cites a text on child development that stresses the importance of knowing applicable rules ahead of time. See TROY, supra note 195, at 1 (citing H. CLAY TRUMBULL, HINIS ON CHILD TRAINING 216 (1890))
    • In support of this intuition, Daniel Troy cites a text on child development that stresses the importance of knowing applicable rules ahead of time. See TROY, supra note 195, at 1 (citing H. CLAY TRUMBULL, HINIS ON CHILD TRAINING 216 (1890)).
  • 440
    • 0001090070 scopus 로고
    • Some kind of hearing
    • 1296 cited in Greenholtz v. Inmates of the Neb. Penal & Corr. Complex, 442 U.S. 1, 10 (1979)
    • Henry J. Friendly, "Some Kind of Hearing," 123 U. PA. L. REV. 1267, 1296 (1975), cited in Greenholtz v. Inmates of the Neb. Penal & Corr. Complex, 442 U.S. 1, 10 (1979). Presaging the economic discussion that follows, Friendly continued, "Revocation of a license is far more serious than denial of an application for one; in the former instance capital has been expended, investor expectations have been aroused, and people have been employed."
    • (1975) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.123 , pp. 1267
    • Friendly, H.J.1
  • 441
    • 70450279553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 442
    • 70450249231 scopus 로고
    • The new liberty: The procedural due process rights of prisoners and others under the burger court
    • 514
    • For further discussion, see Susan H. Herman, The New Liberty: The Procedural Due Process Rights of Prisoners and Others Under the Burger Court, 59 N. Y.U. L. REV. 482, 514 (1984).
    • (1984) N. Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.59 , pp. 482
    • Herman, S.H.1
  • 443
    • 20744452624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The meaning of value: Assessing just compensation for regulatory takings
    • 700-01
    • Christopher Serkin, The Meaning of Value: Assessing Just Compensation for Regulatory Takings, 99 Nw. U. L. REV. 677, 700-01 (2005).
    • (2005) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 677
    • Serkin, C.1
  • 444
    • 70450232396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Id., at 701 n.110 (citing cases)
    • See Id., at 701 n.110 (citing cases);
  • 445
    • 49749092344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taking eminent domain apart
    • 993-95
    • see also Lee Anne Fennell, Taking Eminent Domain Apart, 2004 MICH. ST. L. REV. 957, 993-95 ("It is difficult to know how much value someone places on a property, and resort to proxies such as percentage bonuses will generate inaccuracies in both directions.").
    • Mich. St. L. Rev. , vol.2004 , pp. 957
    • Fennell, L.A.1
  • 446
    • 0347573321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Takings reassessed
    • Richard Epstein has suggested applying some extra percentage increase to compensation at least partly to account for subjective value
    • For a proposal for self-assessment of property values tied to property taxes and sales prices, see Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, Takings Reassessed, 87 VA. L. REV. 277, 300-04 (2001). Richard Epstein has suggested applying some extra percentage increase to compensation at least partly to account for subjective value.
    • (2001) Va. L. Rev. 277 , vol.87 , pp. 300-304
    • Bell, A.1    Parchomovsky, G.2
  • 447
    • 0009992505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A clear view of the cathedral/ the dominance of property rules
    • 2114-15
    • Richard A. Epstein, A Clear View of The Cathedral/ The Dominance of Property Rules, 106 YALE L.J. 2091, 2114-15 (1997).
    • (1997) Yale L.J. , vol.106 , pp. 2091
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 448
    • 84925977763 scopus 로고
    • Self-assessed valuation systems for tort and other law
    • For a discussion of the possibility of self-assessment in other contexts, see generally Saul Levmore, Self-Assessed Valuation Systems for Tort and Other Law, 68 VA. L. REV. 771 (1982).
    • (1982) Va. L. Rev. , vol.68 , pp. 771
    • Levmore, S.1
  • 449
    • 70450240754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I (describing property and land use doctrines protecting existing uses)
    • See supra Part I (describing property and land use doctrines protecting existing uses).
  • 450
    • 70450248423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part III.B.4 (discussing personhood)
    • See infra Part III.B.4 (discussing personhood).
  • 451
    • 84869682206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Dana, supra note 40, at 685 ("The costs of undoing an existing development, moreover, are typically much greater than the costs of preventing development.")
    • See Dana, supra note 40, at 685 ("The costs of undoing an existing development, moreover, are typically much greater than the costs of preventing development.");
  • 452
    • 22744444533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The right to destroy
    • 796
    • cf. Lior Jacob Strahilevitz, The Right To Destroy, 114 YALE L.J. 781, 796 (2005) ("Concern about wasting valuable resources is, by far, the most commonly voiced justification for restricting an owner's ability to destroy her property.").
    • (2005) Yale L.J. , vol.114 , pp. 781
    • Strahilevitz, L.J.1
  • 453
    • 70450250885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 214 (discussing such overweighting). This also resembles at least some characterizations of the sunk cost fallacy in that it unduly privileges money that has already been spent
    • See supra note 214 (discussing such overweighting). This also resembles at least some characterizations of the sunk cost fallacy in that it unduly privileges money that has already been spent.
  • 454
    • 33745956801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The myth of the rational borrower: Rationality, behavioralism, and the misguided "reform" of bankruptcy law
    • 1534
    • See Susan Block-Lieb & Edward J. Janger, The Myth of the Rational Borrower: Rationality, Behavioralism, and the Misguided "Reform" of Bankruptcy Law, 84 TEX. L. REV. 1481, 1534 (2006) ("Cognitive research also finds that individuals are reluctant to walk away from sunk costs, irrationally ignoring the marginal costs and benefits of additional action.");
    • (2006) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 1481
    • Block-Lieb, S.1    Janger, E.J.2
  • 455
    • 0036330130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cognitive loafing, social conformity, and judicial review of agency rulemaking
    • 500
    • Mark Seidenfeld, Cognitive Loafing, Social Conformity, and Judicial Review of Agency Rulemaking, 87 CORNELL L. REV. 486, 500 (2002) ("When making investment decisions, the old economic adage advises that one should ignore sunk costs, but people intuitively tend to let such costs influence their choices.").
    • (2002) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.87 , pp. 486
    • Seidenfeld, M.1
  • 456
    • 70450252856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • That loss includes both the costs of tearing down the theater and the lesser value of the property as low-income housing in relation to the higher-valued movie theater
    • That loss includes both the costs of tearing down the theater and the lesser value of the property as low-income housing in relation to the higher-valued movie theater.
  • 457
    • 84869682207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of endowment effects, see supra notes 216-18 and accompanying text. This waste analysis will not hold true if eliminating the existing use imposes an intergenerational externality. See Strahilevitz, supra note 227, at 793-94 (identifying problem with property destruction as imposing "intergenerational consequences, for better or worse"). By the same token, a regulation can also impose an intergenerational benefit. There is no reason, in the abstract, to suspect that existing uses will be more valuable in the future than the kinds of regulatory benefits the government might seek to obtain by eliminating an existing use. Unless there is some kind of systemic valuation failure for existing uses, the present value of existing uses should capture their value in the future
    • For a discussion of endowment effects, see supra notes 216-18 and accompanying text. This waste analysis will not hold true if eliminating the existing use imposes an intergenerational externality. See Strahilevitz, supra note 227, at 793-94 (identifying problem with property destruction as imposing "intergenerational consequences, for better or worse"). By the same token, a regulation can also impose an intergenerational benefit. There is no reason, in the abstract, to suspect that existing uses will be more valuable in the future than the kinds of regulatory benefits the government might seek to obtain by eliminating an existing use. Unless there is some kind of systemic valuation failure for existing uses, the present value of existing uses should capture their value in the future.
  • 458
    • 70450238493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shavell, supra note 17, at 57-64
    • Shavell, supra note 17, at 57-64.
  • 459
    • 84869682401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 47 ("[A] party ought to continue with its period 1 precaution in period 2 if the cost of the new conventionally optimal precaution for period 2 harm would exceed the marginal reduction in expected harm that would be accomplished by a change to this precaution.")
    • See id. at 47 ("[A] party ought to continue with its period 1 precaution in period 2 if the cost of the new conventionally optimal precaution for period 2 harm would exceed the marginal reduction in expected harm that would be accomplished by a change to this precaution.").
  • 460
    • 33750519220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two models of tort (and takings)
    • 1152
    • See, e.g., Scott Hershovitz, Two Models of Tort (and Takings), 92 VA. L. REV. 1147, 1152 (2006) ("[T]he law aims to place liability on the least-cost avoider. The least-cost avoider is frequently the party best able to control a situation.");
    • (2006) Va. L. Rev , vol.92 , pp. 1147
    • Hershovitz, S.1
  • 461
    • 33750916040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Agency law and contract formation
    • 380
    • Eric Rasmusen, Agency Law and Contract Formation, 6 AM. L. & ECON. REV. 369, 380 (2004) ("The least-cost avoider principle, broadly stated, asks which party has the lower cost of avoiding harm, and assigns liability to that party.").
    • (2004) Am. L. & Econ. Rev. , vol.6 , pp. 369
    • Rasmusen, E.1
  • 462
    • 34250898646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When plaintiffs are premium planners for their injuries: A fresh look at the fireman's rule
    • 771
    • This kind of reasoning is reminiscent of the "last clear chance" doctrine in torts, which "allowed plaintiffs to prevail despite their being the cheaper precaution taker against their injury." Robert H. Heidt, When Plaintiffs Are Premium Planners for Their Injuries: A Fresh Look at the Fireman's Rule, 82 IND. L.J. 745, 771 (2007). This doctrine has been replaced in most jurisdictions by comparative fault regimes.
    • (2007) Ind. L.J. , vol.82 , pp. 745
    • Heidt, R.H.1
  • 463
    • 36249024385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The hidden risk of opportunistic precautions
    • 1418
    • Ehud Guttel, The Hidden Risk of Opportunistic Precautions, 93 VA. L. REV. 1389, 1418 n.62 (2007).
    • (2007) Va. L. Rev. , vol.93 , Issue.62 , pp. 1389
    • Guttel, E.1
  • 464
    • 70450244113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 278-90 and accompanying text discussing transitions literature
    • See infra notes 278-90 and accompanying text (discussing transitions literature).
  • 465
    • 41449095211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The behavioral economics of consumer contracts
    • 791
    • For examination of the complexities of identifying the least-cost avoider in another context, see Oren Bar-Gill, The Behavioral Economics of Consumer Contracts, 92 MINN. L. REV. 749, 791 (2008), which discusses the asymmetrical positions of consumers and sophisticated sellers with regard to the ability to avoid mistakes.
    • (2008) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 749
    • Bar-Gill, O.1
  • 466
    • 0000542896 scopus 로고
    • Property and personhood
    • 965-66 discussing whether people have property interest in their bodies
    • See Margaret Jane Radin, Property and Personhood, 34 STAN. L. REV. 957, 965-66 (1982) (discussing whether people have property interest in their bodies).
    • (1982) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.34 , pp. 957
    • Radin, M.J.1
  • 467
    • 84936628259 scopus 로고
    • Market-Inalienability
    • 1907-09
    • See Margaret Jane Radin, Market-Inalienability, 100 HARV. L. REV. 1849, 1907-09 (1984) (describing application of market-inalienability theory to personhood).
    • (1984) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.100 , pp. 1849
    • Radin, M.J.1
  • 468
    • 70450229332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Radin, supra note 237, at 972-75 (discussing Hegelian theory)
    • Radin, supra note 237, at 972-75 (discussing Hegelian theory).
  • 469
    • 84869671920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As Radin describes it, "Hegel's property theory is an occupancy theory; the owner's will must be present in the object." Id. at 973. The primacy of the object's existence, then, is essential to Radin's personhood perspective on property. Extrapolating from the "notion that the will is embodied in things," Radin concludes that "[t]he idea of embodied will... reminds us that people and things have ongoing relationships which have their own ebb and flow, and that these relationships can be very close to a person's center and sanity." Id. at 977. But see Radin, supra note 161, at 1692 (suggesting people may have personhood interests in plans to build residence)
    • As Radin describes it, "Hegel's property theory is an occupancy theory; the owner's will must be present in the object." Id. at 973. The primacy of the object's existence, then, is essential to Radin's personhood perspective on property. Extrapolating from the "notion that the will is embodied in things," Radin concludes that "[t]he idea of embodied will... reminds us that people and things have ongoing relationships which have their own ebb and flow, and that these relationships can be very close to a person's center and sanity." Id. at 977. But see Radin, supra note 161, at 1692 (suggesting people may have personhood interests in plans to build residence).
  • 470
    • 84869671918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Radin, supra note 237, at 959-60 (describing fungible property as opposite of personal property). Radin argues that "[t]he opposite of holding an object that has become a part of oneself is holding an object that is perfectly replaceable with other goods of equal market value. One holds such an object for purely instrumental reasons." Id
    • Radin, supra note 237, at 959-60 (describing fungible property as opposite of personal property). Radin argues that "[t]he opposite of holding an object that has become a part of oneself is holding an object that is perfectly replaceable with other goods of equal market value. One holds such an object for purely instrumental reasons." Id.
  • 471
    • 70450240385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1004
    • Id. at 1004.
  • 472
    • 70450258492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fashion's just a job; baking's a destiny
    • Sept. 28
    • Individual owners of small businesses may well have their identities bound up in their commercial property. For a pleasant example, see Donna Paul, Fashion's Just a Job; Baking's a Destiny, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 28, 2007, at F3 (describing young couple buying bakery that appeared far more important to them than their house). Line drawing is nevertheless hard, if not impossible. In an interesting new article, Professor Stephanie Stern questions whether personhood interests are actually at stake in the home or whether "residential protectionism" is simply the result of interest group capture.
    • (2007) N.Y. Times
    • Paul, D.1
  • 473
    • 66349136252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Residential protectionism and the legal mythology of home
    • 1096
    • See Stephanie M. Stern, Residential Protectionism and the Legal Mythology of Home, 107 MICH. L. REV. 1093, 1096 (2009).
    • (2009) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.107 , pp. 1093
    • Stern, S.M.1
  • 474
    • 0040172009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The shadow of the cathedral
    • 2187
    • See, e.g., Carol M. Rose, The Shadow of The Cathedral, 106 YALE L.J. 2175, 2187 (1997) ("The usual roles of property rules-defining rights and identifying rights-holders-. . . encourage individual investment, planning, and effort, because actors have a clearer sense of what they are getting.");
    • (1997) Yale L.J. , vol.106 , pp. 2175
    • Rose, C.M.1
  • 475
    • 18144390196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A theory of property
    • 573
    • see also Abraham Bell & Gideon Parchomovsky, A Theory of Property, 90 CORNELL L. REV. 531, 573 (2005) ("The stability in ownership afforded by the law creates the possibility for developing new kinds of value in, and uses of, property that would otherwise be unavailable.");
    • (2005) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.90 , pp. 531
    • Bell, A.1    Parchomovsky, G.2
  • 476
    • 0001845692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Optimal standardization in the law of property: The numerus clausus principle
    • 64
    • Thomas W. Merrill & Henry E. Smith, Optimal Standardization in the Law of Property: The Numerus Clausus Principle, 110 YALE L.J. 1, 64 (2000) ("A rule that has been around a long time and is relatively unchanging is more likely to be understood because actors ... are more apt to have encountered the rule in the past and to have made some previous investment in comprehending the rule.").
    • (2000) Yale L.J. , vol.110 , pp. 1
    • Merrill, T.W.1    Smith, H.E.2
  • 477
    • 0035982093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The reconstitution of property: Property as a web of interests
    • 325
    • See, e.g., Craig Anthony (Tony) Arnold, The Reconstitution of Property: Property as a Web of Interests, 26 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 281, 325 (2002) ("[Property] may involve a 'double bind' between reinforcing the status quo by compromising ideals and making very little real progress toward change, and reinforcing the status quo by insisting on Utopian ideals and making no progress toward change.").
    • (2002) Harv. Envtl. L. Rev. , vol.26 , pp. 281
    • Arnold, C.A.1
  • 478
    • 84869682398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Richard A. Epstein, International News Service v. Associated Press/ Custom and Law as Sources of Property Rights in News, 78 VA. L. REV. 85, 108 (1992) (arguing that distribution of property rights is " functional" and "forward-looking" and suggesting that "the central task is to develop that initial distribution of rights that leads to the shortest path for the productive use of natural resources-that is, to some form of allocative efficiency").
    • See, e.g., Richard A. Epstein, International News Service v. Associated Press/ Custom and Law as Sources of Property Rights in News, 78 VA. L. REV. 85, 108 (1992) (arguing that distribution of property rights is " functional" and "forward-looking" and suggesting that "the central task is to develop that initial distribution of rights that leads to the shortest path for the productive use of natural resources-that is, to some form of allocative efficiency").
  • 479
    • 70450235940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This may also be what Michelman was suggesting in the quotation accompanying note 162, supra
    • This may also be what Michelman was suggesting in the quotation accompanying note 162, supra.
  • 480
    • 70450271530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The harm-prevention exception for regulatory takings liability clearly demonstrates that property is regularly put to a use that is, or later turns out to be, unreasonable. See, e.g., Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1026 (1992) (articulating nuisanceprevention defense); Hadacheck v. Sebastian, 239 U.S. 394 (1915) (upholding law barring operation of brick mills in residential areas).
    • The harm-prevention exception for regulatory takings liability clearly demonstrates that property is regularly put to a use that is, or later turns out to be, unreasonable. See, e.g., Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1026 (1992) (articulating nuisanceprevention defense); Hadacheck v. Sebastian, 239 U.S. 394 (1915) (upholding law barring operation of brick mills in residential areas).
  • 481
    • 70450268240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.C (discussing vested rights doctrine)
    • See supra Part I.C (discussing vested rights doctrine).
  • 482
    • 70450267454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 132-56 and accompanying text (discussing investment-backed expectations prong of Penn Central test)
    • See supra notes 132-56 and accompanying text (discussing investment-backed expectations prong of Penn Central test).
  • 483
    • 70450270658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Serkin, supra note 222, at 689-92 (discussing highest and best use as component of fair market value)
    • See Serkin, supra note 222, at 689-92 (discussing highest and best use as component of fair market value).
  • 484
    • 70349844142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The measure of just compensation
    • 250-51
    • See Katrina Miriam Wyman, The Measure of Just Compensation, 41 U.C. DAVIS L. REV. 239, 250-51 (2007) (problematizing what it means for compensation to make property owners whole).
    • (2007) U.C. Davis L. Rev. , vol.41 , pp. 239
    • Wyman, K.M.1
  • 485
    • 70450250074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Carol Rose offered the following examples of such tradeoffs and concessions: A community might ask a developer to provide park space as a tradeoff for permission to build a new development, or to preserve a familiar community landmark in exchange for permission to build at a higher density; or the tenants of a low income area, through the local government as mediator, may negotiate with a highrise developer for low-income housing to offset the loss of inexpensive residential hotel space.
  • 486
    • 70450263329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rose, supra note 46, at 891 (footnotes omitted)
    • Rose, supra note 46, at 891 (footnotes omitted).
  • 487
    • 70450286035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the Penn Central factors, see supra Part II.B
    • For a discussion of the Penn Central factors, see supra Part II.B.
  • 488
    • 70450270657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 158 and accompanying text (discussing diminution in value test for takings liability)
    • See supra note 158 and accompanying text (discussing diminution in value test for takings liability).
  • 489
    • 70450257639 scopus 로고
    • hereinafter FISCHEL, REG ULATORY TAKINGS
    • WILLIAM A. FISCHEL, REGULATORY TAKINGS 139 (1995) [hereinafter FISCHEL, REG ULATORY TAKINGS].
    • (1995) Regulatory T , vol.139
    • Fischel, W.A.1
  • 490
    • 0141767639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • hereinafter FISCHEL, HOMEVOTER HYPOTHESIS
    • See generally WILLIAM A. FISCHEL, HOMEVOTER HYPOTHESIS (2001) [hereinafter FISCHEL, HOMEVOTER HYPOTHESIS] (arguing that in face of homeowners' political power, developers and owners of undeveloped property need greater protection of property rights). Dean Treanor adopted a similar approach in his leading historical treatment of the Takings Clause, arguing for a political process-based interpretation focused on the political protection of property.
    • (2001) Homevoter Hypothesis
    • Fischel, W.A.1
  • 491
    • 84869664853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Treanor, supra note 165, at 708-10; see also Doremus, supra note 200, at 40 ("More searching review is appropriate where only a minority will bear the regulatory burden .. ..")
    • Treanor, supra note 165, at 708-10; see also Doremus, supra note 200, at 40 ("More searching review is appropriate where only a minority will bear the regulatory burden .. ..");
  • 492
    • 0042577363 scopus 로고
    • Takings, torts, and special interests
    • 1344-45
    • Saul Levmore, Takings, Torts, and Special Interests, 77 VA. L. REV. 1333, 1344-45 (1991) ("[W]hen ... the government's aims could have been achieved in many ways but the means chosen placed losses on an individual or on persons who are not part of an existing or easily organized political coalition, then we can expect to find a compensable taking.").
    • (1991) Va. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 1333
    • Levmore, S.1
  • 493
    • 70450244112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NEIL K. KOMESAR, LAW'S LIMITS 61 (2001) (explaining advantage of "groups with small numbers but high per capita stakes," whose members "have greater incentive to expend the effort necessary to recognize and understand the issues" over "groups with larger numbers and smaller per capita stakes").
    • (2001) Komesar, Law's Limits , vol.61
    • Neil, K.1
  • 494
    • 84869664854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ("[F]or larger groups, the cost of participation depends heavily on the cost of organization, which in turn depends on both the size of the group to be organized and the difficulty of identifying and convincing potential allies.")
    • Id. ("[F]or larger groups, the cost of participation depends heavily on the cost of organization, which in turn depends on both the size of the group to be organized and the difficulty of identifying and convincing potential allies.").
  • 495
    • 70450246988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 496
    • 70450250075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.C.2 (discussing subjective value)
    • See supra Part III.C.2 (discussing subjective value).
  • 497
    • 34548299197 scopus 로고
    • Does interest group theory justify more intrusive judicial review?
    • 37
    • See Einer R. Elhauge, Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review?, 101 YALE L.J. 31, 37 (1991) (predicting that "small groups with concentrated (high per capita) interests in lawmaking will come closer to their optimal level of petitioning than large groups with diffuse (low per capita) interests");
    • (1991) Yale L.J. , vol.101 , pp. 31
    • Elhauge, E.R.1
  • 498
    • 37349087249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eminent domain, inc.
    • 1719
    • Amnon Lehavi & Amir N. Licht, Eminent Domain, Inc., 107 COLUM. L. REV. 1704, 1719 (2007) ("[Public choice theory] points to the disproportionate influence that special interest groups, and chiefly politically powerful real estate entrepreneurs, have over governmental decisions in land policy issues."). For further discussion of the insights of public choice theory and its implications for property protection,
    • (2007) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.107 , pp. 1704
    • Lehavi, A.1    Licht, A.N.2
  • 499
    • 0347450521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making government pay: Markets, politics, and the allocation of constitutional costs
    • see generally Daryl J. Levinson, Making Government Pay: Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 345 (2000),
    • (2000) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 345
    • Levinson, D.J.1
  • 500
    • 33751216161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Big differences for small governments: Local governments and the takings clause
    • 1637-43
    • and Christopher Serkin, Big Differences for Small Governments: Local Governments and the Takings Clause, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1624, 1637-43 (2006).
    • (2006) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.81 , pp. 1624
    • Serkin, C.1
  • 501
    • 84869671912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Elhauge, supra note 261, at 39 (characterizing "[l]arge diffusely interested groups" as underrepresented and as having "a harder time collecting the resources necessary to monitor and evaluate developing issues, make campaign contributions, [and] present information to voters or officials")
    • See, e.g., Elhauge, supra note 261, at 39 (characterizing "[l]arge diffusely interested groups" as underrepresented and as having "a harder time collecting the resources necessary to monitor and evaluate developing issues, make campaign contributions, [and] present information to voters or officials").
  • 502
    • 70450231603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an account of those costs, see Serkin, supra note 261, at 1677-79
    • For an account of those costs, see Serkin, supra note 261, at 1677-79.
  • 504
    • 0347416183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Takings and distributive justice
    • 777
    • see Hanoch Dagan, Takings and Distributive Justice, 85 VA. L. REV. 741, 777 n.119 (1999) (interpreting Fischel as supporting judicial intervention to protect undeveloped land from local governments);
    • (1999) VA. L. Rev. , vol.85 , Issue.119 , pp. 741
    • Dagan, H.1
  • 505
    • 84937271291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Takings, federalism, norms
    • 1126
    • Carol M. Rose, Takings, Federalism, Norms, 105 YALE L.J. 1121, 1126 (1996) (book review) (same);
    • (1996) Yale L.J. , vol.105 , pp. 1121
    • Rose, C.M.1
  • 506
    • 0346485517 scopus 로고
    • Exploring the kozinski paradox: Why is more efficient regulation a taking of property?
    • 866
    • see also William A. Fischel, Exploring the Kozinski Paradox: Why Is More Efficient Regulation a Taking of Property?, 67 CIII.-KENT L. REV. 865, 866 n.7 (1991) ("In many cases, however, zoning imposes burdens on one set of owners (e.g., owners of undeveloped land) to benefit another set of owners (e.g., owners of already-developed homes).").
    • (1991) CIII.-Kent L. Rev. , vol.67 , Issue.7 , pp. 865
    • Fischel, W.A.1
  • 508
    • 70450264174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a thoroughgoing account of the role of exit and voice in local governments, including a description of Hirschman's theory
    • For a thoroughgoing account of the role of exit and voice in local governments, including a description of Hirschman's theory,
  • 509
    • 84928438303 scopus 로고
    • "Exit" as a constraint on land use exactions: rethinking the unconstitutional conditions doctrine
    • 476
    • see Vicki Been, "Exit" as a Constraint on Land Use Exactions: Rethinking the Unconstitutional Conditions Doctrine, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 473, 476 (1991).
    • (1991) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.91 , pp. 473
    • Been, V.1
  • 510
    • 0009651296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 256, at
    • See FISCHEL, REGULATORY TAKINGS, supra note 256, at 139 ("Owners of property whose services are elastic in supply can protect themselves from myopic local regulation by threatening to leave the jurisdiction. The remaining category, regulation of immobile property by independent local governments and state agencies, requires most of the attention of judges in regulatory takings cases.").
    • Regulatory Takings , pp. 139
    • Fischel1
  • 512
    • 84883173744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • unpublished manuscript
    • (unpublished manuscript, on file with the New York University Law Review) (arguing takings compensation is justified because it reduces profitability of rent-seeking behavior).
    • New York University Law Review
  • 513
    • 70450268239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This claim comes with a substantial caveat: Some uses can be moved relatively easily. For example, many businesses do not depend on a specific location
    • This claim comes with a substantial caveat: Some uses can be moved relatively easily. For example, many businesses do not depend on a specific location.
  • 514
    • 84869682397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 77 ("[T]here plainly would be a strong argument for allowing ex post facto criminal legislation, but for a concern about singling out.")
    • Cf. SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 77 ("[T]here plainly would be a strong argument for allowing ex post facto criminal legislation, but for a concern about singling out.").
  • 515
    • 0141767639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 256, at 87-96 (developing median voter model)
    • FISCHEL, HOMEVOTER HYPOTHESIS, supra note 256, at 87-96 (developing median voter model).
    • Homevoter Hypothesis
    • Fischel1
  • 516
    • 70450247808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Serkin, supra note 261, at 1648
    • Serkin, supra note 261, at 1648.
  • 517
    • 70450249232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 518
    • 0141767639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 256, at 9 (discussing NIMBYism)
    • FISCHEL, HOMEVOTER HYPOTHESIS, supra note 256, at 9 (discussing NIMBYism).
    • Homevoter Hypothesis
    • Fischel1
  • 519
    • 70450258491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Serkin, supra note 261, at 1661-64 (arguing that homeowners' political power dissipates at state and federal level)
    • See Serkin, supra note 261, at 1661-64 (arguing that homeowners' political power dissipates at state and federal level).
  • 520
    • 70450253165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The prescriptions arising from this likely political failure are discussed in more detail in Part IV.C, infra. Here, it is enough to repeat Professor Fischel's argument that in the takings context, judicial resources should be focused only on those situations where property owners are unlikely to have a meaningful political remedy. See Fischel, supra note 264, at 911-12
    • The prescriptions arising from this likely political failure are discussed in more detail in Part IV.C, infra. Here, it is enough to repeat Professor Fischel's argument that in the takings context, judicial resources should be focused only on those situations where property owners are unlikely to have a meaningful political remedy. See Fischel, supra note 264, at 911-12.
  • 521
    • 70450264173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Principal among those statutes are the Clean Air Act, the Clean Water Act, the Wilderness Act, the Americans with Disabilities Act, and a number of state statutes, each of which provides special treatment for existing uses. See supra notes 12-24 and accompanying text
    • Principal among those statutes are the Clean Air Act, the Clean Water Act, the Wilderness Act, the Americans with Disabilities Act, and a number of state statutes, each of which provides special treatment for existing uses. See supra notes 12-24 and accompanying text.
  • 522
    • 1842664236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional decision rules
    • For a sampling of this literature, see generally 10 which argues that decision rules are central to judicially-created constitutional doctrine
    • For a sampling of this literature, see generally Mitchell N. Berman, Constitutional Decision Rules, 90 VA. L. REV. 1, 10 (2004), which argues that decision rules are central to judicially-created constitutional doctrine;
    • (2004) Va. L. Rev , vol.90 , pp. 1
    • Berman, M.N.1
  • 523
    • 0141838107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Miranda and some puzzles of "prophylactic" rules
    • 9
    • Evan H. Caminker, Miranda and Some Puzzles of "Prophylactic" Rules, 70 U. CIN. L. REV. 1, 9 (2001), which argues that where risk of false negatives is high, a prophylactic rule might protect constitutional values;
    • (2001) U. Cin. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 1
    • Caminker, E.H.1
  • 524
    • 0039382286 scopus 로고
    • The ubiquity of prophylactic rules
    • 207-209
    • and David A. Strauss, The Ubiquity of Prophylactic Rules, 55 U. CHI. L. REV. 190, 207-09 (1988), which defends constitutional rules based on institutional propensities.
    • (1988) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.55 , pp. 190
    • Strauss, D.A.1
  • 525
    • 84869671915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Nash & Revesz, supra note 10, at 1725 ("[R]elief from a transition in legal regimes is ordinarily inadvisable because it creates an incentive for societal actors not to anticipate changes in the governing law."); see also Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1070 n.5 (Stevens, J., dissenting) ("In the face of uncertainty about changes in the law, developers will overinvest, safe in the knowledge that if the law changes adversely, they will be entitled to compensation."); Serkin, supra note 222, at 677 & n.102 (citing further sources and giving example).
    • See Nash & Revesz, supra note 10, at 1725 ("[R]elief from a transition in legal regimes is ordinarily inadvisable because it creates an incentive for societal actors not to anticipate changes in the governing law."); see also Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1070 n.5 (Stevens, J., dissenting) ("In the face of uncertainty about changes in the law, developers will overinvest, safe in the knowledge that if the law changes adversely, they will be entitled to compensation."); Serkin, supra note 222, at 677 & n.102 (citing further sources and giving example).
  • 526
    • 84869671914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dana, supra note 40, at 677-81 (describing "race to develop")
    • Dana, supra note 40, at 677-81 (describing "race to develop");
  • 527
    • 33747673531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The ownership society and takings of property: castles, investments, and just obligations
    • 325
    • see also Joseph William Singer, The Ownership Society and Takings of Property: Castles, Investments, and Just Obligations, 30 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 309, 325 (2006) ("[Property owners ... should be forced to internalize [the risk of]... foreseeable new regulations designed to protect the public from the harms attendant on the cumulative effects of individual acts of ownership.").
    • (2006) Harv. Envtl. L. Rev. , vol.30 , pp. 309
    • Singer, J.W.1
  • 528
    • 70450241585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.A (discussing inefficiency in terms of antiretroactivity laws)
    • See supra Part III.A (discussing inefficiency in terms of antiretroactivity laws).
  • 529
    • 70450242709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 862 N.Y.S.2d 358 (App. Div. 2008)
    • 862 N.Y.S.2d 358 (App. Div. 2008).
  • 530
    • 70450250076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 359-60
    • Id. at 359-60.
  • 531
    • 70450240758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In his careful taxonomy of retroactive effects, Professor Shaviro identifies instances in which retroactive application of rules will not enhance efficiency. SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 47-53 (looking specifically at retroactive application of taxes)
    • In his careful taxonomy of retroactive effects, Professor Shaviro identifies instances in which retroactive application of rules will not enhance efficiency. SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 47-53 (looking specifically at retroactive application of taxes).
  • 532
    • 70450239584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ; see also Logue, supra note 40, at 235-45 (identifying situations in which anticipation of legal change is desirable)
    • Id. ; see also Logue, supra note 40, at 235-45 (identifying situations in which anticipation of legal change is desirable).
  • 533
    • 84869676716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 48-51; see also Logue, supra note 40, at 236-39 (discussing legal "disasters")
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 48-51; see also Logue, supra note 40, at 236-39 (discussing legal "disasters").
  • 534
    • 84869676715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Logue, supra note 40, at 239-42 ("[I]f the transition is undesirable, the optimal transition policy . . . would be a norm that actually discourages anticipation of the law change and encourages reliance on old law . . . .")
    • See Logue, supra note 40, at 239-42 ("[I]f the transition is undesirable, the optimal transition policy . . . would be a norm that actually discourages anticipation of the law change and encourages reliance on old law . . . .").
  • 535
    • 70450277194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 236 (arguing that desirability of legal rule matters less when regulation destroys property values entirely and irreversibly). For discussion of the problem of social waste, see supra Part III.B.3
    • See id. at 236 (arguing that desirability of legal rule matters less when regulation destroys property values entirely and irreversibly). For discussion of the problem of social waste, see supra Part III.B.3.
  • 536
    • 70450231262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kaplow, supra note 9, at 529
    • Kaplow, supra note 9, at 529.
  • 537
    • 70450278738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 529-31; see also Dana, supra note 40, at 679-80 (describing Kaplow's argument)
    • See id. at 529-31; see also Dana, supra note 40, at 679-80 (describing Kaplow's argument).
  • 538
    • 84869675079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kaplow, supra note 9, at 528-30; see also SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 49 ("Suppose I am considering building a house on a site where the government may at some point exercise its power of eminent domain in order to extend a highway. When and if the highway comes, should I be compensated for the value of my improvements? Here, my incentives will be better if the answer is no."); Levmore, supra note 40, at 1677-79 ("But if the government pays for losses suffered as a result of regulation, then the factory owner has no incentive to anticipate these regulations and to facilitate the move to better and safer methods."); Logue, supra note 40, at 237 ("To ensure that the individual has the ex ante incentives (that is, to force her to internalize the cost of her decision to build on this site), the consequentialist or economic framework would counsel against compensation . . . .")
    • See Kaplow, supra note 9, at 528-30; see also SHAVIRO, supra note 9, at 49 ("Suppose I am considering building a house on a site where the government may at some point exercise its power of eminent domain in order to extend a highway. When and if the highway comes, should I be compensated for the value of my improvements? Here, my incentives will be better if the answer is no."); Levmore, supra note 40, at 1677-79 ("But if the government pays for losses suffered as a result of regulation, then the factory owner has no incentive to anticipate these regulations and to facilitate the move to better and safer methods."); Logue, supra note 40, at 237 ("To ensure that the individual has the ex ante incentives (that is, to force her to internalize the cost of her decision to build on this site), the consequentialist or economic framework would counsel against compensation . . . .").
  • 539
    • 70450231606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is, in fact, sufficiently complex that it demands considerably more treatment than it can be given here. In particular, different regulatory contexts may afford different opportunities for owners to modify their behavior in anticipation of government action. This is a topic that must be reserved for more comprehensive treatment in future work.
  • 540
    • 84869675936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Doremus, supra note 200, at 16 ("Another efficiency concern is the worry that an unstable regulatory climate will inhibit investment, particularly investment that takes a long period of time to mature."). In the tax context, Logue has argued persuasively that failure to provide transition relief will result in taxpayers demanding a "default premium"-that is, more of a tax benefit in the future to induce such investments to account for the possibility of retroactive change. See Logue, supra note 199, at 1139-41
    • See, e.g., Doremus, supra note 200, at 16 ("Another efficiency concern is the worry that an unstable regulatory climate will inhibit investment, particularly investment that takes a long period of time to mature."). In the tax context, Logue has argued persuasively that failure to provide transition relief will result in taxpayers demanding a "default premium"-that is, more of a tax benefit in the future to induce such investments to account for the possibility of retroactive change. See Logue, supra note 199, at 1139-41.
  • 541
    • 70450231604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Dana, supra note 40, at 694-95 & n.107 (collecting examples of accelerated development to beat regulatory clock)
    • See, e.g., Dana, supra note 40, at 694-95 & n.107 (collecting examples of accelerated development to beat regulatory clock).
  • 542
    • 0039471877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Takings, compensation, and equal treatment for owners of developed and undeveloped property
    • 406-07
    • For this reason, economist Robert Innes has argued that developed and undeveloped property should receive equal treatment for takings purposes. See Robert Innes, Takings, Compensation, and Equal Treatment for Owners of Developed and Undeveloped Property, 40 J.L. & ECON. 403, 406-07 (1997).'
    • (1997) J.L. & Econ. , vol.40 , pp. 403
    • Innes, R.1
  • 543
    • 70450228130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Serkin, supra note 261, at 1666-73 (describing governments' risk aversion)
    • See Serkin, supra note 261, at 1666-73 (describing governments' risk aversion).
  • 544
    • 84869675076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Innes, supra note 294, at 406 ("[T]he least valuable undeveloped land should be taken first, which implies that, if takings are not compensated, landowners have an incentive to develop their land early in order to reduce their risk of government appropriation.")
    • See Innes, supra note 294, at 406 ("[T]he least valuable undeveloped land should be taken first, which implies that, if takings are not compensated, landowners have an incentive to develop their land early in order to reduce their risk of government appropriation.").
  • 545
    • 70450240757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I credit Professor Fischel with this interesting suggestion
    • I credit Professor Fischel with this interesting suggestion.
  • 546
    • 70450263331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This concern is often voiced in the zoning and land use literature. See supra note 7 (citing sources)
    • This concern is often voiced in the zoning and land use literature. See supra note 7 (citing sources).
  • 547
    • 34248598144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property and empire: The law of imperialism
    • Johnson v. M'Intosh, 336
    • Favoring existing uses over potential future uses may also privilege a particular kind of property use. Criticisms of labor theories of property point out the harms of privileging active uses of property over passive ones. See, e.g., Jedediah Purdy, Property and Empire: The Law of Imperialism in Johnson v. M'Intosh, 75 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 329, 336 n.36 (2007) (describing Western accounts of property used to "justify colonial expropriations"). The labor theory, in turn, has justified such pernicious acts as the expropriation of land by early European settlers from Native Americans, whose use of land was not perceived as being sufficiently active to warrant legal protection. See generally id. It may continue to privilege buildings over open space, farmed land over conserved fields, and the like, although perhaps the definition of "use" can be made sufficiently capacious to encompass non-intensive uses such as conservation.
    • (2007) Geo. Wash. L. Rev. , vol.75 , Issue.36 , pp. 329
    • Purdy, J.1
  • 548
    • 70450252854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.D (discussing political economy of existing uses)
    • See supra Part III.D (discussing political economy of existing uses).
  • 549
    • 70450260552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Serkin, supra note 261, at 1666-67 (explaining why small local governments might be more risk averse than larger governments)
    • See Serkin, supra note 261, at 1666-67 (explaining why small local governments might be more risk averse than larger governments).
  • 550
    • 70450237643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1666-67, 1672-74
    • See id. at 1666-67, 1672-74.
  • 551
    • 70450242710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The costs of monitoring local governments are typically much lower than the costs of monitoring larger governments. Id.
    • The costs of monitoring local governments are typically much lower than the costs of monitoring larger governments. Id.
  • 552
    • 70450267455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 76-82 and accompanying text (discussing Prince George's County v. Sunrise Development Ltd. Partnership, 623 A.2d 1296 (Md. 1993))
    • See supra notes 76-82 and accompanying text (discussing Prince George's County v. Sunrise Development Ltd. Partnership, 623 A.2d 1296 (Md. 1993)).
  • 553
    • 70450280574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 92 and accompanying text (noting that distinction between preventing harm and conferring benefit is unsettled)
    • See supra note 92 and accompanying text (noting that distinction between preventing harm and conferring benefit is unsettled).
  • 554
    • 70450273149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See City of Gaylord v. Maple Manor Invs., No. 266954, 2006 WL 2270494, at *5 (Mich. Ct. App. Aug. 8, 2006) (finding that home rule cities have authority, under police power, to require homeowners to connect to city's sewer system and cease use of wells)
    • See City of Gaylord v. Maple Manor Invs., No. 266954, 2006 WL 2270494, at *5 (Mich. Ct. App. Aug. 8, 2006) (finding that home rule cities have authority, under police power, to require homeowners to connect to city's sewer system and cease use of wells).
  • 556
    • 70450240756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • for a sophisticated analysis of the systemic effect of grandfathering provisions in environmental regulations, see generally Nash & Revesz, supra note 10. For a formal model developed by Shavell to evaluate the effect of grandfathering provisions generally, see Shavell, supra note 17, at 57-67
    • for a sophisticated analysis of the systemic effect of grandfathering provisions in environmental regulations, see generally Nash & Revesz, supra note 10. For a formal model developed by Shavell to evaluate the effect of grandfathering provisions generally, see Shavell, supra note 17, at 57-67.
  • 557
    • 84869671885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Nash & Revesz, supra note 10, at 1712 ("In general, the question whether grandfathering combined with more stringent regulation of new sources will lead to more pollution is an empirical one."). There are, of course, competing and less rational accounts of how governments actually make decisions. See supra note 261 and accompanying text (discussing public choice theory)
    • See Nash & Revesz, supra note 10, at 1712 ("In general, the question whether grandfathering combined with more stringent regulation of new sources will lead to more pollution is an empirical one."). There are, of course, competing and less rational accounts of how governments actually make decisions. See supra note 261 and accompanying text (discussing public choice theory).
  • 558
    • 70450227289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 181 (citing sources discussing substantive due process)
    • See supra note 181 (citing sources discussing substantive due process).
  • 559
    • 70450240759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These are summaries of the leading takings and due process tests, discussed in Part II, supra
    • These are summaries of the leading takings and due process tests, discussed in Part II, supra.
  • 560
    • 70450253164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 168 (citing sources discussing economic substantive due process)
    • See supra note 168 (citing sources discussing economic substantive due process).
  • 561
    • 70450237043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.D (discussing nuisance exception)
    • See supra Part I.D (discussing nuisance exception).
  • 562
    • 70450231605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part IV.A (discussing incentives created by grandfathering)
    • See supra Part IV.A (discussing incentives created by grandfathering).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.