메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 61, Issue 2, 2008, Pages 271-310

Corporate crime and deterrence

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 62549117850     PISSN: 00389765     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (53)

References (176)
  • 1
    • 62549097274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Brent Fisse, Reconstructing Corporate Criminal Law: Deterrence, Retribution, Fault, and Sanctions, 56 S. CAL. L. REV. 1141, 1183 (1983) (referring to corporate criminal liability jurisprudence as the blackest hole in the theory of corporate criminal law).
    • See, e.g., Brent Fisse, Reconstructing Corporate Criminal Law: Deterrence, Retribution, Fault, and Sanctions, 56 S. CAL. L. REV. 1141, 1183 (1983) (referring to corporate criminal liability jurisprudence as "the blackest hole in the theory of corporate criminal law").
  • 2
    • 38349164137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Symposium, Corporate Criminality: Legal, Ethical, and Managerial Implications, 44 AM. CRIM.. L. REV. 1269 (2007);
    • See, e.g., Symposium, Corporate Criminality: Legal, Ethical, and Managerial Implications, 44 AM. CRIM.. L. REV. 1269 (2007);
  • 3
    • 34547285037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Brandon L. Garrett, Structural Reform Prosecution, 93 VA. L. REV. 853, 854 (2007) (In the past few years, federal prosecutions of organizations have sharply accelerated ....).
    • see also Brandon L. Garrett, Structural Reform Prosecution, 93 VA. L. REV. 853, 854 (2007) ("In the past few years, federal prosecutions of organizations have sharply accelerated ....").
  • 4
    • 38349178230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is Corporate Criminal Liability Unique?, 44
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Sara Sun Beale, Is Corporate Criminal Liability Unique?, 44 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1503, 1522 (2007).
    • (2007) AM. CRIM. L. REV , vol.1503 , pp. 1522
    • Sun Beale, S.1
  • 5
    • 62549094396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This conviction was overturned by the Supreme Court in 2005. Arthur Andersen LLP v. United States, 544 U.S. 696 2005
    • This conviction was overturned by the Supreme Court in 2005. Arthur Andersen LLP v. United States, 544 U.S. 696 (2005).
  • 6
    • 33646434812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indicting Corporations Revisited: Lessons of the Arthur Andersen Prosecution, 43
    • See
    • See Elizabeth K. Ainslie, Indicting Corporations Revisited: Lessons of the Arthur Andersen Prosecution, 43 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 107, 107 (2006).
    • (2006) AM. CRIM. L. REV , vol.107 , pp. 107
    • Ainslie, E.K.1
  • 7
    • 62549149027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See COMM. ON CAPITAL MKTS. REGULATION, INTERIM REPORT, at xii (2006) ([C]riminal enforcement against companies, in light of the experience of Arthur Andersen, should truly be a last resort....);
    • See COMM. ON CAPITAL MKTS. REGULATION, INTERIM REPORT, at xii (2006) ("[C]riminal enforcement against companies, in light of the experience of Arthur Andersen, should truly be a last resort....");
  • 8
    • 62549105318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ainslie, supra note 5, at 110 ([C]riminal prosecution of business entities should be considered only when it is clear that no civil sanction... will suffice to deter the corporate misconduct.).
    • Ainslie, supra note 5, at 110 ("[C]riminal prosecution of business entities should be considered only when it is clear that no civil sanction... will suffice to deter the corporate misconduct.").
  • 9
    • 0042688760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see V.S. Khanna, Corporate Criminal Liability: What Purpose Does It Serve?, 109 HARV. L. REV. 1477, .1499-1512 (1996) (considering the extent to which reputational penalties could deter corporate crime).
    • But see V.S. Khanna, Corporate Criminal Liability: What Purpose Does It Serve?, 109 HARV. L. REV. 1477, .1499-1512 (1996) (considering the extent to which reputational penalties could deter corporate crime).
  • 10
    • 33745945074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Christopher A. Wray & Robert K. Hur, Corporate Criminal Prosecution in a Post-Enron World: The Thompson Memo in Theory and Practice, 43 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1095, 1097 (2006) (referring to such penalties as providing deterrence on a massive scale (quoting Memorandum from Larry D. Thompson, Deputy Attorney Gen., to Heads of Dep't Components, U.S. Attorneys (Jan. 20, 2003), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/cftf/corporate-guidelines.htm)).
    • See, e.g., Christopher A. Wray & Robert K. Hur, Corporate Criminal Prosecution in a Post-Enron World: The Thompson Memo in Theory and Practice, 43 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1095, 1097 (2006) (referring to such penalties as providing "deterrence on a massive scale" (quoting Memorandum from Larry D. Thompson, Deputy Attorney Gen., to Heads of Dep't Components, U.S. Attorneys (Jan. 20, 2003), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/cftf/corporate-guidelines.htm)).
  • 11
    • 62549101343 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is difficult to find an economic justification for corporate sanctions that aim at putting firms out of business, as optimal deterrence requires that penalties equal, social harm (discounted by the probability of detection, See Gary S. Becker, Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach, 76 J. POL. ECON. 169, 192 1968, To be sure, an offense may be strictly undesirable from a social perspective, thereby justifying an attempt to secure full deterrence. Yet, legal economists believe that this objective should not dictate the magnitude of firm-level sanctions
    • It is difficult to find an economic justification for corporate sanctions that aim at putting firms out of business, as optimal deterrence requires that penalties equal, social harm (discounted by the probability of detection). See Gary S. Becker, Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach, 76 J. POL. ECON. 169, 192 (1968). To be sure, an offense may be strictly undesirable from a social perspective, thereby justifying an attempt to secure full deterrence. Yet, legal economists believe that this objective should not dictate the magnitude of firm-level sanctions.
  • 12
    • 0347306177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Daniel R. Fischel & Alan O. Sykes, Corporate Crime, 25 J. LEGAL STUD. 3.19, 322-27 (1996).
    • See Daniel R. Fischel & Alan O. Sykes, Corporate Crime, 25 J. LEGAL STUD. 3.19, 322-27 (1996).
  • 13
    • 62549165820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Garrett, supra note 2, at 859 ('The DOJ could seek to impose optimally deterrent fines, but the dire collateral consequences of such an approach make it highly undesirable.).
    • See Garrett, supra note 2, at 859 ('The DOJ could seek to impose optimally deterrent fines, but the dire collateral consequences of such an approach make it highly undesirable.").
  • 14
    • 62549153569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kathleen F. Brickey, Andersen's Fall from Grace, 81 WASH. U. L.Q. 917, 929 (2003) (Under the respondeat superior rule applicable to federal criminal trials, the acts and intent of agents at any level of an entity's hierarchy-including those at the lower end of the organizational ladder-are imputable to the firm.).
    • See Kathleen F. Brickey, Andersen's Fall from Grace, 81 WASH. U. L.Q. 917, 929 (2003) ("Under the respondeat superior rule applicable to federal criminal trials, the acts and intent of agents at any level of an entity's hierarchy-including those at the lower end of the organizational ladder-are imputable to the firm.").
  • 15
    • 0043262792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For suggestions that imposing liability for misconduct committed by employees against corporate policy or without management's involvement is unfair, see William S. Laufer & Alan Strudler, Corporate Intentionality, Desert, and Variants of Vicarious Liability, 37 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1285, 1297 2000
    • For suggestions that imposing liability for misconduct committed by employees against corporate policy or without management's involvement is unfair, see William S. Laufer & Alan Strudler, Corporate Intentionality, Desert, and Variants of Vicarious Liability, 37 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1285, 1297 (2000).
  • 16
    • 34248564846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compelled Cooperation and the New Corporate Criminal Procedure, 82
    • noting that the threat of indictment induces companies to hand over internal documents and rat out individual employees as targets for prosecution, See
    • See Lisa Kern Griffin, Compelled Cooperation and the New Corporate Criminal Procedure, 82 N.Y.U. L. REV. 311, 331 (2007) (noting that the threat of indictment induces companies to hand over internal documents and rat out individual employees as targets for prosecution).
    • (2007) N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.311 , pp. 331
    • Kern Griffin, L.1
  • 17
    • 62549100005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Julie Creswell, U.S. Indictment for Big Law Firm in Class Actions, N.Y. TIMES, May 19, 2006, at Al (reporting the federal indictment of Milberg Weiss Bershad & Schulman, a leading U.S. class-action law firm, for making illegal payments to clients);
    • See also Julie Creswell, U.S. Indictment for Big Law Firm in Class Actions, N.Y. TIMES, May 19, 2006, at Al (reporting the federal indictment of Milberg Weiss Bershad & Schulman, a leading U.S. class-action law firm, for making illegal payments to clients);
  • 18
    • 62549084728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nathan Koppel, Fatal Vision: How a Bid to Boost Profits Led to a Law Firm's Demise, WALL ST. J., May 17, 2007, at Al (describing the demise of a prominent Dallas law firm as a result of an investigation concerning its role in marketing illegal tax shelters).
    • Nathan Koppel, Fatal Vision: How a Bid to Boost Profits Led to a Law Firm's Demise, WALL ST. J., May 17, 2007, at Al (describing the demise of a prominent Dallas law firm as a result of an investigation concerning its role in marketing illegal tax shelters).
  • 19
    • 62549142686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The profit-sharing quality of professional firms might also improve the monitoring incentives among partners. See, e.g, Armen A. Alchian & Harold Demsetz, Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization, 62 AM. ECON. REV. 777, 786 1972, suggesting that profit-sharing induces monitoring of each employee by every other employee
    • The profit-sharing quality of professional firms might also improve the monitoring incentives among partners. See, e.g., Armen A. Alchian & Harold Demsetz, Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization, 62 AM. ECON. REV. 777, 786 (1972) (suggesting that profit-sharing induces monitoring of each employee by every other employee).
  • 20
    • 62549143523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Eugene Kandel & Edward P. Lazear, Peer Pressure and Partnerships, 100 J. POL. ECON. 801, 813 (1992) (indicating that there is little incentive to engage in mutual monitoring, even with profit sharing).
    • But see Eugene Kandel & Edward P. Lazear, Peer Pressure and Partnerships, 100 J. POL. ECON. 801, 813 (1992) (indicating that "there is little incentive to engage in mutual monitoring, even with profit sharing").
  • 21
    • 62549116985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henry Hansmann labels this effect of profit sharing self monitoring. See Henry Hansmann, When Does Worker Ownership Work? ESOPs, Law Firms, Codetermination, and Economic Democracy, 99 YALE L.J. 1749, 1762 (1990).
    • Henry Hansmann labels this effect of profit sharing "self monitoring." See Henry Hansmann, When Does Worker Ownership Work? ESOPs, Law Firms, Codetermination, and Economic Democracy, 99 YALE L.J. 1749, 1762 (1990).
  • 22
    • 62549102927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Poonam Puri, Judgment Proofing the Profession, 15 GEO. J. LEGAL ETHICS 1, 9-10 (2001) (listing rapid growth, globalization, and increased specialization as factors that explain the inability of law firms to monitor their members).
    • See Poonam Puri, Judgment Proofing the Profession, 15 GEO. J. LEGAL ETHICS 1, 9-10 (2001) (listing rapid growth, globalization, and increased specialization as factors that explain the inability of law firms to monitor their members).
  • 23
    • 0942278828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Sanctions, 56
    • For a comprehensive analysis of collective sanctions, see
    • For a comprehensive analysis of collective sanctions, see Daryl J. Levinson, Collective Sanctions, 56 STAN. L. REV. 345 (2003).
    • (2003) STAN. L. REV , vol.345
    • Levinson, D.J.1
  • 24
    • 34047252038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Punishing the Innocent Along with the Guilty: The Economics of Individual Versus Group Punishment, 36
    • See also
    • See also Thomas J. Miceli & Kathleen Segerson, Punishing the Innocent Along with the Guilty: The Economics of Individual Versus Group Punishment, 36 J. LEGAL STUD. 81 (2007).
    • (2007) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.81
    • Miceli, T.J.1    Segerson, K.2
  • 25
    • 62549161734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economists have shown that, under certain conditions, it may be desirable to lower the sanctions on relatively light offenses in order to enhance the deterrence of more severe ones. See generally Dilip Mookherjee & I.P.L. Png, Marginal Deterrence in Enforcement of Law, 102 J. POL. ECON. 1039 (1994);
    • Economists have shown that, under certain conditions, it may be desirable to lower the sanctions on relatively light offenses in order to enhance the deterrence of more severe ones. See generally Dilip Mookherjee & I.P.L. Png, Marginal Deterrence in Enforcement of Law, 102 J. POL. ECON. 1039 (1994);
  • 26
    • 0010950856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steven Shavell, A Note on Marginal Deterrence, 12 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 345 (1992).
    • Steven Shavell, A Note on Marginal Deterrence, 12 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 345 (1992).
  • 28
    • 62549119123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Memorandum from Larry D. Thompson, Deputy Attorney Gen., to Heads of Dep't Components, U.S. Attorneys, supra note 8.
    • See Memorandum from Larry D. Thompson, Deputy Attorney Gen., to Heads of Dep't Components, U.S. Attorneys, supra note 8.
  • 29
    • 62549135678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Jonathan Macey & Hillary A. Sale, Observations on the Role of Commodification, Independence, and Governance in the Accounting Industry, 48 VILL. L. REV. 1167, 1181 (2003) (arguing that the shift to the LLP organization form deprived members of accounting firms of incentives to monitor their peers);
    • See, e.g., Jonathan Macey & Hillary A. Sale, Observations on the Role of Commodification, Independence, and Governance in the Accounting Industry, 48 VILL. L. REV. 1167, 1181 (2003) (arguing that the shift to the LLP organization form deprived members of accounting firms of incentives to monitor their peers);
  • 30
    • 62549123682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deborah L. Rhode & Paul D. Paton, Lawyers, Ethics, and Enron, 8 STAN. J.L. BUS. & FIN. 9, 30-31 (2002) (Reducing this insulation from accountability could give lawyers greater incentives to address collégial misconduct and to establish the internal oversight structures that can check abuses.).
    • Deborah L. Rhode & Paul D. Paton, Lawyers, Ethics, and Enron, 8 STAN. J.L. BUS. & FIN. 9, 30-31 (2002) ("Reducing this insulation from accountability could give lawyers greater incentives to address collégial misconduct and to establish the internal oversight structures that can check abuses.").
  • 31
    • 38349138849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Pamela H. Buey, Trends in Corporate Criminal Prosecutions, 44 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1287, 1288 (2007) ([T]here is no question that criminal prosecution of a corporation has a tremendous impact on the corporation and its community, employees, customers and lenders.);
    • See, e.g., Pamela H. Buey, Trends in Corporate Criminal Prosecutions, 44 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1287, 1288 (2007) ("[T]here is no question that criminal prosecution of a corporation has a tremendous impact on the corporation and its community, employees, customers and lenders.");
  • 32
    • 62549092686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kern. Griffin, supra note 12, at 330 (noting that prosecutors may decide against prosecuting business organizations because they are justifiably reluctant to cause such extensive economic harm);
    • Kern. Griffin, supra note 12, at 330 (noting that prosecutors may decide against prosecuting business organizations because they are "justifiably reluctant to cause such extensive economic harm");
  • 33
    • 62549086565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eric Holder, Op-Ed., Don't Indict WorldCom, WALL ST. J., July 30, 2002, at A14 ([T]o ensure that even more innocent Americans are not harmed, prosecutors must not give in to the pressures of the day and feel compelled to indict more corporations simply because they can.).
    • Eric Holder, Op-Ed., Don't Indict WorldCom, WALL ST. J., July 30, 2002, at A14 ("[T]o ensure that even more innocent Americans are not harmed, prosecutors must not give in to the pressures of the day and feel compelled to indict more corporations simply because they can.").
  • 34
    • 62549116579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. SENTENCING GUIDELINES MANUAL § 8C1.1 (2008).
    • U.S. SENTENCING GUIDELINES MANUAL § 8C1.1 (2008).
  • 35
    • 62549126469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Christopher A. Wray, Note, Corporate Probation Under the New Organizational Sentencing Guidelines, 101 YALE L.J. 2017, 2027 (1992).
    • See Christopher A. Wray, Note, Corporate Probation Under the New Organizational Sentencing Guidelines, 101 YALE L.J. 2017, 2027 (1992).
  • 36
    • 0242711444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Mitchell F. Crusto, Green Business: Should We Revoke Corporate Charters for Environmental Violations?, 63 LA. L. REV. 175, 189-92 (2003) (analyzing recent proposals to revoke the charter of corporations that committed crimes against the environment).
    • See, e.g., Mitchell F. Crusto, Green Business: Should We Revoke Corporate Charters for Environmental Violations?, 63 LA. L. REV. 175, 189-92 (2003) (analyzing recent proposals to revoke the charter of corporations that committed crimes against the environment).
  • 37
    • 62549164744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Thomas Linzey, Awakening a Sleeping Giant: Creating a Quasi-Private Cause of Action for Revoking Corporate Charters in Response to Environmental Violations, 13 PACE ENVTL. L. REV. 219, 221 (1995) (The power... to revoke corporate charters, and thereby end the corporate life, may be the only effective deterrent for corporate polluters.).
    • See, e.g., Thomas Linzey, Awakening a Sleeping Giant: Creating a Quasi-Private Cause of Action for Revoking Corporate Charters in Response to Environmental Violations, 13 PACE ENVTL. L. REV. 219, 221 (1995) ("The power... to revoke corporate charters, and thereby end the corporate life, may be the only effective deterrent for corporate polluters.").
  • 38
    • 62549095891 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. SENTENCING GUIDELINES MANUAL § 8C3.3.
    • See U.S. SENTENCING GUIDELINES MANUAL § 8C3.3.
  • 39
    • 62549148193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. Eureka Labs., Inc., 103 F.3d 908, 910, 912 (9th Cir. 1996) (holding that the Sentencing Guidelines do not preclude courts from imposing a fine jeopardizing the firm's continued viability).
    • See United States v. Eureka Labs., Inc., 103 F.3d 908, 910, 912 (9th Cir. 1996) (holding that the Sentencing Guidelines do not preclude courts from imposing a fine jeopardizing the firm's continued viability).
  • 40
    • 62549130323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ainslie, supra note 5, at 107
    • See Ainslie, supra note 5, at 107.
  • 41
    • 62549124557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The SEC prohibits any accounting firm convicted of a felony from serving as the auditor of a publicly traded corporation. See 17 C.F.R. § 201.102(e)(2, 2008, Stephan Landsman, Death of an Accountant: The Jury Convicts Arthur Andersen of Obstruction of Justice, 78 CHI, KENT L. REV. 1203, 1223-24 2003
    • The SEC prohibits any accounting firm convicted of a felony from serving as the auditor of a publicly traded corporation. See 17 C.F.R. § 201.102(e)(2) (2008); Stephan Landsman, Death of an Accountant: The Jury Convicts Arthur Andersen of Obstruction of Justice, 78 CHI.- KENT L. REV. 1203, 1223-24 (2003).
  • 42
    • 62549122933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra Part IV.B.
    • See discussion infra Part IV.B.
  • 43
    • 62549099539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See
    • § 93d, 2000
    • See 12 U.S.C. § 93(d) (2000).
    • 12 U.S.C
  • 44
    • 62549098176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Commodity Exchange Act, 7 U.S.C. § 12a 2000
    • See Commodity Exchange Act, 7 U.S.C. § 12a (2000);
  • 45
    • 62549083882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Deposit Insurance Act
    • § 1818(a)2, 2000
    • Federal Deposit Insurance Act, 12 U.S.C. § 1818(a)(2) (2000);
    • 12 U.S.C
  • 46
    • 62549100008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Securities Act of 1933, 15 U.S.C. § 77tb, 2000
    • Securities Act of 1933, 15 U.S.C. § 77t(b) (2000);
  • 47
    • 62549100884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. §§ 78o(b)(4, 6, 78ud, e, 2000
    • Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. §§ 78o(b)(4)-(6), 78u(d)-(e) (2000);
  • 48
    • 62549109984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Investment Advisers Act of 1940, 15 U.S.C. § 80b-3e, f, 2000
    • Investment Advisers Act of 1940, 15 U.S.C. § 80b-3(e)-(f) (2000);
  • 49
    • 84876227045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social Security Act
    • § 1320a-7 2000
    • Social Security Act, 42 U.S.C. § 1320a-7 (2000).
    • 42 U.S.C
  • 50
    • 84978293665 scopus 로고
    • Civil Prosecution of Health Care Fraud, 30
    • discussing the exclusion remedy for health care fraud under which providers might become ineligible to receive any payment under Medicare or any state health care program, See
    • See Pamela H. Buey, Civil Prosecution of Health Care Fraud, 30 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 693, 720-37 (1995) (discussing the exclusion remedy for health care fraud under which providers might become ineligible to receive any payment under Medicare or any state health care program).
    • (1995) WAKE FOREST L. REV , vol.693 , pp. 720-737
    • Buey, P.H.1
  • 51
    • 62549121203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 48 C.F.R. § 9.406-2 (2008) (listing causes for debarment).
    • See 48 C.F.R. § 9.406-2 (2008) (listing causes for debarment).
  • 52
    • 33751106679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Too Little Too Late: An Analysis of the General Service Administration's Proposed Debarment of WorldCom, 56
    • discussing mandatory debarment, See
    • See Andrew T. Schutz, Comment, Too Little Too Late: An Analysis of the General Service Administration's Proposed Debarment of WorldCom, 56 ADMIN. L. REV. 1263, 1273 (2004) (discussing mandatory debarment).
    • (2004) ADMIN. L. REV , vol.1263 , pp. 1273
    • Andrew, T.1    Schutz, C.2
  • 53
    • 50849104655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 7, at, The most powerful sanction that society can impose on a corporation is lost reputation or stigma
    • Khanna, supra note 7, at 1499 ('The most powerful sanction that society can impose on a corporation is lost reputation or stigma.").
    • supra , pp. 1499
    • Khanna1
  • 54
    • 34248562199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Preet Bharara, Corporations Cry Uncle and Their Employees Cry Foul: Rethinking Prosecutorial Pressure on Corporate Defendants, 44 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 53, 73 (2007) ([Corporate defendants, subject as they are to market pressures, may not be able to survive indictment, much less conviction and sentencing.);
    • See, e.g., Preet Bharara, Corporations Cry Uncle and Their Employees Cry Foul: Rethinking Prosecutorial Pressure on Corporate Defendants, 44 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 53, 73 (2007) ("[Corporate defendants, subject as they are to market pressures, may not be able to survive indictment, much less conviction and sentencing.");
  • 55
    • 62549116170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pamela H. Buey, Organizational Sentencing Guidelines: The Cart Before the Horse, 71 WASH. U. L.Q. 329, 352 (1993) (In some instances adverse publicity alone can cause corporate devastation ....).
    • Pamela H. Buey, Organizational Sentencing Guidelines: The Cart Before the Horse, 71 WASH. U. L.Q. 329, 352 (1993) ("In some instances adverse publicity alone can cause corporate devastation ....").
  • 56
    • 62549094864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Khanna, supra note 37, at 1508-09.
    • See Khanna, supra note 37, at 1508-09.
  • 57
    • 62549090184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a thorough analysis of the indictment and its aftermath, see Bruce H. Kobayashi & Larry E. Ribstein, The Hypocrisy of the Milberg Indictment: The Need for a Coherent Framework on Paying for Cooperation in Litigation, 2 J. BUS. & TECH. L. 369, 372-75 (2007).
    • For a thorough analysis of the indictment and its aftermath, see Bruce H. Kobayashi & Larry E. Ribstein, The Hypocrisy of the Milberg Indictment: The Need for a Coherent Framework on Paying for Cooperation in Litigation, 2 J. BUS. & TECH. L. 369, 372-75 (2007).
  • 58
    • 62549129491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The firm agreed to pay $75 million to settle the criminal charges against it. See Jonathan D. Glater, Big Penalty Set for Law Firm, but Not a Trial
    • June 17, at
    • The firm agreed to pay $75 million to settle the criminal charges against it. See Jonathan D. Glater, Big Penalty Set for Law Firm, but Not a Trial, N.Y. TIMES, June 17, 2008, at A1.
    • (2008) N.Y. TIMES
  • 59
    • 62549141823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Nathan Koppel, Fatal Vision: How a Bid to Boost Profits Led. to a Law Firm's Demise, WALL ST. J., May 17, 2007, at Al (describing the demise of Jenkens & Gilchrist).
    • See Nathan Koppel, Fatal Vision: How a Bid to Boost Profits Led. to a Law Firm's Demise, WALL ST. J., May 17, 2007, at Al (describing the demise of Jenkens & Gilchrist).
  • 60
    • 33646724487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Blaming Function of Entity Criminal Liability, 81
    • Managers and their counsel apparently do not see civil and criminal sanctions as substitutes, See
    • See Samuel W. Buell, The Blaming Function of Entity Criminal Liability, 81 IND. L.J. 473, 504 (2006) ("Managers and their counsel apparently do not see civil and criminal sanctions as substitutes....").
    • (2006) IND. L.J , vol.473 , pp. 504
    • Buell, S.W.1
  • 61
    • 62549120772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 505-07 (assessing the practice of firms waiving their procedural safeguards to avert an indictment); Kern Griffin, supra note 12, at 327 (Because virtually no company will risk indictment, prosecutors have come to expect compliance with every government demand.).
    • Id. at 505-07 (assessing the practice of firms waiving their procedural safeguards to avert an indictment); Kern Griffin, supra note 12, at 327 ("Because virtually no company will risk indictment, prosecutors have come to expect compliance with every government demand.").
  • 62
    • 62549128213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Brickey, supra note 11, at 929 (Under the respondeat superior rule applicable to federal criminal trials, the acts and intent of agents at any level of an entity's hierarchyincluding those at the lower end of the organizational ladder-are imputable to the firm..).
    • See Brickey, supra note 11, at 929 ("Under the respondeat superior rule applicable to federal criminal trials, the acts and intent of agents at any level of an entity's hierarchyincluding those at the lower end of the organizational ladder-are imputable to the firm..").
  • 63
    • 34547195189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Samuel W. Buell, Criminal Procedure Within the Firm, 59 STAN. L. REV. 1613, 1662 (2007) (Under current law, a firm, faces criminal liability for virtually any criminal act by an agent.).
    • Samuel W. Buell, Criminal Procedure Within the Firm, 59 STAN. L. REV. 1613, 1662 (2007) ("Under current law, a firm, faces criminal liability for virtually any criminal act by an agent.").
  • 64
    • 62549127762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For suggestions that imposing liability for misconduct committed by employees against corporate policy or without management's involvement is unfair, see Laufer & Strudler, supra note 11, at 1297
    • For suggestions that imposing liability for misconduct committed by employees against corporate policy or without management's involvement is unfair, see Laufer & Strudler, supra note 11, at 1297.
  • 65
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 85-86
    • See infra text accompanying notes 85-86.
    • See infra
  • 66
    • 19744372949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Note, Collective Sanctions and Large Law Firm Discipline, 118 HARV. L. REV. 2336, 2337 (2005) (arguing that the law should provide law firms with incentives to prevent wrongdoing by nonpartners).
    • But see Note, Collective Sanctions and Large Law Firm Discipline, 118 HARV. L. REV. 2336, 2337 (2005) (arguing that the law should provide law firms with incentives to prevent wrongdoing by nonpartners).
  • 67
    • 0000865676 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of the Choice Between Enterprise and Personal Liability for Accidents, 70
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Lewis A. Kornhauser, An Economic Analysis of the Choice Between Enterprise and Personal Liability for Accidents, 70 CAL. L. REV. 1345 (1982);
    • (1982) CAL. L. REV , vol.1345
    • Kornhauser, L.A.1
  • 68
    • 84924434331 scopus 로고
    • Corporate Liability Strategies and the Costs of Legal Controls, 93
    • Reinier Kraakman, Corporate Liability Strategies and the Costs of Legal Controls, 93 YALE L.J. 857 (1984);
    • (1984) YALE L.J , vol.857
    • Kraakman, R.1
  • 69
    • 21644458084 scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Vicarious Liability, 93
    • Alan O. Sykes, The Economics of Vicarious Liability, 93 YALE L.J. 1231 (1984).
    • (1984) YALE L.J , vol.1231
    • Sykes, A.O.1
  • 70
    • 0042260485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another common justification for entity-level liability is that wrongdoers might lack the financial resources to pay fines. See V.S. Khanna, Corporate Liability Standards: When Should Corporations Be Held Criminally Liable, 37 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1239, 1243-44 2000, While it can justify the prevalence of vicarious liability in torts, the assumption that wrongdoers are judgment-proof cannot satisfactorily explain the decision to hold firms criminally liable. The government can overcome offenders' limited wealth by subjecting them to imprisonment. Indeed, the government's ability to impose jail sentences explains why personal liability is essential even under a regime of corporate criminal liability
    • Another common justification for entity-level liability is that wrongdoers might lack the financial resources to pay fines. See V.S. Khanna, Corporate Liability Standards: When Should Corporations Be Held Criminally Liable?, 37 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1239, 1243-44 (2000). While it can justify the prevalence of vicarious liability in torts, the assumption that wrongdoers are judgment-proof cannot satisfactorily explain the decision to hold firms criminally liable. The government can overcome offenders' limited wealth by subjecting them to imprisonment. Indeed, the government's ability to impose jail sentences explains why personal liability is essential even under a regime of corporate criminal liability.
  • 71
    • 0000828504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell, Should Employees Be Subject to Fines and Imprisonment Given the Existence of Corporate Liability?, 13 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 239 (1993).
    • See A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell, Should Employees Be Subject to Fines and Imprisonment Given the Existence of Corporate Liability?, 13 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 239 (1993).
  • 72
    • 0031512311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Controlling Corporate Misconduct: An Analysis of Corporate Liability Regimes, 72
    • See
    • See Jennifer Arlen & Reinier Kraakman, Controlling Corporate Misconduct: An Analysis of Corporate Liability Regimes, 72 N.Y.U. L. REV. 687, 695-96 (1997).
    • (1997) N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.687 , pp. 695-696
    • Arlen, J.1    Kraakman, R.2
  • 73
    • 2442577025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vu, Corporate Criminal Liability: Patchwork Verdicts and the Problem of Locating a Guilty Agent, 104
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Stacey Neumann Vu, Corporate Criminal Liability: Patchwork Verdicts and the Problem of Locating a Guilty Agent, 104 COLUM. L. REV. 459 (2004).
    • (2004) COLUM. L. REV , vol.459
    • Neumann, S.1
  • 74
    • 62549140136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Subjecting firms to liability also might induce them to adopt an optimal scale of production. See Khanna, supra note 7, at 1496.
    • Subjecting firms to liability also might induce them to adopt an optimal scale of production. See Khanna, supra note 7, at 1496.
  • 75
    • 62549158245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While commentators normally agree on the justification for firms' vicarious liability, there is disagreement whether this liability should be criminal or civil. See, e.g, id
    • While commentators normally agree on the justification for firms' vicarious liability, there is disagreement whether this liability should be criminal or civil. See, e.g., id.
  • 76
    • 62549118246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When members are held liable for their misconduct, the effect that we identify in this Part is less likely to take place, as each member will bear the cost of committing misconduct regardless of other members' conduct. As explained earlier, however, the difficulty of identifying culpable agents within the firm provides the principal justification for subjecting firms to liability.
    • When members are held liable for their misconduct, the effect that we identify in this Part is less likely to take place, as each member will bear the cost of committing misconduct regardless of other members' conduct. As explained earlier, however, the difficulty of identifying culpable agents within the firm provides the principal justification for subjecting firms to liability.
  • 77
    • 62549110417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This assumption is made for simplicity only. In a more realistic setting, this Part's analysis applies to the extent that monitoring is imperfect. We return to this issue when we consider the negligence standard. See infra Part IV.B. We also assume that firms cannot turn in wrongdoers after the offense has been committed in order to induce prosecutors to waive a criminal indictment
    • This assumption is made for simplicity only. In a more realistic setting, this Part's analysis applies to the extent that monitoring is imperfect. We return to this issue when we consider the negligence standard. See infra Part IV.B. We also assume that firms cannot turn in wrongdoers after the offense has been committed in order to induce prosecutors to waive a criminal indictment.
  • 78
    • 62549142688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We discuss such an example below. See infra Part IV.B.
    • We discuss such an example below. See infra Part IV.B.
  • 79
    • 62549167099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The analysis assumes that the firm as such does not benefit from wrongdoing. In other words, we assume that corporate crime is to a large extent the byproduct of the socalled agency problem.. See, e.g., Jonathan R. Macey, Agency Theory and the Criminal Liability of Organizations, 71 B.U. L. REV. 315, 319 (1991) (The real aim of criminal behavior by organizations is to advance the careers of the responsible corporate actors.).
    • The analysis assumes that the firm as such does not benefit from wrongdoing. In other words, we assume that corporate crime is to a large extent the byproduct of the socalled agency problem.. See, e.g., Jonathan R. Macey, Agency Theory and the Criminal Liability of Organizations, 71 B.U. L. REV. 315, 319 (1991) ("The real aim of criminal behavior by organizations is to advance the careers of the responsible corporate actors.").
  • 80
    • 33749855378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Organizational Misconduct: Beyond the Principal-Agent Model, 32
    • For a critique of this perception of corporate crime, see generally
    • For a critique of this perception of corporate crime, see generally Kimberly D. Krawiec, Organizational Misconduct: Beyond the Principal-Agent Model, 32 FLA. ST. U. L. REV. 571 (2005).
    • (2005) FLA. ST. U. L. REV , vol.571
    • Krawiec, K.D.1
  • 81
    • 62549116580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We assume for simplicity that the probabilities of conviction for each violation are statistically independent. Relaxing this assumption would not change our qualitative results
    • We assume for simplicity that the probabilities of conviction for each violation are statistically independent. Relaxing this assumption would not change our qualitative results.
  • 82
    • 62549160898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John's loss when the firm unravels is 80. The probability that the firm, will unravel due to John's misconduct is 0.9. John's expected loss thus equals 0.9 × 80 = 72.
    • John's loss when the firm unravels is 80. The probability that the firm, will unravel due to John's misconduct is 0.9. John's expected loss thus equals 0.9 × 80 = 72.
  • 83
    • 62549127761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This probability equals 0.9, 1, 0.9 × 0.9
    • This probability equals 0.9 + (1 - 0.9) × 0.9.
  • 84
    • 62549139212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By implied probability we mean the probability that a member will commit misconduct given that she will do so if and only if her benefit is higher than the threshold
    • By implied probability we mean the probability that a member will commit misconduct given that she will do so if and only if her benefit is higher than the threshold.
  • 85
    • 62549137423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We thus restrict attention to symmetric equilibria only
    • We thus restrict attention to symmetric equilibria only.
  • 86
    • 62549108665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The same analysis can be applied for any other probability distribution of benefits. Note, however, that if the benefit could never exceed 80 (discounting for the probability of detection), the threat of putting the firm out of business would likely deter all members from committing misconduct.
    • The same analysis can be applied for any other probability distribution of benefits. Note, however, that if the benefit could never exceed 80 (discounting for the probability of detection), the threat of putting the firm out of business would likely deter all members from committing misconduct.
  • 87
    • 62549147780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It can be verified that at the maximum p=0.69, and that B*=27.64. The explanation for this result is that the strategic environment significantly reduces the magnitude of the effective penalty facing each member
    • It can be verified that at the maximum p=0.69, and that B*=27.64. The explanation for this result is that the strategic environment significantly reduces the magnitude of the effective penalty facing each member.
  • 88
    • 62549157790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Becker, supra note 9, at .176;
    • See Becker, supra note 9, at .176;
  • 89
    • 84977413772 scopus 로고
    • The Optimal Tradeoff Between the Probability and the Magnitude of Fines, 69
    • A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell, The Optimal Tradeoff Between the Probability and the Magnitude of Fines, 69 AM. ECON. REV. 880 (1979).
    • (1979) AM. ECON. REV , vol.880
    • Mitchell Polinsky, A.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 90
    • 62549087846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra nots 18.
    • See supra nots 18.
  • 91
    • 62549145756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The entity-level fine is 80. Each member's share of the entity-level fine is 40. Since the probability of detection is 0.9, the expected liability cost for each member is 0.9 × 40 = 36.
    • The entity-level fine is 80. Each member's share of the entity-level fine is 40. Since the probability of detection is 0.9, the expected liability cost for each member is 0.9 × 40 = 36.
  • 92
    • 62549143524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For similar reasons, the pervasiveness standard may under certain conditions encourage wrongdoing. A member who believes that other members will always refrain from wrongdoing will expect her misconduct to go unpunished under this standard
    • For similar reasons, the pervasiveness standard may under certain conditions encourage wrongdoing. A member who believes that other members will always refrain from wrongdoing will expect her misconduct to go unpunished under this standard.
  • 93
    • 62549134010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deterrence theory predicts that entity liability will produce overdeterrence when the expected sanction exceeds the expected social harm
    • Deterrence theory predicts that entity liability will produce overdeterrence when the expected sanction exceeds the expected social harm..
  • 94
    • 62549164745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 52, at 696 & n.22.
    • See Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 52, at 696 & n.22.
  • 95
    • 62549088287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The corporate death sanction might also adversely affect ex post measures. For example, a firm that is surely going out of business has no reason to impose private sanctions on culpable individuals
    • The corporate death sanction might also adversely affect ex post measures. For example, a firm that is surely going out of business has no reason to impose private sanctions on culpable individuals.
  • 96
    • 62549109102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under the Federal Sentencing Guidelines for Business Organizations, firms' monitoring policies can affect the magnitude of the sanction imposed on the firm. See Krawiec, supra note 59, at 584 (noting that fines can be reduc[ed] to as little as one-twentieth or increase[ed] by as much as four hundred percent based on the presence of an internal compliance program). This mitigation, however, is unavailable when criminal liability triggers the firm's unraveling.
    • Under the Federal Sentencing Guidelines for Business Organizations, firms' monitoring policies can affect the magnitude of the sanction imposed on the firm. See Krawiec, supra note 59, at 584 (noting that fines can be "reduc[ed] to as little as one-twentieth or increase[ed] by as much as four hundred percent" based on the presence of an internal compliance program). This mitigation, however, is unavailable when criminal liability triggers the firm's unraveling.
  • 97
    • 62549117796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To focus on the impact of criminal liability on the incentives of firms, we assume in this Part that employees face no meaningful, threat of personal liability for their misconduct.
    • To focus on the impact of criminal liability on the incentives of firms, we assume in this Part that employees face no meaningful, threat of personal liability for their misconduct.
  • 98
    • 62549149028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • With a probability of 0.32, only one offense will take place and the firm will pay a fine of $100. With a probability of 0.64, two offenses will take place. Even if two offenses take place, the effective fine remains $100. The total expected cost under Moderate monitoring is thus 0.32 × 100, 0.64 × 100
    • With a probability of 0.32, only one offense will take place and the firm will pay a fine of $100. With a probability of 0.64, two offenses will take place. Even if two offenses take place, the effective fine remains $100. The total expected cost under Moderate monitoring is thus 0.32 × 100 + 0.64 × 100.
  • 99
    • 62549157370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • With a probability of 0.5, only one offense will take place and the firm will pay a fine of $100. With a probability of 0.25, two offenses will take place. Again, even if two offenses take place, the effective fine remains $100. The total expected cost under Extensive monitoring is thus 0.5 × 100, 0.25 × 100
    • With a probability of 0.5, only one offense will take place and the firm will pay a fine of $100. With a probability of 0.25, two offenses will take place. Again, even if two offenses take place, the effective fine remains $100. The total expected cost under Extensive monitoring is thus 0.5 × 100 + 0.25 × 100.
  • 100
    • 62549149435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • With a probability of 0.32, only one employee commits fraud, thereby subjecting the firm to a fine of 50. With a probability of 0.64, two employees will commit fraud, thereby subjecting the firm to a total fine of .100
    • With a probability of 0.32, only one employee commits fraud, thereby subjecting the firm to a fine of 50. With a probability of 0.64, two employees will commit fraud, thereby subjecting the firm to a total fine of .100.
  • 101
    • 62549115315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • With a probability of 0.5, only one employee commits fraud, thereby subjecting the firm to a sanction of 50. With a probability of 0.25, two employees will commit fraud, thereby subjecting the firm to a total fine of 100
    • With a probability of 0.5, only one employee commits fraud, thereby subjecting the firm to a sanction of 50. With a probability of 0.25, two employees will commit fraud, thereby subjecting the firm to a total fine of 100.
  • 102
    • 62549145757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recall that the probability that two employees will commit fraud under Moderate monitoring is 0.64.
    • Recall that the probability that two employees will commit fraud under Moderate monitoring is 0.64.
  • 103
    • 62549126470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The probability that two employees will commit fraud under Extensive monitoring is 0.25.
    • The probability that two employees will commit fraud under Extensive monitoring is 0.25.
  • 104
    • 62549150778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A negligence standard also is likely to achieve this goal. See infra Part IV.B.
    • A negligence standard also is likely to achieve this goal. See infra Part IV.B.
  • 105
    • 62549101344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For some offenses, even a single offense can indicate that the firm did not monitor. We discuss this point below. See infra Part III.B.2.
    • For some offenses, even a single offense can indicate that the firm did not monitor. We discuss this point below. See infra Part III.B.2.
  • 106
    • 62549094395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 59
    • See supra note 59.
  • 107
    • 62549090183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fastow and Arthur Andersen: Some Reflections on Corporate Criminality, Victim Status, and Retribution, 1 OHIO ST
    • See
    • See Alan C. Michaels, Fastow and Arthur Andersen: Some Reflections on Corporate Criminality, Victim Status, and Retribution, 1 OHIO ST. J. CRIM. L. 551, 554 (2004).
    • (2004) J. CRIM , vol.50 , Issue.551 , pp. 554
    • Michaels, A.C.1
  • 108
    • 62549102926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Buell, supra note 46, at 1662 ([C]ourts have all but read the 'intent to benefit' element out of the law.);
    • See Buell, supra note 46, at 1662 ("[C]ourts have all but read the 'intent to benefit' element out of the law.");
  • 109
    • 62549150331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Potter, 463 F.3d 9
    • see also United States v. Potter, 463 F.3d 9, 25 (1st Cir. 2006).
    • (2006) 25 (1st Cir
  • 110
    • 62549139214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B.3.
    • See supra Part II.B.3.
  • 111
    • 62549136116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Likewise, when the probability of detection is small, firms can benefit from imperfect monitoring by reducing the probability of a conviction
    • Likewise, when the probability of detection is small, firms can benefit from imperfect monitoring by reducing the probability of a conviction.
  • 112
    • 84923565081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 2, at, T]he DOJ can readily obtain convictions given broad respondeat superior liability and substantive criminal law
    • See Garrett, supra note 2, at 879 ("[T]he DOJ can readily obtain convictions given broad respondeat superior liability and substantive criminal law.");
    • supra , pp. 879
    • Garrett1
  • 113
    • 62549093541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gerard E. Lynch, The Role of Criminal Law in Policing Corporate Misconduct, 60 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 23, 24 (1997) ([T]here is often no distinction between what the prosecutor would have to prove to establish a crime and what the relevant administrative agency or a private plaintiff would have to prove to show civil liability.).
    • Gerard E. Lynch, The Role of Criminal Law in Policing Corporate Misconduct, 60 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 23, 24 (1997) ("[T]here is often no distinction between what the prosecutor would have to prove to establish a crime and what the relevant administrative agency or a private plaintiff would have to prove to show civil liability.").
  • 114
    • 84888494968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 51-53
    • See supra text accompanying notes 51-53.
    • See supra
  • 115
    • 62549083448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Note, supra note 49.
    • See, e.g., Note, supra note 49.
  • 116
    • 62549118684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ainslie, supra note 5, at 109
    • See Ainslie, supra note 5, at 109.
  • 117
    • 62549151307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States ex rel. Porter v. Kroger Grocery & Baking Co., 163 F.2d 168, 177 (7th Cir. 1947) (As the magnitude of a business increased, with its personal supervision further removed, we apprehend that the difficulties were correspondingly enhanced. Certainly 100% compliance could not be expected in any event; in fact, it would be impossible.). This is also evidenced by the blooming industry of compliance programs that apparently fail to eliminate misconduct.
    • See United States ex rel. Porter v. Kroger Grocery & Baking Co., 163 F.2d 168, 177 (7th Cir. 1947) ("As the magnitude of a business increased, with its personal supervision further removed, we apprehend that the difficulties were correspondingly enhanced. Certainly 100% compliance could not be expected in any event; in fact, it would be impossible."). This is also evidenced by the blooming industry of compliance programs that apparently fail to eliminate misconduct.
  • 118
    • 62549143106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Kimberly D. Krawiec, Cosmetic Compliance and the Failure of Negotiated Governance, 81 WASH. U. L.Q. 487 (2003) (noting that internal compliance mechanisms fail to deter misconduct and merely reduce legal liability and improve market legitimacy).
    • See generally Kimberly D. Krawiec, Cosmetic Compliance and the Failure of Negotiated Governance, 81 WASH. U. L.Q. 487 (2003) (noting that internal compliance mechanisms fail to deter misconduct and merely reduce legal liability and improve market legitimacy).
  • 119
    • 68249108011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Third Party Interests in Criminal Law, 80
    • assessing the implications of considering the collateral consequences of prosecution and punishment, For a comprehensive analysis, see generally
    • For a comprehensive analysis, see generally Darryl K. Brown, Third Party Interests in Criminal Law, 80 TEX. L. REV. 1383 (2002) (assessing the implications of considering the collateral consequences of prosecution and punishment).
    • (2002) TEX. L. REV , vol.1383
    • Brown, D.K.1
  • 120
    • 0042813109 scopus 로고
    • Professional Discipline for Law Firms?, 77
    • arguing that dissolving law firms or temporarily shutting their doors for attorney misconduct would be inappropriate and ineffective, See
    • See Ted Schneyer, Professional Discipline for Law Firms?, 77 CORNELL L. REV. 1, 20-21 (1991) (arguing that dissolving law firms or temporarily shutting their doors for attorney misconduct would be inappropriate and ineffective).
    • (1991) CORNELL L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 20-21
    • Schneyer, T.1
  • 121
    • 62549161732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ainslie, supra note 5, at 1.10 ([Mandatory, automatic and drastic civil sanctions in the wake of criminal convictions are unnecessarily harsh and rigid.).
    • See Ainslie, supra note 5, at 1.10 ("[Mandatory, automatic and drastic civil sanctions in the wake of criminal convictions are unnecessarily harsh and rigid.").
  • 122
    • 62549102456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The debarment provisions, for example, permit excusing debarment if the contractor had effective standards of conduct and internal control systems in place at the time of the activity which constitutes cause for debarment or had adopted such procedures prior to any Government investigation of the activity cited as a cause for debarment. 48 C.F.R. § 9.4064(a)(1) (2008).
    • The debarment provisions, for example, permit excusing debarment if "the contractor had effective standards of conduct and internal control systems in place at the time of the activity which constitutes cause for debarment or had adopted such procedures prior to any Government investigation of the activity cited as a cause for debarment." 48 C.F.R. § 9.4064(a)(1) (2008).
  • 123
    • 62549128212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Fischel & Sykes, supra note 9 (arguing against criminal prosecution for corporate crimes);
    • See generally Fischel & Sykes, supra note 9 (arguing against criminal prosecution for corporate crimes);
  • 124
    • 0033466652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is the Notion of Corporate Fault a Faulty Notion?: The Case of Corporate Mens Rea, 79
    • considering when corporate mens rea is appropriate in prosecution and punishment
    • V.S. Khanna, Is the Notion of Corporate Fault a Faulty Notion?: The Case of Corporate Mens Rea, 79 B.U. L. REV. 355 (1999) (considering when corporate mens rea is appropriate in prosecution and punishment).
    • (1999) B.U. L. REV , vol.355
    • Khanna, V.S.1
  • 125
    • 62549087844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Fischel & Sykes, supra note 9. Jennifer Arlen has shown that strict corporate liability might produce perverse incentives for firms to adopt measures that could increase the likelihood of detecting offenses.
    • See, e.g., Fischel & Sykes, supra note 9. Jennifer Arlen has shown that strict corporate liability might produce perverse incentives for firms to adopt measures that could increase the likelihood of detecting offenses.
  • 126
    • 0008779134 scopus 로고
    • The Potentially Perverse Effects of Corporate Criminal Liability, 23
    • For a comprehensive analysis of modifications that may rectify these distortions, See
    • See Jennifer Arlen, The Potentially Perverse Effects of Corporate Criminal Liability, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 833 (1994). For a comprehensive analysis of modifications that may rectify these distortions,
    • (1994) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.833
    • Arlen, J.1
  • 127
    • 62549146640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 52
    • see Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 52.
  • 128
    • 62549140135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another group of standards focuses on organizational measures of culpability, which can be loosely defined as corporate ethos or corporate culture. These standards of organizational culpability tend to be somewhat indeterminate. See, e.g., Pamela H. Bucy, Corporate Ethos: A Standard for Imposing Corporate Criminal Liability, 75 MINN. L. REV. 1095 (1991).
    • Another group of standards focuses on organizational measures of culpability, which can be loosely defined as corporate ethos or corporate culture. These standards of organizational culpability tend to be somewhat indeterminate. See, e.g., Pamela H. Bucy, Corporate Ethos: A Standard for Imposing Corporate Criminal Liability, 75 MINN. L. REV. 1095 (1991).
  • 129
    • 62549137422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MODEL PENAL CODE § 2.07(1)(c) (1985);
    • See MODEL PENAL CODE § 2.07(1)(c) (1985);
  • 130
    • 62549112613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Commonwealth v. L.A.L. Corp., 511 N.E.2d 599, 602 (Mass. 1987) (The Commonwealth must prove that the individual for whose conduct it seeks to charge the corporation criminally was placed in a position by the corporation where he had enough power, duty, responsibility and authority to act for and in behalf of the corporation to handle the particular business or operation or project. . . . (emphasis omitted)).
    • see also Commonwealth v. L.A.L. Corp., 511 N.E.2d 599, 602 (Mass. 1987) ("The Commonwealth must prove that the individual for whose conduct it seeks to charge the corporation criminally was placed in a position by the corporation where he had enough power, duty, responsibility and authority to act for and in behalf of the corporation to handle the particular business or operation or project. . . ." (emphasis omitted)).
  • 131
    • 62549098604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a survey of states that adopted various formulations of the MPC standard, see RICHARD S. GRUNER, CORPORATE CRIME AND SENTENCING §§ 7.025-.036 (2d. ed. .1997). Management's involvement also can dramatically affect the magnitude of sanctions under the federal sentencing guidelines.
    • For a survey of states that adopted various formulations of the MPC standard, see RICHARD S. GRUNER, CORPORATE CRIME AND SENTENCING §§ 7.025-.036 (2d. ed. .1997). Management's involvement also can dramatically affect the magnitude of sanctions under the federal sentencing guidelines.
  • 132
    • 0007081290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Liability, Risk Shifting, and the Paradox of Compliance, 52
    • See
    • See William S. Laufer, Corporate Liability, Risk Shifting, and the Paradox of Compliance, 52 VAND. L. REV. 1343, 1384-86 (1999).
    • (1999) VAND. L. REV , vol.1343 , pp. 1384-1386
    • Laufer, W.S.1
  • 133
    • 62549114888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fischel & Sykes, supra note 9, at 324-25
    • See Fischel & Sykes, supra note 9, at 324-25.
  • 134
    • 34248536518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mens Rea and the Cost of Ignorance, 93
    • explaining how the responsible corporate officer doctrine might discourage monitoring by officers, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Assaf Hamdani, Mens Rea and the Cost of Ignorance, 93 VA. L. REV. 415, 446-47 (2007) (explaining how the "responsible corporate officer" doctrine might discourage monitoring by officers).
    • (2007) VA. L. REV , vol.415 , pp. 446-447
    • Hamdani, A.1
  • 135
    • 1842592792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the general case against making the involvement of top management a factor in setting corporate sanctions, see Vikramaditya S. Khanna, Should the Behavior of Top Management Matter, 91 GEO. L.J. 1215 2003
    • For the general case against making the involvement of top management a factor in setting corporate sanctions, see Vikramaditya S. Khanna, Should the Behavior of Top Management Matter?, 91 GEO. L.J. 1215 (2003).
  • 136
    • 50849151677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steve Shavell has shown that negligence standards can be more effective than strict liability in inducing judgment-proof injurers to take care. See S. Shavell, The Judgment Proof Problem, 6 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 45,47-48, 1986
    • Steve Shavell has shown that negligence standards can be more effective than strict liability in inducing judgment-proof injurers to take care. See S. Shavell, The Judgment Proof Problem, 6 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 45,47-48 ( 1986).
  • 137
    • 62549116983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Firms' efforts to create the impression that they take the necessary steps to prevent misconduct have been referred to as the problem of cosmetic compliance. See Krawiec, supra note 93
    • Firms' efforts to create the impression that they take the necessary steps to prevent misconduct have been referred to as the problem of cosmetic compliance. See Krawiec, supra note 93.
  • 138
    • 62549089165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Memorandum from Paul J. McNulty, Deputy Attorney Gen., to Heads of Dep't Components, U.S. Attorneys 4 (Dec. 2006) [hereinafter McNulty Memorandum], available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/speeches/2006/mcnulty- memo.pdf.
    • See Memorandum from Paul J. McNulty, Deputy Attorney Gen., to Heads of Dep't Components, U.S. Attorneys 4 (Dec. 2006) [hereinafter McNulty Memorandum], available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/speeches/2006/mcnulty- memo.pdf.
  • 139
    • 62549139213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 6 ([I]t may not be appropriate to impose liability upon a corporation, particularly one with a compliance program in place, under a strict respondeat superior theory for the single isolated act of a rogue employee.).
    • See id. at 6 ("[I]t may not be appropriate to impose liability upon a corporation, particularly one with a compliance program in place, under a strict respondeat superior theory for the single isolated act of a rogue employee.").
  • 140
    • 62549103809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Laufer, supra note 101;
    • See, e.g., Laufer, supra note 101;
  • 141
    • 84922577124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 8, at, stressing the need for consistency in federal corporate crime enforcement
    • Wray & Hur, supra note 8, at 1187 (stressing the need for consistency in federal corporate crime enforcement).
    • supra , pp. 1187
    • Wray1    Hur2
  • 142
    • 84865268624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Problematic and Faintly Promising Dynamics of Corporate Crime Enforcement, 1 OHIO ST
    • noting other ways in which prosecution policy and strict respondeat superior differ, On the difference between the federal regime of criminal liability and prosecution policy, see
    • On the difference between the federal regime of criminal liability and prosecution policy, see Darryl K. Brown, The Problematic and Faintly Promising Dynamics of Corporate Crime Enforcement, 1 OHIO ST. J. CRIM. L. 521, 542 (2004) (noting other ways in which prosecution policy and strict respondeat superior differ).
    • (2004) J. CRIM , vol.50 , Issue.521 , pp. 542
    • Brown, D.K.1
  • 143
    • 62549125449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.B.
    • See supra Part III.B.
  • 144
    • 62549142274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.B.
    • See supra Part III.B.
  • 145
    • 62549136559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As we explained above, the corporate death penalty would not always undermine deterrence. When even a single offense is sufficiently indicative of the firm's failure to monitor, or when the probability of the government's detection is sufficiently low, there is little risk that the putting firms out of business for a single offense would undermine deterrence.
    • As we explained above, the corporate death penalty would not always undermine deterrence. When even a single offense is sufficiently indicative of the firm's failure to monitor, or when the probability of the government's detection is sufficiently low, there is little risk that the putting firms out of business for a single offense would undermine deterrence.
  • 146
    • 62549133105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally William S. Laufer, Corporate Prosecution, Cooperation, and the Trading of Favors, 87 IOWA L. REV. 643, 647, 650-57 (2002) (questioning the fairness of trading corporate cooperation for government-granted favors and discussing the dark side of guideline incentives);
    • See generally William S. Laufer, Corporate Prosecution, Cooperation, and the Trading of Favors, 87 IOWA L. REV. 643, 647, 650-57 (2002) (questioning "the fairness of trading corporate cooperation for government-granted favors" and discussing "the dark side of guideline incentives");
  • 147
    • 56449091304 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prosecutorial Power in an Adversarial System: Lessons from Current White Collar Cases and the Inquisitorial Model, 8 BUFF
    • Geraldine Szott Moohr, Prosecutorial Power in an Adversarial System: Lessons from Current White Collar Cases and the Inquisitorial Model, 8 BUFF. CRIM. L. REV. 165 (2004).
    • (2004) CRIM. L. REV , vol.165
    • Szott Moohr, G.1
  • 148
    • 62549124137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McNulty Memorandum, supra note 107, at 16
    • See McNulty Memorandum, supra note 107, at 16.
  • 149
    • 62549139673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Jennifer H. Arlen & William J. Carney, Vicarious Liability for Fraud on Securities Markets: Theory and Evidence, 1992 U. III. L. REV. 691 (arguing that management-and not issuers-should be held liable for certain types of securities fraud);
    • See, e.g., Jennifer H. Arlen & William J. Carney, Vicarious Liability for Fraud on Securities Markets: Theory and Evidence, 1992 U. III. L. REV. 691 (arguing that management-and not issuers-should be held liable for certain types of securities fraud);
  • 150
    • 62549156251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Laufer, supra note 10.1, at 1346 ([T]he evolution of corporate criminal law in the United States ... is understood best by examining the shifting risks of liability and loss between corporations and their agents . . . .).
    • Laufer, supra note 10.1, at 1346 ("[T]he evolution of corporate criminal law in the United States ... is understood best by examining the shifting risks of liability and loss between corporations and their agents . . . .").
  • 151
    • 62549084727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an insightful analysis of the considerations affecting the choice between entity and personal liability, see Kraakman, supra note 50
    • For an insightful analysis of the considerations affecting the choice between entity and personal liability, see Kraakman, supra note 50.
  • 152
    • 62549136990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part H.A.
    • See supra Part H.A.
  • 153
    • 62549102033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part H.A.
    • See supra Part H.A.
  • 154
    • 62549150775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enron's Legacy, 8 BUFF
    • See
    • See Kathleen F. Brickey, Enron's Legacy, 8 BUFF. CRIM. L. REV. 221, 273-74 (2004).
    • (2004) CRIM. L. REV , vol.221 , pp. 273-274
    • Brickey, K.F.1
  • 155
    • 62549163387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 272
    • Id. at 272.
  • 156
    • 62549141035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Press Release, Dep't of Justice, Fact Sheet: President's Corporate Fraud Task Force Marks Five Years of Ensuring Corporate Integrity (July 17, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/opa/pr/2007/July/07- odag-507.html (reporting the fraud-related convictions of 214 CEOs and presidents, 53 chief financial officers, and 129 vice presidents).
    • See Press Release, Dep't of Justice, Fact Sheet: President's Corporate Fraud Task Force Marks Five Years of Ensuring Corporate Integrity (July 17, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/opa/pr/2007/July/07- odag-507.html (reporting the fraud-related convictions of 214 CEOs and presidents, 53 chief financial officers, and 129 vice presidents).
  • 157
    • 60649106610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Narrow Escape: How a Chastened KPMG Got By Tax-Shelter Crisis
    • Feb. 15, at
    • David Reilly, Narrow Escape: How a Chastened KPMG Got By Tax-Shelter Crisis, WALL ST. J., Feb. 15, 2007, at A1.
    • (2007) WALL ST. J
    • Reilly, D.1
  • 158
    • 84948770390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 9 Charged over Tax Shelters in KPMG Case
    • See, Aug. 30, at
    • See Carrie Johnson, 9 Charged over Tax Shelters in KPMG Case, WASH. POST, Aug. 30, 2005, at A1.
    • (2005) WASH. POST
    • Johnson, C.1
  • 159
    • 62549150776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ben Hallman, Damage Control: Sidley Agrees to Pay $40 Million for a Rogue Partner's Tax Shelter Scliemes. But the Tab Is Still Running, AM. LAW., Nov. 2005, at 18.
    • See Ben Hallman, Damage Control: Sidley Agrees to Pay $40 Million for a Rogue Partner's Tax Shelter Scliemes. But the Tab Is Still Running, AM. LAW., Nov. 2005, at 18.
  • 160
    • 62549104221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Court Ruling Jeopardizes U.S. Tax Case
    • See, May 24, at
    • See Lynnley Browning, Court Ruling Jeopardizes U.S. Tax Case, N.Y. TIMES, May 24, 2007, at C1.
    • (2007) N.Y. TIMES
    • Browning, L.1
  • 161
    • 62549122934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Buell, supra note 43, at 488-89 (reporting KPMG's admission that the conduct involved dozens of KPMG partners and other personnel).
    • See Buell, supra note 43, at 488-89 (reporting KPMG's admission that the conduct involved "dozens of KPMG partners and other personnel").
  • 162
    • 62549136556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Top Tax Shelter Lawyer No Longer at a Big Firm
    • See, June 30, at
    • See Lynnley Browning, Top Tax Shelter Lawyer No Longer at a Big Firm, N.Y. TIMES, June 30, 2004, at C1.
    • (2004) N.Y. TIMES
    • Browning, L.1
  • 163
    • 21844526082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Partners are still liable for their own wrongful acts under all limited liability statutes for professional firms. Some states also hold partners liable for the acts of those whom they supervise and control. See Jennifer J. Johnson, Limited Liability for Lawyers: General Partners Need Not Apply, 51 BUS. LAW. 85,94-95 1995
    • Partners are still liable for their own wrongful acts under all limited liability statutes for professional firms. Some states also hold partners liable for the acts of those whom they supervise and control. See Jennifer J. Johnson, Limited Liability for Lawyers: General Partners Need Not Apply, 51 BUS. LAW. 85,94-95 (1995).
  • 164
    • 62549106194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Who Bears the Costs of Lawyers' Mistakes?-Against Limited Liability, 36
    • See generally
    • See generally Martin C. McWilliams, Jr., Who Bears the Costs of Lawyers' Mistakes?-Against Limited Liability, 36 ARIZ. ST. L.J. 885 (2004);
    • (2004) ARIZ. ST. L.J , vol.885
    • McWilliams Jr., M.C.1
  • 165
    • 62549117795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Puri, supra note 16
    • Puri, supra note 16.
  • 166
    • 62549107053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra note 21
    • See sources cited supra note 21.
  • 167
    • 0346498127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Larry E. Ribstein, Ethical Rules, Agency Costs, and Law Firm Structure, 84 VA. L. REV. 1707, 1727 ( 1998) (A public interest rationale for some form, of mandatory vicarious liability is that it increases monitoring beyond what lawyers otherwise would do in the absence of a mandatory rule.).
    • See, e.g., Larry E. Ribstein, Ethical Rules, Agency Costs, and Law Firm Structure, 84 VA. L. REV. 1707, 1727 ( 1998) ("A public interest rationale for some form, of mandatory vicarious liability is that it increases monitoring beyond what lawyers otherwise would do in the absence of a mandatory rule.").
  • 168
    • 62549148623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a review of the arguments for unlimited liability of professional firms, see Larry E. Ribstein, Limited Liability of Professional Firms After Enron, 29 J. CORP. L. 427, 429 (2004).
    • For a review of the arguments for unlimited liability of professional firms, see Larry E. Ribstein, Limited Liability of Professional Firms After Enron, 29 J. CORP. L. 427, 429 (2004).
  • 169
    • 62549095287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ribstein, supra note 130, at 1707-08 (asserting that limited liability allows law firms to grow larger).
    • See, e.g., Ribstein, supra note 130, at 1707-08 (asserting that limited liability allows law firms to grow larger).
  • 170
    • 48249107721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Will Big Four Audit Firms Survive in a World of Unlimited Liability?
    • reporting a concern that auditor liability would cause audit firms to become insolvent, In theory, partners who are required to bear the cost associated with liability could recover from other partners. However, this is unlikely to provide a meaningful relief. See, e.g, Sept. 10, at
    • See, e.g., Floyd Norris, Will Big Four Audit Firms Survive in a World of Unlimited Liability?, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 10, 2004, at C1 (reporting a concern that auditor liability would cause audit firms to become insolvent). In theory, partners who are required to bear the cost associated with liability could recover from other partners. However, this is unlikely to provide a meaningful relief.
    • (2004) N.Y. TIMES
    • Norris, F.1
  • 171
    • 62549097750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ribstein, supra note 131, at 435
    • See Ribstein, supra note 131, at 435.
  • 172
    • 23744464101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The literature typically depicts unlimited liability as inducing partners to intensify their own monitoring effort rather than increasing the amount that the firm expends on monitoring. See, e.g, Scott Baker & Kimberly D. Krawiec, The Economics of Limited Liability: An Empirical Study of New York Law Firms, 2005 U. ILL. L. REV. 107, 115, U]nlimited liability encourages monitoring of each partner by every other partner
    • The literature typically depicts unlimited liability as inducing partners to intensify their own monitoring effort rather than increasing the amount that the firm expends on monitoring. See, e.g., Scott Baker & Kimberly D. Krawiec, The Economics of Limited Liability: An Empirical Study of New York Law Firms, 2005 U. ILL. L. REV. 107, 115 ("[U]nlimited liability encourages monitoring of each partner by every other partner.").
  • 173
    • 62549110416 scopus 로고
    • The problem might be mitigated, but not eliminated, to the extent that the regime of unlimited liability requires each partner to bear only her share of the damages. See Henry Hansmann & Reinier Kraakman, Toward Unlimited Shareholder Liability for Corporate Torts, 100
    • Also, the problem could be solved if professional firms could purchase satisfactory liability insurance
    • The problem might be mitigated, but not eliminated, to the extent that
    • (1991) YALE L.J. 1879
  • 174
    • 62549108668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See John Romley & Eric Talley, Uncorporated Professionals (U.S.C. CLEO Res. Paper No. C04-18, U.S.C. Law & Econ. Res. Paper No. 04-22), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=587982.
    • See John Romley & Eric Talley, Uncorporated Professionals (U.S.C. CLEO Res. Paper No. C04-18, U.S.C. Law & Econ. Res. Paper No. 04-22), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=587982.
  • 175
    • 62549128660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a description of the game's setup, see supra Part H.A.
    • For a description of the game's setup, see supra Part H.A.
  • 176
    • 62549089709 scopus 로고
    • For a definition of a Bayesian Nash Equilibrium, see
    • For a definition of a Bayesian Nash Equilibrium, see DREW FUDENBERG & JEAN TIROLE, GAME THEORY 215 (1991).
    • (1991) , vol.215
    • FUDENBERG, D.1    TIROLE, J.2    THEORY, G.3


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.