메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 92, Issue 3, 2008, Pages 714-748

Holdup, royalty stacking, and the presumption of injunctive relief for patent infringement: A reply to Lemley and Shapiro

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 41349113847     PISSN: 00265535     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (53)

References (193)
  • 1
    • 34547733961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking, 85
    • See
    • See Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking, 85 TEX. L. REV. 1991, 1992-93 (2007).
    • (2007) TEX. L. REV. 1991 , pp. 1992-1993
    • Lemley, M.A.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 2
    • 41349109288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1993
    • Id. at 1993.
  • 3
    • 41349100217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2010-17.
  • 4
    • 41349096405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2035-39.
  • 5
    • 41349121132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 525 U.S. 366, 370-77 (1999).
    • AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 525 U.S. 366, 370-77 (1999).
  • 6
    • 41349087925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. FCC, 535 U.S. 467, 496-507 (2002).
    • Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. FCC, 535 U.S. 467, 496-507 (2002).
  • 7
    • 41349123683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WILLIAM J. BAUMOL & J. GREGORY SIDAK, TOWARD COMPETITION IN LOCAL TELEPHONY 93-94, 108-16 (1994) (noting that the optimal input price of a product should equal its average-incremental cost, including all pertinent incremental opportunity costs);
    • See WILLIAM J. BAUMOL & J. GREGORY SIDAK, TOWARD COMPETITION IN LOCAL TELEPHONY 93-94, 108-16 (1994) (noting that the optimal input price of a product should equal its "average-incremental cost, including all pertinent incremental opportunity costs");
  • 8
    • 41349100878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT: THE COMPETITIVE TRANSFORMATION OF NETWORK INDUSTRIES IN THE UNITED STATES 319-35 (1997) (arguing that the FCC's rejection of the efficient component-pricing rule (ECPR) as a proper method for setting prices is due to its incorrect definition of opportunity costs);
    • J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT: THE COMPETITIVE TRANSFORMATION OF NETWORK INDUSTRIES IN THE UNITED STATES 319-35 (1997) (arguing that the FCC's rejection of the efficient component-pricing rule (ECPR) as a proper method for setting prices is due to its incorrect definition of opportunity costs);
  • 9
    • 0346089931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J. Gregory Sidak & Daniel F. Spulber, The Tragedy of the Telecommons: Government Pricing of Unbundled Network Elements Under the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 97 COLUM. L. REV. 1081, 1093-98 (1997) (arguing that the FCC's assessment and rejection of the ECPR was erroneous, and that prices for unbundled network elements should be set according to the market-determined efficient component-pricing rule (M-ECPR), by taking into account the incumbent's opportunity cost of providing the unbundled input). The classic definition of opportunity cost comes from Armen Alchian, who wrote that the cost of an event is the highest-valued opportunity necessarily forsaken.
    • J. Gregory Sidak & Daniel F. Spulber, The Tragedy of the Telecommons: Government Pricing of Unbundled Network Elements Under the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 97 COLUM. L. REV. 1081, 1093-98 (1997) (arguing that the FCC's assessment and rejection of the ECPR was erroneous, and that prices for unbundled network elements should be set according to the market-determined efficient component-pricing rule (M-ECPR), by taking into account the incumbent's opportunity cost of providing the unbundled input). The classic definition of opportunity cost comes from Armen Alchian, who wrote that "the cost of an event is the highest-valued opportunity necessarily forsaken."
  • 10
    • 41349101292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Armen A. Alchian, Cost, in 3 INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA OF THE SOCIAL SCIENCES 404, 404 (1968).
    • Armen A. Alchian, Cost, in 3 INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA OF THE SOCIAL SCIENCES 404, 404 (1968).
  • 11
    • 0010332510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jerry A. Hausman & J. Gregory Sidak, A Consumer-Welfare Approach to the Mandatory Unbundling of Telecommunications Networks, 109 YALE L.J. 417, 464-66 (1999) (Regulators distort the apparent need for mandatory unbundling when they force an [incumbent local exchange carrier] to lease a network element at [total element long-run incremental cost], rather than at a price that incorporates the full option value conferred on the [competing local-exchange carrier].);
    • See Jerry A. Hausman & J. Gregory Sidak, A Consumer-Welfare Approach to the Mandatory Unbundling of Telecommunications Networks, 109 YALE L.J. 417, 464-66 (1999) ("Regulators distort the apparent need for mandatory unbundling when they force an [incumbent local exchange carrier] to lease a network element at [total element long-run incremental cost], rather than at a price that incorporates the full option value conferred on the [competing local-exchange carrier].");
  • 12
    • 41349084340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jerry A. Hausman, Valuing the Effect of Regulation on New Services in Telecommunications, in BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: MICROECONOMICS 1997, at 1, 26-35 (Martin Neil Baily et al. eds., 1998) (arguing that the FCC's pricing framework incorrectly assumes that no technological or economic uncertainty exists).
    • Jerry A. Hausman, Valuing the Effect of Regulation on New Services in Telecommunications, in BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: MICROECONOMICS 1997, at 1, 26-35 (Martin Neil Baily et al. eds., 1998) (arguing that the FCC's pricing framework incorrectly assumes that no technological or economic uncertainty exists).
  • 13
    • 41349101502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verizon Commc'ns, 535 U.S. at 495.
    • Verizon Commc'ns, 535 U.S. at 495.
  • 14
    • 41349099589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 518
    • Id. at 518.
  • 15
    • 41349113984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407-08 (2004).
    • Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407-08 (2004).
  • 16
    • 41349116720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ill. Tool Works, Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28, 43 n.4 (2006).
    • Ill. Tool Works, Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28, 43 n.4 (2006).
  • 17
    • 41349107984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407 (To safeguard the incentive to innovate, the possession of monopoly power will not be found unlawful unless it is accompanied by an element of anticompetitive conduct.).
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407 ("To safeguard the incentive to innovate, the possession of monopoly power will not be found unlawful unless it is accompanied by an element of anticompetitive conduct.").
  • 18
    • 41349086167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Rambus, Inc., 2006-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 75,364, at 105,476 (FTC July 31, 2006), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/ d9302/060802commissionopinion.pdf (finding Rambus liable for monopolization).
    • In re Rambus, Inc., 2006-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 75,364, at 105,476 (FTC July 31, 2006), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/ d9302/060802commissionopinion.pdf (finding Rambus liable for monopolization).
  • 19
    • 84956547845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 2 Supp. IV 2006
    • 15 U.S.C. § 2 (Supp. IV 2006).
    • 15 U.S.C
  • 20
    • 84920340702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 45 West 1997 & Supp. 2007
    • 15 U.S.C.A. § 45 (West 1997 & Supp. 2007).
    • 15 U.S.C.A
  • 21
    • 41349112915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Rambus, 2006-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) at 105,476.
    • In re Rambus, 2006-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) at 105,476.
  • 22
    • 41349095625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407 (The mere possession of monopoly power, and the concomitant charging of monopoly prices, is not only not unlawful; it is an important element of the free-market system.).
    • See Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407 ("The mere possession of monopoly power, and the concomitant charging of monopoly prices, is not only not unlawful; it is an important element of the free-market system.").
  • 23
    • 41349118281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Treaty Establishing the European Community, Dec. 29, 2006, 2006 O.J. (C 321E) 37, 74-75 [hereinafter EC Treaty].
    • Treaty Establishing the European Community, Dec. 29, 2006, 2006 O.J. (C 321E) 37, 74-75 [hereinafter EC Treaty].
  • 24
    • 41349102526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Case 27/76, United Brands Co. v. Comm'n, 1978 E.C.R. 207, ¶ 250, at 301 stating that a price is excessive when it has no reasonable relation to the economic value of the product supplied
    • See Case 27/76, United Brands Co. v. Comm'n, 1978 E.C.R. 207, ¶ 250, at 301 (stating that a price is excessive when it "has no reasonable relation to the economic value of the product supplied");
  • 25
    • 27744524290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David S. Evans & A. Jorge Padilla, Excessive Prices: Using Economics to Define Administrable Legal Rules, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 97, 98 (2005) ([A] dominant firm violates Article 82(a) if it charges unfairly high prices to its customers.). Article 82 provides, among other things, that firms with a dominant position are prohibited from directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions. EC Treaty art. 82(a).
    • David S. Evans & A. Jorge Padilla, Excessive Prices: Using Economics to Define Administrable Legal Rules, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 97, 98 (2005) ("[A] dominant firm violates Article 82(a) if it charges unfairly high prices to its customers."). Article 82 provides, among other things, that firms with a dominant position are prohibited from "directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions." EC Treaty art. 82(a).
  • 26
    • 84886342665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying note 9
    • See supra text accompanying note 9.
    • See supra
  • 27
    • 41349104654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407 The opportunity to charge monopoly prices-at least for a short period-is what attracts 'business acumen' in the first place; it induces risk taking that produces innovation and economic growth.
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407 ("The opportunity to charge monopoly prices-at least for a short period-is what attracts 'business acumen' in the first place; it induces risk taking that produces innovation and economic growth."
  • 28
    • 41349099805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966))).
    • (quoting United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966))).
  • 29
    • 41349099126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2008
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2008.
  • 30
    • 41349083727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 126 S. Ct. 1837, 1839 (2006).
    • eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 126 S. Ct. 1837, 1839 (2006).
  • 31
    • 41349110375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1839 These familiar principles apply with equal force to disputes arising under the Patent Act
    • Id. at 1839 ("These familiar principles apply with equal force to disputes arising under the Patent Act.").
  • 32
    • 41349105101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1842 (Kennedy, J., concurring) ([A]n injunction, and the potentially serious sanctions arising from its violation, can be employed as a bargaining tool to charge exorbitant fees to companies that seek to buy licenses to practice the patent.).
    • Id. at 1842 (Kennedy, J., concurring) ("[A]n injunction, and the potentially serious sanctions arising from its violation, can be employed as a bargaining tool to charge exorbitant fees to companies that seek to buy licenses to practice the patent.").
  • 33
    • 41349121550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., 501 F.3d 297, 301 (3d Cir. 2007) (acknowledging the inefficiencies produced by patent holdup).
    • Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., 501 F.3d 297, 301 (3d Cir. 2007) (acknowledging the inefficiencies produced by patent holdup).
  • 34
    • 33846497797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 1, at, discussing the royalty stacking problem in 3G cellular technology using empirical evidence
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2025-27 (discussing the royalty stacking problem in 3G cellular technology using empirical evidence).
    • supra , pp. 2025-2027
    • Lemley1    Shapiro2
  • 35
    • 41349090990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Damien Geradin, Anne Layne-Farrar & A. Jorge Padilla, Royalty Stacking in High Tech Industries: Testing the Theory 29-32 (May 31, 2007) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=949599).
    • See Damien Geradin, Anne Layne-Farrar & A. Jorge Padilla, Royalty Stacking in High Tech Industries: Testing the Theory 29-32 (May 31, 2007) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=949599).
  • 36
    • 41349118502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Damien Geradin & Miguel Rato, Can Standard-Setting Lead to Exploitative Abuse? A Dissonant View on Patent Hold-Up, Royalty Stacking and the Meaning of FRAND 25 Apr. 2006, working paper, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=946792
    • See Damien Geradin & Miguel Rato, Can Standard-Setting Lead to Exploitative Abuse? A Dissonant View on Patent Hold-Up, Royalty Stacking and the Meaning of FRAND 25 (Apr. 2006) (working paper, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=946792).
  • 37
    • 41349123231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.A.
    • See infra Part II.A.
  • 38
    • 41349113981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.A.
    • See infra Part II.A.
  • 39
    • 41349115472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.B.1.
    • See infra Part II.B.1.
  • 40
    • 41349101711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.C.
    • See infra Part II.C.
  • 41
    • 41349095410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 126 S. Ct. 1837, 1842 (2006) (Kennedy, J., concurring) (noting that injunctions can be employed as a bargaining tool allowing companies holding patents to charge high fees).
    • See eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 126 S. Ct. 1837, 1842 (2006) (Kennedy, J., concurring) (noting that injunctions "can be employed as a bargaining tool" allowing companies holding patents to charge high fees).
  • 42
    • 41349101936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 43
    • 41349104650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1994-2010;
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1994-2010;
  • 44
    • 41349116719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carl Shapiro, Injunctions, Hold-Up, and Patent Royalties 6 (Competition Policy Ctr., Working Paper No. CPC06-062, 2006), available at http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/royalties.pdf.
    • Carl Shapiro, Injunctions, Hold-Up, and Patent Royalties 6 (Competition Policy Ctr., Working Paper No. CPC06-062, 2006), available at http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/royalties.pdf.
  • 45
    • 41349104651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1996 (If the patent is ruled invalid or not infringed, the downstream firm . . . owes nothing to the patent holder . . . but if the patent is ruled valid and infringed, the downstream firm must pay reasonable royalties [and] the court enters an injunction. . . .).
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1996 ("If the patent is ruled invalid or not infringed, the downstream firm . . . owes nothing to the patent holder . . . but if the patent is ruled valid and infringed, the downstream firm must pay reasonable royalties [and] the court enters an injunction. . . .").
  • 46
    • 41349113332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2001-02.
    • Id. at 2001-02.
  • 47
    • 41349088363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2008-10.
  • 48
    • 41349106953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2010-11.
  • 49
    • 41349083284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1995-98.
  • 50
    • 41349086168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1995
    • Id. at 1995.
  • 51
    • 41349097681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1995-96.
  • 52
    • 41349118714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1999 ([T]he royalty rate that would be reasonable and expected in the ideal patent system without any element of holdup.).
    • Id. at 1999 ("[T]he royalty rate that would be reasonable and expected in the ideal patent system without any element of holdup.").
  • 53
    • 41349100876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1997-98 (assigning B as the [bargaining skill of the patent holder, as measured by the fraction of the combined gains from settling, instead of litigating).
    • Id. at 1997-98 (assigning B as the "[bargaining skill of the patent holder, as measured by the fraction of the combined gains from settling," instead of litigating).
  • 54
    • 41349108653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1996 (assigning V as the [v]alue per unit of the patented feature to the downstream firm in comparison with the next best alternative technology).
    • Id. at 1996 (assigning V as the "[v]alue per unit of the patented feature to the downstream firm in comparison with the next best alternative technology").
  • 55
    • 41349094543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1999
    • Id. at 1999.
  • 56
    • 41349086378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 57
    • 41349119992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1996 (describing the strength of the patent as the probability that litigation will result in a finding that the patent is valid and infringed by the downstream firm's product).
    • Id. at 1996 (describing the strength of the patent as "the probability that litigation will result in a finding that the patent is valid and infringed by the downstream firm's product").
  • 58
    • 41349112269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2000
    • Id. at 2000.
  • 59
    • 41349095629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2001
    • Id. at 2001.
  • 60
    • 41349115473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2001-02.
    • Id. at 2001-02.
  • 61
    • 41349097683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 62
    • 41349110161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004) (stating that monopolists may charge monopoly prices so long as they do not engage in anticompetitive conduct).
    • See Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004) (stating that monopolists may charge "monopoly prices" so long as they do not engage in anticompetitive conduct).
  • 63
    • 41349087695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 407-08 (holding that the ability to charge monopoly prices increases the incentive to innovate, but forced sharing would decrease that incentive).
    • See id. at 407-08 (holding that the ability to charge "monopoly prices" increases the incentive to innovate, but "forced sharing" would decrease that incentive).
  • 64
    • 41349091410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2001
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2001.
  • 65
    • 41349104438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 66
    • 41349090326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2001-02.
    • Id. at 2001-02.
  • 67
    • 41349093114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2002
    • Id. at 2002.
  • 68
    • 41349122400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 69
    • 41349094334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 70
    • 41349083936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 71
    • 41349093116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 72
    • 41349086620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This use of Θ is confusing. The variable is the probability of patent validity. But the no infringement scenario would entail a legal conclusion regarding the defendant's actions toward a valid patent-such as the conclusion that the defendant's product acts outside the scope of the valid patent. The Lemley-Shapiro analysis depends on whether the patent can be enforced. But if Lemley and Shapiro are emphasizing lack of validity specifically, then it is inappropriate for them to let Θ serve a larger purpose in their model. If one's objective is to drive the probability of an enforceable property right in an invention as low as possible, there are numerous policy levers that one might choose to manipulate. As discussed below, Lemley has made numerous recommendations to this effect, using other levers in patent law
    • This use of Θ is confusing. The variable is the probability of patent validity. But the "no infringement" scenario would entail a legal conclusion regarding the defendant's actions toward a valid patent-such as the conclusion that the defendant's product acts outside the scope of the valid patent. The Lemley-Shapiro analysis depends on whether the patent can be enforced. But if Lemley and Shapiro are emphasizing lack of validity specifically, then it is inappropriate for them to let Θ serve a larger purpose in their model. If one's objective is to drive the probability of an enforceable property right in an invention as low as possible, there are numerous policy levers that one might choose to manipulate. As discussed below, Lemley has made numerous recommendations to this effect, using other levers in patent law.
  • 73
    • 41349095411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2002
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2002.
  • 74
    • 41349101499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2003
    • Id. at 2003.
  • 75
    • 41349101501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2003-04.
    • Id. at 2003-04.
  • 76
    • 41349104244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2004
    • Id. at 2004.
  • 77
    • 41349087924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geradin & Rato, supra note 30, at 7
    • Geradin & Rato, supra note 30, at 7.
  • 78
    • 30344448855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Daniel G. Swanson & William J. Baumol, Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory (RAND) Royalties, Standards Selection, and Control of Market Power, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 1, 5 (2005);
    • See Daniel G. Swanson & William J. Baumol, Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory (RAND) Royalties, Standards Selection, and Control of Market Power, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 1, 5 (2005);
  • 79
    • 41349098781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geradin et al, supra note 29, at 2-3
    • Geradin et al., supra note 29, at 2-3.
  • 80
    • 41349102299 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2004-05. This aspect of the model explicitly relies on the earlier Lemley-Shapiro analysis of probabilistic patents.
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2004-05. This aspect of the model explicitly relies on the earlier Lemley-Shapiro analysis of probabilistic patents.
  • 81
    • 22144437353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Probabilistic Patents, 19
    • arguing that the scope of a patent right is uncertain, See
    • See Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Probabilistic Patents, 19 J. ECON. PERSP. 75, 95 (2005) (arguing that the scope of a patent right is uncertain).
    • (2005) J. ECON. PERSP , vol.75 , pp. 95
    • Lemley, M.A.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 82
    • 41349113765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2005. The overcharge that Lemley and Shapiro discuss in this context is only an overcharge if one considers any deviation from the hypothetical benchmark that they have defined as an overcharge. In some sense any royalty is an overcharge because the marginal cost to the patent holder is zero.
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2005. The "overcharge" that Lemley and Shapiro discuss in this context is only an "overcharge" if one considers any deviation from the hypothetical benchmark that they have defined as an overcharge. In some sense any royalty is an overcharge because the marginal cost to the patent holder is zero.
  • 83
    • 41349083935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 84
    • 41349119799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2001-02.
    • Id. at 2001-02.
  • 85
    • 41349094130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2002
    • Id. at 2002.
  • 86
    • 41349096004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2010
    • Id. at 2010.
  • 87
    • 41349121975 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2010-11.
  • 88
    • 41349120694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2011-12.
  • 89
    • 41349118504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2012-13.
  • 90
    • 41349114368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2013 (The Cournot Complements effect arises when multiple input owners each charge more than marginal cost for their input, thereby raising the price of the downstream product and reducing sales of that product.).
    • Id. at 2013 ("The Cournot Complements effect arises when multiple input owners each charge more than marginal cost for their input, thereby raising the price of the downstream product and reducing sales of that product.").
  • 91
    • 41349096402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2015-16.
  • 92
    • 41349119339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2019
    • Id. at 2019.
  • 93
    • 41349123681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2017
    • Id. at 2017.
  • 94
    • 41349113142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2020-21.
  • 95
    • 41349106954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (citing Seymour v. McCormick, 57 U.S. (16 How.) 480, 491 (1853)).
    • Id. (citing Seymour v. McCormick, 57 U.S. (16 How.) 480, 491 (1853)).
  • 96
    • 41349109508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2021-22.
    • See id. at 2021-22.
  • 97
    • 41349107559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2025-29. All of these are newer technologies that incorporate many different patented components. 3G cellular technology allows the transmission of both voice and data over cellular networks.
    • Id. at 2025-29. All of these are newer technologies that incorporate many different patented components. 3G cellular technology allows the transmission of both voice and data over cellular networks.
  • 98
    • 85008016603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, Jan, at, Wi-Fi is the term used to describe a particular technology for wireless networking using low power and an unlicensed spectrum
    • See Lee Garber, Will 3G Be the Next Big Wireless Technology?, COMPUTER, Jan. 2002, at 26. Wi-Fi is the term used to describe a particular technology for wireless networking using low power and an unlicensed spectrum.
    • (2002) Will 3G Be the Next Big Wireless Technology?, COMPUTER , pp. 26
    • Garber, L.1
  • 99
    • 41349099806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Randall Stross, Wireless Internet for All, Without the Towers, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 4, 2007, § 3, at 3. DVD media, or digital video discs, enable the storage of large amounts of information (originally, primarily movies) on a single compact and portable disc.
    • Randall Stross, Wireless Internet for All, Without the Towers, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 4, 2007, § 3, at 3. DVD media, or digital video discs, enable the storage of large amounts of information (originally, primarily movies) on a single compact and portable disc.
  • 100
    • 41349085153 scopus 로고
    • Release, Toshiba Corp
    • See, Dec. 8, available at, Radio frequency identification (RFID) technology has numerous applications in both payment systems and tracking technologies and involves a chip that emits a unique radio signal for identification purposes
    • See Press Release, Toshiba Corp., DVD Format Unification (Dec. 8, 1995), available at http://www.toshiba.co.jp/about/press/1995_12/pr0802. htm. Radio frequency identification (RFID) technology has numerous applications in both payment systems and tracking technologies and involves a chip that emits a unique radio signal for identification purposes.
    • (1995) DVD Format Unification
    • Press1
  • 101
    • 41349114196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jeremy Landt, Shrouds of Time, the History of RFID 3 (Oct, 1, 2001) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://www.transcore.com/pdf/ AIM%20shrouds_of_time.pdf).
    • See Jeremy Landt, Shrouds of Time, the History of RFID 3 (Oct, 1, 2001) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://www.transcore.com/pdf/ AIM%20shrouds_of_time.pdf).
  • 102
    • 41349116283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2025
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2025.
  • 103
    • 41349120695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2026. Although they do not state so explicitly, Lemley and Shapiro are citing the price of the cell phone to the service provider and not the price of the phone to the end consumer.
    • Id. at 2026. Although they do not state so explicitly, Lemley and Shapiro are citing the price of the cell phone to the service provider and not the price of the phone to the end consumer.
  • 104
    • 0742271490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Latent Dangers in a
    • See, Patent Pool: The European Commission's Approval of the 3G Wireless Technology Licensing Agreements, 91 CAL. L. REV. 1693, 1704 n.69 2003, Furthermore, Lemley and Shapiro do not cite to any source for this statistic
    • See Michael R. Franzinger, Latent Dangers in a Patent Pool: The European Commission's Approval of the 3G Wireless Technology Licensing Agreements, 91 CAL. L. REV. 1693, 1704 n.69 (2003). Furthermore, Lemley and Shapiro do not cite to any source for this statistic.
    • Franzinger, M.R.1
  • 105
    • 41349121977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Geradin et al, supra note 29, at 22-23
    • See Geradin et al., supra note 29, at 22-23.
  • 106
    • 41349090992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2030
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2030.
  • 107
    • 41349083729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2032
    • Id. at 2032.
  • 108
    • 41349085345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2033
    • Id. at 2033.
  • 109
    • 41349118713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2032
    • Id. at 2032.
  • 110
    • 41349117365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2034
    • Id. at 2034.
  • 111
    • 41349102297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 112
    • 41349098109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2035
    • Id. at 2035.
  • 113
    • 41349105245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 114
    • 41349113334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2036
    • Id. at 2036.
  • 115
    • 41349106354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 116
    • 41349093944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 117
    • 41349118943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2039
    • Id. at 2039.
  • 118
    • 41349087479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2035-39.
    • See id. at 2035-39.
  • 119
    • 41349090077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2036-37. Lemley and Shapiro limit application of their analysis to situations where the patent holder's predominant commercial interest in bringing a patent infringement case is to obtain licensing revenues and do not apply their analysis where the patent holder suffers significant lost profits as a result of the allegedly infringing activities of the downstream firm and seeks to use the patent to exclude a competitor from the market in order to preserve its profit margins.
    • Id. at 2036-37. Lemley and Shapiro limit application of their analysis to situations where "the patent holder's predominant commercial interest in bringing a patent infringement case is to obtain licensing revenues" and do not apply their analysis where "the patent holder suffers significant lost profits as a result of the allegedly infringing activities of the downstream firm and seeks to use the patent to exclude a competitor from the market in order to preserve its profit margins."
  • 120
    • 41349115248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 121
    • 41349106547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2001-02.
    • Id. at 2001-02.
  • 122
    • 41349123469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 123
    • 41349109726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2003
    • Id. at 2003.
  • 124
    • 41349093737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2037-38.
  • 125
    • 41349103399 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2038
    • Id. at 2038.
  • 126
    • 41349115030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 127
    • 41349089292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2002 (discussing the Redesign and Litigate strategy).
    • See id. at 2002 (discussing the "Redesign and Litigate" strategy).
  • 128
    • 41349114795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2038
    • Id. at 2038.
  • 129
    • 41349086834 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2008
    • Id. at 2008.
  • 130
    • 41349093324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2038-39.
  • 131
    • 41349097063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2038
    • Id. at 2038.
  • 132
    • 41349093115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 133
    • 41349095413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 134
    • 41349111848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 135
    • 41349110837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2035-36.
  • 136
    • 41349101937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2035
    • Id. at 2035.
  • 137
    • 41349103188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2035-36.
    • See id. at 2035-36.
  • 138
    • 41349090324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 139
    • 41349114370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 2036-37.
  • 140
    • 41349085560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2036-37.
    • See id. at 2036-37.
  • 141
    • 41349110376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1991.
    • See id. at 1991.
  • 142
    • 41349109940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 143
    • 41349091409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2021.
    • See id. at 2021.
  • 144
    • 41349086623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1993
    • Id. at 1993.
  • 145
    • 41349121336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 24 (7th ed. 2007).
    • See RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 24 (7th ed. 2007).
  • 146
    • 41349087258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • discussing how economic analyses can be used to create a more efficient system for achieving social objectives
    • See id. (discussing how economic analyses can be used to create a more efficient system for achieving social objectives).
    • See id
  • 147
    • 41349111432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1999
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1999.
  • 148
    • 41349083080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1991.
    • See id. at 1991.
  • 149
    • 41349108453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WILLIAM H. GREENE, ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS 156 (3d ed. 1997).
    • See WILLIAM H. GREENE, ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS 156 (3d ed. 1997).
  • 150
    • 41349108860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This assumption is not necessary for the analysis. In general, the probability of either type of error will not be a function of the error cost
    • This assumption is not necessary for the analysis. In general, the probability of either type of error will not be a function of the error cost.
  • 151
    • 41349107164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2044
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2044.
  • 152
    • 41349121762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1991, 1993, 1997, 2009, 2010, 2012 (twice), 2015, 2024.
    • See id. at 1991, 1993, 1997, 2009, 2010, 2012 (twice), 2015, 2024.
  • 153
    • 41349095195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2013 (first emphasis added).
    • Id. at 2013 (first emphasis added).
  • 154
    • 41349089492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 155
    • 41349085154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2016
    • Id. at 2016.
  • 156
    • 41349088586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grain Processing Corp. v. Am. Maize-Prods. Co., 185 F.3d 1341, 1356 (Fed. Cir. 1999) (holding that an infringer may claim that it would have adopted noninfringing technology despite the fact that the infringer had never done so).
    • Grain Processing Corp. v. Am. Maize-Prods. Co., 185 F.3d 1341, 1356 (Fed. Cir. 1999) (holding that an infringer may claim that it would have adopted noninfringing technology despite the fact that the infringer had never done so).
  • 157
    • 41349115884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Jerry A. Hausman, Gregory K. Leonard & J. Gregory Sidak, Patent Damages and Real Options: How Judicial Characterization of Noninfringing Alternatives Reduces Incentives to Innovate, 22 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 825 (2007) (discussing Grain Processing Corp., 185 F.3d at 1341).
    • See generally Jerry A. Hausman, Gregory K. Leonard & J. Gregory Sidak, Patent Damages and Real Options: How Judicial Characterization of Noninfringing Alternatives Reduces Incentives to Innovate, 22 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 825 (2007) (discussing Grain Processing Corp., 185 F.3d at 1341).
  • 158
    • 41349099587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY (7th ed. 1999).
    • BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY (7th ed. 1999).
  • 159
    • 41349098536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an application of this real-option analysis to legal and regulatory rules, see Hausman & Sidak, supra note 8 and Hausman, supra note 8, at 13-24.
    • For an application of this real-option analysis to legal and regulatory rules, see Hausman & Sidak, supra note 8 and Hausman, supra note 8, at 13-24.
  • 160
    • 0346406668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property Rights and Property Rules for Commercializing Inventions, 85
    • noting the frequently enjoyed competitive advantages of second movers, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., F. Scott Kieff, Property Rights and Property Rules for Commercializing Inventions, 85 MINN. L. REV. 697, 708-09 (2001) (noting the frequently enjoyed competitive advantages of second movers).
    • (2001) MINN. L. REV , vol.697 , pp. 708-709
    • Scott Kieff, F.1
  • 161
    • 33846828281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J. Gregory Sidak, A Consumer-Welfare Approach to Network Neutrality Regulation of the Internet, 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 349, 357 (2006).
    • J. Gregory Sidak, A Consumer-Welfare Approach to Network Neutrality Regulation of the Internet, 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 349, 357 (2006).
  • 162
    • 41349103616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEE AVINASH K. DIXIT & ROBERT S. PINDYCK, INVESTMENT UNDER UNCERTAINTY 153 (1994).
    • SEE AVINASH K. DIXIT & ROBERT S. PINDYCK, INVESTMENT UNDER UNCERTAINTY 153 (1994).
  • 163
    • 41349111250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 164
    • 41349107985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hausman & Sidak, supra note 8, at 462-63
    • See Hausman & Sidak, supra note 8, at 462-63.
  • 165
    • 41349100026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DIXIT & PINDYCK, supra note 146, at 3
    • DIXIT & PINDYCK, supra note 146, at 3.
  • 166
    • 41349111430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 3, 135.
    • See id. at 3, 135.
  • 167
    • 41349112267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 4
    • Id. at 4.
  • 168
    • 41349114369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 6-7
    • Id. at 6-7.
  • 169
    • 41349096640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 170
    • 41349114195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1999
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1999.
  • 171
    • 41349095626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1996
    • Id. at 1996.
  • 172
    • 41349092040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2040 (noting, for example, that it is important that the fact finder has the information necessary to assess the contribution of a component invention in the context of the value of the entire product).
    • See id. at 2040 (noting, for example, that it is important "that the fact finder has the information necessary to assess the contribution of a component invention in the context of the value of the entire product").
  • 173
    • 41349102953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1999-2000.
    • See id. at 1999-2000.
  • 174
    • 41349105685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An additional case not considered by Lemley and Shapiro is when the patented feature adds no value to the consumer but makes it significantly less costly to produce the good. In this sense the focus of the hypothetical benchmark calculation in the Lemley-Shapiro model is incorrect from the outset. Focusing only on value to consumers ignores the other valuable aspects of the patent feature, including cost savings and the value of the real option created
    • An additional case not considered by Lemley and Shapiro is when the patented feature adds no value to the consumer but makes it significantly less costly to produce the good. In this sense the focus of the hypothetical benchmark calculation in the Lemley-Shapiro model is incorrect from the outset. Focusing only on value to consumers ignores the other valuable aspects of the patent feature, including cost savings and the value of the real option created.
  • 175
    • 41349105901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2036 (acknowledging that some injunctions will not lead to a risk of holdup).
    • Cf. Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 2036 (acknowledging that "some injunctions will not lead to a risk of holdup").
  • 176
    • 41349096213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To my knowledge, the option-value approach to solving the optimal royalty rate has not been developed in a formal model. Two other methods that economists have proposed are an ex ante auction based on the ECPR, see generally Swanson & Baumol, supra note 71, and the Shapley value in cooperative game theory,
    • To my knowledge, the option-value approach to solving the optimal royalty rate has not been developed in a formal model. Two other methods that economists have proposed are an ex ante auction based on the ECPR, see generally Swanson & Baumol, supra note 71, and the Shapley value in cooperative game theory,
  • 177
    • 39449084376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see generally Anne Layne-Farrar, A. Jorge Padilla & Richard Schmalensee, Pricing Patents for Licensing in Standard Setting Organizations: Making Sense of FRAND Commitments, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 671, 693 (2007).
    • see generally Anne Layne-Farrar, A. Jorge Padilla & Richard Schmalensee, Pricing Patents for Licensing in Standard Setting Organizations: Making Sense of FRAND Commitments, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 671, 693 (2007).
  • 178
    • 41349118503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1999;
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1999;
  • 179
    • 41349083077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also supra Part I.A.1 (discussing the Lemley-Shapiro model for holdup).
    • see also supra Part I.A.1 (discussing the Lemley-Shapiro model for holdup).
  • 180
    • 41349094544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1999
    • Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 1, at 1999.
  • 181
    • 41349084755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 182
    • 41349083728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. at 1998 ([T]he model will produce similar results with any value of B.).
    • See, e.g., id. at 1998 ("[T]he model will produce similar results with any value of B.").
  • 183
    • 41349089024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2001
    • Id. at 2001.
  • 184
    • 41349118282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2002
    • Id. at 2002.
  • 185
    • 41349097682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2001
    • Id. at 2001.
  • 186
    • 41349108244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2001-02.
    • Id. at 2001-02.
  • 187
    • 41349102952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. at 2001.
    • See, e.g., id. at 2001.
  • 188
    • 41349083078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Geradin et al, supra note 29, at 39
    • See Geradin et al., supra note 29, at 39.
  • 189
    • 41349096006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 190
    • 33846706738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci & Francesco Parisi, Substituting Complements, 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 333, 340 (2006). They write in a more general context than the specific two-party bargaining context considered by Lemley and Shapiro, but their result is nevertheless important in terms of assessing the plausibility of the Lemley-Shapiro model.
    • See Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci & Francesco Parisi, Substituting Complements, 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 333, 340 (2006). They write in a more general context than the specific two-party bargaining context considered by Lemley and Shapiro, but their result is nevertheless important in terms of assessing the plausibility of the Lemley-Shapiro model.
  • 191
    • 41349090322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 337 (It is important to note that the legal problems to which the complementary oligopoly and anticommons theories have been applied have the common characteristic of the uniqueness of the complements. Fragmented owners face an anticommons problem to the extent that the complementary rights that they seek to acquire cannot easily be substituted with other rights.).
    • See id. at 337 ("It is important to note that the legal problems to which the complementary oligopoly and anticommons theories have been applied have the common characteristic of the uniqueness of the complements. Fragmented owners face an anticommons problem to the extent that the complementary rights that they seek to acquire cannot easily be substituted with other rights.").
  • 192
    • 41349097062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Geradin & Rato, supra note 30, at 21
    • See Geradin & Rato, supra note 30, at 21.
  • 193
    • 41349084555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 24-25
    • Id. at 24-25.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.