메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 83, Issue 3, 2008, Pages 1035-1096

Insuring corporate crime

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 49049085671     PISSN: 00196665     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (23)

References (326)
  • 1
    • 49049104692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N.Y. Cent. & Hudson River R.R. v. United States, 212 U.S. 481, 493-94 (1909) (explaining that it is well established that in actions for tort, corporations are responsible for the actions of their agents).
    • N.Y. Cent. & Hudson River R.R. v. United States, 212 U.S. 481, 493-94 (1909) (explaining that it is "well established" that in actions for tort, corporations are responsible for the actions of their agents).
  • 2
    • 49049086614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Mary Kreiner Ramirez, The Science Fiction of Corporate Criminal Liability: Containing the Machine Through the Corporate Death Penalty, 47 ARIZ. L. REV. 933 (2005) (embracing deterrence rationale and proposing a three strikes death penalty approach towards corporations whose employees violate the law);
    • See, e.g., Mary Kreiner Ramirez, The Science Fiction of Corporate Criminal Liability: Containing the Machine Through the Corporate Death Penalty, 47 ARIZ. L. REV. 933 (2005) (embracing deterrence rationale and proposing a "three strikes" death penalty approach towards corporations whose employees violate the law);
  • 3
    • 49049097391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael L. Seigel, Corporate America Fights Back: The Battle over Waiver of the Attorney-Client Privilege, 49 B.C. L. REV. 1, 10-11 (2008) (corporate culpability achieves significant additional deterrence, specific and general, beyond that achieved solely by the prosecution of individuals).
    • Michael L. Seigel, Corporate America Fights Back: The Battle over Waiver of the Attorney-Client Privilege, 49 B.C. L. REV. 1, 10-11 (2008) ("corporate culpability achieves significant additional deterrence, specific and general, beyond that achieved solely by the prosecution of individuals").
  • 4
    • 34248562199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Preet Bharara, Corporations Cry Uncle and their Employees Cry Foul: Rethinking Prosecutorial Pressure on Corporate Defendants, 44 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 53, 113 (2007) (accepting general premise that corporate criminal liability deters wrongdoing but arguing for narrower standard of liability);
    • But see Preet Bharara, Corporations Cry Uncle and their Employees Cry Foul: Rethinking Prosecutorial Pressure on Corporate Defendants, 44 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 53, 113 (2007) (accepting general premise that corporate criminal liability deters wrongdoing but arguing for narrower standard of liability);
  • 5
    • 0347306177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Crime, 25
    • questioning theoretical necessity of criminal liability as means of achieving deterrence
    • Daniel R. Fischel & Alan O. Sykes, Corporate Crime, 25 J. LEGAL STUD. 319 (1996) (questioning theoretical necessity of criminal liability as means of achieving deterrence);
    • (1996) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.319
    • Fischel, D.R.1    Sykes, A.O.2
  • 6
    • 57649215824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empirical Evidence and the Legal Doctrine of Corporate Criminal Liability, 29 AM
    • calling for empirical testing of efficacy of corporate criminal liability
    • Gilbert Geis & Joseph F. C. DiMento, Empirical Evidence and the Legal Doctrine of Corporate Criminal Liability, 29 AM J. CRIM. L. 341 (2002) (calling for empirical testing of efficacy of corporate criminal liability);
    • (2002) J. CRIM , vol.50 , pp. 341
    • Geis, G.1    DiMento, J.F.C.2
  • 7
    • 0042688760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vikamaditya S. Khanna, Corporate Criminal Liability: What Purpose Does it Serve?, 109 HARV. L. REV. 1477, 1478 & n.2 (1996) (criticizing analysis of corporate criminal liability and citing earlier critiques and defenses).
    • Vikamaditya S. Khanna, Corporate Criminal Liability: What Purpose Does it Serve?, 109 HARV. L. REV. 1477, 1478 & n.2 (1996) (criticizing analysis of corporate criminal liability and citing earlier critiques and defenses).
  • 8
    • 33746265972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Julie O'Sullivan, The Federal Criminal Code Is a Disgrace: Obstruction Statutes as a Case Study, 96 J. CRIM. L. AND CRIMINOLOGY 643, 668 (2006) (it is difficult to find a case in which a corporation cannot be tagged for the activities of its agents);
    • See Julie O'Sullivan, The Federal Criminal "Code" Is a Disgrace: Obstruction Statutes as a Case Study, 96 J. CRIM. L. AND CRIMINOLOGY 643, 668 (2006) ("it is difficult to find a case in which a corporation cannot be tagged for the activities of its agents");
  • 9
    • 38549128274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Approach to Corporate Criminal Liability, 44
    • observing that even minimal employee conduct will trigger corporate-level liability
    • Andrew Weissman, A New Approach to Corporate Criminal Liability, 44 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1319, 1320-21 (2007) (observing that even minimal employee conduct will trigger corporate-level liability).
    • (2007) AM. CRIM. L. REV , vol.1319 , pp. 1320-1321
    • Weissman, A.1
  • 10
    • 36549076493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the collateral consequences of corporate indictment, see discussion infra at 28-29 n. 144-49, and Erik Paulsen, Note, Imposing Limits on Prosecutorial Discretion in Corporate Prosecution Agreements, 82 NYU L. REV. 1434, 1453-54 (2007). For a discussion of costs and inefficiencies encountered in compliance programs, see infra at 23-26.
    • For a discussion of the collateral consequences of corporate indictment, see discussion infra at 28-29 n. 144-49, and Erik Paulsen, Note, Imposing Limits on Prosecutorial Discretion in Corporate Prosecution Agreements, 82 NYU L. REV. 1434, 1453-54 (2007). For a discussion of costs and inefficiencies encountered in compliance programs, see infra at 23-26.
  • 11
    • 34547310373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Seigel, supra note 2, at 12-13 (observing - without apparent criticism - that uncertainty inherent in corporate criminal law undoubtedly makes corporate officers much more risk averse). For a more negative view of liability-fueled risk aversion, see Assaf Hamdani, Rewarding Outside Directors, 105 MICH. L. REV. 1677, 1679 (2007) (arguing that liability imposed on lawyers, accountants, and directors for failing to prevent misconduct may cause risk aversion particularly since they act on behalf of third parties and therefore do not bear the full costs of taking precautionary measures or making conservative decisions).
    • Cf. Seigel, supra note 2, at 12-13 (observing - without apparent criticism - that uncertainty inherent in corporate criminal law "undoubtedly makes corporate officers much more risk averse"). For a more negative view of liability-fueled risk aversion, see Assaf Hamdani, Rewarding Outside Directors, 105 MICH. L. REV. 1677, 1679 (2007) (arguing that liability imposed on lawyers, accountants, and directors for failing to prevent misconduct may cause risk aversion "particularly since they act on behalf of third parties and therefore do not bear the full costs of taking precautionary measures or making conservative decisions").
  • 12
    • 49049106429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra at 33-34 (discussing costs of corporate cooperation).
    • See discussion infra at 33-34 (discussing costs of corporate cooperation).
  • 13
    • 49049099303 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 4
    • See supra note 4.
  • 14
    • 49049100871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra at 15 and notes 81-85.
    • See discussion infra at 15 and notes 81-85.
  • 15
    • 49049118000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. See also Weissman, supra note 3, at 1320 (observing that minimal employee conduct will trigger entity liability).
    • Id. See also Weissman, supra note 3, at 1320 (observing that "minimal" employee conduct will trigger entity liability).
  • 16
    • 49049103523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [A]n indictment - especially of a financial services firm - threatens to destroy the business regardless of whether the firm ultimately is convicted or acquitted. United States v. Stein, 440 F. Supp. 2d 315, 337 (S.D.N.Y. 2006); see also Weissman, supra note 3, at 1321.
    • "[A]n indictment - especially of a financial services firm - threatens to destroy the business regardless of whether the firm ultimately is convicted or acquitted." United States v. Stein, 440 F. Supp. 2d 315, 337 (S.D.N.Y. 2006); see also Weissman, supra note 3, at 1321.
  • 17
    • 34547285037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Brandon L. Garrett, Structural Reform Prosecutions, 93 VA. L. REV. 853, 916 (2007) (describing four recent agreements that required the corporate defendant to make payments to entities that were unconnected to the underlying harm).
    • See Brandon L. Garrett, Structural Reform Prosecutions, 93 VA. L. REV. 853, 916 (2007) (describing four recent agreements that required the corporate defendant to make payments to entities that were unconnected to the underlying harm).
  • 18
    • 49049088502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of monitoring regimes, see at
    • For a discussion of monitoring regimes, see infra at 35-38.
    • infra , pp. 35-38
  • 19
    • 49049108103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Garrett, supra note 10, at 899
    • See Garrett, supra note 10, at 899.
  • 20
    • 33846467857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • See infra at 29-38.
    • See infra , pp. 29-38
  • 21
    • 49049121217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As of July 31, 2006, the Department of Justice had announced twelve deferred prosecution agreements for the year. Sue Reisinger, Deal-Making by DOJ Is on the Rise, NAT'L L.J, July 31, 2006, at 8. Since 1992, over forty pre-trial agreements have been documented and reported by either the Department of Justice or individual United States Attorneys' Offices. Lawrence D. Finder & Ryan D. McConnell, Devolution of Authority: The Department of Justice's Corporate Charging Policies, 51 ST. LOUIS U. L.J. 1, 2 fig.1 (2006, Whereas DPAs prior to 1999 were fairly simple settlements that called for fines and limited corporate reforms, today's DPAs require, among other things: outside monitors and extensive reporting; the corporate defendant's promise to prohibit its employees from contradicting factual statements contained in the DPA; and waiver of the attorney-client privilege. See Garrett, supra note 10, at 853 discussing increase in c
    • As of July 31, 2006, the Department of Justice had announced twelve deferred prosecution agreements for the year. Sue Reisinger, Deal-Making by DOJ Is on the Rise, NAT'L L.J., July 31, 2006, at 8. Since 1992, over forty pre-trial agreements have been documented and reported by either the Department of Justice or individual United States Attorneys' Offices. Lawrence D. Finder & Ryan D. McConnell, Devolution of Authority: The Department of Justice's Corporate Charging Policies, 51 ST. LOUIS U. L.J. 1, 2 fig.1 (2006). Whereas DPAs prior to 1999 were fairly simple settlements that called for fines and limited corporate reforms, today's DPAs require, among other things: outside monitors and extensive reporting; the corporate defendant's promise to prohibit its employees from contradicting factual statements contained in the DPA; and waiver of the attorney-client privilege. See Garrett, supra note 10, at 853 (discussing increase in corporate prosecutions that seek far-reaching "structural reforms" in lieu of indictments); Finder & McConnell, supra, at 5-7, 17-19.
  • 22
    • 33846467857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • See infra at 31-32.
    • See infra , pp. 31-32
  • 23
    • 49049102061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Despite the federal government's increased prosecution of corporate entities and defendants, corporate crime (particularly, corporate fraud, which is one of the key forms of criminal conduct in the white collar context) remains a significant problem across thousands of organizations. See KPMG FORENSIC, KPMG FORENSIC FRAUD SURVEY 2003 at 2, available at http://www.us.kpmg.com/RutUS_prod/Documents/9/ FINALFraudSur.pdf (reports of employee fraud increasing even though organizations are responding with anti-fraud measures);
    • Despite the federal government's increased prosecution of corporate entities and defendants, corporate crime (particularly, corporate fraud, which is one of the key forms of criminal conduct in the white collar context) remains a significant problem across thousands of organizations. See KPMG FORENSIC, KPMG FORENSIC FRAUD SURVEY 2003 at 2, available at http://www.us.kpmg.com/RutUS_prod/Documents/9/ FINALFraudSur.pdf (reports of employee fraud increasing even though organizations are "responding with anti-fraud" measures);
  • 24
    • 49049087293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PRICEWATERHOUSECOOPERS, 2005 GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRIME STUDY: US AND NORTH AMERICA 4, available at http://www.pwc.com (follow publications hyperlink) [hereinafter PWC 2005 REPORT] (economic crime is pervasive throughout North American companies despite increased reliance on internal controls and audits).
    • PRICEWATERHOUSECOOPERS, 2005 GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRIME STUDY: US AND NORTH AMERICA 4, available at http://www.pwc.com (follow "publications" hyperlink) [hereinafter PWC 2005 REPORT] (economic crime is "pervasive" throughout North American companies despite increased reliance on internal controls and audits).
  • 25
    • 33846467857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • See infra at 35.
    • See infra , pp. 35
  • 26
    • 49049084203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JOHN HASNAS, TRAPPED: WHEN ACTING ETHICALLY IS AGAINST THE LAW (2006) (corporate criminal liability results in unethical conduct); Elizabeth K. Ainslie, Indicting Corporations Revisited: Lessons of the Arthur Andersen Prosecution, 43 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 107 (2006) (arguing that costs of corporate prosecutions often outweigh benefits); Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 319 (arguing that civil liability more efficiently deters corporate conduct than criminal liability); Khanna, supra note 2, at 1477 (same);
    • See, e.g., JOHN HASNAS, TRAPPED: WHEN ACTING ETHICALLY IS AGAINST THE LAW (2006) (corporate criminal liability results in unethical conduct); Elizabeth K. Ainslie, Indicting Corporations Revisited: Lessons of the Arthur Andersen Prosecution, 43 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 107 (2006) (arguing that costs of corporate prosecutions often outweigh benefits); Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 319 (arguing that civil liability more efficiently deters corporate conduct than criminal liability); Khanna, supra note 2, at 1477 (same);
  • 27
    • 0007081290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Liability, Risk Shifting, and the Paradox of Compliance, 52
    • criticizing liability scheme's emphasis on compliance programs
    • William S. Laufer, Corporate Liability, Risk Shifting, and the Paradox of Compliance, 52 VAND. L. REV. 1343 (1999) (criticizing liability scheme's emphasis on compliance programs);
    • (1999) VAND. L. REV , vol.1343
    • Laufer, W.S.1
  • 28
    • 0347803909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shayne Kennedy, Note, Probation and the Failure to Optimally Deter Corporate Misconduct, 71 S. CAL. L. REV. 1075 (1998) (arguing that civil fines would more effectively deter misconduct than probationary sentences envisioned by the Organizational Sentencing Guidelines).
    • Shayne Kennedy, Note, Probation and the Failure to Optimally Deter Corporate Misconduct, 71 S. CAL. L. REV. 1075 (1998) (arguing that civil fines would more effectively deter misconduct than probationary sentences envisioned by the Organizational Sentencing Guidelines).
  • 29
    • 49049096998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For criticism of the waiver issue generally, see AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION, REPORT OF ABA TASK FORCE ON ATTORNEY-CLIENT PRIVILEGE 1 (2006), available at http://www.abanet.org/buslaw/attorneyclient/materials/hod/ emprights_report_adopted.pdf [hereinafter ABA TASK FORCE REPORT] (emphasizing unanimous support for Resolution 111 opposing further erosion of attorney-client privilege);
    • For criticism of the waiver issue generally, see AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION, REPORT OF ABA TASK FORCE ON ATTORNEY-CLIENT PRIVILEGE 1 (2006), available at http://www.abanet.org/buslaw/attorneyclient/materials/hod/ emprights_report_adopted.pdf [hereinafter ABA TASK FORCE REPORT] (emphasizing unanimous support for Resolution 111 opposing further erosion of attorney-client privilege);
  • 30
    • 49049087700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elkan Abramowitz & Barry A. Bohrer, Waiver of Corporate Attorney-Client and Work Product Protection, N.Y. L.J. Nov. 1, 2005, at 3 (pointing out efforts by the ABA and SEC to prevent the erosion of corporate attorney-client privilege);
    • Elkan Abramowitz & Barry A. Bohrer, Waiver of Corporate Attorney-Client and Work Product Protection, N.Y. L.J. Nov. 1, 2005, at 3 (pointing out efforts by the ABA and SEC to prevent the erosion of corporate attorney-client privilege);
  • 31
    • 49049084413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lynnley Browning, Ex-Officials of Justice Dept. Oppose Prosecutors' Tactic in Corporate Criminal Cases, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 7, 2006, at C1 (describing letter from Kenneth Starr and Richard Thornburgh to the Justice Department criticizing government's request for privilege waivers in corporate prosecutions). On December 11, 2006, in response to threatened legislation and criticism of prosecutorial practices, the Department of Justice promulgated new guidelines for prosecutors.
    • Lynnley Browning, Ex-Officials of Justice Dept. Oppose Prosecutors' Tactic in Corporate Criminal Cases, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 7, 2006, at C1 (describing letter from Kenneth Starr and Richard Thornburgh to the Justice Department criticizing government's request for privilege waivers in corporate prosecutions). On December 11, 2006, in response to threatened legislation and criticism of prosecutorial practices, the Department of Justice promulgated new guidelines for prosecutors.
  • 32
    • 49049092997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Memorandum from Paul J. McNulty, Deputy Attorney General, to United States Attorneys, Principles of Federal Prosecution of Business Organizations, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/speeches/2006/mcnulty_memo.pdf [hereinafter McNulty Memo]. The McNulty Memo requires prosecutors to classify potentially privileged material into two categories and then seek approval from the Department of Justice prior to seeking the material.
    • Memorandum from Paul J. McNulty, Deputy Attorney General, to United States Attorneys, Principles of Federal Prosecution of Business Organizations, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/speeches/2006/mcnulty_memo.pdf [hereinafter McNulty Memo]. The McNulty Memo requires prosecutors to classify potentially privileged material into two categories and then seek approval from the Department of Justice prior to seeking the material.
  • 33
    • 49049094391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a defense of the government's procedure of obtaining waivers, see George M. Cohen, Of Coerced Waiver, Government Leverage, and Corporate Loyalty: The Holder, Thompson and McNulty Memos and Their Critics, 93 VA. L. REV. (IN BRIEF) 137 (2007) (contending that unwillingness to waive privilege is simply a manifestation of corporate management's attempt at saving their own necks).
    • For a defense of the government's procedure of obtaining waivers, see George M. Cohen, Of Coerced Waiver, Government Leverage, and Corporate Loyalty: The Holder, Thompson and McNulty Memos and Their Critics, 93 VA. L. REV. (IN BRIEF) 137 (2007) (contending that unwillingness to waive privilege is simply a manifestation of corporate management's attempt at "saving their own necks").
  • 34
    • 49049101994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As described by the court, the scheme: allegedly involved at least four separate tax shelter vehicles, called FLIP, OPIS, BLIPS, and SOS, designed to generate phony tax losses through a series of sham transactions. The conspirators allegedly sought to protect their clients from potential IRS penalties by paying co-defendant Raymond Ruble, a New York tax attorney, to issue opinion letters falsely representing that the tax shelters were likely to survive IRS review. United States v. Stein, 488 F. Supp. 2d 350, 354 (S.D.N.Y. 2007).
    • As described by the court, the scheme: allegedly involved at least four separate tax shelter vehicles, called FLIP, OPIS, BLIPS, and SOS, designed to generate phony tax losses through a series of sham transactions. The conspirators allegedly sought to protect their clients from potential IRS penalties by paying co-defendant Raymond Ruble, a New York tax attorney, to issue opinion letters falsely representing that the tax shelters were likely to survive IRS review. United States v. Stein, 488 F. Supp. 2d 350, 354 (S.D.N.Y. 2007).
  • 35
    • 49049090249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Stein (Stein I), 435 F. Supp. 2d 330, 338 (S.D.N.Y. 2006). Pursuant to revised prosecutorial guidelines contained in the memorandum issued in the McNulty Memo of December 2006, prosecutors may no longer consider the payment of an employee's attorney fees as reason for an indictment except in extraordinary circumstances. See McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 11 (stating that [p]rosecutors generally should not take into account whether a corporation is advancing attorneys' fees to employees or agents under investigation and indictment).
    • United States v. Stein (Stein I), 435 F. Supp. 2d 330, 338 (S.D.N.Y. 2006). Pursuant to revised prosecutorial guidelines contained in the memorandum issued in the McNulty Memo of December 2006, prosecutors may no longer consider the payment of an employee's attorney fees as reason for an indictment except in extraordinary circumstances. See McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 11 (stating that "[p]rosecutors generally should not take into account whether a corporation is advancing attorneys' fees to employees or agents under investigation and indictment").
  • 36
    • 49049121736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kaplan suppressed several of the KPMG employees' statements. United States v. Stein (Stein II), 440 F. Supp. 2d 315, 319 (S.D.N.Y. 2006).
    • Kaplan suppressed several of the KPMG employees' statements. United States v. Stein (Stein II), 440 F. Supp. 2d 315, 319 (S.D.N.Y. 2006).
  • 37
    • 49049097806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stein I, 435 F. Supp. at 345-47.
    • Stein I, 435 F. Supp. at 345-47.
  • 38
    • 49049120005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In other words, KPMG told its personnel that it would cut off payment of legal expenses of any employee who refused to talk to the government or who invoked the Fifth Amendment. Stein II, 440 F. Supp. at 318.
    • "In other words, KPMG told its personnel that it would cut off payment of legal expenses of any employee who refused to talk to the government or who invoked the Fifth Amendment." Stein II, 440 F. Supp. at 318.
  • 39
    • 49049108233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stein II, 440 F. Supp. at 319.
    • Stein II, 440 F. Supp. at 319.
  • 40
    • 49049112742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Stein (Stein III), 495 F. Supp. 2d 390, 414 (S.D.N.Y. 2007) (criticizing the government's willingness . . . to use their life and death power over KPMG to induce KPMG to coerce its personnel to bend to the government's wishes notwithstanding the fact that the Constitution barred the government from doing directly what it forced KPMG to do for it). Previously, the court had attempted to remedy the situation by suppressing the coerced employee statements and by authorizing and taking ancillary jurisdiction over a civil suit between the former employees and KPMG over the attorney fee payments. United States v. Stein, 452 F. Supp. 2d 230, 242-43 (2006), vacated, Stein v. KPMG, 486 F.3d 753 (2d Cir. 2007) (holding that the district court had no jurisdiction).
    • United States v. Stein (Stein III), 495 F. Supp. 2d 390, 414 (S.D.N.Y. 2007) (criticizing the government's "willingness . . . to use their life and death power over KPMG to induce KPMG to coerce its personnel to bend to the government's wishes notwithstanding the fact that the Constitution barred the government from doing directly what it forced KPMG to do for it"). Previously, the court had attempted to remedy the situation by suppressing the coerced employee statements and by authorizing and taking ancillary jurisdiction over a civil suit between the former employees and KPMG over the attorney fee payments. United States v. Stein, 452 F. Supp. 2d 230, 242-43 (2006), vacated, Stein v. KPMG, 486 F.3d 753 (2d Cir. 2007) (holding that the district court had no jurisdiction).
  • 41
    • 49049117932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McNulty Memo, supra note 19. The McNulty Memo in part arose in response to proposed legislation authored by Arlen Specter that would make it illegal for prosecutors to request a waiver of the attorney-client privilege. Attorney-Client Privilege Protection Act of 2006, S. 30, 109th Cong. (2006), available at http://online.wsj.com/public/resources/documents/ WSJ_thompsonmemoleg.pdf.
    • See McNulty Memo, supra note 19. The McNulty Memo in part arose in response to proposed legislation authored by Arlen Specter that would make it illegal for prosecutors to request a waiver of the attorney-client privilege. Attorney-Client Privilege Protection Act of 2006, S. 30, 109th Cong. (2006), available at http://online.wsj.com/public/resources/documents/ WSJ_thompsonmemoleg.pdf.
  • 42
    • 49049107454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Judge Kaplan's attempts at reform were made moot when the Second Circuit found a lack of ancillary jurisdiction over the KPMG attorneys' fees dispute. The Second Circuit took no position on Kaplan's previous conclusion that the DOJ had violated the employees' rights to counsel by placing pressure on KPMG to withhold payments for attorneys fees. See KPMG, 486 F.3d at 753. Another court criticized the attorneys fees policy as unquestionably obnoxious. United States v. Rosen, 487 F. Supp. 2d 721, 737 (E.D. Va. 2007).
    • Judge Kaplan's attempts at reform were made moot when the Second Circuit found a lack of ancillary jurisdiction over the KPMG attorneys' fees dispute. The Second Circuit took no position on Kaplan's previous conclusion that the DOJ had violated the employees' rights to counsel by placing pressure on KPMG to withhold payments for attorneys fees. See KPMG, 486 F.3d at 753. Another court criticized the attorneys fees policy as "unquestionably obnoxious." United States v. Rosen, 487 F. Supp. 2d 721, 737 (E.D. Va. 2007).
  • 43
    • 49049119583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 11
    • See McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 11.
  • 44
    • 49049097191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • According to several studies, corporate crime has increased in the last five years. PWC 2005 REPORT, supra note 16, at 4 (explaining that [e]conomic crime is a pervasive and growing threat to US and North American businesses of all types). According to the PWC Report, internal controls fail to detect economic crime approximately sixty percent of the time. Id. at 16.
    • According to several studies, corporate crime has increased in the last five years. PWC 2005 REPORT, supra note 16, at 4 (explaining that "[e]conomic crime is a pervasive and growing threat to US and North American businesses of all types"). According to the PWC Report, internal controls fail to detect economic crime approximately sixty percent of the time. Id. at 16.
  • 45
    • 49049102408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To the extent entities were already the subject of civil lawsuits, the system simply would ensure that the entity's insurance paid for the costs of its employees' wrongdoing, regardless of whether that wrongdoing was labeled criminal
    • To the extent entities were already the subject of civil lawsuits, the system simply would ensure that the entity's insurance paid for the costs of its employees' wrongdoing, regardless of whether that wrongdoing was labeled "criminal."
  • 46
    • 49049108971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This Article focuses primarily on federal criminal prosecutions. I intend the term corporate criminal liability to encompass prosecutions of all legitimate business entities corporations, partnerships, associations, and other unincorporated organizations, The concerns discussed in this Article do not apply to entities created solely for the purpose of masking criminal conduct
    • This Article focuses primarily on federal criminal prosecutions. I intend the term "corporate criminal liability" to encompass prosecutions of all legitimate business entities (corporations, partnerships, associations, and other unincorporated organizations). The concerns discussed in this Article do not apply to entities created solely for the purpose of masking criminal conduct.
  • 47
    • 49049098375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stolt-Nielsen S.A. v. United States, 442 F.3d 177, 183 (3d Cir. 2006) ([T]he executive branch 'has exclusive authority and absolute discretion to decide whether to prosecute a case . . . .' (quoting United States v. Nixon, 418 U.S. 683, 693 (1974))); see also Jennifer Arlen & Reinier Kraakman, Controlling Corporate Misconduct: An Analysis of Corporate Liability Regimes, 72 N.Y.U. L. REV. 687, 688 (1997) (explaining that the corporate liability standard is far reaching).
    • Stolt-Nielsen S.A. v. United States, 442 F.3d 177, 183 (3d Cir. 2006) ("[T]he executive branch 'has exclusive authority and absolute discretion to decide whether to prosecute a case . . . .'" (quoting United States v. Nixon, 418 U.S. 683, 693 (1974))); see also Jennifer Arlen & Reinier Kraakman, Controlling Corporate Misconduct: An Analysis of Corporate Liability Regimes, 72 N.Y.U. L. REV. 687, 688 (1997) (explaining that the corporate liability standard is "far reaching").
  • 48
    • 0042260485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 33, at 688; Vikamaditya S. Khanna, Corporate Liability Standards: When Should Corporations Be Held Criminally Liable?, 37 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1239 (2000);
    • See, e.g., Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 33, at 688; Vikamaditya S. Khanna, Corporate Liability Standards: When Should Corporations Be Held Criminally Liable?, 37 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1239 (2000);
  • 49
    • 33749855378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Organizational Misconduct: Beyond the Principal-Agent Model, 32
    • Kimberly D. Krawiec, Organizational Misconduct: Beyond the Principal-Agent Model, 32 FLA. ST. U. L. REV. 571, 581-83 (2005).
    • (2005) FLA. ST. U. L. REV , vol.571 , pp. 581-583
    • Krawiec, K.D.1
  • 52
    • 49049116624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Donald C. Langevoort, Monitoring: The Behavioral Economics of Corporate Compliance with the Law, 2002 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 71, 72 (2002).
    • See Donald C. Langevoort, Monitoring: The Behavioral Economics of Corporate Compliance with the Law, 2002 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 71, 72 (2002).
  • 53
    • 49049086613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Howard W. Goldstein, When the Government Ends a Deferred Prosecution Pact, N.Y. L. J., May 4, 2006, at 5 (explaining that from the point of view of the corporate target, a deferred prosecution agreement - no matter how harsh and intrusive the terms - is frequently an offer the company simply cannot refuse when the alternative is possibly death or less drastic, but nonetheless severe, consequences); Langevoort, supra note 37, at 74 (concluding that overestimates of the reliability of in-house monitoring combined with underestimates of the costs of third-party audits biases the legal response towards insisting on too much auditing, forcing unnecessarily costly compliance initiatives).
    • See Howard W. Goldstein, When the Government Ends a Deferred Prosecution Pact, N.Y. L. J., May 4, 2006, at 5 (explaining that from the point of view of "the corporate target, a deferred prosecution agreement - no matter how harsh and intrusive the terms - is frequently an offer the company simply cannot refuse when the alternative is possibly death or less drastic, but nonetheless severe, consequences"); Langevoort, supra note 37, at 74 (concluding that overestimates of the reliability of in-house monitoring combined with underestimates of the costs of third-party audits "biases the legal response towards insisting on too much auditing, forcing unnecessarily costly compliance initiatives").
  • 54
    • 33646724487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ainslie, supra note 18, at 110 (listing four suggested reforms); Samuel W. Buell, The Blaming Function of Entity Criminal Liability, 81 IND. L.J. 473, 530-32 (2006) (suggesting that the criminal prosecution of corporations should be limited to situations where the agent's action is the result of institutional influence).
    • See Ainslie, supra note 18, at 110 (listing four suggested reforms); Samuel W. Buell, The Blaming Function of Entity Criminal Liability, 81 IND. L.J. 473, 530-32 (2006) (suggesting that the criminal prosecution of corporations should be limited to situations where the agent's action is the result of institutional influence).
  • 55
    • 31544463030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard A. Bierschbach & Alex Stein, Overenforcement, 93 GEO. L. J. 1743, 1758 (2005).
    • Richard A. Bierschbach & Alex Stein, Overenforcement, 93 GEO. L. J. 1743, 1758 (2005).
  • 56
    • 27844540349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Benjamin M. Greenblum, Note, What Happens to a Prosecution Deferred? Judicial Oversight of Corporate Deferred Prosecution Agreements, 105 COLUM. L. REV. 1863, 1896-1904 (2005).
    • Benjamin M. Greenblum, Note, What Happens to a Prosecution Deferred? Judicial Oversight of Corporate Deferred Prosecution Agreements, 105 COLUM. L. REV. 1863, 1896-1904 (2005).
  • 57
    • 49049116417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 319
    • Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 319.
  • 58
    • 0346674064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even in the tort context, the wisdom of corporate vicarious liability has been questioned. See, e.g., Gary T. Schwartz, The Hidden and Fundamental Issue of Employer Vicarious Liability, 69 S. CAL. L. REV. 1739, 1749-1754 (1996) (criticizing fairness-based explanations for vicarious liability).
    • Even in the tort context, the wisdom of corporate vicarious liability has been questioned. See, e.g., Gary T. Schwartz, The Hidden and Fundamental Issue of Employer Vicarious Liability, 69 S. CAL. L. REV. 1739, 1749-1754 (1996) (criticizing fairness-based explanations for vicarious liability).
  • 59
    • 16244413218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professors Ronen and Cunningham have proposed and elaborated on an insurance scheme that would replace auditor liability for misstatements or omissions later found in public companies' financial statements. See Lawrence A. Cunningham, Choosing Gatekeepers: The Financial Statement Insurance Alternative to Auditor Liability, 52 UCLA L. REV. 413 (2004);
    • Professors Ronen and Cunningham have proposed and elaborated on an insurance scheme that would replace auditor liability for misstatements or omissions later found in public companies' financial statements. See Lawrence A. Cunningham, Choosing Gatekeepers: The Financial Statement Insurance Alternative to Auditor Liability, 52 UCLA L. REV. 413 (2004);
  • 60
    • 49049113646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joshua Ronen, Post-Enron Reform: Financial Statement Insurance, and GAAP Re-Visited, 8 STAN. J.L. BUS. & FIN. 39 (2002). Professor Griffith has also argued for mandatory disclosure of directors' and officers' policies as a market signal.
    • Joshua Ronen, Post-Enron Reform: Financial Statement Insurance, and GAAP Re-Visited, 8 STAN. J.L. BUS. & FIN. 39 (2002). Professor Griffith has also argued for mandatory disclosure of directors' and officers' policies as a market signal.
  • 61
    • 33745217788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sean J. Griffith, Uncovering a Gatekeeper: Why the SEC Should Mandate Disclosure of Details Concerning Directors' and Officers' Liability Insurance Policies, 154 U. PA. L. REV. 1147 (2006) (calling for mandatory disclosure of officers' and directors' policies because policies can signal market on strength of corporation's internal governance mechanisms).
    • Sean J. Griffith, Uncovering a Gatekeeper: Why the SEC Should Mandate Disclosure of Details Concerning Directors' and Officers' Liability Insurance Policies, 154 U. PA. L. REV. 1147 (2006) (calling for mandatory disclosure of officers' and directors' policies because policies can signal market on strength of corporation's internal governance mechanisms).
  • 62
    • 2442671585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gatekeepers have been described as persons who use their reputation capital to bridge the gap between investors and corporate managers. See John C. Coffee, Jr, Gatekeeper Failure and Reform: The Challenge of Fashioning Relevant Reforms, 84 B.U. L. REV. 301, 308 2004, hereinafter Coffee, Gatekeeper Reform];
    • Gatekeepers have been described as persons who use their reputation capital to bridge the gap between investors and corporate managers. See John C. Coffee, Jr., Gatekeeper Failure and Reform: The Challenge of Fashioning Relevant Reforms, 84 B.U. L. REV. 301, 308 (2004) [hereinafter Coffee, Gatekeeper Reform];
  • 63
    • 0036704563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John C. Coffee, Jr., Understanding Enron: It's About the Gatekeepers, Stupid, 57 BUS. LAW. 1403, 1405 (2002) (describing gatekeepers as reputational intermediates). Sean J. Griffith has referred to insurance carriers as accidental gatekeepers, since their primary intent is to assess risk and not to provide information to investors. Griffith, supra note 44, at 1150.
    • John C. Coffee, Jr., Understanding Enron: "It's About the Gatekeepers, Stupid," 57 BUS. LAW. 1403, 1405 (2002) (describing gatekeepers as "reputational intermediates"). Sean J. Griffith has referred to insurance carriers as "accidental gatekeepers," since their primary intent is to assess risk and not to provide information to investors. Griffith, supra note 44, at 1150.
  • 64
    • 49049091254 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By the mid-1800s, some courts permitted criminal prosecution of municipal corporations for failing to maintain public bridges or highways. See Ainslie, supra note 18, at 110-11; Laufer, supra note 18, at 1361. Under English common law: well into the 1800s, the corporation could not be indicted at all unless it created a nuisance by failing to perform a public duty. Prosecution in such instances was not viewed as a criminal proceeding, but as a means of ensuring that duties imposed by charter or statute were carried out. Most cases involved a failure to repair highways or bridges, or to keep navigable waterways clear. Not until the 1840s, just as the corporation was becoming intertwined in the daily lives of ordinary men and women, was it held that corporations could be prosecuted criminally for malfeasance, at least when nonviolent misdemeanors were charged. Lawrence Mitchell Rothman, Life After Doe? Self-incrimination and Business Documents
    • By the mid-1800s, some courts permitted criminal prosecution of municipal corporations for failing to maintain public bridges or highways. See Ainslie, supra note 18, at 110-11; Laufer, supra note 18, at 1361. Under English common law: well into the 1800s - the corporation could not be indicted at all unless it created a nuisance by failing to perform a public duty. "Prosecution" in such instances was not viewed as a criminal proceeding, but as a means of ensuring that duties imposed by charter or statute were carried out. Most cases involved a failure to repair highways or bridges, or to keep navigable waterways clear. Not until the 1840s - just as the corporation was becoming intertwined in the daily lives of ordinary men and women - was it held that corporations could be prosecuted criminally for malfeasance, at least when nonviolent misdemeanors were charged. Lawrence Mitchell Rothman, Life After Doe? Self-incrimination and Business Documents, 56 U. CIN. L. REV. 387, 403 n.82 (1987) (citations omitted).
  • 67
    • 49049099378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 494
    • Id. at 494.
  • 68
    • 49049100643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 495
    • Id. at 495.
  • 69
    • 49049095678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pamela H. Bucy, Organizational Sentencing Guidelines: The Cart Before the Horse, 71 WASH. U. L.Q. 329, 340 (1993) (describing the Court's reasoning as flawed and outdated).
    • See Pamela H. Bucy, Organizational Sentencing Guidelines: The Cart Before the Horse, 71 WASH. U. L.Q. 329, 340 (1993) (describing the Court's reasoning as "flawed and outdated").
  • 70
    • 49049087500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1885-89 (explaining that the government may seek civil fines or forfeiture; freeze the offender's assets; obtain cease and desist orders; withdraw necessary licenses or permits; and/or cancel government contracts and debar or disqualify the offender from contracting to supply future business to government agencies).
    • See Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1885-89 (explaining that the government may seek civil fines or forfeiture; freeze the offender's assets; obtain cease and desist orders; withdraw necessary licenses or permits; and/or cancel government contracts and debar or disqualify the offender from contracting to supply future business to government agencies).
  • 71
    • 49049096304 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vikamaditya S. Khanna, Corporate Crime Legislation: A Political Economy Analysis, 82 WASH. U. L.Q. 95, 95 (2004) ([M]ost corporate crime legislation arises when there is a large public outcry over a series of corporate scandals during or around a downturn in the economy.).
    • Vikamaditya S. Khanna, Corporate Crime Legislation: A Political Economy Analysis, 82 WASH. U. L.Q. 95, 95 (2004) ("[M]ost corporate crime legislation arises when there is a large public outcry over a series of corporate scandals during or around a downturn in the economy.").
  • 72
    • 49049098062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert A. Creamer, Criminal Law Concerns for Civil Lawyers, FED. LAW., May 2005, at 34, 35 (citing the thirteen federal criminal statutes that are most often invoked against individuals in white-collar cases). Unlike common law fraud, which required a showing of loss caused by a particular false statement, the federal mail and wire fraud statutes require only the use of the mails or interstate wires and a scheme to defraud a person of property or the intangible right to another person's honest services. HASNAS, supra note 18, at 12 (concluding that the federal fraud statutes authorize the punishment of almost any kind of dishonest or deceptive behavior, even when no other party has suffered any harm).
    • See Robert A. Creamer, Criminal Law Concerns for Civil Lawyers, FED. LAW., May 2005, at 34, 35 (citing the thirteen federal criminal statutes that are most often invoked against individuals in white-collar cases). Unlike common law fraud, which required a showing of loss caused by a particular false statement, the federal mail and wire fraud statutes require only the use of the mails or interstate wires and a scheme to defraud a person of property or the intangible right to another person's honest services. HASNAS, supra note 18, at 12 (concluding that the federal fraud statutes "authorize the punishment of almost any kind of dishonest or deceptive behavior, even when no other party has suffered any harm").
  • 73
    • 0009918541 scopus 로고
    • Does "Unlawful" Mean "Criminal"?: Reflections on the Disappearing Tort/Crime Distinction in American Law, 71
    • See
    • See John C. Coffee, Jr., Does "Unlawful" Mean "Criminal"?: Reflections on the Disappearing Tort/Crime Distinction in American Law, 71 B.U. L. REV. 193, 202 (1991).
    • (1991) B.U. L. REV , vol.193 , pp. 202
    • Coffee Jr., J.C.1
  • 74
    • 49049088902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Appeal and Limits of Internal Controls to Fight Fraud, Terrorism, Other Ills, 29 J. CORP. L. 267, 280 (2004) (noting the recent increase in corporate compliance programs).
    • See generally Lawrence A. Cunningham, The Appeal and Limits of Internal Controls to Fight Fraud, Terrorism, Other Ills, 29 J. CORP. L. 267, 280 (2004) (noting the recent increase in corporate compliance programs).
  • 76
    • 49049098814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rebecca Walker, The Evolution of the Law of Corporate Compliance in the United States: A Brief Overview, 1561 PLI/CORP 13 (2006). Later scandals in the defense contracting, health care, and securities industries prompted further rounds of internal controls. Id.
    • Rebecca Walker, The Evolution of the Law of Corporate Compliance in the United States: A Brief Overview, 1561 PLI/CORP 13 (2006). Later scandals in the defense contracting, health care, and securities industries prompted further rounds of internal controls. Id.
  • 77
    • 49049098990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See John C. Coffee, Jr., Paradigms Lost: The Blurring of the Criminal and Civil Law Models - And What Can Be Done About It, 101 YALE L.J. 1875, 1880 (1992) (explaining the vulnerability of corporations to be a result of the common statutory pattern in the United States for a statute establishing an administrative agency to provide that any willful violation of the rules adopted by the agency constitutes a federal felony).
    • See John C. Coffee, Jr., Paradigms Lost: The Blurring of the Criminal and Civil Law Models - And What Can Be Done About It, 101 YALE L.J. 1875, 1880 (1992) (explaining the vulnerability of corporations to be a result of "the common statutory pattern in the United States for a statute establishing an administrative agency to provide that any willful violation of the rules adopted by the agency constitutes a federal felony").
  • 78
    • 32044450366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Political Constitution of Criminal Justice, 119
    • For a more general discussion of over-criminalization and legislators' political incentives to err on the side of greater criminal liability than necessary, see
    • For a more general discussion of over-criminalization and legislators' political incentives to err on the side of greater criminal liability than necessary, see William J. Stuntz, The Political Constitution of Criminal Justice, 119 HARV. L. REV. 780, 802-07 (2006).
    • (2006) HARV. L. REV , vol.780 , pp. 802-807
    • Stuntz, W.J.1
  • 79
    • 49049100225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pamela H. Bucy, Moral Messengers: Delegating Prosecutorial Power, 59 SMU L. REV. 321, 327 (2006) (noting that states have lagged behind the federal government in passing aggressive laws).
    • See Pamela H. Bucy, Moral Messengers: Delegating Prosecutorial Power, 59 SMU L. REV. 321, 327 (2006) (noting that states have lagged behind the federal government in passing aggressive laws).
  • 80
    • 49049095031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 321 (discussing broad prosecutorial subpoena power). Unless protected by the attorney-client privilege or work product doctrines, entities must produce the documents specified in the grand jury subpoena. See id. They may not rely on the Fifth Amendment privilege against self-incrimination. See Hale v. Henkel, 201 U.S. 43, 74 (1906); HASNAS, supra note 18, at 27.
    • Id. at 321 (discussing broad prosecutorial subpoena power). Unless protected by the attorney-client privilege or work product doctrines, entities must produce the documents specified in the grand jury subpoena. See id. They may not rely on the Fifth Amendment privilege against self-incrimination. See Hale v. Henkel, 201 U.S. 43, 74 (1906); HASNAS, supra note 18, at 27.
  • 81
    • 49049107126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. R. Enters., 498 U.S. 292, 298 (1991) (emphasizing that rules and restrictions that apply at trial do not apply to grand jury proceedings); see also Niki Kuckes, The Useful, Dangerous Fiction of Grand Jury Independence, 41 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1, 3 (2004) (criticizing pretense that grand jury is independent from federal prosecutor).
    • United States v. R. Enters., 498 U.S. 292, 298 (1991) (emphasizing that rules and restrictions that apply at trial do not apply to grand jury proceedings); see also Niki Kuckes, The Useful, Dangerous Fiction of Grand Jury Independence, 41 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1, 3 (2004) (criticizing pretense that grand jury is independent from federal prosecutor).
  • 82
    • 49049117103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chavez v. Martinez, 538 U.S. 760, 767-68 (2003) (It is well established that the government may compel witnesses to testify at trial or before a grand jury, on pain of contempt, so long as the witness is not the target of the criminal case in which he testifies.).
    • Chavez v. Martinez, 538 U.S. 760, 767-68 (2003) ("It is well established that the government may compel witnesses to testify at trial or before a grand jury, on pain of contempt, so long as the witness is not the target of the criminal case in which he testifies.").
  • 83
    • 49049106935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 768 (Even for persons who have a legitimate fear that their statements may subject them to criminal prosecution, we have long permitted the compulsion of incriminating testimony so long as those statements (or evidence derived from those statements) cannot be used against the speaker in any criminal case.); Bucy, supra note 51, at 341 (discussing broad prosecutorial power to grant immunity).
    • See id. at 768 ("Even for persons who have a legitimate fear that their statements may subject them to criminal prosecution, we have long permitted the compulsion of incriminating testimony so long as those statements (or evidence derived from those statements) cannot be used against the speaker in any criminal case."); Bucy, supra note 51, at 341 (discussing broad prosecutorial power to grant immunity).
  • 84
    • 49049107523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fed. R. Crim. P. 41 (authorizing search warrants); 18 U.S.C. § 1505 (2000) (criminalizing obstruction of justice in federal investigations); 18 U.S.C. § 1511 (2000) (criminalizing obstruction of state or local investigations); 18 U.S.C. § 1519 (Supp. V 2005) (criminalizing destruction or alteration of records with the intent to impede or obstruct federal investigations).
    • See Fed. R. Crim. P. 41 (authorizing search warrants); 18 U.S.C. § 1505 (2000) (criminalizing obstruction of justice in federal investigations); 18 U.S.C. § 1511 (2000) (criminalizing obstruction of state or local investigations); 18 U.S.C. § 1519 (Supp. V 2005) (criminalizing destruction or alteration of records with the intent to impede or obstruct federal investigations).
  • 85
    • 33748581335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Susan R. Klein, Enhancing the Judicial Role in Criminal Plea and Sentence Bargaining, 84 TEX. L. REV. 2023, 2043-45 (2006). Compare FED. R. CRIM. P. 16, with FED. R. CRIM. P. 26.
    • See Susan R. Klein, Enhancing the Judicial Role in Criminal Plea and Sentence Bargaining, 84 TEX. L. REV. 2023, 2043-45 (2006). Compare FED. R. CRIM. P. 16, with FED. R. CRIM. P. 26.
  • 86
    • 49049116304 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • R. Enters., 498 U.S. at 301 (limiting quashing of grand jury subpoenas to situations in which there is no reasonable possibility of uncovering relevant information).
    • R. Enters., 498 U.S. at 301 (limiting quashing of grand jury subpoenas to situations in which there is no reasonable possibility of uncovering relevant information).
  • 87
    • 49049085446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Matter of Sealed Affidavits to Search Warrants Executed on February 14, 1977, 600 F.2d 1256, 1257 (9th Cir. 1979, courts have inherent power, as an incident of their constitutional function, to control papers filed within the courts within constitutional and other limitations, United States v. Napier, 436 F.3d 1133,1139 (9th Cir. 2006, affirming lower court's refusal to unseal portions of affidavit that related to confidential informant, Times Mirror Co. v. U.S. District Court, 873 F.2d 1210, 1219 (9th Cir. 1999, sealing of affidavit appropriate to protect pre-indictment investigation, See also David Horan, Breaking the Seal on White Collar Search Warrant Materials, 28 PEP. L. REV. 317, 324 2001, observing that sealing of federal search warrants has become common
    • Matter of Sealed Affidavits to Search Warrants Executed on February 14, 1977, 600 F.2d 1256, 1257 (9th Cir. 1979) ("courts have inherent power, as an incident of their constitutional function, to control papers filed within the courts within constitutional and other limitations"); United States v. Napier, 436 F.3d 1133,1139 (9th Cir. 2006) (affirming lower court's refusal to unseal portions of affidavit that related to confidential informant); Times Mirror Co. v. U.S. District Court, 873 F.2d 1210, 1219 (9th Cir. 1999) (sealing of affidavit appropriate to protect pre-indictment investigation). See also David Horan, Breaking the Seal on White Collar Search Warrant Materials, 28 PEP. L. REV. 317, 324 (2001) (observing that sealing of federal search warrants has become common).
  • 89
    • 49049101863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 90
    • 49049111788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In our system, so long as the prosecutor has probable cause to believe that the accused committed an offense defined by statute, the decision whether or not to prosecute, and what charge to file or bring before a grand jury, generally rests entirely in his discretion. Bordenkircher v. Hayes, 434 U.S. 357, 364 (1978); see also U.S. CONST. art. D, § 3 (granting Executive power to take Care that the Laws be faithfully executed).
    • "In our system, so long as the prosecutor has probable cause to believe that the accused committed an offense defined by statute, the decision whether or not to prosecute, and what charge to file or bring before a grand jury, generally rests entirely in his discretion." Bordenkircher v. Hayes, 434 U.S. 357, 364 (1978); see also U.S. CONST. art. D, § 3 (granting Executive power to "take Care that the Laws be faithfully executed").
  • 91
    • 49049106507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Linda R.S. v. Richard D., 410 U.S. 614, 619 (1973) (holding that private individuals lack judicially cognizable interest in prosecution of another person).
    • See generally Linda R.S. v. Richard D., 410 U.S. 614, 619 (1973) (holding that private individuals lack "judicially cognizable interest" in prosecution of another person).
  • 92
    • 49049122026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Williams, 504 U.S. 36, 48 (1992) (holding that prosecutor not required to seek court's approval for indictment).
    • United States v. Williams, 504 U.S. 36, 48 (1992) (holding that prosecutor not required to seek court's approval for indictment).
  • 93
    • 33846473169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DPAs fall within two broad categories. Some are drafted and entered into before the prosecutor has filed any charges whatsoever. In those instances, the DPA is purely private and the courts have no interest in these agreements ex ante. In a second group, the Government files an information or complaint, but the parties agree that it will be deferred for the length of time agreed upon in the DPA. A court then must sign off on the DPA insofar as it implicates the Speedy Trial Act. Other than the Speedy Trial Act concern, however, the court does not review the agreement's substance. See Wilson Meeks, Note, Corporate and White-Collar Crime Enforcement: Should Regulation and Rehabilitation Spell an End to Corporate Criminal Liability, 40 COLUM. J.L. & SOC. PROBS. 77, 107 2006
    • DPAs fall within two broad categories. Some are drafted and entered into before the prosecutor has filed any charges whatsoever. In those instances, the DPA is purely "private" and the courts have no interest in these agreements ex ante. In a second group, the Government files an information or complaint, but the parties agree that it will be deferred for the length of time agreed upon in the DPA. A court then must sign off on the DPA insofar as it implicates the Speedy Trial Act. Other than the Speedy Trial Act concern, however, the court does not review the agreement's substance. See Wilson Meeks, Note, Corporate and White-Collar Crime Enforcement: Should Regulation and Rehabilitation Spell an End to Corporate Criminal Liability?, 40 COLUM. J.L. & SOC. PROBS. 77, 107 (2006).
  • 94
    • 49049116814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For similar criticisms of the judiciary, see Richard A. Epstein, The Unintended Revolution in Products Liability Law, 10 CARDOZO L. REV. 2193, 2202-03 (1980) (Today all doctrinal innovation has to come from the courts, where the technical lags and information deficits are at their highest. Yet there is no alternative forum, save legislation, in which to override judgments when they have proved mistaken; indeed, there is no way to find out whether they are mistaken at all.).
    • For similar criticisms of the judiciary, see Richard A. Epstein, The Unintended Revolution in Products Liability Law, 10 CARDOZO L. REV. 2193, 2202-03 (1980) ("Today all doctrinal innovation has to come from the courts, where the technical lags and information deficits are at their highest. Yet there is no alternative forum, save legislation, in which to override judgments when they have proved mistaken; indeed, there is no way to find out whether they are mistaken at all.").
  • 95
    • 49049097264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bharara, supra note 2, at 72 (citing the widespread - and largely legitimate - view that white collar crime is singularly difficult to detect, investigate, and prosecute); Peter J. Henning, Testing the Limits of Investigating and Prosecuting White-Collar Crime: How Far Will the Courts Allow Prosecutors to Go?, 54 U. PITT. L. REV. 405 (1993) (analyzing current trends in white collar cases that courts are struggling to resolve).
    • See Bharara, supra note 2, at 72 (citing the "widespread - and largely legitimate - view that white collar crime is singularly difficult to detect, investigate, and prosecute"); Peter J. Henning, Testing the Limits of Investigating and Prosecuting White-Collar Crime: How Far Will the Courts Allow Prosecutors to Go?, 54 U. PITT. L. REV. 405 (1993) (analyzing current trends in white collar cases that courts are struggling to resolve).
  • 96
    • 49049110246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cohen, supra note 19, at 146-47
    • Cohen, supra note 19, at 146-47.
  • 97
    • 49049117104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally HASNAS, supra note 18, at 23-55 (describing solutions to enforcement of corporate criminal liability).
    • See generally HASNAS, supra note 18, at 23-55 (describing solutions to enforcement of corporate criminal liability).
  • 98
    • 49049102913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hale v. Henkel, 201 U.S. 43 (1906).
    • Hale v. Henkel, 201 U.S. 43 (1906).
  • 99
    • 49049088903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HASNAS, supra note 18, at 31-32
    • HASNAS, supra note 18, at 31-32.
  • 100
    • 49049100872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Frank O. Bowman, Pour Encourager Les Autres? The Curious History and Distressing Implications of the Criminal Provisions of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the Sentencing Guidelines Amendments that Followed, 1 OHIO ST. J. CRIM. L. 373 (2004) (tracking the increase of penalties for economic crime offenders under United States Sentencing Guidelines in 2001, and additional increases that occurred following passage of Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002);
    • See Frank O. Bowman, Pour Encourager Les Autres? The Curious History and Distressing Implications of the Criminal Provisions of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the Sentencing Guidelines Amendments that Followed, 1 OHIO ST. J. CRIM. L. 373 (2004) (tracking the increase of penalties for economic crime offenders under United States Sentencing Guidelines in 2001, and additional increases that occurred following passage of Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002);
  • 101
    • 49049085227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geraldine Szott Moohr, An Enron Lesson: The Modest Role of Criminal Law in Preventing Corporate Crime, 55 FLA. L. REV. 937, 954 (2003) (describing significant increases in statutory maximum penalties for economic crimes pursuant to Sarbanes-Oxley).
    • Geraldine Szott Moohr, An Enron Lesson: The Modest Role of Criminal Law in Preventing Corporate Crime, 55 FLA. L. REV. 937, 954 (2003) (describing significant increases in statutory maximum penalties for economic crimes pursuant to Sarbanes-Oxley).
  • 102
    • 49049093387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In a 2005 speech, Mary Jo White, a former United States Attorney of the Southern District of New York, soberly warned an audience of defense attorneys: [T]he sweep of corporate criminal liability could hardly be broader. All of you in this audience probably know the law well, but its breathtaking scope always bears repeating: If a single employee, however low down in the corporate hierarchy, commits a crime in the course of his or her employment, even in part to benefit the corporation, the corporate employer is criminally liable for that employee's crime. It is essentially absolute liability. Mary Jo White, Corporate Criminal Liability: What Has Gone Wrong, 1517 PLI/CORP 815 2005
    • In a 2005 speech, Mary Jo White, a former United States Attorney of the Southern District of New York, soberly warned an audience of defense attorneys: [T]he sweep of corporate criminal liability could hardly be broader. All of you in this audience probably know the law well, but its breathtaking scope always bears repeating: If a single employee, however low down in the corporate hierarchy, commits a crime in the course of his or her employment, even in part to benefit the corporation, the corporate employer is criminally liable for that employee's crime. It is essentially absolute liability. Mary Jo White, Corporate Criminal Liability: What Has Gone Wrong?, 1517 PLI/CORP 815 (2005).
  • 103
    • 49049088503 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Automated Med. Labs
    • See, e.g., United States v. Automated Med. Labs, 770 F.2d 399 (4th Cir. 1985).
    • (1985) 770 F.2d 399 (4th Cir
  • 104
    • 49049109614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Hilton Hotels Corp., 467 F.2d 1000 (9th Cir. 1972).
    • United States v. Hilton Hotels Corp., 467 F.2d 1000 (9th Cir. 1972).
  • 105
    • 49049116489 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Bank of New Eng
    • See United States v. Bank of New Eng., 821 F.2d 844 (1st Cir. 1987).
    • (1987) 821 F.2d 844 (1st Cir
  • 106
    • 49049102186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HASNAS, supra note 18, at 12 (federal criminal law statutes such as mail fraud statute authorize the punishment of almost any kind of dishonest or deceptive behavior, even when no other party has suffered harm).
    • See HASNAS, supra note 18, at 12 (federal criminal law statutes such as mail fraud statute "authorize the punishment of almost any kind of dishonest or deceptive behavior, even when no other party has suffered harm").
  • 107
    • 49049083371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legislative and regulatory responses to private sector crises using internal controls enable the state to reach into the private sector to exert power, while preserving the essentially private character of its organizations and their operation. Cunningham, supra note 56, at 281.
    • "Legislative and regulatory responses to private sector crises using internal controls enable the state to reach into the private sector to exert power, while preserving the essentially private character of its organizations and their operation." Cunningham, supra note 56, at 281.
  • 108
    • 49049105055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 33, at 718. Arlen and Kraakman further distinguish between adjusted strict liability regimes that hold firms strictly liable for their employees' crimes, but insulate their monitoring results (through an evidentiary privilege, for example); and composite regimes, which hold firms liable for all detected wrongs but impos[e] an additional sanction on firms with suboptimal policing measures. Id. at 726. As used in this Article, the term composite liability refers to this second category of mixed liability regimes.
    • Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 33, at 718. Arlen and Kraakman further distinguish between "adjusted strict liability" regimes that hold firms strictly liable for their employees' crimes, but insulate their monitoring results (through an evidentiary privilege, for example); and "composite regimes," which hold firms liable for "all detected wrongs but impos[e] an additional sanction on firms with suboptimal policing measures." Id. at 726. As used in this Article, the term "composite liability" refers to this second category of mixed liability regimes.
  • 109
    • 49049112542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 715-16
    • Id. at 715-16.
  • 110
    • 49049096806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 111
    • 49049092919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 112
    • 49049093719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 707-09; see also Jennifer Arlen, The Potentially Perverse Effects of Corporate Criminal Liability, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 833 (1994) (presenting an economic analysis of the impact of strict liability on corporate expenditures on enforcement costs). Even under a strict liability regime, some corporate managers will employ monitoring as a form of self-defense, which in turn may disclose crimes that help the organization.
    • Id. at 707-09; see also Jennifer Arlen, The Potentially Perverse Effects of Corporate Criminal Liability, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 833 (1994) (presenting an economic analysis of the impact of strict liability on corporate expenditures on enforcement costs). Even under a strict liability regime, some corporate managers will employ monitoring as a form of self-defense, which in turn may disclose crimes that "help" the organization.
  • 113
    • 49049116416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, a CFO who is cooking the books might also be siphoning money from corporate accounts into his own bank account. If organizations employ controls to deter the second type of conduct, they may simultaneously detect the first type. See James D. Cox, Private Litigation and the Deterrence of Corporate Misconduct, 60 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 1, 14-15 (1997). Self-defensive monitoring, however, may be insufficient if the employee of the organization is effectively insulated from the effects of the employee's criminal conduct (e.g., dumping toxic chemicals into a river that is located far away).
    • For example, a CFO who is cooking the books might also be siphoning money from corporate accounts into his own bank account. If organizations employ controls to deter the second type of conduct, they may simultaneously detect the first type. See James D. Cox, Private Litigation and the Deterrence of Corporate Misconduct, 60 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 1, 14-15 (1997). Self-defensive monitoring, however, may be insufficient if the employee of the organization is effectively insulated from the effects of the employee's criminal conduct (e.g., dumping toxic chemicals into a river that is located far away).
  • 114
    • 49049084326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nor does it ensure that corporations will report to authorities the misconduct that they detect. Cf. Richard A. Epstein, Imperfect Liability Regimes: Individual and Corporate Issues, 53 S.C. L. REV. 1153, 1156-57 (2001) (in the context of automobile accidents, observing that self-bonding is an incomplete deterrent when injurer can insulate himself from harm).
    • Nor does it ensure that corporations will report to authorities the misconduct that they detect. Cf. Richard A. Epstein, Imperfect Liability Regimes: Individual and Corporate Issues, 53 S.C. L. REV. 1153, 1156-57 (2001) (in the context of automobile accidents, observing that self-bonding is an incomplete deterrent when injurer can insulate himself from harm).
  • 115
    • 49049098916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 33, at 707, and Arlen, supra note 91, at 836, for discussions of diversion of resources. For cosmetic compliance, see Vikramaditya S. Khanna, Should the Behavior of Top Management Matter?, 91 GEO. L.J. 1215, 1231 (2003) (describing window dressing measures);
    • See Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 33, at 707, and Arlen, supra note 91, at 836, for discussions of diversion of resources. For
  • 116
    • 49049106652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kimberly D. Krawiec, Cosmetic Compliance and the Failure of Negotiated Governance, 81 WASH. U. L.Q. 487 (2003).
    • Kimberly D. Krawiec, Cosmetic Compliance and the Failure of Negotiated Governance, 81 WASH. U. L.Q. 487 (2003).
  • 117
    • 49049090858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 33, at 714-15. If the probability of detection were already very high, firms subject to strict liability might still adopt monitoring regimes since they would not increase the probability of detection substantially. See Khanna, supra note 92, at 1232.
    • Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 33, at 714-15. If the probability of detection were already very high, firms subject to strict liability might still adopt monitoring regimes since they would not increase the probability of detection substantially. See Khanna, supra note 92, at 1232.
  • 118
    • 49049104690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Khanna, supra note 92, at 1268-69
    • See Khanna, supra note 92, at 1268-69.
  • 119
    • 49049087702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I am referring to the tri-partite discussion of regulation (command-and-control rules, performance based standards, and incentives) set out by Susan Rose-Ackerman and amplified by Jon Hanson and Kyle Logue. Jon D. Hanson & Kyle D. Logue, The Costs of Cigarettes: The Economic Case for Ex Post Incentive-Based Regulation, 107 YALE L.J. 1163, 1173-74, 1264 (1998) (citing SUSAN ROSE-ACKERMAN, RETHINKING THE PROGRESSIVE AGENDA: THE REFORM OF THE AMERICAN REGULATORY STATE (1992)).
    • I am referring to the tri-partite discussion of regulation (command-and-control rules, performance based standards, and incentives) set out by Susan Rose-Ackerman and amplified by Jon Hanson and Kyle Logue. Jon D. Hanson & Kyle D. Logue, The Costs of Cigarettes: The Economic Case for Ex Post Incentive-Based Regulation, 107 YALE L.J. 1163, 1173-74, 1264 (1998) (citing SUSAN ROSE-ACKERMAN, RETHINKING THE PROGRESSIVE AGENDA: THE REFORM OF THE AMERICAN REGULATORY STATE (1992)).
  • 120
    • 49049085844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The most profound problem with [the composite regime] is the likely indeterminacy of the undertaking to engage in 'optimal' compliance efforts. Such a finding will be made ex post and there likely will be little guidance ex ante as to what constitutes optimal compliance efforts. Cox, supra note 91, at 16 (emphasis in original).
    • "The most profound problem with [the composite regime] is the likely indeterminacy of the undertaking to engage in 'optimal' compliance efforts. Such a finding will be made ex post and there likely will be little guidance ex ante as to what constitutes optimal compliance efforts." Cox, supra note 91, at 16 (emphasis in original).
  • 121
    • 0013317678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is unclear how the DOJ would respond to instances in which prosecutors failed to adhere to these policies, which expressly deny the creation of any substantive or procedural rights for business entities. See, e.g., McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 19. The Department of Justice historically has exercised uneven levels of authority over the United States Attorneys' offices. See Daniel C. Richman, Federal Criminal Law, Congressional Delegation, and Enforcement Discretion, 46 UCLA L. REV. 757, 805 (1999) (discussing dispersed authority of U.S. Attorneys' offices).
    • It is unclear how the DOJ would respond to instances in which prosecutors failed to adhere to these policies, which expressly deny the creation of any substantive or procedural rights for business entities. See, e.g., McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 19. The Department of Justice historically has exercised uneven levels of authority over the United States Attorneys' offices. See Daniel C. Richman, Federal Criminal Law, Congressional Delegation, and Enforcement Discretion, 46 UCLA L. REV. 757, 805 (1999) (discussing dispersed authority of U.S. Attorneys' offices).
  • 122
    • 49049093802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The SEC maintains a separate Framework for Cooperation by which its Enforcement Division evaluates whether corporations should be fined or criminally prosecuted for their employee's violations of the security laws. Like the DOJ's internal policies, the SEC's framework urges its regulators to examine the organization's compliance program and its subsequent cooperation with SEC staff. Criminal charging decisions, however, are ultimately made by the prosecutors within the United States Attorneys' Offices and the Department of Justice. The relationship between federal prosecutors and regulators and the costs and benefits of parallel civil and criminal litigation is beyond the scope of this Article
    • The SEC maintains a separate Framework for Cooperation by which its Enforcement Division evaluates whether corporations should be fined or criminally prosecuted for their employee's violations of the security laws. Like the DOJ's internal policies, the SEC's framework urges its regulators to examine the organization's compliance program and its subsequent cooperation with SEC staff. Criminal charging decisions, however, are ultimately made by the prosecutors within the United States Attorneys' Offices and the Department of Justice. The relationship between federal prosecutors and regulators and the costs and benefits of parallel civil and criminal litigation is beyond the scope of this Article.
  • 123
    • 49049092778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McNulty Memo, supra note 19
    • See McNulty Memo, supra note 19.
  • 125
    • 33745934648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under Pressure to Catch the Crooks: The Impact of Corporate Privilege Waiver on the Adversarial System, 43
    • Earl J. Silbert & Demme Doufekias Joannou, Under Pressure to Catch the Crooks: The Impact of Corporate Privilege Waiver on the Adversarial System, 43 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1225, 1238 (2006).
    • (2006) AM. CRIM. L. REV , vol.1225 , pp. 1238
    • Silbert, E.J.1    Doufekias Joannou, D.2
  • 126
    • 49049112203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On September 13, 2006, Paul McNulty, then Deputy Attorney General, announced during testimony before the Judiciary Committee (then headed by Specter) that the Department of Justice was reviewing its internal charging memorandum in light of the criticism of the KPMG case. See Lynnley Browning, Justice Department is Reviewing Corporate Prosecution Guidelines, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 13, 2006, at C3.
    • On September 13, 2006, Paul McNulty, then Deputy Attorney General, announced during testimony before the Judiciary Committee (then headed by Specter) that the Department of Justice was reviewing its internal charging memorandum in light of the criticism of the KPMG case. See Lynnley Browning, Justice Department is Reviewing Corporate Prosecution Guidelines, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 13, 2006, at C3.
  • 127
    • 49049085653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 8. In order to obtain such approval, the individual prosecutor must demonstrate a legitimate need for such documents, which in turn depends on: (a) the likelihood the privileged information will assist the government's investigation; (b) whether alternate means of obtaining the information exist; (c) the completeness of the organization's voluntary disclosure; and (d) the collateral consequences of waiver to the corporation. Id. at 9.
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 8. In order to obtain such approval, the individual prosecutor must demonstrate a "legitimate need" for such documents, which in turn depends on: (a) the likelihood the privileged information will assist the government's investigation; (b) whether alternate means of obtaining the information exist; (c) the completeness of the organization's voluntary disclosure; and (d) the collateral consequences of waiver to the corporation. Id. at 9.
  • 128
    • 49049105385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prosecutors generally should not take into account whether a corporation is advancing attorneys' fees to employees or agents under investigation and indictment. Id. at 11. A footnote suggests, however, that such payments may be taken into account if it appears that the corporation is behaving in such a manner as to obstruct the investigation. Id. at 11 n.3. It is unclear what the DOJ means by this footnote since any payment of fees is obstructive insofar as it assists a target in leveraging his defense.
    • "Prosecutors generally should not take into account whether a corporation is advancing attorneys' fees to employees or agents under investigation and indictment." Id. at 11. A footnote suggests, however, that such payments may be taken into account if it appears that the corporation is behaving in such a manner as to obstruct the investigation. Id. at 11 n.3. It is unclear what the DOJ means by this footnote since any payment of fees is "obstructive" insofar as it assists a target in leveraging his defense.
  • 129
    • 49049084414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The first DOJ memo to set forth the government's position on charging corporations for their employees' crimes was released by Deputy Attorney General Eric Holder in 1999. The Holder Memo, which originally was not released to the public, was intended only as a summary of best practices that different United States Attorneys' Offices had adopted, partly in response to the Organizational Sentencing Guidelines, which also employed a similar carrot and stick approach. Finder & McConnell, supra note 14, at 3, 6-9.
    • The first DOJ memo to set forth the government's position on charging corporations for their employees' crimes was released by Deputy Attorney General Eric Holder in 1999. The Holder Memo, which originally was not released to the public, was intended only as a summary of "best" practices that different United States Attorneys' Offices had adopted, partly in response to the Organizational Sentencing Guidelines, which also employed a similar "carrot and stick" approach. Finder & McConnell, supra note 14, at 3, 6-9.
  • 130
    • 49049106231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Memorandum from Larry D. Thompson, Deputy Attorney General, to United States Attorneys, Principles of Federal Prosecution of Business Organizations (Jan. 20, 2003), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/ cftf/business_organizations.pdf [hereinafter Thompson Memo]; McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 2;
    • Memorandum from Larry D. Thompson, Deputy Attorney General, to United States Attorneys, Principles of Federal Prosecution of Business Organizations (Jan. 20, 2003), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/ cftf/business_organizations.pdf [hereinafter Thompson Memo]; McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 2;
  • 131
    • 33745953363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Push Down the Road of Good Corporate Citizenship: The Deferred Prosecution Agreement Between the U.S. Attorney for the District of New Jersey and Bristol-Meyers Squibb Co., 43
    • noting that the Thompson Memo's analytical framework applies in all corporate fraud investigations, see also
    • see also Christopher J. Christie & Robert M. Hanna, A Push Down the Road of Good Corporate Citizenship: The Deferred Prosecution Agreement Between the U.S. Attorney for the District of New Jersey and Bristol-Meyers Squibb Co., 43 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1043, 1045 (2006) (noting that the Thompson Memo's "analytical framework applies in all corporate fraud investigations").
    • (2006) AM. CRIM. L. REV , vol.1043 , pp. 1045
    • Christie, C.J.1    Hanna, R.M.2
  • 132
    • 49049106074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 4; Thompson Memo, supra note 105, at 3-4. Those nine factors are: (1) the nature and seriousness of the offense; (2) the pervasiveness of wrongdoing within the organization; (3) the organization's history of similar conduct; (4) the organization's timely and voluntary disclosure of wrongdoing and its willingness to cooperate in the investigation of its agents including willingness to waive the attorney-client privilege; (5) the existence and adequacy of the corporation's compliance program; (6) remedial actions, including any efforts to implement an effective corporate compliance program or to improve an existing one or to replace, discipline, or terminate wrongdoers; (7) collateral consequences and impact on the public arising from the prosecution; (8) the adequacy of the prosecution of individuals responsible for the corporation's malfeasance; and (9) the adequacy of civil or regulator
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 4; Thompson Memo, supra note 105, at 3-4. Those nine factors are: (1) the nature and seriousness of the offense; (2) the "pervasiveness of wrongdoing within the organization; (3) the organization's history of similar conduct; (4) the organization's "timely and voluntary disclosure of wrongdoing and its willingness to cooperate in the investigation of its agents" including willingness to waive the attorney-client privilege; (5) the "existence and adequacy of the corporation's compliance program"; (6) remedial actions, including any efforts to implement an "effective" corporate compliance program or to improve an existing one or to replace, discipline, or terminate "wrongdoers"; (7) collateral consequences and impact on the public arising from the prosecution; (8) the adequacy of the prosecution of individuals responsible for the corporation's malfeasance; and (9) the adequacy of civil or regulatory enforcement actions. Id.
  • 133
    • 49049106310 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 1
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 1.
  • 134
    • 49049084825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Pub. L. 107-204, 116 Stat. 745 (2002).
    • See Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Pub. L. 107-204, 116 Stat. 745 (2002).
  • 135
    • 49049095265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 2; Thompson Memo, supra note 105, at 1.
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 2; Thompson Memo, supra note 105, at 1.
  • 136
    • 0040740672 scopus 로고
    • Corporate Ethos: A Standard for Imposing Corporate Criminal Liability, 75
    • Buell, supra note 39. E.g
    • E.g., Pamela H. Bucy, Corporate Ethos: A Standard for Imposing Corporate Criminal Liability, 75 MINN. L. REV. 1095, 1099 (1991); Buell, supra note 39.
    • (1991) MINN. L. REV , vol.1095 , pp. 1099
    • Bucy, P.H.1
  • 137
    • 0345818470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • According to Professor Brown: Criminal law has well established ways to address conduct that wrongly compels others to commit crimes - for example, liability for coercion and duress defenses - or wrongly encourages or aids others in crime commission - for example, complicity and accomplice liability. And when another's influence on an actor's conduct falls short of complicity . . . no liability follows, even though it may be a real influence. Darryl K. Brown, Street Crime, Corporate Crime and the Contingency of Criminal Liability, 149 U. PA. L. REV. 1295, 1318 (2001).
    • According to Professor Brown: Criminal law has well established ways to address conduct that wrongly compels others to commit crimes - for example, liability for coercion and duress defenses - or wrongly encourages or aids others in crime commission - for example, complicity and accomplice liability. And when another's influence on an actor's conduct falls short of complicity . . . no liability follows, even though it may be a real influence. Darryl K. Brown, Street Crime, Corporate Crime and the Contingency of Criminal Liability, 149 U. PA. L. REV. 1295, 1318 (2001).
  • 138
    • 49049104352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ADOLF A. BERLE & GARDINER C. MEANS, THE MODERN CORPORATION AND PRIVATE PROPERTY (1932).
    • See ADOLF A. BERLE & GARDINER C. MEANS, THE MODERN CORPORATION AND PRIVATE PROPERTY (1932).
  • 139
    • 44649197264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Agency costs are the costs that arise when managers' interests diverge from those of the principals (shareholders) on whose behalf they act. See Michael C. Jensen & William H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure, 3 J. FIN. ECON. 305 (1976). Agency costs have often been described as one of the central problems organizing the field of corporate law.
    • Agency costs are the costs that arise when managers' interests diverge from those of the principals (shareholders) on whose behalf they act. See Michael C. Jensen & William H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure, 3 J. FIN. ECON. 305 (1976). Agency costs have often been described as "one of the central problems organizing the field of corporate law."
  • 140
    • 0347739373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vicarious Liability in Tort: On the Sources and Limits of Employee Reasonableness, 69
    • Steven P. Croley, Vicarious Liability in Tort: On the Sources and Limits of Employee Reasonableness, 69 S. CAL. L. REV. 1705, 1715 (1996).
    • (1996) S. CAL. L. REV , vol.1705 , pp. 1715
    • Croley, S.P.1
  • 141
    • 49049091657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As explained by Dean Oakes: The truth is that organizational failure is caused by more than a failure in coordination, planning or information processing. There are micro-economic rewards and punishments within the organization and varying levels of leadership and employee motivation. The corporate setting is even more complicated by concepts and practices such as team production, work groups, independent departmental profit and loss calculations, etc. Richard T. Oakes, Anthropomorphic Projection and Chapter Eight of the Federal Sentencing Guidelines: Punishing the Good Organization When It Does Evil, 22 HAMLINE L. REV. 749, 759 1999, see also Croley, supra note 113, at 1706, R]eal firms are not monolithic actors, rather, they are networks of many semi-autonomous actors whose behavior is related in many complicated and contingent ways
    • As explained by Dean Oakes: The truth is that organizational failure is caused by more than a failure in coordination, planning or information processing. There are micro-economic rewards and punishments within the organization and varying levels of leadership and employee motivation. The corporate setting is even more complicated by concepts and practices such as team production, work groups, independent departmental profit and loss calculations, etc. Richard T. Oakes, Anthropomorphic Projection and Chapter Eight of the Federal Sentencing Guidelines: Punishing the Good Organization When It Does Evil, 22 HAMLINE L. REV. 749, 759 (1999); see also Croley, supra note 113, at 1706 ("[R]eal firms are not monolithic actors . . . [rather,] they are networks of many semi-autonomous actors whose behavior is related in many complicated and contingent ways.").
  • 142
    • 49049104150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a similar criticism of enterprise liability for fraud on the market, see Jennifer H. Arlen & William J. Carney, Vicarious Liability for Fraud on Security Markets: Theory and Evidence, 1992 U. ILL. L. REV. 691, 693 (1992, S]hareholders face collective action problems because they are too numerous to manage the firm, They therefore hire agents (directors) to manage it for them. These directors, not the firm's owners, decide how the firm will deter wrongful acts by its agents, But, t]hese directors may not impose optimal sanctions on the firm's agents. This possibility introduces an additional level of agency costs [and, is particularly important in Fraud on the Market cases, because Fraud on the Market is generally committed by some of the very directors and senior officers hired to manage the firm and to deter fraud. Id, citation omitted);
    • For a similar criticism of enterprise liability for fraud on the market, see Jennifer H. Arlen & William J. Carney, Vicarious Liability for Fraud on Security Markets: Theory and Evidence, 1992 U. ILL. L. REV. 691, 693 (1992): [S]hareholders face collective action problems because they are too numerous to manage the firm . . . . They therefore hire agents (directors) to manage it for them. These directors, not the firm's owners, decide how the firm will deter wrongful acts by its agents. . . . [But] [t]hese directors may not impose optimal sanctions on the firm's agents. This possibility introduces an additional level of agency costs [and] . . . is particularly important in Fraud on the Market cases, because Fraud on the Market is generally committed by some of the very directors and senior officers hired to manage the firm and to deter fraud. Id. (citation omitted);
  • 143
    • 33845795315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also John C. Coffee, Reforming the Securities Class Action: An Essay on Deterrence and Its Implementation, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 1534, 1537 (2006) (To punish the corporation and its shareholders in such a case is much like seeking to deter burglary by imposing penalties on the victim for having suffered a burglary.).
    • see also John C. Coffee, Reforming the Securities Class Action: An Essay on Deterrence and Its Implementation, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 1534, 1537 (2006) ("To punish the corporation and its shareholders in such a case is much like seeking to deter burglary by imposing penalties on the victim for having suffered a burglary.").
  • 144
    • 27844582941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 2. This deterrence argument nevertheless rests in part on a belief that government can improve the moral fiber of individuals who run corporate firms. SEC officials, for example, have claimed an obligation to improve the moral DNA of corporate executives. See Cristie L. Ford, Toward a New Model for Securities Law Enforcement, 57 ADMIN. L. REV. 757, 773 (2005) (quoting then-SEC Chairman William Donaldson's 2004 speech to the Practicing Law Institute).
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 2. This deterrence argument nevertheless rests in part on a belief that government can improve the moral fiber of individuals who run corporate firms. SEC officials, for example, have claimed an obligation to improve the "moral DNA" of corporate executives. See Cristie L. Ford, Toward a New Model for Securities Law Enforcement, 57 ADMIN. L. REV. 757, 773 (2005) (quoting then-SEC Chairman William Donaldson's 2004 speech to the Practicing Law Institute).
  • 145
    • 49049115907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, the DOJ's attempt to define good corporate governance is in stark contrast to the business judgment rule, which ordinarily leaves the internal affairs of the corporation to its board of directors. See Del. Code Ann. tit. 8, § 141(a) (2007); Smith v. Van Gorkom, 488 A.2d 858 (Del. 1985). The corollary to this rule is that shareholders are best served when board members are not unduly risk averse (i.e., when they are free to make decisions that later on turn out to be wrong). See, e.g., Gagliardi v. Trifoods Int'l, 683 A.2d 1049, 1052 (Del. Ch. 1996).
    • Indeed, the DOJ's attempt to define good corporate governance is in stark contrast to the business judgment rule, which ordinarily leaves the internal affairs of the corporation to its board of directors. See Del. Code Ann. tit. 8, § 141(a) (2007); Smith v. Van Gorkom, 488 A.2d 858 (Del. 1985). The corollary to this rule is that shareholders are best served when board members are not unduly risk averse (i.e., when they are free to make decisions that later on turn out to be wrong). See, e.g., Gagliardi v. Trifoods Int'l, 683 A.2d 1049, 1052 (Del. Ch. 1996).
  • 146
    • 49049095679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In many of the cases we have seen in the past couple of years, two of the most important factors we've focused on are the corporation's culture, and the authenticity of the company's cooperation. Those two factors are, in some sense, two sides of the same coin. Christopher Wray, Assistant Attorney General, Criminal Division, Department of Justice, Remarks at the 22nd Annual Corporate Counsel Institute (Dec. 12, 2003) 5, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/criminal/pr/speeches/2003/12/ 2003_2986_rmrk121203Corprtconslinst.pdf.
    • "In many of the cases we have seen in the past couple of years, two of the most important factors we've focused on are the corporation's culture, and the authenticity of the company's cooperation. Those two factors are, in some sense, two sides of the same coin." Christopher Wray, Assistant Attorney General, Criminal Division, Department of Justice, Remarks at the 22nd Annual Corporate Counsel Institute (Dec. 12, 2003) 5, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/criminal/pr/speeches/2003/12/ 2003_2986_rmrk121203Corprtconslinst.pdf.
  • 147
    • 49049091736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 14; Thompson Memo, supra note 105, at 7.
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 14; Thompson Memo, supra note 105, at 7.
  • 148
    • 49049112540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 14; Thompson Memo, supra note 105, at 7.
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 14; Thompson Memo, supra note 105, at 7.
  • 149
    • 49049117105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In contrast, the Delaware Chancery Court's decision in In re Caremark International, Inc., 698 A.2d 959 (Del. Ch. 1996), which both Memos cite, simply held that directors should ensure that some method of measuring compliance or internal controls existed within the firm. In fact, the Caremark court stressed that the level of detail that is appropriate for [a legal compliance] system is a question of business judgment and that, at least as Delaware law was concerned, board members should not be held civilly liable for trusting their employees absent grounds to suspect deception. Id. at 970. Many of the compliance programs that are the source of federal scrutiny would meet the standard laid out by Chancellor Allen in Caremark.
    • In contrast, the Delaware Chancery Court's decision in In re Caremark International, Inc., 698 A.2d 959 (Del. Ch. 1996), which both Memos cite, simply held that directors should ensure that some method of measuring compliance or internal controls existed within the firm. In fact, the Caremark court stressed that "the level of detail that is appropriate for [a legal compliance] system is a question of business judgment" and that, at least as Delaware law was concerned, board members should not be held civilly liable for trusting their employees "absent grounds to suspect deception." Id. at 970. Many of the compliance programs that are the source of federal scrutiny would meet the standard laid out by Chancellor Allen in Caremark.
  • 150
    • 49049116689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Paul Rose, The Corporate Governance Industry, 32 J. CORP. L. 887, 908 (A review of recent finance literature suggests that a number of the governance metrics selected [by rating agencies] do not reliably predict firm performance.).
    • See Paul Rose, The Corporate Governance Industry, 32 J. CORP. L. 887, 908 ("A review of recent finance literature suggests that a number of the governance metrics selected [by rating agencies] do not reliably predict firm performance.").
  • 151
    • 42649121771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deterrence's Difficulty, 95
    • See generally
    • See generally Neal Kumar Katyal, Deterrence's Difficulty, 95 MICH. L. REV. 2385, 2387 (1997);
    • (1997) MICH. L. REV , vol.2385 , pp. 2387
    • Kumar Katyal, N.1
  • 152
    • 33750506264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chris W. Sanchirico, Detection Avoidance, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1331, 1352-60 (2006) (discussing detection avoidance costs).
    • Chris W. Sanchirico, Detection Avoidance, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1331, 1352-60 (2006) (discussing detection avoidance costs).
  • 153
    • 49049105142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sanchirico, supra note 123, at 1368-69
    • See Sanchirico, supra note 123, at 1368-69.
  • 154
    • 49049101576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Katyal, supra note 123, at 2387
    • See Katyal, supra note 123, at 2387.
  • 155
    • 49049101769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2387; Sanchirico, supra note 123, at 1337
    • Id. at 2387; Sanchirico, supra note 123, at 1337.
  • 156
    • 56449108573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Imagine at a given time T, a crime produces a Benefit, B, of 10, with a 1% Probability of Detection, p, and Sanction, s, of 100. Under such conditions, B is greater than the expected value of the penalty (p multiplied by s) and the rational criminal will commit the crime. If, sometime during or following the commission of the crime, at T1, Company X increases its enforcement efforts such that expected penalty increases to 20 (either by increasing sanctions or probability of detection, then the costs of the conduct outweigh the benefits since 20 obviously exceeds 10. Criminals who have not yet committed the crime will be deterred. Criminals who have committed prior crimes and who are committed to engaging in future crimes in order to cover up the initial crimes (such as fraudulent financial reports for public companies) are much less likely to be deterred, however, because the benefit now includes the foregone sanction from the prior crime assu
    • Imagine at a given time T, a crime produces a Benefit, B, of 10, with a 1% Probability of Detection, p, and Sanction, s, of 100. Under such conditions, B is greater than the expected value of the penalty (p multiplied by s) and the rational criminal will commit the crime. If, sometime during or following the commission of the crime, at T1, Company X increases its enforcement efforts such that expected penalty increases to 20 (either by increasing sanctions or probability of detection), then the costs of the conduct outweigh the benefits since 20 obviously exceeds 10. Criminals who have not yet committed the crime will be deterred. Criminals who have committed prior crimes and who are committed to engaging in future crimes in order to cover up the initial crimes (such as fraudulent financial reports for public companies) are much less likely to be deterred, however, because the benefit now includes the foregone sanction from the prior crime assuming cessation of criminal conduct increases the probability of detection to 100%. Or, 10 + 100 [the benefit plus the foregone sanction] > 20 [the expected value of the new penalty] For a more in depth discussion of this timing problem, see Miriam H. Baer, Linkage and the Deterrence of Corporate Fraud, 94 VA. L. REV. (2008) (forthcoming).
  • 157
    • 49049121143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Katyal, supra note 123, at 2415
    • Katyal, supra note 123, at 2415.
  • 158
    • 49049097996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2414 (pointing out that equal detection rates may bring down the overall crime rate but encourage the proliferation of particularly heinous crimes).
    • Id. at 2414 (pointing out that equal detection rates may bring down the overall crime rate but encourage the proliferation of "particularly heinous" crimes).
  • 159
    • 84867666491 scopus 로고
    • Criminal Law and the Optimal Use of Nonmonetary Sanctions as a Deterrent, 85
    • explaining that uniformly high sanctions eliminate marginal deterrence for varying crimes, See
    • See Steven Shavell, Criminal Law and the Optimal Use of Nonmonetary Sanctions as a Deterrent, 85 COLUM. L. REV. 1232, 1245-46 (1985) (explaining that uniformly high sanctions eliminate marginal deterrence for varying crimes).
    • (1985) COLUM. L. REV , vol.1232 , pp. 1245-1246
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 160
    • 49049103845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Katyal, supra note 123, at 2414-15 discussing problems when range of sanctions is limited
    • See Katyal, supra note 123, at 2414-15 (discussing problems when range of sanctions is limited).
  • 161
    • 49049121703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cleave another violation with a sanction and you discourage it. Cleave detection avoidance, and like the hydra, it grows another head. Sanchirico, supra note 123, at 1367.
    • "Cleave another violation with a sanction and you discourage it. Cleave detection avoidance, and like the hydra, it grows another head." Sanchirico, supra note 123, at 1367.
  • 162
    • 49049118842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Christine Jolls, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard H. Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, in BEHAVIORAL LAW AND ECONOMICS 38-39 (Cass R. Sunstein ed., 2000) (discussing hindsight bias in the context of negligence determinations by juries). These biases and heuristics apply informatively to prosecutors.
    • See generally Christine Jolls, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard H. Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, in BEHAVIORAL LAW AND ECONOMICS 38-39 (Cass R. Sunstein ed., 2000) (discussing hindsight bias in the context of negligence determinations by juries). These biases and heuristics apply informatively to prosecutors.
  • 163
    • 36849066160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Improving Prosecutorial Decision Making: Some Lessons of Cognitive Science, 47
    • See
    • See Alafair S. Burke, Improving Prosecutorial Decision Making: Some Lessons of Cognitive Science, 47 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1587, 1590-91 (2006);
    • (2006) WM. & MARY L. REV , vol.1587 , pp. 1590-1591
    • Burke, A.S.1
  • 164
    • 33747496708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keith A. Findley & Michael S. Scott, The Multiple Dimensions of Tunnel Vision in Criminal Cases, 2006 WIS. L. REV. 291 (2006) (discussing hindsight bias as it applies to criminal prosecutions);
    • Keith A. Findley & Michael S. Scott, The Multiple Dimensions of Tunnel Vision in Criminal Cases, 2006 WIS. L. REV. 291 (2006) (discussing hindsight bias as it applies to criminal prosecutions);
  • 165
    • 33748568161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rachel E. Barkow & Kathleen M. O'Neill, Delegating Punitive Power: The Political Economy of Sentencing Commission and Guideline Formation, 84 TEX. L. REV. 1973, 1981-82 & n.35 (2006);
    • Rachel E. Barkow & Kathleen M. O'Neill, Delegating Punitive Power: The Political Economy of Sentencing Commission and Guideline Formation, 84 TEX. L. REV. 1973, 1981-82 & n.35 (2006);
  • 166
    • 49049088218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sara Sun Beale, What's Law Got to Do With It? The Political, Social, Psychological and Other Non-Legal Factors Influencing the Development of (Federal) Criminal Law, 1 BUFF. CRIM. L. REV. 23 (1997) (discussing accessibility).
    • Sara Sun Beale, What's Law Got to Do With It? The Political, Social, Psychological and Other Non-Legal Factors Influencing the Development of (Federal) Criminal Law, 1 BUFF. CRIM. L. REV. 23 (1997) (discussing accessibility).
  • 167
    • 49049092915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 7-12; Thompson Memo, supra note 105, at 5-6.
    • McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 7-12; Thompson Memo, supra note 105, at 5-6.
  • 168
    • 0345807564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. William J. Stuntz, The Pathological Politics of Criminal Law, 100 MICH. L. REV. 505, 535-37 (2001) (describing local prosecutors' incentives to preserve resources through plea bargaining procedures).
    • Cf. William J. Stuntz, The Pathological Politics of Criminal Law, 100 MICH. L. REV. 505, 535-37 (2001) (describing local prosecutors' incentives to preserve resources through plea bargaining procedures).
  • 169
    • 49049120931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Michael A. Simons, Prosecutorial Discretion and Prosecution Guidelines: A Case Study in Controlling Federalization, 75 N.Y.U. L. REV. 893, 932-33 (2000, I]t is at least the perception in United States Attorney's Offices that those offices that bring increasing numbers of prosecutions will be 'rewarded' with increasing allocations of resources (i.e, more positions for prosecutors, investigators, and support staff) and that those offices that bring decreasing numbers of prosecutions will be 'penalized' by the Department of Justice through corresponding reductions in resources, Simons concludes that this perception leads prosecutors to prosecute crimes that could otherwise be prosecuted in state courts. Id. at 933. The perception, however, just as easily supports the hypothesis that prosecutors will extract maximum convictions and maximum terms from corporate defendants
    • See generally Michael A. Simons, Prosecutorial Discretion and Prosecution Guidelines: A Case Study in Controlling Federalization, 75 N.Y.U. L. REV. 893, 932-33 (2000) ("[I]t is at least the perception in United States Attorney's Offices that those offices that bring increasing numbers of prosecutions will be 'rewarded' with increasing allocations of resources (i.e., more positions for prosecutors, investigators, and support staff) and that those offices that bring decreasing numbers of prosecutions will be 'penalized' by the Department of Justice through corresponding reductions in resources."). Simons concludes that this perception leads prosecutors to prosecute crimes that could otherwise be prosecuted in state courts. Id. at 933. The perception, however, just as easily supports the hypothesis that prosecutors will extract maximum convictions and maximum terms from corporate defendants.
  • 170
    • 49049091652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Additionally, prosecutors may be unduly influenced by personal interests such as self promotion or ego. See generally Kenneth Bresler, I Never Lost a Trial: When Prosecutors Keep Score of Criminal Convictions, 9 GEO. J. LEGAL ETHICS 537, 541 (1996) (criticizing prosecutors who maintain win-loss tallies).
    • Additionally, prosecutors may be unduly influenced by personal interests such as self promotion or ego. See generally Kenneth Bresler, "I Never Lost a Trial:" When Prosecutors Keep Score of Criminal Convictions, 9 GEO. J. LEGAL ETHICS 537, 541 (1996) (criticizing prosecutors who maintain win-loss tallies).
  • 171
    • 49049092449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Daniel Richman, Institutional Competence and Organizational Prosecutions, 93 VA. L. REV. IN BRIEF 115, 116 (2007), http//:www.virginialawreview.org/inbrief/2007/06/18/richman.pdf ([P]rosecutors rarely act alone, and are unlikely to do so in a sustained white collar investigation.).
    • Daniel Richman, Institutional Competence and Organizational Prosecutions, 93 VA. L. REV. IN BRIEF 115, 116 (2007), http//:www.virginialawreview.org/inbrief/2007/06/18/richman.pdf ("[P]rosecutors rarely act alone, and are unlikely to do so in a sustained white collar investigation.").
  • 172
    • 33745653897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Plea bargaining in general reduces transparency in the enforcement of criminal law, with negative effects on public legitimacy. See Stephanos Bibas, Transparency and Participation in Criminal Procedure, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 911 (2006).
    • Plea bargaining in general reduces transparency in the enforcement of criminal law, with negative effects on public legitimacy. See Stephanos Bibas, Transparency and Participation in Criminal Procedure, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 911 (2006).
  • 173
    • 49049089862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If the legal standard is uncertain, even actors who behave 'optimally' in terms of overall social welfare will face some chance of being held liable because of the unpredictability of the legal rule. More important, these actors can usually reduce that chance by 'overcomplying,' that is, modifying their behavior beyond the point that would be socially optimal. John E. Calfee & Richard Craswell, Some Effects of Uncertainty on Compliance with Legal Standards, 70 VA. L. REV. 965, 966 (1984).
    • "If the legal standard is uncertain, even actors who behave 'optimally' in terms of overall social welfare will face some chance of being held liable because of the unpredictability of the legal rule. More important, these actors can usually reduce that chance by 'overcomplying,' that is, modifying their behavior beyond the point that would be socially optimal." John E. Calfee & Richard Craswell, Some Effects of Uncertainty on Compliance with Legal Standards, 70 VA. L. REV. 965, 966 (1984).
  • 174
    • 0347803930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is a common problem that can render standards (which are defined ex post) more costly than rules (which are defined ex ante) for regulated entities. See Ehud Kamar, A Regulatory Competition Theory of Indeterminacy In Corporate Law, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 1908, 1919 (1998, concluding that indeterminate laws increase costs of obtaining legal advice and risk of litigation, Louis Kaplow, Rules Versus Standards: An Economic Analysis, 42 DUKE L.J. 557, 569 1992
    • This is a common problem that can render standards (which are defined ex post) more costly than rules (which are defined ex ante) for regulated entities. See Ehud Kamar, A Regulatory Competition Theory of Indeterminacy In Corporate Law, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 1908, 1919 (1998) (concluding that indeterminate laws increase costs of obtaining legal advice and risk of litigation); Louis Kaplow, Rules Versus Standards: An Economic Analysis, 42 DUKE L.J. 557, 569 (1992).
  • 175
    • 49049105581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An exception to this rule is the government's prosecution of KPMG, which resulted in a DPA and the government's indictment of former KPMG employees. Jonathan D. Glater, 8 Former Partners of KPMG Are Indicted, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 30, 2005, at C1. It should be noted, however, that the entity itself did not challenge the government's behavior in court; rather, the individual defendants who were the subject of the government's prosecution brought the government's conduct to the attention of the court
    • An exception to this rule is the government's prosecution of KPMG, which resulted in a DPA and the government's indictment of former KPMG employees. Jonathan D. Glater, 8 Former Partners of KPMG Are Indicted, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 30, 2005, at C1. It should be noted, however, that the entity itself did not challenge the government's behavior in court; rather, the individual defendants who were the subject of the government's prosecution brought the government's conduct to the attention of the court.
  • 176
    • 33745653897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because these negotiations occur before charges are filed and outside the judicial system, they too lack transparency and, in many instances, accountability for the negotiating parties. See Stephanos Bibas, Transparency and Participation in Criminal Procedure, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 911, 938 (2006).
    • Because these negotiations occur before charges are filed and outside the judicial system, they too lack transparency and, in many instances, accountability for the negotiating parties. See Stephanos Bibas, Transparency and Participation in Criminal Procedure, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 911, 938 (2006).
  • 177
    • 49049089437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Bierschbach & Stein, supra note 40, at 1749-51 (discussing collateral consequences in terms of market spillovers); Creamer, supra note 54, at 35-37 (describing effects).
    • See generally Bierschbach & Stein, supra note 40, at 1749-51 (discussing collateral consequences in terms of "market spillovers"); Creamer, supra note 54, at 35-37 (describing effects).
  • 178
    • 49049088219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Acquisition Regulation (FAR), 48 C.F.R. §§ 9.406-2, -5(a) (2006). For a more in-depth discussion of debarment, see H. Lowell Brown, The Corporate Director's Compliance Oversight Responsibility in the Post-Caremark Era, 26 DEL. J. CORP. L. 1, 93-102 (2001).
    • Federal Acquisition Regulation (FAR), 48 C.F.R. §§ 9.406-2, -5(a) (2006). For a more in-depth discussion of debarment, see H. Lowell Brown, The Corporate Director's Compliance Oversight Responsibility in the Post-Caremark Era, 26 DEL. J. CORP. L. 1, 93-102 (2001).
  • 179
    • 49049099302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Creamer, supra note 54, at 35
    • Creamer, supra note 54, at 35.
  • 180
    • 33846546663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 41, at, cataloguing consequences of criminal convictions
    • See Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1885-86 (cataloguing consequences of criminal convictions).
    • supra , pp. 1885-1886
    • Greenblum1
  • 181
    • 49049118352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a recent empirical study of losses suffered by managers upon the disclosure of corporate financial misconduct, see Jonathan M. Karpoff, D. Scott Lee & Gerald S. Martin, The Consequences to Managers for Financial Misrepresentation (April 16, 2007, available at at 30-34 describing combination of job losses and civil and criminal penalties
    • For a recent empirical study of losses suffered by managers upon the disclosure of corporate financial misconduct, see Jonathan M. Karpoff, D. Scott Lee & Gerald S. Martin, The Consequences to Managers for Financial Misrepresentation (April 16, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=972607 at 30-34 (describing combination of job losses and civil and criminal penalties).
  • 182
    • 0041125557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reputation losses are also discussed at length in Cindy R Alexander, On the Nature of the Reputational Penalty for Corporate Crime: Evidence, 42 J.L. & ECON. 489 (1999);
    • Reputation losses are also discussed at length in Cindy R Alexander, On the Nature of the Reputational Penalty for Corporate Crime: Evidence, 42 J.L. & ECON. 489 (1999);
  • 183
    • 49049092452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mark A. Cohen, Corporate Crime and Punishment: An Update on Sentencing Practice in the Federal Courts, 1988-1990, 71 B.U. L. REV. 247, 266-67 (1991);
    • Mark A. Cohen, Corporate Crime and Punishment: An Update on Sentencing Practice in the Federal Courts, 1988-1990, 71 B.U. L. REV. 247, 266-67 (1991);
  • 184
    • 85050840323 scopus 로고
    • The Reputational Penalty Firms Bear from Committing Criminal Fraud, 36
    • Jonathan M. Karpoff & John R. Lott, Jr., The Reputational Penalty Firms Bear from Committing Criminal Fraud, 36 J.L. & ECON. 757 (1993);
    • (1993) J.L. & ECON , vol.757
    • Karpoff, J.M.1    Lott Jr., J.R.2
  • 185
    • 49049100549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dennis Recca, Note, Reputational Penalties For Corporations and the Federal Sentencing Guidelines, 2004 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 879.
    • Dennis Recca, Note, Reputational Penalties For Corporations and the Federal Sentencing Guidelines, 2004 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 879.
  • 186
    • 49049106869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • '[A] wrongful indictment . . . works a grievous, irreparable injury to the person indicted' resulting in damage to the person's reputation which, because the public remembers the accusation and suspects guilt, can not be simply cured by a subsequent finding of not guilty. Stolt-Nielsen, S.A. v. United States, 352 F. Supp. 2d 553, 560 n.8 (E.D. Pa. 2005) (quoting In re Fried, 161 F.2d 453, 458-59 (2d Cir. 1947)), rev'd, 442 F.3d 177 (3rd Cir. 2006).
    • "'[A] wrongful indictment . . . works a grievous, irreparable injury to the person indicted' resulting in damage to the person's reputation which, because the public remembers the accusation and suspects guilt, can not be simply cured by a subsequent finding of not guilty." Stolt-Nielsen, S.A. v. United States, 352 F. Supp. 2d 553, 560 n.8 (E.D. Pa. 2005) (quoting In re Fried, 161 F.2d 453, 458-59 (2d Cir. 1947)), rev'd, 442 F.3d 177 (3rd Cir. 2006).
  • 187
    • 77951745460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S, The government declined to retry Andersen
    • Arthur Andersen LLP v. United States, 544 U.S. 696 (2005). The government declined to retry Andersen.
    • (2005) United States , vol.544 , pp. 696
    • Arthur Andersen, L.V.1
  • 188
    • 49049095179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although the following comments on overdeterrence were not made in regard to corporate criminal liability, they are nevertheless particularly apt: If there is a risk either of accidental violation of the criminal law or of legal error, an expected penalty will induce innocent people to forgo socially desirable activities at the borderline of criminal activity. The effect is magnified if people are risk averse and penalties are severe. Richard A. Posner, An Economic Theory of the Criminal Law, 85 COLUM. L. REV. 1193, 1206 1985
    • Although the following comments on overdeterrence were not made in regard to corporate criminal liability, they are nevertheless particularly apt: "If there is a risk either of accidental violation of the criminal law or of legal error, an expected penalty will induce innocent people to forgo socially desirable activities at the borderline of criminal activity. The effect is magnified if people are risk averse and penalties are severe." Richard A. Posner, An Economic Theory of the Criminal Law, 85 COLUM. L. REV. 1193, 1206 (1985).
  • 189
    • 49049113783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is also possible that some organizations underpay for corporate crime by creating cosmetic compliance programs and/or designating certain employees as corporate scapegoats for criminal conduct that was sanctioned more broadly. Because the facts supporting these agreements (and indeed, many of the agreements themselves) are not public, it is difficult to test these theories. Nevertheless, recent reports regarding the negotiation of agreements with KPMG and Bristol Myers Squibb suggest an overpayment rather than an underpayment scenario
    • It is also possible that some organizations underpay for corporate crime by creating cosmetic compliance programs and/or designating certain employees as corporate scapegoats for criminal conduct that was sanctioned more broadly. Because the facts supporting these agreements (and indeed, many of the agreements themselves) are not public, it is difficult to test these theories. Nevertheless, recent reports regarding the negotiation of agreements with KPMG and Bristol Myers Squibb suggest an overpayment rather than an underpayment scenario.
  • 190
    • 57649215824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empirical Evidence and the Legal Doctrine of Corporate Criminal Liability, 29 AM
    • observing dearth of proof of corporate criminal liability's effectiveness and suggesting topics for further empirical inquiry, See
    • See Gilbert Geis & Joseph F.C. DiMento, Empirical Evidence and the Legal Doctrine of Corporate Criminal Liability, 29 AM. J. CRIM. L. 341 (2002) (observing dearth of proof of corporate criminal liability's effectiveness and suggesting topics for further empirical inquiry).
    • (2002) J. CRIM , vol.50 , pp. 341
    • Geis, G.1    DiMento, J.F.C.2
  • 191
    • 49049097995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professor Krawiec has questioned whether compliance programs are effective at all. Krawiec, supra note 34, at 591-596. Krawiec hypothesizes that compliance programs remain popular because of political influence exerted by the business lobby and compliance professionals. Id. at 610-12. Krawiec further develops her public choice theory in another recent article. Cosmetic Compliance and the Failure of Negotiated Governance, 81 WASH. U. L.Q. 487 (2003) (concluding that business professionals would rather pay for cosmetic compliance programs than affect real organizational change).
    • Professor Krawiec has questioned whether compliance programs are effective at all. Krawiec, supra note 34, at 591-596. Krawiec hypothesizes that compliance programs remain popular because of political influence exerted by the business lobby and compliance professionals. Id. at 610-12. Krawiec further develops her public choice theory in another recent article. Cosmetic Compliance and the Failure of Negotiated Governance, 81 WASH. U. L.Q. 487 (2003) (concluding that business professionals would rather pay for "cosmetic" compliance programs than affect real organizational change).
  • 192
    • 49049101203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 14. Some agencies have filled in this gap. See, e.g., OIG Compliance Program Guidance for Pharmaceutical Manufacturers, Department of Health and Human Services, 68 Fed. Reg. 23, 731 (May 5, 2003).
    • See McNulty Memo, supra note 19, at 14. Some agencies have filled in this gap. See, e.g., OIG Compliance Program Guidance for Pharmaceutical Manufacturers, Department of Health and Human Services, 68 Fed. Reg. 23, 731 (May 5, 2003).
  • 193
    • 49049104689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The McNulty and Thompson Memos include both rules and standards as those terms have been defined by Louis Kaplow. Because key terms such as effective compliance program and sufficient cooperation are only partially defined ex ante, they are best viewed as standards. See Kaplow, supra note 141, at 559-60 & n.2. Kaplow theorizes that when activity is infrequent or affects few individuals, standards are preferable to rules because the promulgation costs of defining a rule ex ante are high. Id. at 573. By contrast, the greater the frequency with which a legal command will apply, the more desirable rules tend to be relative to standards. This result arises because promulgation costs are borne only once, whereas efforts to comply with and action to enforce the law may occur rarely or often. Rules cost more to promulgate; standards cost more to enforce. Id. at 577. Corporate crime and entity-based li
    • The McNulty and Thompson Memos include both rules and standards as those terms have been defined by Louis Kaplow. Because key terms such as "effective compliance program" and "sufficient cooperation" are only partially defined ex ante, they are best viewed as "standards." See Kaplow, supra note 141, at 559-60 & n.2. Kaplow theorizes that when activity is infrequent or affects few individuals, standards are preferable to rules because the promulgation costs of defining a rule ex ante are high. Id. at 573. By contrast, "the greater the frequency with which a legal command will apply, the more desirable rules tend to be relative to standards. This result arises because promulgation costs are borne only once, whereas efforts to comply with and action to enforce the law may occur rarely or often. Rules cost more to promulgate; standards cost more to enforce." Id. at 577. Corporate crime and entity-based liability questions are neither infrequent nor so heterogeneous to render ex ante rules infeasible. Moreover, if one considers corporate criminal liability to affect all shareholders and stakeholders (employees, customers, etc.), corporate criminal liability affects potentially millions of people. Given the foregoing, we should expect the government to promulgate rules instead of standards. Kaplow nevertheless concedes the possibility that political motivations may cause a governing authority to prefer standards even though rules appear more efficient. Id. at 609.
  • 194
    • 49049120420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cunningham, supra note 56, at 286 n.74 (suggesting that regulation in this context may in fact be involuntary).
    • Cunningham, supra note 56, at 286 n.74 (suggesting that regulation in this context may in fact be involuntary).
  • 195
    • 49049105579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Laufer, supra note 18, at 1343 (describing elaborate cottage industry of experts who lay claim to dramatically reducing the likelihood of criminal liability); Rose, supra note 122, at 925-26 (criticizing homogenization of corporate governance industry); Linda Klebe Trevino, Out of Touch: The CEO's Role in Corporate Misbehavior, 70 BROOK. L. REV. 1195, 1196-97 (2005) (noting that Ethics Officers in charge of compliance programs meet regularly to benchmark and discuss best practices in ethics and legal compliance management).
    • See Laufer, supra note 18, at 1343 (describing "elaborate cottage industry" of experts who "lay claim to dramatically reducing the likelihood of criminal liability"); Rose, supra note 122, at 925-26 (criticizing "homogenization" of corporate governance industry); Linda Klebe Trevino, Out of Touch: The CEO's Role in Corporate Misbehavior, 70 BROOK. L. REV. 1195, 1196-97 (2005) (noting that Ethics Officers in charge of compliance programs "meet regularly to benchmark and discuss best practices in ethics and legal compliance management").
  • 196
    • 33646587009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zaring defines best practices as a form of regulation that encourages regulated parties' input and experimentation instead of handing down distinct rules. David Zaring, Best Practices, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 294, 297 (2006, Regulation is horizontal instead of hierarchical insofar as organizations look to each other for the content of rules. Id. Zaring observes that although best practices might suggest a rather democratic form of regulatory experimentalism, wherein organizations learn from each other and regulators publicize their successes, best practices usually fall short of this ideal. They are not a panacea, not always horizontal, and often, at least in effect, not really voluntary. In short, although best practices purport to be 'best, there is nothing particularly 'best' about them. The rulemaking technique is a way of obtaining common practices, not ideal ones. Id. at 297-98 emphasis
    • Zaring defines "best practices" as a form of regulation that encourages regulated parties' input and experimentation instead of handing down distinct rules. David Zaring, Best Practices, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 294, 297 (2006). Regulation is "horizontal" instead of "hierarchical" insofar as organizations look to each other for the content of rules. Id. Zaring observes that although best practices "might suggest a rather democratic form of regulatory experimentalism, " wherein organizations learn from each other and regulators publicize their successes, "best practices usually fall short of this ideal. They are not a panacea, not always horizontal, and often, at least in effect, not really voluntary. In short, although best practices purport to be 'best,' there is nothing particularly 'best' about them. The rulemaking technique is a way of obtaining common practices, not ideal ones." Id. at 297-98 (emphasis in original).
  • 197
    • 33745945074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Criminal Prosecution in a Post-Enron World: The Thompson Memo in Theory and Practice, 43
    • Christopher A. Wray & Robert K. Hur, Corporate Criminal Prosecution in a Post-Enron World: The Thompson Memo in Theory and Practice, 43 AM. CRIM. L. REV. 1095, 1185 (2006).
    • (2006) AM. CRIM. L. REV , vol.1095 , pp. 1185
    • Wray, C.A.1    Hur, R.K.2
  • 198
    • 33845526369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rachel E. Barkow, Separation of Powers and the Criminal Law, 58 STAN. L. REV. 989, 1024-25 (2006) (arguing for greater oversight of prosecutor's plea bargaining power). See also Garrett, supra note 10, at 861-69 (observing that the government's agreement with KPMG effectively regulates the manner in which accounting firms provide certain tax planning advice).
    • Rachel E. Barkow, Separation of Powers and the Criminal Law, 58 STAN. L. REV. 989, 1024-25 (2006) (arguing for greater oversight of prosecutor's plea bargaining power). See also Garrett, supra note 10, at 861-69 (observing that the government's agreement with KPMG effectively regulates the manner in which accounting firms provide certain tax planning advice).
  • 199
    • 49049086815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although Christopher Wray and Robert Hur agree that the proliferation of corporate prosecutions raises the possibility that the government will inconsistently enforce corporate governance standards, their proposed solution is for DOJ officials to watch for inconsistency and, if necessary, impose a more centralized system. See Wray & Hur, supra note 160, at 1187-88
    • Although Christopher Wray and Robert Hur agree that the proliferation of corporate prosecutions raises the possibility that the government will inconsistently enforce corporate governance standards, their proposed solution is for DOJ officials to watch for inconsistency and, if necessary, impose a more centralized system. See Wray & Hur, supra note 160, at 1187-88.
  • 200
    • 49049119580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In contrast, Ayers and Braithwaite assumed that the enforced self-regulatory model of compliance would include an individualized ex ante review of the corporation's compliance program before wrongdoing was detected. IAN AYERS & JOHN BRAITHEWAITE, RESPONSIVE REGULATION: TRANSCENDING THE DEREGULATION DEBATE 106 (1992). Under enforced self-regulation, the government would compel each company to write a set of rules tailored to the unique set of contingencies facing that firm. A regulatory agency would either approve these rules or send them back for revision if they were insufficiently stringent. Id.
    • In contrast, Ayers and Braithwaite assumed that the "enforced self-regulatory" model of compliance would include an individualized ex ante review of the corporation's compliance program before wrongdoing was detected. IAN AYERS & JOHN BRAITHEWAITE, RESPONSIVE REGULATION: TRANSCENDING THE DEREGULATION DEBATE 106 (1992). "Under enforced self-regulation, the government would compel each company to write a set of rules tailored to the unique set of contingencies facing that firm. A regulatory agency would either approve these rules or send them back for revision if they were insufficiently stringent." Id.
  • 201
    • 49049102829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Tom E. Tyler, Promoting Employee Policy Adherence and Rule Following in Work Settings: The Value of Self-Regulatory Approaches, 70 BROOK. L. REV. 1287, 1301-02 (2005) (command-and-control systems consume organizational resources. Even if they work, these strategies are costly and inefficient).
    • See Tom E. Tyler, Promoting Employee Policy Adherence and Rule Following in Work Settings: The Value of Self-Regulatory Approaches, 70 BROOK. L. REV. 1287, 1301-02 (2005) (command-and-control systems "consume organizational resources. Even if they work, these strategies are costly and inefficient").
  • 202
    • 49049111393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Langevoort, supra note 37, at 75-76 (stating that lawyers are primary compliance engineers in many firms).
    • Langevoort, supra note 37, at 75-76 (stating that lawyers are primary "compliance engineers" in many firms).
  • 203
    • 49049097607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ironically, the DOJ's flexible standards encourage firms to adopt command-and-control internal compliance regimes. See Cunningham, supra note 56, at 307; Langevoort, supra note 37, at 73.
    • Ironically, the DOJ's "flexible" standards encourage firms to adopt command-and-control internal compliance regimes. See Cunningham, supra note 56, at 307; Langevoort, supra note 37, at 73.
  • 204
    • 49049093927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Langevoort hypothesizes that lawyers in particular prefer rules and command-and-control based systems. See Langevoort, supra note 37, at 118.
    • Langevoort hypothesizes that lawyers in particular prefer rules and command-and-control based systems. See Langevoort, supra note 37, at 118.
  • 205
    • 49049117931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tyler, supra note 164, at 1300-01 (arguing that the self-regulatory approach is preferable to command-and-control systems because employees are more likely to follow rules that conform to their ethical values and are promulgated by institutions they view as fair).
    • Tyler, supra note 164, at 1300-01 (arguing that the "self-regulatory" approach is preferable to command-and-control systems because employees are more likely to follow rules that conform to their ethical values and are promulgated by institutions they view as fair).
  • 206
    • 49049092044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cunningham, supra note 56, at 307-09.
    • See Cunningham, supra note 56, at 307-09.
  • 207
    • 49049095398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of these arguments, see Bharara, supra note 2, at 96-97 describing pressure on organizations to waive privilege
    • For an overview of these arguments, see Bharara, supra note 2, at 96-97 (describing pressure on organizations to waive privilege).
  • 208
    • 49049102614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Stolt-Nielsen, an antitrust case, the corporation's counsel (a former DOJ antitrust attorney) initiated an internal investigation after he had already contacted the government and had advised it of possible illegal conduct. See Stolt-Nielsen S.A. v. United States, 352 F. Supp. 2d. 553, 556-57 (E.D. Pa. 2005, internal counsel purposely notified government prior to completing investigation in order to preserve marker for company, rev'd, 442 F.3d 177 3rd Cir. 2006, He contacted the DOJ prior to completing his investigation because he wished to preserve his client's chances of obtaining amnesty under the Antitrust Division's Amnesty program. The Antitrust Division employs a corporate leniency program that immunizes the first entity that discloses illegal conduct. For a general discussion of the program and its effect on enforcement of antitrust violations, see Bruce H. Kobayashi, Antitrust, Agency, and Amnesty: An Economic Analysis of the Criminal Enforcement
    • In Stolt-Nielsen, an antitrust case, the corporation's counsel (a former DOJ antitrust attorney) initiated an internal investigation after he had already contacted the government and had advised it of possible illegal conduct. See Stolt-Nielsen S.A. v. United States, 352 F. Supp. 2d. 553, 556-57 (E.D. Pa. 2005) (internal counsel purposely notified government prior to completing investigation in order to preserve marker for company), rev'd, 442 F.3d 177 (3rd Cir. 2006). He contacted the DOJ prior to completing his investigation because he wished to preserve his client's chances of obtaining amnesty under the Antitrust Division's Amnesty program. The Antitrust Division employs a corporate leniency program that immunizes the first entity that discloses illegal conduct. For a general discussion of the program and its effect on enforcement of antitrust violations, see Bruce H. Kobayashi, Antitrust, Agency, and Amnesty: An Economic Analysis of the Criminal Enforcement of the Antitrust Laws Against Corporations, 69 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 715 (2001) (arguing that excessive fines and "first to cooperate" amnesty policy may lead to overdeterrence within firms).
  • 209
    • 49049083368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professor Laufer has argued that the company might purposely scapegoat an innocent employee in order to gain the government's good will and obtain a DPA. See Laufer, supra note 18, at 1413-14
    • Professor Laufer has argued that the company might purposely scapegoat an innocent employee in order to gain the government's good will and obtain a DPA. See Laufer, supra note 18, at 1413-14.
  • 210
    • 49049097388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wray & Hur, supra note 160, at 1182
    • Wray & Hur, supra note 160, at 1182.
  • 211
    • 49049086182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The power exercised by way of the flip is also unnecessary in the corporate context because the organization is already obligated to answer government queries for information and documents. See Hale v. Henkel, 201 U.S. 43 (1906).
    • The power exercised by way of the "flip" is also unnecessary in the corporate context because the organization is already obligated to answer government queries for information and documents. See Hale v. Henkel, 201 U.S. 43 (1906).
  • 212
    • 49049101990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Boeing entered into an agreement with the DOJ that explicitly stated that future crimes by low-level employees would not be considered a violation by Boeing. Peter Lattman, Boeing's Non-Non Prosecution Agreement, WALL ST. J. LAW BLOG, July 6, 2006, http://blogs.wsj.com/law/2006/07/06/boeings-non-non-prosecution-agreement. This provision, however, has not been widely used. In another prosecution, Stolt-Nielsen became a victim of its lack of information when prosecutors in the Antitrust Division, having learned that one of Stolt's employees lied to Antitrust investigators about the date he terminated his conduct in a price-fixing cartel, withdrew their prior leniency agreement and decided to indict the company, despite its prior cooperation efforts. See Stolt-Nielsen, S.A. v. United States, 442 F.3d 177 3rd Cir. 2006, company cannot attempt to enforce leniency agreement until after government obtains grand jury indictment, ce
    • Boeing entered into an agreement with the DOJ that explicitly stated that future crimes by low-level employees would not be considered a violation by Boeing. Peter Lattman, Boeing's Non-Non Prosecution Agreement, WALL ST. J. LAW BLOG, July 6, 2006, http://blogs.wsj.com/law/2006/07/06/boeings-non-non-prosecution-agreement. This provision, however, has not been widely used. In another prosecution, Stolt-Nielsen became a victim of its lack of information when prosecutors in the Antitrust Division, having learned that one of Stolt's employees lied to Antitrust investigators about the date he terminated his conduct in a price-fixing cartel, withdrew their prior leniency agreement and decided to indict the company, despite its prior cooperation efforts. See Stolt-Nielsen, S.A. v. United States, 442 F.3d 177 (3rd Cir. 2006) (company cannot attempt to enforce leniency agreement until after government obtains grand jury indictment), cert. denied, 127 S. Ct. 494 (2006); Press Release, Dept. of Justice, Stolt-Nielsen S.A. Indicted on Customer Allocation, Price Fixing, and Bid-Rigging Charges for its Role in an Int'l Parcel Tanker Shipping Cartel (Sept. 6, 2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/ public/press_releases/2006/218199.pdf.
  • 213
    • 49049100355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One of the few articles addressing this topic is Brandon Garrett's Structural Reform Prosecution, which analyzes DPAs and concludes that the DOJ has consistently pursued compliance through monitors and other structural reforms. Garrett, supra note 10, at 860. For two recent discussions of issues created by corporate monitoring, see Jennifer O'Hare, The Use of the Corporate Monitor in SEC Enforcement Actions, 1 BROOK. J. CORP. FIN. & COM. L. 89 (2006); Vikramaditya Khanna & Timothy L. Dickinson, The Corporate Monitor: The New Corporate Czar, 105 MICH. L. REV. 1713 (2007).
    • One of the few articles addressing this topic is Brandon Garrett's Structural Reform Prosecution, which analyzes DPAs and concludes that the DOJ has "consistently pursued compliance" through monitors and other structural reforms. Garrett, supra note 10, at 860. For two recent discussions of issues created by corporate monitoring, see Jennifer O'Hare, The Use of the Corporate Monitor in SEC Enforcement Actions, 1 BROOK. J. CORP. FIN. & COM. L. 89 (2006); Vikramaditya Khanna & Timothy L. Dickinson, The Corporate Monitor: The New Corporate Czar, 105 MICH. L. REV. 1713 (2007).
  • 214
    • 27844582941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JAMES JACOBS, MOBSTERS, UNIONS, AND FEDS: THE MAFIA AND THE AMERICAN LABOR MOVEMENT 138-60 (discussing the use of federal monitors in the context of civil RICO suits filed by DOJ against various unions, Borrowing a page from bank regulation, Professor James Fanto has proposed that the SEC hire, train, and pay yearly salaries to corporate monitors who would engage in a constant dialogue with management of the public firm and alert officers and directors at an early stage to problematic transactions and SEC concerns. James Fanto, Paternalistic Regulation of Public Company Management: Lessons from Bank Regulation, 58 FLA. L. REV. 859, 915 2006, Although Fanto's proposal alleviates some of the overbilling concerns discussed infra in the text, it does not solve the confidentiality and authority issues that a monitor poses for the board and the c
    • See JAMES JACOBS, MOBSTERS, UNIONS, AND FEDS: THE MAFIA AND THE AMERICAN LABOR MOVEMENT 138-60 (discussing the use of federal monitors in the context of civil RICO suits filed by DOJ against various unions). Borrowing a page from bank regulation, Professor James Fanto has proposed that the SEC hire, train, and pay yearly salaries to corporate monitors who would "engage in a constant dialogue with management of the public firm and alert officers and directors at an early stage to problematic transactions and SEC concerns." James Fanto, Paternalistic Regulation of Public Company Management: Lessons from Bank Regulation, 58 FLA. L. REV. 859, 915 (2006). Although Fanto's proposal alleviates some of the overbilling concerns discussed infra in the text, it does not solve the confidentiality and authority issues that a monitor poses for the board and the corporation's management. Similar problems plague Cristie Ford's proposal for independent "third party" monitors to report to the SEC on corporate governance issues within firms. See Cristie L. Ford, Toward a New Model for Securities Law Enforcement, 57 ADMIN. L. REV. 757, 798 (2005).
  • 215
    • 49049118968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One notable exception to the lack of oversight problem is Richard Breeden's oversight of MCI, which occurred in the context of the MCI bankruptcy and was overseen by the district court supervising the bankruptcy process.
    • One notable exception to the lack of oversight problem is Richard Breeden's oversight of MCI, which occurred in the context of the MCI bankruptcy and was overseen by the district court supervising the bankruptcy process.
  • 216
    • 49049093308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Craig Morford, Acting Deputy Attorney General, Selection and Use of Monitors in Deferred Prosecution Agreements and Non-Prosecution Agreements with Corporations, March 7, 2008, available at http://lawprofessors.typepad. com/whitecollarcrime_blog/files/doj_principles.pdf [hereinafter Morford Memo] The Morford Memo was released in advance of a March 11, 2008, House Hearing on deferred prosecution agreements and corporate monitors. See U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on the Judiciary, Hearing on Deferred Prosecution: Should Corporate Settlement Agreements Be Without Guidelines?, http://judiciary.house.gov/oversight.aspx?ID=425.
    • Craig Morford, Acting Deputy Attorney General, Selection and Use of Monitors in Deferred Prosecution Agreements and Non-Prosecution Agreements with Corporations, March 7, 2008, available at http://lawprofessors.typepad. com/whitecollarcrime_blog/files/doj_principles.pdf [hereinafter Morford Memo] The Morford Memo was released in advance of a March 11, 2008, House Hearing on deferred prosecution agreements and corporate monitors. See U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on the Judiciary, Hearing on Deferred Prosecution: Should Corporate Settlement Agreements Be Without Guidelines?, http://judiciary.house.gov/oversight.aspx?ID=425.
  • 217
    • 49049114174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although the monitor has no legal obligation to report to the corporation's board, management, or shareholders, the DOJ's newly-released Morford Memo recognizes that the monitor may wish to communicate with both the Government and the corporation. Morford Memo, supra note 179, at 6. The same Memo, however, also implies that it may be appropriate to communicate solely with the Government about the corporation's progress in meeting the terms of its DPA. Id
    • Although the monitor has no legal obligation to report to the corporation's board, management, or shareholders, the DOJ's newly-released Morford Memo recognizes that the monitor may wish to communicate with both the Government and the "corporation." Morford Memo, supra note 179, at 6. The same Memo, however, also implies that it may be appropriate to communicate solely with the Government about the corporation's progress in meeting the terms of its DPA. Id.
  • 218
    • 49049104477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I am not suggesting that the monitor will intentionally defraud the corporation. Without any market restraints or significant oversight, he either may provide excessive services or charge in excess of their value
    • I am not suggesting that the monitor will intentionally defraud the corporation. Without any market restraints or significant oversight, he either may provide excessive services or charge in excess of their value.
  • 219
    • 49049105054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prosecutors who are supported by attenuated yearly budgets are least likely to be sensitive to these costs
    • Prosecutors who are supported by attenuated yearly budgets are least likely to be sensitive to these costs.
  • 220
    • 49049093925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Delaware judiciary has criticized and overturned agreements in which the board abdicates its judgment to legal advisors in the context of a merger agreement. See ACE Limited v. Capital Re Corp, 747 A.2d 95, 106-07 Del. Ch. 1999, criticizing contract provision that delegated a merger decision to outside lawyer's legal opinion: does it make sense for the board to be able to hide behind its lawyers
    • The Delaware judiciary has criticized and overturned agreements in which the board abdicates its judgment to legal advisors in the context of a merger agreement. See ACE Limited v. Capital Re Corp., 747 A.2d 95, 106-07 (Del. Ch. 1999) (criticizing contract provision that delegated a merger decision to outside lawyer's legal opinion: "does it make sense for the board to be able to hide behind its lawyers?").
  • 221
    • 84863324201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • June 15, 2006
    • Bristol-Myers Squib, Deferred Prosecution Agreement (June 15, 2006), http://www.Bristol-Myers.com/static/pdf/dpa.pdf.
    • Deferred Prosecution Agreement
  • 222
    • 49049097804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Following his appointment as monitor, Lacey and members of his law firm, LeBoef, Lamb, Greene & MacRae became regular fixtures at Bristol-Myers and provided the United States Attorneys Office with quarterly reports of 400 to 500 pages that were unavailable to the public. See Stephanie Saul, A Corporate Nanny Turns Assertive, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 19, 2006, at C1.
    • Following his appointment as monitor, Lacey and members of his law firm, LeBoef, Lamb, Greene & MacRae "became regular fixtures at Bristol-Myers" and provided the United States Attorneys Office with quarterly reports of 400 to 500 pages that were unavailable to the public. See Stephanie Saul, A Corporate Nanny Turns Assertive, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 19, 2006, at C1.
  • 223
    • 49049096803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Christie & Hanna, supra note 105, at 1044
    • Christie & Hanna, supra note 105, at 1044.
  • 224
    • 49049107242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Saul, supra note 185
    • See Saul, supra note 185.
  • 225
    • 49049090856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For discussion of the facts leading up to BMS's guilty plea, see Bristol-Myers Faces Charges, L.A. TIMES, May 31, 2007, at C6; Press Release, U.S. Department of Justice, Bristol-Myers Squibb Pleads Guilty to Lying to the Federal Government About Deal Involving Blood-Thinning Drug (May 30, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/press_releases/ 2007/223634.pdf.
    • For discussion of the facts leading up to BMS's guilty plea, see Bristol-Myers Faces Charges, L.A. TIMES, May 31, 2007, at C6; Press Release, U.S. Department of Justice, Bristol-Myers Squibb Pleads Guilty to Lying to the Federal Government About Deal Involving Blood-Thinning Drug (May 30, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/press_releases/ 2007/223634.pdf.
  • 226
    • 49049085367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John Carreyrou, Bristol-Myers Settles Probe of Apotex Deal, WALL ST. J., May 11, 2007, at B2; Press Release, Bristol-Myers Squibb, (June 11, 2007), available at http://newsroom.bms.com/index.php? s=press_releases&item=271.
    • John Carreyrou, Bristol-Myers Settles Probe of Apotex Deal, WALL ST. J., May 11, 2007, at B2; Press Release, Bristol-Myers Squibb, (June 11, 2007), available at http://newsroom.bms.com/index.php? s=press_releases&item=271.
  • 227
    • 49049107240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BMS's press release states in pertinent part: The company acknowledge[s] that a former Bristol-Myers Squibb senior executive made oral representations to Apotex for the purpose of causing Apotex to conclude that [BMS] would not launch an authorized generic in the event that the parties reached a final revised settlement agreement. Those representations included the former senior executive's statement that he expected to oppose personally the launch of an authorized generic in the future, his statement that he expected to advocate against such a launch, and his implied suggestion that the company's former CEO shared his views, The company acknowledged in court today its responsibility for the conduct of the former senior officer. The company continues to believe that there was no side agreement with Apotex. Press Release, Bristol-Myers Squibb, June 11, 2007, available at
    • BMS's press release states in pertinent part: The company acknowledge[s] that a former Bristol-Myers Squibb senior executive made oral representations to Apotex for the purpose of causing Apotex to conclude that [BMS] would not launch an authorized generic in the event that the parties reached a final revised settlement agreement. Those representations included the former senior executive's statement that he expected to oppose personally the launch of an authorized generic in the future, his statement that he expected to advocate against such a launch, and his implied suggestion that the company's former CEO shared his views. . . . The company acknowledged in court today its responsibility for the conduct of the former senior officer. The company continues to believe that there was no "side agreement" with Apotex. Press Release, Bristol-Myers Squibb, (June 11, 2007), available at http://newsroom.bms.com/index.php?s=press_releases&item=271.
  • 228
    • 49049087415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carreyrou, supra note 189
    • Carreyrou, supra note 189.
  • 229
    • 49049122365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bodnar's resignation was announced on May 14, 2007. See Shannon Pettypiece, Shakers: Business Personalities in the News, INT'L HERALD TRIB., May 14, 2007, http://www.iht.com/articles/2007/ 05/13/business/bxshake.php
    • Bodnar's resignation was announced on May 14, 2007. See Shannon Pettypiece, Shakers: Business Personalities in the News, INT'L HERALD TRIB., May 14, 2007, http://www.iht.com/articles/2007/ 05/13/business/bxshake.php
  • 230
    • 49049092917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Significantly, the Antitrust Division, which initiated the investigation, has not filed any charges against BMS and its two former top executives
    • Significantly, the Antitrust Division, which initiated the investigation, has not filed any charges against BMS and its two former top executives.
  • 231
    • 49049104894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Buell, supra note 39, at 532 (arguing that liability should attach only when it was employee's primary intent to benefit employer).
    • See Buell, supra note 39, at 532 (arguing that liability should attach only when it was employee's primary intent to benefit employer).
  • 232
    • 49049112330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bierschbach & Stein, supra note 40, at 1775
    • See Bierschbach & Stein, supra note 40, at 1775.
  • 233
    • 49049117715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1898
    • Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1898.
  • 234
    • 49049099911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bharara, supra note 2, at 112 arguing that Congress and the courts should develop clear and expert standards in order to shift discretion away from prosecutors
    • See Bharara, supra note 2, at 112 (arguing that Congress and the courts should develop "clear and expert standards" in order to shift discretion away from prosecutors).
  • 235
    • 49049086184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Buell, supra note 39, at 532
    • Buell, supra note 39, at 532.
  • 237
    • 49049085979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Buell praises reputation effects as a means of disciplining firms. See Buell, supra note 39, at 535.
    • Buell praises reputation effects as a means of disciplining firms. See Buell, supra note 39, at 535.
  • 238
    • 49049083734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Model Penal Code § 2.07(1) (2001); Ainslie, supra note 18, at 120-21.
    • Model Penal Code § 2.07(1) (2001); Ainslie, supra note 18, at 120-21.
  • 239
    • 49049092688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stuntz, supra note 135, at 529 (Legislators presumably want to stay in office, and perhaps to position themselves for higher office. To do those things, legislators must please their constituents.).
    • Stuntz, supra note 135, at 529 ("Legislators presumably want to stay in office, and perhaps to position themselves for higher office. To do those things, legislators must please their constituents.").
  • 240
    • 34248578687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Criminal Corporate Liability, 82
    • Andrew Weissman & David Newman, Rethinking Criminal Corporate Liability, 82 IND. L.J. 411, 414 (2007).
    • (2007) IND. L.J , vol.411 , pp. 414
    • Weissman, A.1    Newman, D.2
  • 241
    • 84888494968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 74-76
    • See supra text accompanying notes 74-76.
    • See supra
  • 242
    • 49049108232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1865
    • Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1865.
  • 243
    • 49049108020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bierschbach & Stein, supra note 40, at 1776
    • Bierschbach & Stein, supra note 40, at 1776.
  • 244
    • 49049109743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1865; see also Garrett, supra note 10, at 924 (arguing courts could impose reasonableness review on DPA process).
    • Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1865; see also Garrett, supra note 10, at 924 (arguing courts could impose " reasonableness" review on DPA process).
  • 245
    • 49049107451 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This would require that all agreements be filed in court. See Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1900
    • This would require that all agreements be filed in court. See Greenblum, supra note 41, at 1900.
  • 246
    • 49049115055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ainslie, supra note 18, at 110-15 (civil sanctions can generally be shaped far more precisely to meet the targeted evil); Khanna, supra note 34, at 1275-76 (Most, if not all, of the advantages of corporate criminal liability can be achieved by various forms of civil liability at lower cost to the government and society.); Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 322-24: [economic deterrence arguments] are not arguments for corporate criminal liability in particular, but, rather, arguments for a set of monetary penalties, properly calibrated in light of the social harm caused by the criminal acts of corporate agents.).
    • See Ainslie, supra note 18, at 110-15 ("civil sanctions can generally be shaped far more precisely to meet the targeted evil"); Khanna, supra note 34, at 1275-76 ("Most, if not all, of the advantages of corporate criminal liability can be achieved by various forms of civil liability at lower cost to the government and society."); Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 322-24: "[economic deterrence arguments] are not arguments for corporate criminal liability in particular, but, rather, arguments for a set of monetary penalties, properly calibrated in light of the social harm caused by the criminal acts of corporate agents.").
  • 247
    • 49049086401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 321
    • Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 321.
  • 248
    • 49049112328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A] total penalty equal to the social cost of crime, discounted by the probability of nondetection, is an appropriate rule of thumb to use in setting the penalty. Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 325-26. Additional factors, such as the penalty's effect on enforcement costs or likelihood of detection may also affect the penalty. Id. at 326. In addition, a proper system should also consider the penalties imposed on the individual employee, apart from those imposed on the organization, because the individual employee presumably will demand greater compensation ex ante to make up for the ex post damages he may suffer. Id, see also Ronald Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. ECON. 1 1960, This Coasian shift is rather uneven. When liability is aimed primarily at the corporation and not the manager, the corporation will have a difficult time shifting liability back to the manager because negotiation with management
    • "[A] total penalty equal to the social cost of crime, discounted by the probability of nondetection, is an appropriate rule of thumb to use in setting the penalty." Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 325-26. Additional factors, such as the penalty's effect on enforcement costs or likelihood of detection may also affect the penalty. Id. at 326. In addition, a proper system should also consider the penalties imposed on the individual employee - apart from those imposed on the organization - because the individual employee presumably will demand greater compensation ex ante to make up for the ex post damages he may suffer. Id.; see also Ronald Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. ECON. 1 (1960). This Coasian shift is rather uneven. When liability is aimed primarily at the corporation and not the manager, the corporation will have a difficult time shifting liability back to the manager because negotiation with management is not arm's length. Khanna, supra note 34, at 1255. This problem, however, would seem to be limited to top managers and not all employees.
  • 249
    • 49049105798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • According to Professor Stuntz, this tendency toward criminalization is shared and supported by prosecutors. See Stuntz, supra note 135, at 534 ([A]t the most basic level, elected legislators and elected prosecutors are natural allies.). Although Stuntz was referring to elected prosecutors, this alliance should extend to political appointees as well.
    • According to Professor Stuntz, this tendency toward criminalization is shared and supported by prosecutors. See Stuntz, supra note 135, at 534 ("[A]t the most basic level, elected legislators and elected prosecutors are natural allies."). Although Stuntz was referring to elected prosecutors, this alliance should extend to political appointees as well.
  • 250
    • 49049108793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [B]ecause the costs of excessive monitoring must be recovered through prices, improperly high penalties create additional inefficiencies because the price of goods or services produced by corporations will exceed their social costs. Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 324.
    • "[B]ecause the costs of excessive monitoring must be recovered through prices, improperly high penalties create additional inefficiencies because the price of goods or services produced by corporations will exceed their social costs." Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 324.
  • 251
    • 49049115434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cunningham, supra note 56, at 308-09 (discussing perception gap between legal culture's expectation of absolute assurance and reality of leakiness); Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 346 (compliance at all costs not desirable); Langevoort, supra note 37, at 73 (perfection not possible).
    • See Cunningham, supra note 56, at 308-09 (discussing perception gap between legal culture's expectation of "absolute assurance" and reality of leakiness); Fischel & Sykes, supra note 2, at 346 (compliance at all costs not desirable); Langevoort, supra note 37, at 73 (perfection not possible).
  • 252
    • 49049117714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jonathan Macey, Agency Theory and the Criminal Liability of Organizations, 71 B.U. L. Rev. 315, 326-32 (1991) (describing three primary causes of corporate crime). For further discussion of how corporate culture allegedly causes crime, see generally Ford, supra note 116, at 762.
    • Jonathan Macey, Agency Theory and the Criminal Liability of Organizations, 71 B.U. L. Rev. 315, 326-32 (1991) (describing three primary causes of corporate crime). For further discussion of how corporate culture allegedly causes crime, see generally Ford, supra note 116, at 762.
  • 253
    • 49049101993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Baysinger argues that corporate compliance programs should be judged like any other corporate output: Like other aspects of production, the outputs of compliance programs must be judged realistically: no system that is cost effective and otherwise tolerable to live with can be absolutely foolproof. Barry Baysinger, Organization Theory and the Criminal Liability of Organizations, 71 B.U. L. Rev. 341, 367-68 1991
    • Baysinger argues that corporate compliance programs should be judged like any other corporate output: "Like other aspects of production, the outputs of compliance programs must be judged realistically: no system that is cost effective and otherwise tolerable to live with can be absolutely foolproof." Barry Baysinger, Organization Theory and the Criminal Liability of Organizations, 71 B.U. L. Rev. 341, 367-68 (1991).
  • 254
    • 49049108023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because of the uncertainties about whether and how a market would function, my proposal presumes that the program would be optional for a defined period of time. After the market was established, the regime could become mandatory for organizations above a certain size in terms of capitalization or employees. Cf. Richard Epstein, Imperfect Liability Regimes: Individual and Corporate Issues, 53 S.C.L. REV. 1153, 1160-61 (2002) (discussing benefits of mandatory insurance tort regime for small corporations). Whether compulsory compliance insurance is necessary or advisable, however, is beyond the scope of this article.
    • Because of the uncertainties about whether and how a market would function, my proposal presumes that the program would be optional for a defined period of time. After the market was established, the regime could become mandatory for organizations above a certain size in terms of capitalization or employees. Cf. Richard Epstein, Imperfect Liability Regimes: Individual and Corporate Issues, 53 S.C.L. REV. 1153, 1160-61 (2002) (discussing benefits of mandatory insurance tort regime for small corporations). Whether compulsory compliance insurance is necessary or advisable, however, is beyond the scope of this article.
  • 255
    • 49049093307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By insurance, I mean the company's purchase of insurance from an insurance carrier, who pools and aggregates the risks of multiple organizations. I do not mean self-insurance, which the current regime of corporate criminal liability effectively requires. See Laufer, supra note 18, at 1349 explaining how corporate compliance has become a carefully conceived and arguably overpriced form of risk management that serves as an insurance function
    • By "insurance," I mean the company's purchase of insurance from an insurance carrier, who pools and aggregates the risks of multiple organizations. I do not mean "self-insurance," which the current regime of corporate criminal liability effectively requires. See Laufer, supra note 18, at 1349 (explaining how corporate compliance has become "a carefully conceived and arguably overpriced form of risk management that serves as an insurance function").
  • 256
    • 49049112116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Admittedly, the process for devising a schedule of minimum coverage could itself become quite complex and/or inefficient, particularly if the regulator who set a mandatory schedule of minimum insurance set amounts too high or too low as a result of making incorrect assumptions or becoming politically captured by one or more parties. See Hanson & Logue, supra note 95, at 1267 (discussing information inefficiencies of performance-based regulation). If the schedule were transparent, however, and subject to the ordinary rule-making notice and comment procedures outlined by the APA, the inefficiencies would likely be less than those caused by the processes described in Part I of this Article.
    • Admittedly, the process for devising a schedule of minimum coverage could itself become quite complex and/or inefficient, particularly if the regulator who set a mandatory schedule of minimum insurance set amounts too high or too low as a result of making incorrect assumptions or becoming politically captured by one or more parties. See Hanson & Logue, supra note 95, at 1267 (discussing information inefficiencies of performance-based regulation). If the schedule were transparent, however, and subject to the ordinary rule-making notice and comment procedures outlined by the APA, the inefficiencies would likely be less than those caused by the processes described in Part I of this Article.
  • 257
    • 49049116623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Griffith, supra note 44, at 1167-68. Coverage under Side A (referred to as Insurance Clause 1 in some policies) provides coverage to individual insureds where the company is legally or financially unable to indemnify them. Coverage under Side B (or Insuring Clause 2 in some policies) provides corporate reimbursement coverage to the extent the company indemnifies the individual directors and officers, usually in excess of a large deductible. Finally, many traditional D&O policies today also include Side C coverage that provides entity coverage for securities claims, again in excess of a large deductible. John C. Tanner and David E. Howard, Blowing Whistles & Climbing Ladders, 23 No. 4. ACC Docket 32 (April 2005) at 50. Professor Coffee has explained that Side C coverage came about because of allocation issues that arose when both the corporation and managers were sued in class action suits. Carriers would demand an allocation of the defense costs b
    • See Griffith, supra note 44, at 1167-68. Coverage under Side A (referred to as Insurance Clause 1 in some policies) provides coverage to individual insureds where the company is legally or financially unable to indemnify them. Coverage under Side B (or Insuring Clause 2 in some policies) provides corporate reimbursement coverage to the extent the company indemnifies the individual directors and officers, usually in excess of a large deductible. Finally, many traditional D&O policies today also include Side C coverage that provides entity coverage for securities claims, again in excess of a large deductible. John C. Tanner and David E. Howard, Blowing Whistles & Climbing Ladders, 23 No. 4. ACC Docket 32 (April 2005) at 50. Professor Coffee has explained that Side C coverage came about because of allocation issues that arose when both the corporation and managers were sued in class action suits. Carriers would "demand an allocation of the defense costs between their clients [the individual directors and officers] and the corporation...[and] thereby plac[e] the individual defendants at risk for these payments." Accordingly, in or about 1996, carriers began to extend entity-based coverage, "which directly reimbursed the corporation for its own litigation expenses, its own settlement payments in securities cases, and certain other forms of litigation." Coffee, supra note 115, at 1569-70.
  • 258
    • 33845624856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Entity-based policies do not currently cover losses caused by fraudulent or dishonest conduct. See David T. Case and Matthew L. Jacobs, Insurance Coverage for Governmental Investigations of Financial Institutions, 123 BANKING L.J. 256, 260 (2006); supra note 127.
    • Entity-based policies do not currently cover losses caused by fraudulent or dishonest conduct. See David T. Case and Matthew L. Jacobs, Insurance Coverage for Governmental Investigations of Financial Institutions, 123 BANKING L.J. 256, 260 (2006); supra note 127.
  • 259
    • 33845776606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ronen, supra note 44, at 48 (We need to create, an agency relationship between the auditor and an appropriate principal, one whose economic interests are aligned with those of investors, who are the ultimate intended beneficiaries of the auditor's attestation, I]nsurance carriers are an eminently reasonable candidate, See also Lawrence A. Cunningham, Too Big to Fail: Moral Hazard in Auditing and the Need to Restructure the Industry Before It Unravels, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 1698, 1738-47 (2006, hereinafter Cunningham, Too Big To Fail, Cunningham, supra note 44; Lawrence A. Cunningham, A Model Financial Statement Insurance Act, 11 CONN. INS. L.J. 69 2004, Other scholars have called for the imposition of limited strict liability to force auditors to behave more like insurers. Frank Partnoy, Strict Liability For Gatekeepers: A Reply to Professor Coffee, 84 B.U. L. REV
    • Ronen, supra note 44, at 48 ("We need to create ... an agency relationship between the auditor and an appropriate principal - one whose economic interests are aligned with those of investors, who are the ultimate intended beneficiaries of the auditor's attestation.... [I]nsurance carriers are an eminently reasonable candidate."). See also Lawrence A. Cunningham, Too Big to Fail: Moral Hazard in Auditing and the Need to Restructure the Industry Before It Unravels, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 1698, 1738-47 (2006) [hereinafter Cunningham, Too Big To Fail]; Cunningham, supra note 44; Lawrence A. Cunningham, A Model Financial Statement Insurance Act, 11 CONN. INS. L.J. 69 (2004). Other scholars have called for the imposition of limited strict liability to force auditors to behave "more like insurers." Frank Partnoy, Strict Liability For Gatekeepers: A Reply to Professor Coffee, 84 B.U. L. REV. 365, 375 (2004); see also Frank Partnoy, Barbarians at the Gatekeepers?: A Proposal for a Modified Strict Liability Regime, 79 WASH. U. L.Q. 491 (2001); Coffee, Gatekeeper Reform, supra note 45, at 349.
  • 260
    • 49049121342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 222, at, his latest article, Cunningham suggests that FSI should be mandatory instead of optional. Id. at
    • See Cunningham, Too Big to Fail, supra note 222, at 1742. In his latest article, Cunningham suggests that FSI should be mandatory instead of optional. Id. at 1738.
    • Too Big to Fail, supra
    • Cunningham1
  • 261
    • 49049121734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [T]he criminal law prohibits while the civil law prices. Coffee, supra note 58, at 1884 (criticizing legislative habit of criminalizing violations of agency-promulgated regulations).
    • "[T]he criminal law prohibits while the civil law prices." Coffee, supra note 58, at 1884 (criticizing legislative habit of criminalizing violations of agency-promulgated regulations).
  • 262
    • 49049109166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under Ronen's proposal, instead of paying auditors to audit the corporation's financial statements, corporate managers would purchase financial statement insurance from insurance carriers. To assess their risk of payout, insurance carriers would employ auditors to review the corporate books. This alters the agency cost problem because auditors are no longer paid by the very party (corporate managers) that they are auditing. Ronen, supra note 44, at 48-49
    • Under Ronen's proposal, instead of paying auditors to audit the corporation's financial statements, corporate managers would purchase financial statement insurance from insurance carriers. To assess their risk of payout, insurance carriers would employ auditors to review the corporate books. This alters the agency cost problem because auditors are no longer paid by the very party (corporate managers) that they are auditing. Ronen, supra note 44, at 48-49.
  • 263
    • 49049101768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A D&O policy covers directors, officers, and insured entities for litigation against directors and officers for violations of fiduciary duty. D&O policies are most often paid out for shareholder litigation
    • A D&O policy covers directors, officers, and insured entities for litigation against directors and officers for violations of fiduciary duty. D&O policies are most often paid out for shareholder litigation.
  • 264
    • 34547457486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Insurance carriers already perform some of these tasks when assessing risks for D&O policies. See Tom Baker & Sean Griffith, Predicting Governance Risk: Evidence From the Directors' and Officers' Liability Insurance Market, 74 CHI. L. REV. 487 (2007) [hereinafter Baker & Griffith, Predicting Governance Risk];
    • Insurance carriers already perform some of these tasks when assessing risks for D&O policies. See Tom Baker & Sean Griffith, Predicting Governance Risk: Evidence From the Directors' and Officers' Liability Insurance Market, 74 CHI. L. REV. 487 (2007) [hereinafter Baker & Griffith, Predicting Governance Risk];
  • 265
    • 49049088432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James Cox, Private Litigation and the Deterrence of Corporate Misconduct, 60 L. & CONTEMP. PROBS. 1, 31-32 (Fall 1997); Griffith, supra note 44, at 1175.
    • James Cox, Private Litigation and the Deterrence of Corporate Misconduct, 60 L. & CONTEMP. PROBS. 1, 31-32 (Fall 1997); Griffith, supra note 44, at 1175.
  • 266
    • 49049098728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because compliance risk would include matters known to internal counsel, Underwriter U might request privileged information and/or access to C Corp's privileged documents. A similar issue has already been flagged with regard to auditors who review financial statements. See ABA TASK FORCE REPORT, supra note 19, at 1052. As a result of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act, auditors have begun to demand from corporate clients documents that historically were considered covered by the attorney-client privilege. Id. at 1052-53. Although the ABA Task Force did not take a formal position on the issue, it noted with apparent approval the suggestion that Congress enact selective waiver legislation that would permit corporations to supply materials to auditors but maintain the attorney-client privilege or work product protection with regard to other parties. Id. at 1055 & n.106. Similar legislation could apply to compliance insurance
    • Because compliance risk would include matters known to internal counsel, Underwriter U might request privileged information and/or access to C Corp's privileged documents. A similar issue has already been flagged with regard to auditors who review financial statements. See ABA TASK FORCE REPORT, supra note 19, at 1052. As a result of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act, auditors have begun to demand from corporate clients documents that historically were considered covered by the attorney-client privilege. Id. at 1052-53. Although the ABA Task Force did not take a formal position on the issue, it noted with apparent approval the suggestion that Congress enact selective waiver legislation that would permit corporations to supply materials to auditors but maintain the attorney-client privilege or work product protection with regard to other parties. Id. at 1055 & n.106. Similar legislation could apply to compliance insurance.
  • 267
    • 49049105384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Critics will argue that the federal regulator who sets the schedule will likely reintroduce inefficiencies into the system. Cf. Hanson & Logue, supra note 95, at 1281 ([The process] place[s] huge information demands on regulators . . . . Without perfect information, regulators will set prices too high or too low, and they will be unable to respond properly to changes in the amount of harm a product does.). However, assuming the regulator published the schedule and its factors every year and made this schedule available for notice and comment, it would be far more transparent and still less inefficient than the current system.
    • Critics will argue that the federal regulator who sets the schedule will likely reintroduce inefficiencies into the system. Cf. Hanson & Logue, supra note 95, at 1281 ("[The process] place[s] huge information demands on regulators . . . . Without perfect information, regulators will set prices too high or too low, and they will be unable to respond properly to changes in the amount of harm a product does."). However, assuming the regulator published the schedule and its factors every year and made this schedule available for notice and comment, it would be far more transparent and still less inefficient than the current system.
  • 268
    • 49049089861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some might argue that this system makes sense only for economic crimes (which are the bulk of crimes that occur within corporate settings) and not those employee crimes that lack a readily quantifiable value, such as obstruction of justice. (I am thankful for Steve Schulhofer's comment on this distinction). Although certain crimes may cause valuation problems, those problems would persist regardless of whether the underlying crime resulted in either criminal or civil fines imposed on the entity.
    • Some might argue that this system makes sense only for economic crimes (which are the bulk of crimes that occur within corporate settings) and not those employee crimes that lack a readily quantifiable value, such as obstruction of justice. (I am thankful for Steve Schulhofer's comment on this distinction). Although certain crimes may cause valuation problems, those problems would persist regardless of whether the underlying crime resulted in either criminal or civil fines imposed on the entity.
  • 269
    • 49049114632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Since this system presupposes the elimination of corporate criminal liability, the insurance carriers would take on the organization's liability in tort for all civil fines and penalties assessed as a result of the organization's employees' criminal misconduct
    • Since this system presupposes the elimination of corporate criminal liability, the insurance carriers would take on the organization's liability in tort for all civil fines and penalties assessed as a result of the organization's employees' criminal misconduct.
  • 270
    • 49049114177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Since some criminal statutes do not have a civil or regulatory component, Congress might enact an omnibus statute permitting civil government lawsuits on behalf of victims against corporations whose employees were found guilty of federal crimes. This would ensure that the federal government had the same ability to pursue corporate entities civilly for the same crimes that previously would have triggered corporate criminal liability. The difference, of course, is that corporations would be forced to insure the liability, and the collateral consequences of criminal indictment (and the leverage accruing to the prosecutor as a result of those consequences) would drop out
    • Since some criminal statutes do not have a civil or regulatory component, Congress might enact an omnibus statute permitting civil government lawsuits on behalf of victims against corporations whose employees were found guilty of federal crimes. This would ensure that the federal government had the same ability to pursue corporate entities civilly for the same crimes that previously would have triggered corporate criminal liability. The difference, of course, is that corporations would be forced to insure the liability, and the collateral consequences of criminal indictment (and the leverage accruing to the prosecutor as a result of those consequences) would drop out.
  • 271
    • 49049102828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This article presumes that corporations would continue to be held strictly liable (albeit with some encouragement for self-reporting) for their employees' crimes. I choose strict liability as a baseline because: (a) employees may be insolvent and therefore entity liability will prevent the employee's moral hazard; and (b) the costs and errors associated with discerning negligent monitoring outweigh the value of a negligence scheme.
    • This article presumes that corporations would continue to be held strictly liable (albeit with some encouragement for self-reporting) for their employees' crimes. I choose strict liability as a baseline because: (a) employees may be insolvent and therefore entity liability will prevent the employee's moral hazard; and (b) the costs and errors associated with discerning negligent monitoring outweigh the value of a negligence scheme.
  • 272
    • 49049102613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The expected value would be a multiple of the expected criminal penalty for a given crime multiplied by the probability of detection
    • The expected value would be a multiple of the expected criminal penalty for a given crime multiplied by the probability of detection.
  • 273
    • 49049113781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 33, at 707-09. Although presumably the same problem should plague D&O liability (whereby increased corporate governance leads to greater detection but not a sufficient decrease in actual wrongdoing), Griffith does not address it. See Griffith, supra note 44, at 1181 (By continually optimizing its governance structure, a corporation ought to find that it pays consistently less for D&O insurance than its competitors.).
    • See Arlen & Kraakman, supra note 33, at 707-09. Although presumably the same problem should plague D&O liability (whereby increased corporate governance leads to greater detection but not a sufficient decrease in actual wrongdoing), Griffith does not address it. See Griffith, supra note 44, at 1181 ("By continually optimizing its governance structure, a corporation ought to find that it pays consistently less for D&O insurance than its competitors.").
  • 274
    • 49049099914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I am grateful to Professor Krawiec for bringing up this point
    • I am grateful to Professor Krawiec for bringing up this point.
  • 275
    • 49049101205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Geneaology of Moral Hazard, 75
    • See generally
    • See generally Tom Baker, On the Geneaology of Moral Hazard, 75 TEX. L. REV. 237, 270 (1996).
    • (1996) TEX. L. REV , vol.237 , pp. 270
    • Baker, T.1
  • 276
    • 49049100550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Nw. Nat'l Cas. Co. v. McNulty, 307 F.2d 432, 440 (5th Cir. 1962) (proclaiming insurance against criminal penalties void and against public policy in deciding against insurability of punitive damages); see also Catherine M. Sharkey, Revisiting the Noninsurable Costs of Accidents, 64 MD. L. REV. 409, 421-32 (2005) (discussing debate over insurability of punitive damages and suggesting that insurability should fall along lines of whether conduct was intentional instead of whether given relief is labeled compensatory or punitive).
    • See Nw. Nat'l Cas. Co. v. McNulty, 307 F.2d 432, 440 (5th Cir. 1962) (proclaiming insurance against criminal penalties void and against public policy in deciding against insurability of punitive damages); see also Catherine M. Sharkey, Revisiting the Noninsurable Costs of Accidents, 64 MD. L. REV. 409, 421-32 (2005) (discussing debate over insurability of punitive damages and suggesting that insurability should fall along lines of whether conduct was intentional instead of whether given relief is labeled compensatory or punitive).
  • 277
    • 49049108792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sharkey, supra note 238, at 428-29 (Most of the states that prohibit insurance for punitive damages on public policy grounds nonetheless permit that insurance when punitive damages are vicariously (as opposed to directly) assessed against a defendant.). See also Deborah Travis, Comment, Broker Churning: Who is Punished? Vicariously Assessed Punitive Damages in the Context of Brokerage Houses and Their Agents, 30 HOUS. L. REV. 1775, 1812 (1994) (explaining that as of 1988, all but three states permitted insurance of vicarious punitive damages).
    • Sharkey, supra note 238, at 428-29 ("Most of the states that prohibit insurance for punitive damages on public policy grounds nonetheless permit that insurance when punitive damages are vicariously (as opposed to directly) assessed against a defendant."). See also Deborah Travis, Comment, Broker Churning: Who is Punished? Vicariously Assessed Punitive Damages in the Context of Brokerage Houses and Their Agents, 30 HOUS. L. REV. 1775, 1812 (1994) (explaining that as of 1988, all but three states permitted insurance of vicarious punitive damages).
  • 278
    • 49049097805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This at least provides a doctrinal backdrop to the otherwise completely intuitive notion that management's participation in a criminal act should result in greater penalties for the organization. See generally Khanna, supra note 34
    • This at least provides a doctrinal backdrop to the otherwise completely intuitive notion that management's participation in a criminal act should result in greater penalties for the organization. See generally Khanna, supra note 34.
  • 279
    • 49049083944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michael A. Pope, Punitive Damages: When, Where and How They Are Covered, 62 DEF. COUNSEL J. 539, 541 (1995) (If the persons responsible for the corporation's misconduct are officers or directors of the corporation, the misconduct is generally attributed directly to the corporation.).
    • See Michael A. Pope, Punitive Damages: When, Where and How They Are Covered, 62 DEF. COUNSEL J. 539, 541 (1995) ("If the persons responsible for the corporation's misconduct are officers or directors of the corporation, the misconduct is generally attributed directly to the corporation.").
  • 280
    • 49049117713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf Sharkey, supra note 238, at 432 (criticizing label-based approach to deciding availability of insurance for punitive damages). The resistance to insuring criminal liability - even liability that is vicarious in nature - may stem from the historical fears that insurance fuels crime. See Baker, supra note 237, at 259 (explaining that morality of insurance is linked to exclusion of criminals and those linked with criminals).
    • Cf Sharkey, supra note 238, at 432 (criticizing label-based approach to deciding availability of insurance for punitive damages). The resistance to insuring criminal liability - even liability that is vicarious in nature - may stem from the historical fears that insurance fuels crime. See Baker, supra note 237, at 259 (explaining that morality of insurance is linked to exclusion of criminals and those "linked with" criminals).
  • 281
    • 49049118765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It might increase overall investment in corporations if shareholders believe an insurance system results in less waste and uncertainty than under a corporate criminal liability regime
    • It might increase overall investment in corporations if shareholders believe an insurance system results in less waste and uncertainty than under a corporate criminal liability regime.
  • 282
    • 49049114178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This in fact has become the problem with D&O insurance. The corporation not only purchases D&O insurance for the directors and officers, but it also purchases Side C coverage for entity-level penalties incurred during securities litigation. Because one insurer covers everything, directors and officers need not worry about allocation or contribution, except where the penalties exceed coverage. Coffee, supra note 115, at 1567, I]f the settlement is fully covered by the corporation's own liability insurance, the board has little reason to resist a settlement that involves no contribution by the individual defendants
    • This in fact has become the problem with D&O insurance. The corporation not only purchases D&O insurance for the directors and officers, but it also purchases Side C coverage for entity-level penalties incurred during securities litigation. Because one insurer covers everything, directors and officers need not worry about allocation or contribution, except where the penalties exceed coverage. Coffee, supra note 115, at 1567 ("[I]f the settlement is fully covered by the corporation's own liability insurance . . . the board has little reason to resist a settlement that involves no contribution by the individual defendants.").
  • 283
    • 33845526565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Outside Director Liability, 58
    • P]olicies are now widely available that provide for full severability with respect to both conduct exclusions and the insurer's right to rescind the policy
    • Bernard Black, Brian Cheffins & Michael Klausner, Outside Director Liability, 58 STAN. L. REV. 1055, 1087 (2006) ("[P]olicies are now widely available that provide for full severability with respect to both conduct exclusions and the insurer's right to rescind the policy.").
    • (2006) STAN. L. REV , vol.1055 , pp. 1087
    • Black, B.1    Cheffins, B.2    Klausner, M.3
  • 284
    • 49049118353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 285
    • 49049099712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One way to shore up an ownership rule is to require that all insurance contracts are negotiated and approved by independent directors. Cf. Coffee, supra note 115, at 1575 (suggesting that SEC require independent directors to examine proposed class action settlements to prevent self-dealing).
    • One way to shore up an ownership rule is to require that all insurance contracts are negotiated and approved by independent directors. Cf. Coffee, supra note 115, at 1575 (suggesting that SEC require independent directors to examine proposed class action settlements to prevent self-dealing).
  • 286
    • 49049120419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. Se. Underwriters Ass'n, 322 U.S. 533 (1944).
    • See United States v. Se. Underwriters Ass'n, 322 U.S. 533 (1944).
  • 287
    • 49049086400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1011 (2000, Congress hereby declares that the continued regulation and taxation by the several States of the business of insurance is in the public interest, and that silence on the part of the Congress shall not be construed to impose any barrier to the regulation or taxation of such business by the several States. Over the years, commentators have periodically called for a repeal of the McCarran-Ferguson Act on various grounds. See Susan Randall, Insurance Regulation in the United States: Regulatory Federalism and the National Association of Insurance Commissioners, 26 FLA. ST. U. L. REV. 625, 641-44 1998, discussing Congressional criticism of state regulation of insurance, Following the terrorist attacks on September 11, 2001, Congress partially preempted state regulation of insurance with the passage of the Terrorism Risk Insurance Act of 2002. Terrorism Risk Insurance Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 107-297, 116 Stat. 2322
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1011 (2000): Congress hereby declares that the continued regulation and taxation by the several States of the business of insurance is in the public interest, and that silence on the part of the Congress shall not be construed to impose any barrier to the regulation or taxation of such business by the several States. Over the years, commentators have periodically called for a repeal of the McCarran-Ferguson Act on various grounds. See Susan Randall, Insurance Regulation in the United States: Regulatory Federalism and the National Association of Insurance Commissioners, 26 FLA. ST. U. L. REV. 625, 641-44 (1998) (discussing Congressional criticism of state regulation of insurance). Following the terrorist attacks on September 11, 2001, Congress partially preempted state regulation of insurance with the passage of the Terrorism Risk Insurance Act of 2002. Terrorism Risk Insurance Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 107-297, 116 Stat. 2322.
  • 288
    • 49049101766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under this analysis, partnerships ordinarily would be ineligible for such insurance as well
    • Under this analysis, partnerships ordinarily would be ineligible for such insurance as well.
  • 289
    • 49049103656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is some evidence that auditors charge higher fees to issuers with higher liability risks. See Coffee, Gatekeeper Reform, supra note 45, at 348-49 (expressing concern that auditor screening may drive law-abiding firms from the market); Partnoy, supra note 222, at 374 (citing Ronald A. Dye, Auditing Standards, Legal Liability, and Auditor Wealth, 101 J. POL. ECON. 887, 908 (1993)).
    • There is some evidence that auditors charge higher fees to issuers with higher liability risks. See Coffee, Gatekeeper Reform, supra note 45, at 348-49 (expressing concern that auditor screening may drive law-abiding firms from the market); Partnoy, supra note 222, at 374 (citing Ronald A. Dye, Auditing Standards, Legal Liability, and Auditor Wealth, 101 J. POL. ECON. 887, 908 (1993)).
  • 290
    • 34548349188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • D&O carriers do not assume defense of claims, which unfortunately permits greater ex post loss. In other words, management will settle any claim that does not exceed the coverage amount. Tom Baker & Sean J. Griffith, The Missing Monitor in Corporate Governance: The Directors' and Officers' Liability Insurer, 95 GEO. L.J. 1795, 1813-17 (2007, hereinafter Baker & Griffith, Missing Monitor, see also Baker, supra note 227, at 270 discussing ex post losses and moral hazard, In other insurance contexts, such as commercial liability, carriers take over the entire defense of the claim. Baker & Griffith, Missing Monitor, supra at 1814. It is unclear how compliance insurance would function in this context. Again, if the insurance contracts were negotiated and approved by outside directors, carriers might obtain the right to defend the claim, rather than reimburse the corporation for its own defense
    • D&O carriers do not assume defense of claims, which unfortunately permits greater ex post loss. In other words, management will settle any claim that does not exceed the coverage amount. Tom Baker & Sean J. Griffith, The Missing Monitor in Corporate Governance: The Directors' and Officers' Liability Insurer, 95 GEO. L.J. 1795, 1813-17 (2007) [hereinafter Baker & Griffith, Missing Monitor]; see also Baker, supra note 227, at 270 (discussing ex post losses and moral hazard). In other insurance contexts, such as commercial liability, carriers take over the entire defense of the claim. Baker & Griffith, Missing Monitor, supra at 1814. It is unclear how compliance insurance would function in this context. Again, if the insurance contracts were negotiated and approved by outside directors, carriers might obtain the right to defend the claim, rather than reimburse the corporation for its own defense.
  • 291
    • 49049096021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Assuming a strict liability regime, litigation costs should be lower than current costs under a criminal regime. Ideally, compliance insurance would assume some of the characteristics of first party insurance in that the finder of fact should not focus time and energy on how or why the crime was committed by the given employee. Cf. MARK GEISTFELD, PRINCIPLES OF PRODUCTS LIABILITY 55-56 (2006).
    • Assuming a strict liability regime, litigation costs should be lower than current costs under a criminal regime. Ideally, compliance insurance would assume some of the characteristics of "first party insurance" in that the finder of fact should not focus time and energy on how or why the crime was committed by the given employee. Cf. MARK GEISTFELD, PRINCIPLES OF PRODUCTS LIABILITY 55-56 (2006).
  • 292
    • 49049103243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As the role of criminal prosecutors decreased, regulatory agencies might see their role increase under this system. Overall, this should be a good result. See Gerard E. Lynch, The Role of Criminal Law in Policing Corporate Misconduct, 60 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 23, 35 (1997) (preferring expert regulators to criminal prosecutors in field of corporate crime). However, inefficient aspects of the criminal process, such as overly intrusive unbonded monitors, might reappear through civil and regulatory settlements. I leave these worries for future consideration.
    • As the role of criminal prosecutors decreased, regulatory agencies might see their role increase under this system. Overall, this should be a good result. See Gerard E. Lynch, The Role of Criminal Law in Policing Corporate Misconduct, 60 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 23, 35 (1997) (preferring "expert regulators" to criminal prosecutors in field of corporate crime). However, inefficient aspects of the criminal process, such as overly intrusive unbonded monitors, might reappear through civil and regulatory settlements. I leave these worries for future consideration.
  • 293
    • 49049100870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cox, note 227, at, criticizing the fact that D&O insurance is on a claims made and not occurrence basis
    • See Cox, supra note 227, at 33 (criticizing the fact that D&O insurance is on a claims made and not occurrence basis).
    • supra , pp. 33
  • 294
    • 49049106228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Griffith theorizes that disclosure of D&O premiums creates an additional incentive to reduce the premiums and improve governance. See Griffith, supra note 44, at 1181-82.
    • Griffith theorizes that disclosure of D&O premiums creates an additional incentive to reduce the premiums and improve governance. See Griffith, supra note 44, at 1181-82.
  • 295
    • 49049084746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Griffith raises similar arguments in his proposal for D&O disclosure. See id. at 1182-85.
    • Griffith raises similar arguments in his proposal for D&O disclosure. See id. at 1182-85.
  • 296
    • 49049094111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ronen also proposes disclosure for Financial Statement Insurance. Ronen, supra note 44, at 48-49 (describing flight to quality that occurs when companies realize that their policies will signal quality of their financial statements and controls).
    • Ronen also proposes disclosure for Financial Statement Insurance. Ronen, supra note 44, at 48-49 (describing "flight to quality" that occurs when companies realize that their policies will signal quality of their financial statements and controls).
  • 297
    • 49049106230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bharara, supra note 2, at 107. [T]he elimination of all criminal liability for business entities would completely eviscerate prosecutors' leverage against corporations to obtain incriminating information about individual miscreants. Id.
    • See Bharara, supra note 2, at 107. "[T]he elimination of all criminal liability for business entities would completely eviscerate prosecutors' leverage against corporations to obtain incriminating information about individual miscreants." Id.
  • 298
    • 49049116415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 18 U.S.C. § 3 states in pertinent part: Whoever, knowing that an offense against the United States has been committed, receives, relieves, comforts or assists the offender in order to hinder or prevent his apprehension, trial or punishment, is an accessory after the fact, A]n accessory after the fact shall be imprisoned not more than one-half the maximum term of imprisonment or, fined not more than one-half the maximum fine prescribed for the punishment of the principal. 18 U.S.C. § 4 states in pertinent part: Whoever, having knowledge of the actual commission of a felony cognizable by a court of the United States, conceals and does not as soon as possible make known the same to some judge or other person in civil or military authority under the United States, shall be fined under this title or imprisoned not more than three years, or both
    • 18 U.S.C. § 3 states in pertinent part: Whoever, knowing that an offense against the United States has been committed, receives, relieves, comforts or assists the offender in order to hinder or prevent his apprehension, trial or punishment, is an accessory after the fact. . . . [A]n accessory after the fact shall be imprisoned not more than one-half the maximum term of imprisonment or . . . fined not more than one-half the maximum fine prescribed for the punishment of the principal. 18 U.S.C. § 4 states in pertinent part: Whoever, having knowledge of the actual commission of a felony cognizable by a court of the United States, conceals and does not as soon as possible make known the same to some judge or other person in civil or military authority under the United States, shall be fined under this title or imprisoned not more than three years, or both.
  • 299
    • 49049098374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Julie Creswell, Ex-Partner at Milberg Pleads Guilty to Conspiracy, N.Y. TIMES, July 10, 2007, at C1. For the plea agreement, see Plea Agreement for Defendant David J. Bershad, No. CR 05-587(B) JFW (C.A.C.D. July 9, 2007), available at http://www.nylawyer.com/adgifs/ decisions/071007bershad_agreement.pdf. Bershad's plea agreement was followed by William Lerach's and Melvin Weiss' guilty pleas. See Anthony Lin, Weiss Agrees to Plead Guilty to Role in Kickback Scheme, NEW YORK L.J., March 21, 2008, at 1.
    • See Julie Creswell, Ex-Partner at Milberg Pleads Guilty to Conspiracy, N.Y. TIMES, July 10, 2007, at C1. For the plea agreement, see Plea Agreement for Defendant David J. Bershad, No. CR 05-587(B) JFW (C.A.C.D. July 9, 2007), available at http://www.nylawyer.com/adgifs/ decisions/071007bershad_agreement.pdf. Bershad's plea agreement was followed by William Lerach's and Melvin Weiss' guilty pleas. See Anthony Lin, Weiss Agrees to Plead Guilty to Role in Kickback Scheme, NEW YORK L.J., March 21, 2008, at 1.
  • 300
    • 0000099617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Smaller organizations, however, may not need compliance insurance. Cf. Clifford G. Holderness, Liability Insurers as Corporate Monitors, 10 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 115, 124 (1990) (finding from review of 1979 data that smaller closely-held organizations and partnerships do not purchase D&O insurance).
    • Smaller organizations, however, may not need compliance insurance. Cf. Clifford G. Holderness, Liability Insurers as Corporate Monitors, 10 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 115, 124 (1990) (finding from review of 1979 data that smaller closely-held organizations and partnerships do not purchase D&O insurance).
  • 301
    • 49049099499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Most insurance underwriting exercises involve classifying risks using general actuarial tools rather than specific investigation, at
    • Cunningham, Too Big to Fail, supra note 222, at 1743 ("Most insurance underwriting exercises involve classifying risks using general actuarial tools rather than specific investigation.").
    • Too Big to Fail, supra note , vol.222 , pp. 1743
    • Cunningham1
  • 302
    • 49049111207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1743-44 (listing other products in which carriers rely on specific investigation).
    • Id. at 1743-44 (listing other products in which carriers rely on specific investigation).
  • 303
    • 49049092689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, for FSI, Professor Cunningham presumes that insurers would hire external auditors to assess the reliability of the corporation's financial statements, at
    • For example, for FSI, Professor Cunningham presumes that insurers would hire external auditors to assess the reliability of the corporation's financial statements. Id. at 1744.
    • Id , pp. 1744
  • 304
    • 49049090465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, we might learn through a compliance insurance regime that it is simply impossible to reduce certain risks of employee crime in certain sectors or industries beyond a certain point. If so, the costs of that crime should simply be internalized and expressed as a cost of doing business, rather than cited as cause for moral shame and massive penalties
    • Indeed, we might learn through a compliance insurance regime that it is simply impossible to reduce certain risks of employee crime in certain sectors or industries beyond a certain point. If so, the costs of that crime should simply be internalized and expressed as a cost of doing business, rather than cited as cause for moral shame and massive penalties.
  • 305
    • 49049121145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1740
    • Id. at 1740.
  • 308
    • 49049088220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • According to Baker and Griffith, the one carrier of which they were aware that made an attempt to specialize in loss prevention could not demonstrate the value of their services and eventually left the D&O market. Id. at 1810-11.
    • According to Baker and Griffith, the one carrier of which they were aware that made an attempt to specialize in loss prevention could not demonstrate the value of their services and eventually left the D&O market. Id. at 1810-11.
  • 309
    • 49049099105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1822
    • Id. at 1822.
  • 310
    • 49049114633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1833-34.
  • 311
    • 49049101204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1840-41.
  • 312
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 235 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 235 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 313
    • 49049113153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another possibility is that shareholders want their agents to purchase D&O insurance-minus-monitoring because: (1) they know that their agents inflate the company's books; and (2) they believe that they will, on average, benefit from their agents' fraud. If they believe that they will benefit from such fraud, they will prefer a policy that caps wealth transfers to loser shareholders, but still permits their agents the latitude to continue inflating the books. By contrast, portfolio diversification zeroes out the shareholders' wins and losses. D&O insurance-minus-monitoring preserves benefits for winner shareholders, which they willingly share with their agents. Although this theory would undermine some of my arguments against corporate criminal liability shareholders are usually viewed as innocents, it does not seem particularly plausible beyond a small portion of traders who are particularly savvy and enjoy risk
    • Another possibility is that shareholders want their agents to purchase D&O insurance-minus-monitoring because: (1) they know that their agents inflate the company's books; and (2) they believe that they will, on average, benefit from their agents' fraud. If they believe that they will benefit from such fraud, they will prefer a policy that caps wealth transfers to loser shareholders, but still permits their agents the latitude to continue inflating the books. By contrast, portfolio diversification zeroes out the shareholders' wins and losses. D&O insurance-minus-monitoring preserves benefits for "winner" shareholders, which they willingly share with their agents. Although this theory would undermine some of my arguments against corporate criminal liability (shareholders are usually viewed as innocents), it does not seem particularly plausible beyond a small portion of traders who are particularly savvy and enjoy risk.
  • 314
    • 49049086611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sean M. Fitzpatrick, Fear is the Key: A Behavioral Guide to Underwriting Cycles, 10 CONN. INS. L. J. 255, 259 (2004) ([P]ricing volatility and periodic constrictions of supply will be inevitable in the insurance market, as insurers react to unforeseen changes in the underlying liability environment that affect policies written in earlier periods, or simply to having 'guessed wrong' in their pricing in a stable liability environment.).
    • See Sean M. Fitzpatrick, Fear is the Key: A Behavioral Guide to Underwriting Cycles, 10 CONN. INS. L. J. 255, 259 (2004) ("[P]ricing volatility and periodic constrictions of supply will be inevitable in the insurance market, as insurers react to unforeseen changes in the underlying liability environment that affect policies written in earlier periods, or simply to having 'guessed wrong' in their pricing in a stable liability environment.").
  • 315
    • 49049110591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coffee, supra note 115, at 1550 (explaining that the corporate entity and the insurer ordinarily pay entire amount in securities litigation). In fact, one of the exceptions to this rule is when individual defendants have been prosecuted criminally. Id. at 1551.
    • Coffee, supra note 115, at 1550 (explaining that the corporate entity and the insurer ordinarily pay entire amount in securities litigation). In fact, one of the exceptions to this rule is when individual defendants have been prosecuted criminally. Id. at 1551.
  • 316
    • 49049091655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Officers, however, do sometimes face civil liabilities in excess of their insurance coverage. Id. at 1577.
    • Officers, however, do sometimes face civil liabilities in excess of their insurance coverage. Id. at 1577.
  • 317
    • 49049109744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Baker & Griffith, Predicting Governance Risk, supra note 227, at 504 (describing towers of coverage, which are essentially separate layers of insurance policies stacked to reach a desired total amount of insurance coverage). According to Baker and Griffith, the layering of coverage may decrease each carrier's incentive to monitor the insured's corporate governance practices because the costs of the monitoring are borne solely by the monitoring carrier while the benefits are spread to all layers of insurance. Baker & Griffith, Missing Monitor, supra note 252, at 1811 n.72, 1839.
    • See Baker & Griffith, Predicting Governance Risk, supra note 227, at 504 (describing "towers" of coverage, which are essentially "separate layers of insurance policies stacked to reach a desired total amount of insurance coverage"). According to Baker and Griffith, the layering of coverage may decrease each carrier's incentive to monitor the insured's corporate governance practices because the costs of the monitoring are borne solely by the monitoring carrier while the benefits are spread to all layers of insurance. Baker & Griffith, Missing Monitor, supra note 252, at 1811 n.72, 1839.
  • 319
    • 49049118354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, this is why they are the preferred monitor. See id. at 1834-35.
    • Indeed, this is why they are the preferred monitor. See id. at 1834-35.
  • 321
    • 49049085366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ronen, supra note 44, at 47
    • Ronen, supra note 44, at 47.
  • 322
    • 49049084747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Title II of Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Pub. L. 107-204, 116 Stat. 745 (2002).
    • See Title II of Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Pub. L. 107-204, 116 Stat. 745 (2002).
  • 323
    • 49049098181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • one might argue that auditors systematically ignored risks because the "capital" they gave up-their reputation-was hard to define or calculate. See Coffee
    • at
    • Moreover, one might argue that auditors systematically ignored risks because the "capital" they gave up-their reputation-was hard to define or calculate. See Coffee, Gatekeeper Reform, supra note 45, at 326.
    • Gatekeeper Reform, supra note , vol.45 , pp. 326
    • Moreover1
  • 324
    • 49049083369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professor Griffith has argued: Insurance companies are experts at assessing risk. Because the success of an insurer's business depends upon taking in more capital than it pays out, the insurer must develop an ability to assess the probable payout obligations of each exposure and then charge an appropriate premium for the risk. . . . D&O underwriters therefore ought to develop categories of high risk corporate governance and low risk corporate governance and, in a well-working insurance market, seek to price and sell their policies at least partly on that basis. Griffith, supra note 44, at 1174.
    • Professor Griffith has argued: Insurance companies are experts at assessing risk. Because the success of an insurer's business depends upon taking in more capital than it pays out, the insurer must develop an ability to assess the probable payout obligations of each exposure and then charge an appropriate premium for the risk. . . . D&O underwriters therefore ought to develop categories of high risk corporate governance and low risk corporate governance and, in a well-working insurance market, seek to price and sell their policies at least partly on that basis. Griffith, supra note 44, at 1174.
  • 325
    • 49049089028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moreover, carriers already evaluate compliance risk insofar as they may be liable under D&O policies for the follow-on civil suits that are filed after the announcement of criminal charges
    • Moreover, carriers already evaluate compliance risk insofar as they may be liable under D&O policies for the follow-on civil suits that are filed after the announcement of criminal charges.
  • 326
    • 49049096995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coverage disputes between insureds and carriers would further increase these costs. See Cox, supra note 227, at 32 (discussing D&O coverage disputes and their effect on management).
    • Coverage disputes between insureds and carriers would further increase these costs. See Cox, supra note 227, at 32 (discussing D&O coverage disputes and their effect on management).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.