-
1
-
-
39449124236
-
-
Daniel Swanson and William J. Baumol note: It is widely acknowledged that, in fact, there are no generally agreed upon tests to determine whether a particular license does or does not satisfy a RAND commitment. Daniel G. Swanson & William J. Baumol, Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory (RAND) Royalties, Standards Selection, and Control of Market Power, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 1, 5 (2005).
-
Daniel Swanson and William J. Baumol note: "It is widely acknowledged that, in fact, there are no generally agreed upon tests to determine whether a particular license does or does not satisfy a RAND commitment." Daniel G. Swanson & William J. Baumol, Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory (RAND) Royalties, Standards Selection, and Control of Market Power, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 1, 5 (2005).
-
-
-
-
2
-
-
39449123200
-
-
Larry Goldstein and Brian Kearsey echo this: Unfortunately, [RAND and FRAND] are not well defined. Ambiguity in the definition of 'FRAND' is, in our opinion, one of the core problems in the licensing of rights to patents essential for implementation of a written technical standard. LARRY M. GOLDSTEIN & BRUN N. KEARSEY, TECHNOLOGY PATENT LICENSING: AN INTERNATIONAL REFERENCE ON 21ST CENTURY PATENT LICENSING, PATENT POOLS AND PATENT PIATFORMS 27 (2004).
-
Larry Goldstein and Brian Kearsey echo this: "Unfortunately, [RAND and FRAND] are not well defined. Ambiguity in the definition of 'FRAND' is, in our opinion, one of the core problems in the licensing of rights to patents essential for implementation of a written technical standard." LARRY M. GOLDSTEIN & BRUN N. KEARSEY, TECHNOLOGY PATENT LICENSING: AN INTERNATIONAL REFERENCE ON 21ST CENTURY PATENT LICENSING, PATENT POOLS AND PATENT PIATFORMS 27 (2004).
-
-
-
-
3
-
-
39449119966
-
-
Like-wise, Richard Rapp and Lauren Stiroh state: The typical [standard setting organization] patent policy mandating that a royalty be 'fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory' gives little guidance for royalty determination because 'reasonable' can mean different things to a technology owner and a technology buyer. Richard T. Rapp & Lauren J. Stiroh, Standard Setting and Market Power, Comments Submitted to Joint Hearings of the U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based Economy 9 (Apr. 18, 2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020418rappstiroh.pdf.
-
Like-wise, Richard Rapp and Lauren Stiroh state: "The typical [standard setting organization] patent policy mandating that a royalty be 'fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory' gives little guidance for royalty determination because 'reasonable' can mean different things to a technology owner and a technology buyer." Richard T. Rapp & Lauren J. Stiroh, Standard Setting and Market Power, Comments Submitted to Joint Hearings of the U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based Economy 9 (Apr. 18, 2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020418rappstiroh.pdf.
-
-
-
-
4
-
-
39449100155
-
-
For a survey of the debate surrounding FRAND, see Damien Geradin, Standardization and Technological Innovation: Some Reflections on Ex-ante Licensing, FRAND, and the Proper Means to Reward Innovation (Tilburg Law and Econ. Ctr., Discussion Paper No. 2006-017), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=909011.
-
For a survey of the debate surrounding FRAND, see Damien Geradin, Standardization and Technological Innovation: Some Reflections on Ex-ante Licensing, FRAND, and the Proper Means to Reward Innovation (Tilburg Law and Econ. Ctr., Discussion Paper No. 2006-017), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=909011.
-
-
-
-
5
-
-
0036535933
-
-
Rudi Bekkers et al., Intellectual Properly Rights and Standardization: The Case of GSM, 26 TELECOMM. POL'Y 171, 173 (2002).
-
Rudi Bekkers et al., Intellectual Properly Rights and Standardization: The Case of GSM, 26 TELECOMM. POL'Y 171, 173 (2002).
-
-
-
-
6
-
-
39449109406
-
-
Firms not making relevant disclosures risk litigation over unfair business practices. See, e.g., Rambus, Inc., FTC Docket No. 9302, 2006 WL 2330119 (Aug. 2, 2006) (Opinion of the Commission), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9302/index.shtm.
-
Firms not making relevant disclosures risk litigation over unfair business practices. See, e.g., Rambus, Inc., FTC Docket No. 9302, 2006 WL 2330119 (Aug. 2, 2006) (Opinion of the Commission), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9302/index.shtm.
-
-
-
-
7
-
-
33845978742
-
-
For a discussion of SSO intellectual property rules, see, Harvard NOM Research Paper No. 05-05, available at
-
For a discussion of SSO intellectual property rules, see Benjamin Chiao, Josh Lerner & Jean Tirole, The Rules of Standard Setting Organizations: An Empirical Analysis (Harvard NOM Research Paper No. 05-05, 2005), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract-664643.
-
(2005)
The Rules of Standard Setting Organizations: An Empirical Analysis
-
-
Chiao, B.1
Lerner, J.2
Tirole, J.3
-
8
-
-
39449113822
-
-
See, e.g, Harvard Univ, Working Paper No. 903214, available at
-
See, e.g., Brian DeLacey, Kerry Herman, David Kiron & Josh Lerner, Strategic Behavior in Standard-Setting Organizations (Harvard Univ., Working Paper No. 903214, 2006), available at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=903214.
-
(2006)
Strategic Behavior in Standard-Setting Organizations
-
-
DeLacey, B.1
Herman, K.2
Kiron, D.3
Lerner, J.4
-
9
-
-
39449112632
-
-
Required may often be too strong a word. See Chiao et al, supra note 4 (discussing how and why patents get disclosed to SSOs). Moreover, even if a patent is technically essential for implementing a standard, it might be relatively easy to invent around, or it might cover an optional feature of the standard that can be omitted in some applications.
-
"Required" may often be too strong a word. See Chiao et al,, supra note 4 (discussing how and why patents get disclosed to SSOs). Moreover, even if a patent is technically essential for implementing a standard, it might be relatively easy to invent around, or it might cover an optional feature of the standard that can be omitted in some applications.
-
-
-
-
10
-
-
39449110015
-
-
Complaint, Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., No. 05-3350, 2006 WL 2528545 (D.N.J. filed Aug. 31, 2006).
-
Complaint, Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., No. 05-3350, 2006 WL 2528545 (D.N.J. filed Aug. 31, 2006).
-
-
-
-
11
-
-
39449128447
-
-
The district court granted Qualcomm's motion to dismiss, but the Third Circuit recently reversed the dismissal of the Sherman Act monopolization and attempted monopolization claims, and affirmed the dismissal of the unlawful monopoly maintenance claim. Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., No. 05-3350, 2006 WL 2528545 (D.N.J. Aug. 31, 2006),
-
The district court granted Qualcomm's motion to dismiss, but the Third Circuit recently reversed the dismissal of the Sherman Act monopolization and attempted monopolization claims, and affirmed the dismissal of the unlawful monopoly maintenance claim. Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., No. 05-3350, 2006 WL 2528545 (D.N.J. Aug. 31, 2006),
-
-
-
-
12
-
-
39449090314
-
-
WL 2475847 3d Cir. Sept. 4
-
rev'd in part, aff'd in part, No. 06-4292, 2007 WL 2475847 (3d Cir. Sept. 4, 2007).
-
(2007)
rev'd in part, aff'd in part
, Issue.6-4292
-
-
-
13
-
-
39449083425
-
-
See Nokia Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., No. 06-509, 2006 WL 2521328 (D. Del. Aug. 29, 2006).
-
See Nokia Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., No. 06-509, 2006 WL 2521328 (D. Del. Aug. 29, 2006).
-
-
-
-
14
-
-
39449101069
-
-
Earlier cases have involved similar claims of contract, but settled prior to a ruling. See ESS Tech., Inc. v. PC-Tel, Inc., No. C-99-20292 (N.D. Cal. Feb. 21, 2002) (stipulation and order of dismissal);
-
Earlier cases have involved similar claims of contract, but settled prior to a ruling. See ESS Tech., Inc. v. PC-Tel, Inc., No. C-99-20292 (N.D. Cal. Feb. 21, 2002) (stipulation and order of dismissal);
-
-
-
-
15
-
-
39449130358
-
-
PC-TEL INC, Apr. 4, 2001, available at
-
PC-TEL INC., ANNUAL REPORT 6 (Form 10-K) (Apr. 4, 2001), available at http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/ data/1057083/000089161802001574/f78706e10-k.txt;
-
ANNUAL REPORT 6 (Form 10-K)
-
-
-
16
-
-
39449083421
-
-
see also Agere Sys. Guardian Corp. v. Proxim, Inc., No. 01-CV-00339 (D. Del. Sept. 19, 2002) (stipulation and order of dismissal);
-
see also Agere Sys. Guardian Corp. v. Proxim, Inc., No. 01-CV-00339 (D. Del. Sept. 19, 2002) (stipulation and order of dismissal);
-
-
-
-
17
-
-
39449135226
-
-
AGERE SYS. GUARDIAN CORP., ANNUAL REPORT 49 (Form 10-K) (Dec. 5, 2003), available at http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1129446/000120677403000880/d13642. htm.
-
AGERE SYS. GUARDIAN CORP., ANNUAL REPORT 49 (Form 10-K) (Dec. 5, 2003), available at http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1129446/000120677403000880/d13642. htm.
-
-
-
-
18
-
-
39449117292
-
-
The EC announced the initiation of its formal investigation of Qualcomm on October 1, 2007. European Comm'n, Press Release, http://europa.eu/rapid/ pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/07/389&format=HTML&aged= 0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en.
-
The EC announced the initiation of its formal investigation of Qualcomm on October 1, 2007. European Comm'n, Press Release, http://europa.eu/rapid/ pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/07/389&format=HTML&aged= 0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en.
-
-
-
-
19
-
-
39449139236
-
-
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116, 1120 (S.D.N.Y. 1970).
-
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116, 1120 (S.D.N.Y. 1970).
-
-
-
-
21
-
-
39449128442
-
-
See also Case COMP/C-3/39.247, Texas Instrs. v. Qualcomm (2005);
-
See also Case COMP/C-3/39.247, Texas Instrs. v. Qualcomm (2005);
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
39449139563
-
-
Case COMP/C-3/39.248, Broadcom v. Qualcomm (2006);
-
Case COMP/C-3/39.248, Broadcom v. Qualcomm (2006);
-
-
-
-
23
-
-
39449131023
-
-
Case COMP/C-3/39.249, Nokia v. Qualcomm;
-
Case COMP/C-3/39.249, Nokia v. Qualcomm;
-
-
-
-
24
-
-
39449121528
-
-
Case COMP/C-3/39.250, Panasonic v. Qualcomm (2006);
-
Case COMP/C-3/39.250, Panasonic v. Qualcomm (2006);
-
-
-
-
25
-
-
39449116520
-
-
Case COMP/C-3/39.251, NEC v. Qualcomm (2005);
-
Case COMP/C-3/39.251, NEC v. Qualcomm (2005);
-
-
-
-
26
-
-
39449094488
-
-
Case COMP/C-3/39.252, Ericsson v. Qualcomm (2006).
-
Case COMP/C-3/39.252, Ericsson v. Qualcomm (2006).
-
-
-
-
27
-
-
39449117078
-
-
Press Release, Ericsson, Leading Mobile Wireless Technology Companies Call on European Commission to Investigate Qualcomm's Anti-competitive Conduct (Oct. 28, 2005), available at http://www.ericsson.com/ericsson/press/ releases/20051028-1018618. shtml;
-
Press Release, Ericsson, Leading Mobile Wireless Technology Companies Call on European Commission to Investigate Qualcomm's Anti-competitive Conduct (Oct. 28, 2005), available at http://www.ericsson.com/ericsson/press/ releases/20051028-1018618. shtml;
-
-
-
-
29
-
-
39449136699
-
-
William J. Baumol, Some Subtle Pricing Issues in Railroad Regulation, 10 INT'L. J. TRANSPORT ECON. 341 (1983);
-
William J. Baumol, Some Subtle Pricing Issues in Railroad Regulation, 10 INT'L. J. TRANSPORT ECON. 341 (1983);
-
-
-
-
30
-
-
39449104996
-
-
Robert D. Willig, The Theory of Network Access Pricing, in ISSUES IN PUBLIC UTILITY REGULATION 109 (Harry M. Trebing ed., 1979).
-
Robert D. Willig, The Theory of Network Access Pricing, in ISSUES IN PUBLIC UTILITY REGULATION 109 (Harry M. Trebing ed., 1979).
-
-
-
-
31
-
-
39449090594
-
-
For a recent application of ECPR to FRAND, see Swanson & Baumol, supra note 1
-
For a recent application of ECPR to FRAND, see Swanson & Baumol, supra note 1.
-
-
-
-
32
-
-
39449115900
-
-
Lloyd S. Shapley, A Value for N-Person Games, in 2 CONTRIBUTIONS TO THE THEORY OF GAMES 307 (H.W. Kuhn & A.W. Tucker eds., 1953).
-
Lloyd S. Shapley, A Value for N-Person Games, in 2 CONTRIBUTIONS TO THE THEORY OF GAMES 307 (H.W. Kuhn & A.W. Tucker eds., 1953).
-
-
-
-
33
-
-
39449083136
-
-
See Christian Ahlborn & Carsten Grave, Walter Eucken and Ordoliberalism: An Introduction from a Consumer Welfare Perspective, 2 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 197 (2006);
-
See Christian Ahlborn & Carsten Grave, Walter Eucken and Ordoliberalism: An Introduction from a Consumer Welfare Perspective, 2 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 197 (2006);
-
-
-
-
34
-
-
39449116811
-
-
see also DAVID J. GERBER, LAW AND COMPETITION IN TWENTIETH CENTURY EUROPE: PROTECTING PROMETHEUS (1998).
-
see also DAVID J. GERBER, LAW AND COMPETITION IN TWENTIETH CENTURY EUROPE: PROTECTING PROMETHEUS (1998).
-
-
-
-
35
-
-
39449122608
-
-
For surveys of the theoretical literature, see Morton I. Kamien, Patent Licensing, in 1 HANDBOOK OF GAME THEORY WITH ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS 332 (R.J. Aumann & S. Hart eds., 1992);
-
For surveys of the theoretical literature, see Morton I. Kamien, Patent Licensing, in 1 HANDBOOK OF GAME THEORY WITH ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS 332 (R.J. Aumann & S. Hart eds., 1992);
-
-
-
-
37
-
-
39449118489
-
-
Russell L. Parr & Gordon V. Smith, Quantitative Methods of Valuing Intellectual Property, in THE NEW ROLE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY IN COMMERCIAL TRANSACTIONS (Melvin Simensky & Lanning G. Bryer eds., 1994).
-
Russell L. Parr & Gordon V. Smith, Quantitative Methods of Valuing Intellectual Property, in THE NEW ROLE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY IN COMMERCIAL TRANSACTIONS (Melvin Simensky & Lanning G. Bryer eds., 1994).
-
-
-
-
38
-
-
39449110010
-
Pakes develops a model in which patents are compared to options. Ariel Pakes,
-
Patents as Options: Some Estimates of the Value of Holding European Patent Stocks, 54 ECONOMETRICA 755 1986
-
Ariel Pakes develops a model in which patents are compared to options. Ariel Pakes, Patents as Options: Some Estimates of the Value of Holding European Patent Stocks, 54 ECONOMETRICA 755 (1986).
-
-
-
Ariel1
-
39
-
-
39449090311
-
-
For a discussion of the strengths and weaknesses of option value analyses, see Josh Lerner & John Willinge, A Note on Valuation in Private Equity Settings 9 (Harvard Bus. Sch., Working Paper No. 9-297-050, 2002).
-
For a discussion of the strengths and weaknesses of option value analyses, see Josh Lerner & John Willinge, A Note on Valuation in Private Equity Settings 9 (Harvard Bus. Sch., Working Paper No. 9-297-050, 2002).
-
-
-
-
40
-
-
39449113819
-
-
Skewness refers to the shape of the distribution curve. In this case, the curve is shifted to the left, with a large peak at very low values and a long tail representing a small number of patents with high values. For examples in the literature discussing the skewed distribution of patent value, see F.M. SCHERER ET AL., PATENTS AND THE CORPORATION: A REPORT ON INDUSTRIAL TECHNOLOGY UNDER CHANGING PUBUC POLICY (2d ed. 1959);
-
Skewness refers to the shape of the distribution curve. In this case, the curve is shifted to the left, with a large peak at very low values and a long "tail" representing a small number of patents with high values. For examples in the literature discussing the skewed distribution of patent value, see F.M. SCHERER ET AL., PATENTS AND THE CORPORATION: A REPORT ON INDUSTRIAL TECHNOLOGY UNDER CHANGING PUBUC POLICY (2d ed. 1959);
-
-
-
-
41
-
-
0032359895
-
How To Count
-
Patents and Value Intellectual Property: The Uses of Patent Renewal and Application Data, 46 J. INDUS. ECON. 405 1998
-
Jean O. Lanjouw et al., How To Count Patents and Value Intellectual Property: The Uses of Patent Renewal and Application Data, 46 J. INDUS. ECON. 405 (1998);
-
-
-
Lanjouw, J.O.1
-
42
-
-
0033416992
-
Citation Frequency and the Value of Patented Inventions, 81
-
Dietmar Harhoff et al., Citation Frequency and the Value of Patented Inventions, 81 REV. ECON. STAT. 511 (1999);
-
(1999)
REV. ECON. STAT
, vol.511
-
-
Harhoff, D.1
-
43
-
-
0001093103
-
-
F.M. Scherer & Dietmar Harhoff, Technology Policy for a World of Skew-Distributed Outcomes, 29 RES. POL'Y 559 (2000);
-
F.M. Scherer & Dietmar Harhoff, Technology Policy for a World of Skew-Distributed Outcomes, 29 RES. POL'Y 559 (2000);
-
-
-
-
44
-
-
39449094182
-
-
Wesley M. Cohen & Stephen A. Merrill, Introduction, in PATENTS IN THE KNOWLEDGE BASED ECONOMY 1, 8 (Wesley M. Cohen & Stephen A. Merrill eds., 2003).
-
Wesley M. Cohen & Stephen A. Merrill, Introduction, in PATENTS IN THE KNOWLEDGE BASED ECONOMY 1, 8 (Wesley M. Cohen & Stephen A. Merrill eds., 2003).
-
-
-
-
45
-
-
39449109088
-
-
GOLDSTEIN & KEARSEY, supra note 1, at 89
-
GOLDSTEIN & KEARSEY, supra note 1, at 89.
-
-
-
-
46
-
-
39449106538
-
-
Chiao et al, supra note 4, at 5-6
-
Chiao et al., supra note 4, at 5-6.
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
84927964083
-
-
Including strategic decision makers in the team for standard-setting organization meetings is a relatively new phenomenon. See, e.g, Neil Gandal, Nataly Gantman & David Genesove, Intellectual Property and Standardization Committee Participation in the U.S. Modem Industry, in STANDARDS AND PUBLIC POLICY 208 Shane Greenstein & Victor Stango eds, 2004
-
Including strategic decision makers in the team for standard-setting organization meetings is a relatively new phenomenon. See, e.g., Neil Gandal, Nataly Gantman & David Genesove, Intellectual Property and Standardization Committee Participation in the U.S. Modem Industry, in STANDARDS AND PUBLIC POLICY 208 (Shane Greenstein & Victor Stango eds., 2004).
-
-
-
-
48
-
-
39449125195
-
-
Chiao et al, supra note 4, at 6
-
Chiao et al,, supra note 4, at 6.
-
-
-
-
49
-
-
84882012690
-
-
European Telecommunications Standards Institute, available at
-
European Telecommunications Standards Institute, Intellectual Property Rights Policy, available at http://www.etsi.org/legal/documents/ ETSI_IPRPolicy.pdf.
-
Intellectual Property Rights Policy
-
-
-
50
-
-
39449122907
-
Labs., Inc. v. Mitsubishi Elecs. Am. Inc
-
See, Fed. Cir
-
See Wang Labs., Inc. v. Mitsubishi Elecs. Am. Inc., 103 F.3d 1571 (Fed. Cir. 1997);
-
(1997)
103 F.3d 1571
-
-
Wang1
-
51
-
-
39449102907
-
-
Qualcomm Inc. v. Broadcom Corp, No. 05-CV-1958-B (BLM), 2007 WL 2296441 (S.D. Cal. Aug. 6, 2007);
-
Qualcomm Inc. v. Broadcom Corp, No. 05-CV-1958-B (BLM), 2007 WL 2296441 (S.D. Cal. Aug. 6, 2007);
-
-
-
-
52
-
-
39449107355
-
-
Stambler v. Diebold, Inc., 11 U.S.P.Q.2d 1709, 1988 WL 95479 (E.D.N.Y. 1988),
-
Stambler v. Diebold, Inc., 11 U.S.P.Q.2d 1709, 1988 WL 95479 (E.D.N.Y. 1988),
-
-
-
-
53
-
-
39449132055
-
-
aff'd mem., 878 F.2d 1445 (Fed. Cir. 1989) (unpublished);
-
aff'd mem., 878 F.2d 1445 (Fed. Cir. 1989) (unpublished);
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
39449139239
-
-
Potter Instr. Co. v. Storage Tech. Corp., 207 U.S.P.Q. 763, 1980 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 14348 (E.D. Va. 1980),
-
Potter Instr. Co. v. Storage Tech. Corp., 207 U.S.P.Q. 763, 1980 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 14348 (E.D. Va. 1980),
-
-
-
-
55
-
-
39449132056
-
-
aff'd, 641 F.2d 190 (4th Cir. 1981);
-
aff'd, 641 F.2d 190 (4th Cir. 1981);
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
39449128446
-
-
Dell Computer Corp., 121 F.T.C. 616, 1996 WL 33412055 (1996) (Statement of the Federal Trade Commission).
-
Dell Computer Corp., 121 F.T.C. 616, 1996 WL 33412055 (1996) (Statement of the Federal Trade Commission).
-
-
-
-
57
-
-
39449090313
-
-
Of course, other cases brought in U.S. courts have been decided in favor of the defendants, such as Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Techs. AG, 318 F.3d 1081 Fed. Cir. 2003
-
Of course, other cases brought in U.S. courts have been decided in favor of the defendants, such as Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Techs. AG, 318 F.3d 1081 (Fed. Cir. 2003).
-
-
-
-
58
-
-
39449110317
-
-
Press Release, European Commission, Competition: Commission Welcomes Changes in ETSI IPR Rules to Prevent Patent Ambush (Dec. 12, 2005), available at http://europa.eu.int/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference= IP/05/1565&type=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=EN.
-
Press Release, European Commission, Competition: Commission Welcomes Changes in ETSI IPR Rules to Prevent "Patent Ambush" (Dec. 12, 2005), available at http://europa.eu.int/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference= IP/05/1565&type=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=EN.
-
-
-
-
59
-
-
39449116200
-
-
Letter from Thomas O. Barnett, Ass't Att'y Gen., U.S. Dep't of Justice, to Michael A. Lindsay, Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers (Apr. 30, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/222978. htm;
-
Letter from Thomas O. Barnett, Ass't Att'y Gen., U.S. Dep't of Justice, to Michael A. Lindsay, Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers (Apr. 30, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/222978. htm;
-
-
-
-
60
-
-
39449135519
-
-
Letter from Thomas O. Barnett, Ass't Att'y Gen., U.S. Dep't of Justice, to Robert A. Skitol, VMEbus Int'l Trade Ass'n (Oct. 30, 2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/219380.htm.
-
Letter from Thomas O. Barnett, Ass't Att'y Gen., U.S. Dep't of Justice, to Robert A. Skitol, VMEbus Int'l Trade Ass'n (Oct. 30, 2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/219380.htm.
-
-
-
-
61
-
-
39449135030
-
-
VMEbUs International Trade Association, Oct. 30, 2006, available at
-
VMEbUs International Trade Association, VITA Patent Policy (Oct. 30, 2006), available at http://www.vita.com/disclosure/ VITA%20Patent%20Policy%20section%2010%20draft.pdf.
-
VITA Patent Policy
-
-
-
62
-
-
39449124855
-
Release, Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers, IEEE Enhances Standards
-
Patent Policy to Permit Fuller Disclosure on Licensing Apr. 30, 2007, available at http://standards.ieee.org/announcements/ stdspatpol.html
-
Press Release, Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers, IEEE Enhances Standards Patent Policy to Permit Fuller Disclosure on Licensing (Apr. 30, 2007), available at http://standards.ieee.org/announcements/ stdspatpol.html.
-
-
-
Press1
-
63
-
-
39449094793
-
-
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970).
-
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970).
-
-
-
-
64
-
-
39449109405
-
-
Legal scholars appear to agree that the ' Georgia-Pacific factors' have served as the standard framework . . . for over thirty years. Roy J. Epstein & Alan J. Marcus, Economic Analysis of the Reasonable Royalty: Simplification and Extension of the Georgia-Pacific Factors, 85 J. PAT. & TRADEMARK OFF. SOC'Y 555, 555 (2003).
-
Legal scholars appear to agree that the " ' Georgia-Pacific factors' have served as the standard framework . . . for over thirty years." Roy J. Epstein & Alan J. Marcus, Economic Analysis of the Reasonable Royalty: Simplification and Extension of the Georgia-Pacific Factors, 85 J. PAT. & TRADEMARK OFF. SOC'Y 555, 555 (2003).
-
-
-
-
65
-
-
39449106540
-
-
Georgia-Pacific., 318 F. Supp. at 1120.
-
Georgia-Pacific., 318 F. Supp. at 1120.
-
-
-
-
66
-
-
39449101731
-
-
This is by necessity a hypothetical exercise, since in each patent infringement case there is no willing licensee and no willing licensor; otherwise there would be no case. This is a point recognized in the Georgia-Pacific decision and by subsequent courts, such as the Sixth Circuit in Panduit. See Panduit Corp. v. Stahlin Bros. Fibre Works, Inc, 575 F.2d 1152 6th Cir. 1978, The exercise is worthwhile nonetheless since it casts the reasonable royalty question in the specific circumstances of the firms and patents involved
-
This is by necessity a hypothetical exercise, since in each patent infringement case there is no willing licensee and no willing licensor; otherwise there would be no case. This is a point recognized in the Georgia-Pacific decision and by subsequent courts, such as the Sixth Circuit in Panduit. See Panduit Corp. v. Stahlin Bros. Fibre Works, Inc., 575 F.2d 1152 (6th Cir. 1978). The exercise is worthwhile nonetheless since it casts the reasonable royalty question in the specific circumstances of the firms and patents involved.
-
-
-
-
67
-
-
39449133253
-
-
See, e.g., Smithkline Diagnostics, Inc. v. Helena Labs. Corp., 926 F.2d 1161, 1164 n.2 (Fed. Cir. 1991).
-
See, e.g., Smithkline Diagnostics, Inc. v. Helena Labs. Corp., 926 F.2d 1161, 1164 n.2 (Fed. Cir. 1991).
-
-
-
-
68
-
-
39449098036
-
-
Fauldine, supra note 13
-
Fauldine, supra note 13.
-
-
-
-
69
-
-
39449107100
-
-
Anne Layne-Farrar & Josh Lerner, To Join or Not to Join: Examining Patent Pool Participation and Rent Sharing Rules Working Paper Nov. 11, 2006, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract-945189
-
Anne Layne-Farrar & Josh Lerner, To Join or Not to Join: Examining Patent Pool Participation and Rent Sharing Rules (Working Paper Nov. 11, 2006), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract-945189.
-
-
-
-
70
-
-
39449109698
-
-
See GOLDSTEIN & KEARSEY, supra note 1, at 88-135
-
See GOLDSTEIN & KEARSEY, supra note 1, at 88-135.
-
-
-
-
71
-
-
39449118493
-
-
Patents are complex legal and technical documents. The reviewer would need to be well-versed in both patent law and the technology at hand
-
Patents are complex legal and technical documents. The reviewer would need to be well-versed in both patent law and the technology at hand.
-
-
-
-
72
-
-
39449137722
-
-
See GOLDSTEIN & KEARSEY, supra note 1, at 88-135
-
See GOLDSTEIN & KEARSEY, supra note 1, at 88-135.
-
-
-
-
73
-
-
39449100481
-
-
Participants may be unwilling to review competitors' claims of essentiality. See Chiao et al., supra note 4, at 6 n.3 (In fact, U.S. legal rules mandating trebled damages for willful infringement lead firms to discourage their engineers from even examining the patent portfolios of their competitors.).
-
Participants may be unwilling to review competitors' claims of essentiality. See Chiao et al., supra note 4, at 6 n.3 ("In fact, U.S. legal rules mandating trebled damages for willful infringement lead firms to discourage their engineers from even examining the patent portfolios of their competitors.").
-
-
-
-
74
-
-
39449114692
-
-
That is, it would be both unfair and unreasonable since companies with large portfolios of relatively unimportant patents would capture the most royalty earnings, while firms with a smaller number of critical patents would receive less
-
That is, it would be both unfair and unreasonable since companies with large portfolios of relatively unimportant patents would capture the most royalty earnings, while firms with a smaller number of critical patents would receive less.
-
-
-
-
75
-
-
34547768018
-
Navigating the
-
It would thus exacerbate any worries over patent proliferation and patent thickets, already hotly debated in the academic literature and popular press. For influential papers on patent thickets, see, Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard-Setting Competition Pol'y Ctr, Paper CPC00-011, 2001, available at http://repositories.cdlib.org/iber/cpc/CPC00-011
-
It would thus exacerbate any worries over patent proliferation and patent thickets, already hotly debated in the academic literature and popular press. For influential papers on patent thickets, see Carl Shapiro, Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard-Setting (Competition Pol'y Ctr., Paper CPC00-011, 2001), available at http://repositories.cdlib.org/iber/cpc/CPC00-011/,
-
-
-
Shapiro, C.1
-
76
-
-
39449101072
-
-
reprinted in I INNOVATION POLICY AND THE ECONOMY (Adam Jaffe, Joshua Lerner & Scott Stern eds., 2001);
-
reprinted in I INNOVATION POLICY AND THE ECONOMY (Adam Jaffe, Joshua Lerner & Scott Stern eds., 2001);
-
-
-
-
77
-
-
0032076909
-
Can Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in Biomedical Research, 280
-
Michael Heller & Rebecca Eisenberg, Can Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in Biomedical Research, 280 SCI. 698 (1998);
-
(1998)
SCI
, vol.698
-
-
Heller, M.1
Eisenberg, R.2
-
78
-
-
39449115315
-
-
see also Danny Bradbury, Canadian Innovation Choked by U.S. Laws, NAT'L POST, NOV. 17, 2003, at FE1.
-
see also Danny Bradbury, Canadian Innovation Choked by U.S. Laws, NAT'L POST, NOV. 17, 2003, at FE1.
-
-
-
-
79
-
-
39449129780
-
-
See Parr & Smith, supra note 18;
-
See Parr & Smith, supra note 18;
-
-
-
-
80
-
-
39449122909
-
-
Richard S. Toikka, Patent Licensing Under Competitive and Non-Competitive Conditions, 82 J. PAT. & TRADEMARK OFF. SOC'Y 279 (2000).
-
Richard S. Toikka, Patent Licensing Under Competitive and Non-Competitive Conditions, 82 J. PAT. & TRADEMARK OFF. SOC'Y 279 (2000).
-
-
-
-
81
-
-
39449101730
-
-
Layne-Farrar & Lerner, supra note 35
-
Layne-Farrar & Lerner, supra note 35.
-
-
-
-
82
-
-
39449094792
-
-
Swanson & Baumol, supra note 1
-
Swanson & Baumol, supra note 1.
-
-
-
-
83
-
-
39449121226
-
-
While Swanson and Baumol define options in terms of cost, the analysis is unchanged if we instead hold cost constant and maximize the quality or performance of the technology. Id. at 19
-
While Swanson and Baumol define options in terms of cost, the analysis is unchanged if we instead hold cost constant and maximize the quality or performance of the technology. Id. at 19.
-
-
-
-
87
-
-
39449084011
-
-
Id. at 39
-
Id. at 39.
-
-
-
-
88
-
-
39449090597
-
-
50As measured by declared essential patents, issued worldwide, posted on ETSI's Web site for UMTS and other 3G projects. See ETSI IPR Database, http://webapp.etsi.org/ipr/. Note that while many more thousands of patents are listed for these projects on the Web site, as of March 20, 2006, a great many of these are duplicate entries. After duplicate patent numbers are eliminated, about 4,650 patents remain, covering patents issued across the globe.
-
50As measured by declared essential patents, issued worldwide, posted on ETSI's Web site for UMTS and other 3G projects. See ETSI IPR Database, http://webapp.etsi.org/ipr/. Note that while many more thousands of patents are listed for these projects on the Web site, as of March 20, 2006, a great many of these are duplicate entries. After duplicate patent numbers are eliminated, about 4,650 patents remain, covering patents issued across the globe.
-
-
-
-
89
-
-
39449111459
-
-
This is a simplifying assumption that does not change the main results. The results still hold true in the general case, with n IP components produced by the same company, or n IP components produced by z companies
-
This is a simplifying assumption that does not change the main results. The results still hold true in the general case, with n IP components produced by the same company, or n IP components produced by z companies.
-
-
-
-
90
-
-
39449100760
-
-
A Nash equilibrium, named after the mathematiclan who proposed it, John Forbes Nash of A Beautiful Mind fame, is a game theory concept. A Nash equilibrium is a solution to a game involving two or more players in which no player has anything to gain by changing only his or her own strategy unilaterally. In other words, if I take your possible actions into account and pick my best strategy, and you do the same, neither one of us has any incentive to change our strategies unless something else changes, like new informa tion. John Nash, Equilibrium Points in n-Person Games, 36 PROC. NAT'L ACAD. SCI. 48 1950, An equilibrium is subgame perfect if it represents a Nash equilibrium of every subgame the original game can be divided into. Since our purpose is to lay out the possible tools that courts and competition authorities can use to define FRAND, we do not go into detail on the derivation of any equilibria
-
A Nash equilibrium, named after the mathematiclan who proposed it - John Forbes Nash of A Beautiful Mind fame - is a game theory concept. A Nash equilibrium is a solution to a game involving two or more players in which no player has anything to gain by changing only his or her own strategy unilaterally. In other words, if I take your possible actions into account and pick my best strategy, and you do the same, neither one of us has any incentive to change our strategies unless something else changes, like new informa tion. John Nash, Equilibrium Points in n-Person Games, 36 PROC. NAT'L ACAD. SCI. 48 (1950). An equilibrium is subgame perfect if it represents a Nash equilibrium of every subgame the original game can be divided into. Since our purpose is to lay out the possible tools that courts and competition authorities can use to define FRAND, we do not go into detail on the derivation of any equilibria.
-
-
-
-
91
-
-
39449101070
-
-
We assume for simplicity that in case of a tie in the royalty rates quoted by the owners of components a and c, the SSO selects the component with a greater absolute contribution to the standard: component a
-
We assume for simplicity that in case of a tie in the royalty rates quoted by the owners of components a and c, the SSO selects the component with a greater absolute contribution to the standard: component a.
-
-
-
-
92
-
-
39449117575
-
-
See Ahlborn & Grave, supra note 16;
-
See Ahlborn & Grave, supra note 16;
-
-
-
-
93
-
-
39449118492
-
-
see also GERBER, supra note 16
-
see also GERBER, supra note 16.
-
-
-
-
94
-
-
39449135785
-
-
Cooperative game theory does not set out to describe the way individuals behave. Rather, it recommends reasonable rules of allocation, or proposes indices to measure power. Eyal Winter, The Shapley Value, in 3 HANDBOOK OF GAME THEORY WITH ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS 2025, 2049 (Robert Aumann & Sergiu Hart eds., 2002).
-
"Cooperative game theory does not set out to describe the way individuals behave. Rather, it recommends reasonable rules of allocation, or proposes indices to measure power." Eyal Winter, The Shapley Value, in 3 HANDBOOK OF GAME THEORY WITH ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS 2025, 2049 (Robert Aumann & Sergiu Hart eds., 2002).
-
-
-
-
95
-
-
39449110014
-
-
See Shapley, supra note 15
-
See Shapley, supra note 15.
-
-
-
-
96
-
-
39449091834
-
-
Winter, supra note 55, at 2033
-
Winter, supra note 55, at 2033.
-
-
-
-
97
-
-
39449108507
-
-
For useful expositions and discussions of the Shapley value, see R. DUNCAN LUCE & HOWARD RAIFFA, GAMES AND DECISIONS (1957);
-
For useful expositions and discussions of the Shapley value, see R. DUNCAN LUCE & HOWARD RAIFFA, GAMES AND DECISIONS (1957);
-
-
-
-
98
-
-
39449116199
-
-
MARTIN SHUBIK, GAME THEORY IN THE SOCIAL SCIENCES: CONCEPTS AND SOLUTIONS (1983);
-
MARTIN SHUBIK, GAME THEORY IN THE SOCIAL SCIENCES: CONCEPTS AND SOLUTIONS (1983);
-
-
-
-
99
-
-
39449099539
-
-
and GUILLERMO OWEN, GAME THEORY (2d ed. 1982).
-
and GUILLERMO OWEN, GAME THEORY (2d ed. 1982).
-
-
-
-
100
-
-
39449112336
-
-
H.P. Young, Individual Contribution and Just Compensation, in THE SHAPLEY VALUE: ESSAYS IN HONOR OF LLOYD S. SHAPLEY 267 (Alvin E. Roth ed., 2005)
-
H.P. Young, Individual Contribution and Just Compensation, in THE SHAPLEY VALUE: ESSAYS IN HONOR OF LLOYD S. SHAPLEY 267 (Alvin E. Roth ed., 2005)
-
-
-
-
101
-
-
39449094184
-
-
[hereinafter THE SHAPLEY VALUE].
-
[hereinafter THE SHAPLEY VALUE].
-
-
-
-
102
-
-
39449122609
-
-
In a standard-setting context, this condition implicitly assumes that while patent holders need to be given incentives to develop their IP, this is not so for downstream manufacturers. Moreover, unlike the analysis of the previous section, it is assumed here that the total value captured by IP owners in aggregate is independent of the extent and nature of IP competition ex ante. Relaxing this assumption would not alter our conclusions regarding the relative compensations of patent holders with different average marginal contributions to the standard
-
In a standard-setting context, this condition implicitly assumes that while patent holders need to be given incentives to develop their IP, this is not so for downstream manufacturers. Moreover, unlike the analysis of the previous section, it is assumed here that the total value captured by IP owners in aggregate is independent of the extent and nature of IP competition ex ante. Relaxing this assumption would not alter our conclusions regarding the relative compensations of patent holders with different average marginal contributions to the standard.
-
-
-
-
104
-
-
39449137019
-
-
THE SHAPLEY VALUE, supra note 58, at 4-7
-
THE SHAPLEY VALUE, supra note 58, at 4-7.
-
-
-
-
105
-
-
39449136701
-
-
LUCE & RAIFFA, supra note 57, at 250;
-
LUCE & RAIFFA, supra note 57, at 250;
-
-
-
-
106
-
-
39449095628
-
-
SHUBIK, supra note 57, at 181;
-
SHUBIK, supra note 57, at 181;
-
-
-
-
107
-
-
39449117293
-
-
OWEN, supra note 57, at 197
-
OWEN, supra note 57, at 197.
-
-
-
-
108
-
-
39449117897
-
-
See infra Part IV.A.2.
-
See infra Part IV.A.2.
-
-
-
-
109
-
-
39449124234
-
-
The analysis of Case D in Part V above shows that even imperfect substitutes decrease Shapley value returns: the smaller is S or the larger is n, the lower the share of b1,even though its patent has no perfect substitutes. Case 3 in Part IV indicates that a similar property is satisfied by the Swanson-Baumol ex ante auction approach
-
1,even though its patent has no perfect substitutes. Case 3 in Part IV indicates that a similar property is satisfied by the Swanson-Baumol ex ante auction approach.
-
-
-
-
110
-
-
39449091523
-
-
The royalty payments do need to be incentive-compatible for IP owners to license their technology, so b' s license fees should cover the incremental costs of licensing, which we have neglected for simplicity.
-
The royalty payments do need to be incentive-compatible for IP owners to license their technology, so b' s license fees should cover the incremental costs of licensing, which we have neglected for simplicity.
-
-
-
-
111
-
-
39449113515
-
-
Note that under the ECPR an IP owner will get reimbursed for his incremental costs irrespective of how small the marginal contribution of his technology is, as long as it is sufficient to cover those costs. Likewise, under the Shapley value, owners whose marginal contributions are positive on any arrival sequence receive royalty payments
-
Note that under the ECPR an IP owner will get reimbursed for his incremental costs irrespective of how small the marginal contribution of his technology is, as long as it is sufficient to cover those costs. Likewise, under the Shapley value, owners whose marginal contributions are positive on any arrival sequence receive royalty payments.
-
-
-
|