메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 60, Issue 3, 2007, Pages 803-862

The uneasy case for patent races over auctions

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 40749093601     PISSN: 00389765     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (21)

References (264)
  • 1
    • 40749111652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under the Copyright Act, Copyright protection subsists . . . in original works of authorship fixed in any tangible medium of expression. 17 U.S.C § 102(a) (2000). A caveat is that in theory, someone independently could originate the exact same work and be entitled to a copyright too. See Sheldon v. Metro-Goldwyn Pictures Corp., 81 F.2d 49, 54 (2d Cir. 1936) ([I]f by some magic a man who had never known it were to compose anew Keats's Ode on a Grecian Urn, he would be entitled to copyright protection.). That, however, virtually never happens in practice, because of the large number of ways in which ideas can be expressed.
    • Under the Copyright Act, "Copyright protection subsists . . . in original works of authorship fixed in any tangible medium of expression." 17 U.S.C § 102(a) (2000). A caveat is that in theory, someone independently could originate the exact same work and be entitled to a copyright too. See Sheldon v. Metro-Goldwyn Pictures Corp., 81 F.2d 49, 54 (2d Cir. 1936) ("[I]f by some magic a man who had never known it were to compose anew Keats's Ode on a Grecian Urn," he would be entitled to copyright protection.). That, however, virtually never happens in practice, because of the large number of ways in which ideas can be expressed.
  • 2
    • 40749156434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The term 'trademark' includes any word, name, symbol, or device, or any combination thereof . . . used by a person, or . . . which a person has a bona fide intention to use in commerce and applies to register
    • Under the Lanham Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1127 2000
    • Under the Lanham Act, "The term 'trademark' includes any word, name, symbol, or device, or any combination thereof . . . used by a person, or . . . which a person has a bona fide intention to use in commerce and applies to register." 15 U.S.C. § 1127 (2000).
  • 3
    • 40749158113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Patent Act provides, Whoever invents or discovers any new and useful process, machine, manufacture, or composition of matter, or any new and useful improvement thereof, may obtain a patent therefor, subject to the conditions and requirements of this title. 35 U.S.C. § 101 2000
    • The Patent Act provides, "Whoever invents or discovers any new and useful process, machine, manufacture, or composition of matter, or any new and useful improvement thereof, may obtain a patent therefor, subject to the conditions and requirements of this title." 35 U.S.C. § 101 (2000).
  • 4
    • 40749139623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The most famous article urging a shift from the administrative approach to auctions is R. H. Coase, The Federal Communications Commission, 2 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1959), which included a brief version of what would later be known as the Coase Theorem. For a later analysis,
    • The most famous article urging a shift from the administrative approach to auctions is R. H. Coase, The Federal Communications Commission, 2 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1959), which included a brief version of what would later be known as the Coase Theorem. For a later analysis,
  • 5
    • 84935992831 scopus 로고
    • The Rationality of U.S. Regulation of the Broadcast Spectrum, 33
    • see
    • see Thomas W. Hazlett, The Rationality of U.S. Regulation of the Broadcast Spectrum, 33 J.L. & ECON. 133 (1990).
    • (1990) J.L. & ECON , vol.133
    • Hazlett, T.W.1
  • 6
    • 0032822669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Richard L. Fullerton & R. Preston McAfee, Auctioning Entry into Tournaments, 107 J. POL. ECON. 573, 581-82 (1999) (showing that under certain conditions, an auction should be used to limit a research tournament to the two participants willing to pay the most for the right to participate).
    • See, e.g., Richard L. Fullerton & R. Preston McAfee, Auctioning Entry into Tournaments, 107 J. POL. ECON. 573, 581-82 (1999) (showing that under certain conditions, an auction should be used to limit a research tournament to the two participants willing to pay the most for the right to participate).
  • 7
    • 40749122735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The difference is that in a research tournament, the terminal date is fixed, and the quality of innovations varies, while in an innovation race, the quality standard is fixed, and the date of discovery is variable. Curtis R. Taylor, Digging for Golden Carrots: An Analysis of Research Tournaments, 85 AM. ECON. REV. 872, 874 (1995).
    • The difference is that "in a research tournament, the terminal date is fixed, and the quality of innovations varies, while in an innovation race, the quality standard is fixed, and the date of discovery is variable." Curtis R. Taylor, Digging for Golden Carrots: An Analysis of Research Tournaments, 85 AM. ECON. REV. 872, 874 (1995).
  • 8
    • 0346449636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A notable exception is Gideon Parchomovsky's proposal for using auctions to distribute domain names. See Gideon Parchomovsky, On Trademarks, Domain Names, and Internal Auctions, 2001 U. III. L. REV. 211. NO one appears to have considered auctioning rights to genres of copyrighted works, and such broad copyrights would almost certainly be unattractive on economic and free speech grounds.
    • A notable exception is Gideon Parchomovsky's proposal for using auctions to distribute domain names. See Gideon Parchomovsky, On Trademarks, Domain Names, and Internal Auctions, 2001 U. III. L. REV. 211. NO one appears to have considered auctioning rights to genres of copyrighted works, and such broad copyrights would almost certainly be unattractive on economic and free speech grounds.
  • 9
    • 31144432380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michael Abramowicz, A Theory of Copyright's Derivative Right and Related Doctrines, 90 MINN. L. REV. 317, 356-57 (2005) (explaining why a super-copyright regime would be problematic). The possibility that the government might auction patent rights has received only two footnotes plus one sentence worth of attention in the literature.
    • See Michael Abramowicz, A Theory of Copyright's Derivative Right and Related Doctrines, 90 MINN. L. REV. 317, 356-57 (2005) (explaining why a "super-copyright" regime would be problematic). The possibility that the government might auction patent rights has received only two footnotes plus one sentence worth of attention in the literature.
  • 10
    • 40749104397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Parts I.A-I.B.
    • See infra Parts I.A-I.B.
  • 11
    • 40749123797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Patent and Trademark Office already defines various invention classifications through the U.S. Patent Classification System. See, e.g, U.S. Patent and Trademark Office, Patent Classification Home Page, http://www.uspto.gov/go/classification;
    • The Patent and Trademark Office already defines various invention classifications through the U.S. Patent Classification System. See, e.g., U.S. Patent and Trademark Office, Patent Classification Home Page, http://www.uspto.gov/go/classification;
  • 12
    • 40749124621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also 35 U.S.C § 8 (2000) (authorizing the classification system). A single patent conceivably might be classified in several classifications, however, and if rights to a particular subclass were to be auctioned, more attention might need to be paid to careful definition of the scope of the subclass.
    • see also 35 U.S.C § 8 (2000) (authorizing the classification system). A single patent conceivably might be classified in several classifications, however, and if rights to a particular subclass were to be auctioned, more attention might need to be paid to careful definition of the scope of the subclass.
  • 13
    • 34547752801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Nature and Function of the
    • Patent System, 20 J.L. & ECON. 265 1977
    • Edmund W. Kitch, The Nature and Function of the Patent System, 20 J.L. & ECON. 265 (1977).
    • Kitch, E.W.1
  • 16
    • 34547759046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Complex Economics of
    • Patent Scope, 90 COLUM. L. REV. 839, 908 1990
    • Robert P. Merges & Richard R. Nelson, On the Complex Economics of Patent Scope, 90 COLUM. L. REV. 839, 908 (1990);
    • Merges, R.P.1    Nelson, R.R.2
  • 17
    • 40749100800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also id. at 877, W]e have little faith in the imagination and willingness of a 'prospect' holder to develop that prospect as energetically or creatively as she would when engaged in competition, Mark Lemley insists that [t]he claim that an initial inventor is better suited to control research than the market is fundamentally an empirical one and that this empirical claim has been tested and found wanting
    • see also id. at 877 ("[W]e have little faith in the imagination and willingness of a 'prospect' holder to develop that prospect as energetically or creatively as she would when engaged in competition."). Mark Lemley insists that "[t]he claim that an initial inventor is better suited to control research than the market is fundamentally an empirical one" and that this empirical claim "has been tested and found wanting."
  • 18
    • 1842764749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mark A. Lemley, Ex Ante Versus Ex Post Justifications for Intellectual Property, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 129, 140 2004, The ultimate question, however, is not simply whether an initial inventor will better control research than competitive firms, but whether an early granting of an intellectual property right may lead to earlier invention. There are strong theoretical reasons for believing that the answer is affirmative
    • Mark A. Lemley, Ex Ante Versus Ex Post Justifications for Intellectual Property, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 129, 140 (2004). The ultimate question, however, is not simply whether an "initial inventor" will better control research than competitive firms, but whether an early granting of an intellectual property right may lead to earlier invention. There are strong theoretical reasons for believing that the answer is affirmative.
  • 19
    • 40749095014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I.C (considering Professor Duffy's demonstration of how the reduction in competition associated with patent races may accelerate innovation).
    • See infra Part I.C (considering Professor Duffy's demonstration of how the reduction in competition associated with patent races may accelerate innovation).
  • 20
    • 33645814048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Tim Wu, Intellectual Property, Innovation, and Decentralized Decisions, 92 VA. L. REV. 123 (2006) (arguing that patents may harm innovation by centralizing decisionmaking, but acknowledging that centralized information may be useful in some information contexts).
    • See Tim Wu, Intellectual Property, Innovation, and Decentralized Decisions, 92 VA. L. REV. 123 (2006) (arguing that patents may harm innovation by centralizing decisionmaking, but acknowledging that centralized information may be useful in some information contexts).
  • 21
    • 40749120639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an argument that centralized decisionmaking may reduce costs associated with duplication and delay, see Patrick Bolton & Joseph Farrell, Decentralization, Duplication, and Delay, 98 J. POL. ECON. 803 1990, Wu disputes the relevance of Bolton and Farrell's analysis for intellectual property, arguing that the relative quickness of centralized decisionmaking structures, seems less important in the intellectual property context
    • For an argument that centralized decisionmaking may reduce costs associated with duplication and delay, see Patrick Bolton & Joseph Farrell, Decentralization, Duplication, and Delay, 98 J. POL. ECON. 803 (1990). Wu disputes the relevance of Bolton and Farrell's analysis for intellectual property, arguing that "the relative quickness of centralized decisionmaking structures . . . seems less important in the intellectual property context."
  • 22
    • 40749106320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wu, supra note 12, at 130 n.18. But in innovation as in tax, timing is everything, since any feasible and potentially valuable invention presumably will be created someday. Bolton and Farrell note that if two firms have equal costs, they may enter into what eventually will be a natural monopoly market simultaneously, creating duplication, and if both have high costs, they may both wait, creating delay.
    • Wu, supra note 12, at 130 n.18. But in innovation as in tax, timing is everything, since any feasible and potentially valuable invention presumably will be created someday. Bolton and Farrell note that if two firms have equal costs, they may enter into what eventually will be a natural monopoly market simultaneously, creating duplication, and if both have high costs, they may both wait, creating delay.
  • 23
    • 40749123140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bolton & Farrell, supra, at 805. These problems exist as well in the intellectual property context, when two potential inventors have roughly equal chances of winning a patent
    • Bolton & Farrell, supra, at 805. These problems exist as well in the intellectual property context, when two potential inventors have roughly equal chances of winning a patent.
  • 24
    • 40749153689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For overviews of the economics of patent races, see JEAN TIRÓLE, THE THEORY OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 394-414 (1988);
    • For overviews of the economics of patent races, see JEAN TIRÓLE, THE THEORY OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 394-414 (1988);
  • 25
    • 0003164458 scopus 로고
    • Uncertainty, Industrial Structure, and the Speed of R&D, 11
    • Partha Dasgupta & Joseph Stiglitz, Uncertainty, Industrial Structure, and the Speed of R&D, 11 BELL J.ECON. 1 (1980).
    • (1980) BELL J.ECON , vol.1
    • Dasgupta, P.1    Stiglitz, J.2
  • 26
    • 40749093430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.A.2.a.
    • See infra Part II.A.2.a.
  • 27
    • 40749149744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federal Circuit has embraced inventing around, insisting that it is the stuff of which competition is made. State Indus., Inc. v. A.O. Smith Corp., 751 F.2d 1226, 1236 (Fed. Cir. 1985);
    • The Federal Circuit has embraced "inventing around," insisting that it "is the stuff of which competition is made." State Indus., Inc. v. A.O. Smith Corp., 751 F.2d 1226, 1236 (Fed. Cir. 1985);
  • 28
    • 40749150420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Designing Around a United States Patent, 45 S
    • endorsing the Federal Circuit conclusion and claiming that designing around is one of the ways in which the patent system works to the advantage of the public, Some commentators, however, have emphasized the inefficiencies associated with inventing around. see also
    • see also Paul N. Katz & Robert R. Riddle, Designing Around a United States Patent, 45 S. TEX. L. REV. 647, 649 (2004) (endorsing the Federal Circuit conclusion and claiming that designing around is "one of the ways in which the patent system works to the advantage of the public"). Some commentators, however, have emphasized the inefficiencies associated with inventing around.
    • (2004) TEX. L. REV , vol.647 , pp. 649
    • Katz, P.N.1    Riddle, R.R.2
  • 29
    • 84935498471 scopus 로고
    • The Patent-Antitrust Intersection: A Reappraisal, 97
    • recognizing that if the new invention adds no functionality, the expense of creating it is wasted and the reward function of the patent system is dampened, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Louis Kaplow, The Patent-Antitrust Intersection: A Reappraisal, 97 HARV. L. REV. 1813, 1869 (1984) (recognizing that if the new invention adds no functionality, the expense of creating it is wasted and the reward function of the patent system is dampened).
    • (1984) HARV. L. REV. 1813 , pp. 1869
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 30
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 106-07
    • See infra text accompanying notes 106-07.
    • See infra
  • 31
    • 26044434924 scopus 로고
    • Patents, Prospects, and Economic Surplus: A Comment, 23
    • See
    • See Donald G. McFetridge & Douglas A. Smith, Patents, Prospects, and Economic Surplus: A Comment, 23 J.L. & ECON. 197 (1980).
    • (1980) J.L. & ECON , vol.197
    • McFetridge, D.G.1    Smith, D.A.2
  • 32
    • 0037226804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perfecting
    • See, e.g, Patent Prizes, 56 VAND. L. REV. 115 2003
    • See, e.g., Michael Abramowicz, Perfecting Patent Prizes, 56 VAND. L. REV. 115 (2003);
    • Abramowicz, M.1
  • 33
    • 40749150836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steve P. Calandrillo, An Economic Analysis of Property Rights in Information: Justifications and Problems of Exclusive Rights, Incentives to Generate Information, and the Alternative of a Government-Run Reward System, 9 FORDHAM INTELL. PROP. MEDIA & ENT. L.J. 301 (1998);
    • Steve P. Calandrillo, An Economic Analysis of Property Rights in Information: Justifications and Problems of Exclusive Rights, Incentives to Generate Information, and the Alternative of a Government-Run Reward System, 9 FORDHAM INTELL. PROP. MEDIA & ENT. L.J. 301 (1998);
  • 35
    • 0035649475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steven Shavell & Tanguy van Ypersele, Rewards Versus Intellectual Property Rights, 44 J.L. & ECON. 525, 537-39 (2001). Conceivably, an auction system might be combined with a reward system, in which the government sometimes might take exclusive rights it had previously granted in exchange for just compensation. The reward system would thus be invoked only once the auction system had provided sufficient incentives for an auction winner to generate (and perhaps commercialize) socially valuable inventions.
    • Steven Shavell & Tanguy van Ypersele, Rewards Versus Intellectual Property Rights, 44 J.L. & ECON. 525, 537-39 (2001). Conceivably, an auction system might be combined with a reward system, in which the government sometimes might take exclusive rights it had previously granted in exchange for just compensation. The reward system would thus be invoked only once the auction system had provided sufficient incentives for an auction winner to generate (and perhaps commercialize) socially valuable inventions.
  • 36
    • 2942520956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking the Prospect Theory of Patents, 71
    • Some earlier commentators recognized the similarity between a patent race and an auction
    • John F. Duffy, Rethinking the Prospect Theory of Patents, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 439, 476-80 (2004). Some earlier commentators recognized the similarity between a patent race and an auction.
    • (2004) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.439 , pp. 476-480
    • Duffy, J.F.1
  • 37
    • 84970159940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wolfgang Leininger, Escalation and Cooperation in Conflict Situations, 33 J. CONFLICT RESOL. 231, 233 (1989) (analogizing a patent race to an escalation or all pay auction in which all auction participants must pay but only the highest bidder wins). Duffy, however, appears to be the first commentator to recognize that patent racers bid not only by committing a particular amount of money to research and development but also by deciding when to commit that money.
    • See, e.g., Wolfgang Leininger, Escalation and Cooperation in Conflict Situations, 33 J. CONFLICT RESOL. 231, 233 (1989) (analogizing a patent race to an "escalation" or "all pay" auction in which all auction participants must pay but only the highest bidder wins). Duffy, however, appears to be the first commentator to recognize that patent racers bid not only by committing a particular amount of money to research and development but also by deciding when to commit that money.
  • 38
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part LC For example, Duffy rejects the classic prospect theory position that patents should be broad, but the possibility of explicit auctions helps crystallize the benefits of broad patents. The endorsement of relatively broad patents is critical to the Article's ultimate policy proposal
    • See infra Part LC For example, Duffy rejects the classic prospect theory position that patents should be broad, but the possibility of explicit auctions helps crystallize the benefits of broad patents. The endorsement of relatively broad patents is critical to the Article's ultimate policy proposal.
    • See infra
  • 39
    • 40749108217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV.B.
    • See infra Part IV.B.
  • 40
    • 40749109135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part III.A.
    • See infra Part III.A.
  • 41
    • 40749127758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Parts III.B.1, III.B.2 (considering and comparing patent term auctions and pure cash auctions).
    • See infra Parts III.B.1, III.B.2 (considering and comparing patent term auctions and pure cash auctions).
  • 42
    • 40749126937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even where a patent might cover numerous products or services, a patent auction could approximate the low price approach by awarding the patent to the bidder who agrees to accept the lowest fraction of typical patent damages, compulsory license rates, or regulated prices. See infra text accompanying notes 179-82.
    • Even where a patent might cover numerous products or services, a patent auction could approximate the low price approach by awarding the patent to the bidder who agrees to accept the lowest fraction of typical patent damages, compulsory license rates, or regulated prices. See infra text accompanying notes 179-82.
  • 43
    • 40749095754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To the extent that the existing patent system functions as an implicit auction, it too may have this feature, as the winning inventors are those who offer the shortest effective patent terms. See infra Part LC discussing Professor Duffy's insight, Explicit price auctions, however, may be more efficient, because the last increment of monopoly pricing tends to be the most socially costly
    • To the extent that the existing patent system functions as an implicit auction, it too may have this feature, as the winning inventors are those who offer the shortest effective patent terms. See infra Part LC (discussing Professor Duffy's insight). Explicit price auctions, however, may be more efficient, because the last increment of monopoly pricing tends to be the most socially costly.
  • 44
    • 40749151654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 167-73 (discussing the implications of an analysis by Ian Ayres and Paul Klemperer). A slight price concession for a long patent term is likely more efficient than a large price concession for a short term, if the two provide equal value to the bidders.
    • See infra text accompanying notes 167-73 (discussing the implications of an analysis by Ian Ayres and Paul Klemperer). A slight price concession for a long patent term is likely more efficient than a large price concession for a short term, if the two provide equal value to the bidders.
  • 45
    • 40749143317 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • All that is needed to implement such a design is an announcement of some conversion rate between the different components of an auction bid. Another alternative is to declare a fixed requirement for all components but one, which then becomes the auction currency. Indeed, as argued below, it will generally be necessary even for patent term and price auctions to insist that bids have at least some cash component, as a means of deterring frivolous bids. See infra text introducing Part III
    • All that is needed to implement such a design is an announcement of some conversion rate between the different components of an auction bid. Another alternative is to declare a fixed requirement for all components but one, which then becomes the auction currency. Indeed, as argued below, it will generally be necessary even for patent term and price auctions to insist that bids have at least some cash component, as a means of deterring frivolous bids. See infra text introducing Part III.
  • 46
    • 40749155602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Article will consider how the government might seek to harness private information in comparing bids. If such approaches could be perfected, the optimal approach might not be for the government to hold patent auctions, but for the government to hold auctions that would give bidders incentives to define the optimal structure of patent law in particular technological fields. See infra Part IV.B
    • The Article will consider how the government might seek to harness private information in comparing bids. If such approaches could be perfected, the optimal approach might not be for the government to hold patent auctions, but for the government to hold auctions that would give bidders incentives to define the optimal structure of patent law in particular technological fields. See infra Part IV.B.
  • 47
    • 40749097875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., WILLIAM D. NORDHAUS, INVENTION, GROWTH, AND WELFARE: A THEORETICAL TREATMENT OF TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE 76 (1969) ([A] longer [patent] life increases invention and thus gives on balance a larger amount of output for a given level of inputs. . . . [But] a longer life means that the monopoly on information lasts longer and thus there are more losses from inefficiencies associated with monopoly.).
    • See, e.g., WILLIAM D. NORDHAUS, INVENTION, GROWTH, AND WELFARE: A THEORETICAL TREATMENT OF TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE 76 (1969) ("[A] longer [patent] life increases invention and thus gives on balance a larger amount of output for a given level of inputs. . . . [But] a longer life means that the monopoly on information lasts longer and thus there are more losses from inefficiencies associated with monopoly.").
  • 48
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 103 and accompanying text discussing the doctrine of equivalents
    • See infra note 103 and accompanying text (discussing the doctrine of equivalents);
    • See infra
  • 49
    • 1842764747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Prosecution History Estoppel, 71
    • providing an analysis of the doctrine of equivalents and the related doctrine of prosecution history estoppel, see also
    • see also Douglas Lichtman, Rethinking Prosecution History Estoppel, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 151 (2004) (providing an analysis of the doctrine of equivalents and the related doctrine of prosecution history estoppel).
    • (2004) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.151
    • Lichtman, D.1
  • 50
    • 0001016406 scopus 로고
    • Optimal Timing of Innovations, 50
    • Yoram Barzel, Optimal Timing of Innovations, 50 REV. ECON. & STAT. 348 (1968).
    • (1968) REV. ECON. & STAT , vol.348
    • Barzel, Y.1
  • 52
    • 40749103082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 349 (assumptions 1 and 3).
    • Id. at 349 (assumptions 1 and 3).
  • 53
    • 40749152478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 352 n.11 (A conceptual way to overcome this kind of misallocation is by granting (or by auctioning) monopoly rights on potential innovations before resources are committed to the innovating activity.).
    • Id. at 352 n.11 ("A conceptual way to overcome this kind of misallocation is by granting (or by auctioning) monopoly rights on potential innovations before resources are committed to the innovating activity.").
  • 54
    • 40749099179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 349 (assumption 4).
    • Id. at 349 (assumption 4).
  • 55
    • 40749136469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 350
    • Id. at 350.
  • 56
    • 40749113345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 355 tbl.2.
    • Id. at 355 tbl.2.
  • 57
    • 40749124620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is clear in the first sentence of his piece. See id. at 348 It is widely recognized that when innovators are unable to realize the full benefits generated by their innovations the profit motive may not provide an incentive strong enough for them to innovate at the socially optimal rate
    • This is clear in the first sentence of his piece. See id. at 348 ("It is widely recognized that when innovators are unable to realize the full benefits generated by their innovations the profit motive may not provide an incentive strong enough for them to innovate at the socially optimal rate.").
  • 58
    • 0000423201 scopus 로고
    • Measuring the Spillovers from Technical Advance: Mainframe Computers in Financial Services, 76
    • For attempts to measure the extent of spillovers, see
    • For attempts to measure the extent of spillovers, see Timothy F. Bresnahan, Measuring the Spillovers from Technical Advance: Mainframe Computers in Financial Services, 76 AM. ECON. REV. 742, 753 (1986);
    • (1986) AM. ECON. REV , vol.742 , pp. 753
    • Bresnahan, T.F.1
  • 59
    • 0001037934 scopus 로고
    • Imitation Costs and Patents: An Empirical Study, 91
    • Edwin Mansfield et al, Imitation Costs and Patents: An Empirical Study, 91 ECON. J. 907 (1981);
    • (1981) ECON. J , vol.907
    • Mansfield, E.1
  • 61
    • 40749161672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Janusz A. Ordover, Economic Foundations and Considerations in Protecting Industrial and Intellectual Property, 53 ANTITRUST L.J. 503, 509 (1984) (noting that governmental research subsidies may be needed when stringent property rights are not available to reduce the extent of inventive spillovers).
    • See, e.g., Janusz A. Ordover, Economic Foundations and Considerations in Protecting Industrial and Intellectual Property, 53 ANTITRUST L.J. 503, 509 (1984) (noting that governmental research subsidies may be needed when stringent property rights are not available to reduce the extent of inventive spillovers).
  • 62
    • 40749104395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kitch, supra note 9
    • Kitch, supra note 9.
  • 63
    • 40749085807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 265
    • Id. at 265.
  • 64
    • 40749134319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 65
    • 40749106750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 265-66
    • Id. at 265-66.
  • 66
    • 40749126543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 266 n.4.
    • Id. at 266 n.4.
  • 67
    • 40749109544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 276-78
    • Id. at 276-78.
  • 68
    • 40749157293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McFetridge & Smith, supra note 18, at 198
    • McFetridge & Smith, supra note 18, at 198.
  • 69
    • 40749141746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Prospect Theory of the
    • See, e.g, Patent System and Unproductive Competition, 5 RES. L. & ECON. 193, 194 1983
    • See, e.g., Roger L. Beck, The Prospect Theory of the Patent System and Unproductive Competition, 5 RES. L. & ECON. 193, 194 (1983).
    • Beck, R.L.1
  • 70
    • 40749098278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kitch, supra note 9, at 285
    • Kitch, supra note 9, at 285.
  • 71
    • 40749143326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 72
    • 35548966117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Danger of Underdeveloped
    • For a more detailed version of this argument, see, Patent Prospects, 92 CORNELL L. REV. 1065 2007
    • For a more detailed version of this argument, see Michael Abramowicz, The Danger of Underdeveloped Patent Prospects, 92 CORNELL L. REV. 1065 (2007).
    • Abramowicz, M.1
  • 73
    • 47749097403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally note 28, at, exploring this trade-off
    • See generally NORDHAUS, supra note 28, at 76 (exploring this trade-off).
    • supra , pp. 76
    • NORDHAUS1
  • 74
    • 33846467857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part III
    • See infra Part III.
    • See infra
  • 75
    • 40749096604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duffy, supra note 20
    • Duffy, supra note 20.
  • 76
    • 40749098759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duffy's analysis also helped answer the second major criticism of the prospect theory, that our patent system is not a prospect system that genuinely gives a patentee the power to control innovation, because it allows improvers to receive patents within the claims of the granted patent. Id. at 443 n.22 (citing sources making this objection);
    • Duffy's analysis also helped answer the second major criticism of the prospect theory, that our patent system is not a prospect system that genuinely gives a patentee the power to control innovation, because it allows improvers to receive patents within the claims of the granted patent. Id. at 443 n.22 (citing sources making this objection);
  • 77
    • 40749127336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see supra note 47 and accompanying text (noting this objection). A true prospect system that did prevent improvements, moreover, might stifle innovation. Duffy notes that the power of a prospect patent holder to block holders of improvement patents from using their inventions provides some control over invention.
    • see supra note 47 and accompanying text (noting this objection). A true prospect system that did prevent improvements, moreover, might stifle innovation. Duffy notes that the power of a prospect patent holder to block holders of improvement patents from using their inventions provides some control over invention.
  • 78
    • 40749148674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 485. More importantly, the inevitability of patent expiration provides prospect patent holders a continuing incentive to compete to obtain patentable improvements.
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 485. More importantly, the inevitability of patent expiration provides prospect patent holders a continuing incentive to compete to obtain patentable improvements.
  • 79
    • 40749150427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 488. Thus, even under a prospect system, inventors will compete in time to improve earlier, with the result that improvements also end up in the public domain earlier
    • Id. at 488. Thus, even under a prospect system, inventors will compete in time to improve earlier, with the result that improvements also end up in the public domain earlier.
  • 80
    • 40749162502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McFetridge & Smith, supra note 18, at 198. Later commentators suggested that the patent system might be seen as a mechanism that seeks to reduce the sum of the inefficiencies associated with patent races and competitive development of patented inventions.
    • McFetridge & Smith, supra note 18, at 198. Later commentators suggested that the patent system might be seen as a mechanism that seeks to reduce the sum of the inefficiencies associated with patent races and competitive development of patented inventions.
  • 81
    • 0002322382 scopus 로고
    • Patent Law and Rent Dissipation, 78
    • A] full accounting of the effects of the patent system must balance the savings in reduced follow-on investment against the losses from accelerated pioneering investment, See
    • See Mark F. Grady & Jay I. Alexander, Patent Law and Rent Dissipation, 78 VA. L. REV. 305, 317 (1992) ("[A] full accounting of the effects of the patent system must balance the savings in reduced follow-on investment against the losses from accelerated pioneering investment.").
    • (1992) VA. L. REV , vol.305 , pp. 317
    • Grady, M.F.1    Alexander, J.I.2
  • 82
    • 40749152883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 443-44, 464-75
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 443-44, 464-75.
  • 83
    • 40749090573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 475-80
    • Id. at 475-80.
  • 84
    • 0001849038 scopus 로고
    • Why Regulate Utilities?, 11
    • Harold Demsetz, Why Regulate Utilities?, 11 J.L. & ECON. 55, 63 (1968).
    • (1968) J.L. & ECON , vol.55 , pp. 63
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 85
    • 40749105456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demsetz's theory on natural monopolies does not necessarily depend on the government holding a centralized auction, though a centralized auction in effect usefully facilitates collusion among buyers. Id. at 57-58 (providing a simple example involving a natural monopoly in production of license plates).
    • Demsetz's theory on natural monopolies does not necessarily depend on the government holding a centralized auction, though a centralized auction in effect usefully facilitates collusion among buyers. Id. at 57-58 (providing a simple example involving a natural monopoly in production of license plates).
  • 86
    • 40749092231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 469-75 offering a model in which inventors race to obtain a patent
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 469-75 (offering a model in which inventors race to obtain a patent).
  • 87
    • 40749111199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There may be some randomness in who obtains the patent, because an attempt to invent may or may not be successful. Nonetheless, this does not change the fundamental conclusions of Duffy's analysis. Id. at 480-82.
    • There may be some randomness in who obtains the patent, because an attempt to invent may or may not be successful. Nonetheless, this does not change the fundamental conclusions of Duffy's analysis. Id. at 480-82.
  • 88
    • 40749100376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 470-72
    • Id. at 470-72.
  • 89
    • 40749120640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 11 (noting commentators' failure to recognize the point later made by Duffy).
    • See supra note 11 (noting commentators' failure to recognize the point later made by Duffy).
  • 90
    • 40749137931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kitch recognized the possible inefficiency of inventing around, but thought prospects might help patentees enter into agreements with potential competitors that would help forestall the wasteful investment. Kitch, supra note 9, at 279. Kitch, however, acknowledged that the patent holder cannot offer discounts to everyone who threatens to look for a substitute.
    • Kitch recognized the possible inefficiency of inventing around, but thought prospects might help patentees enter into agreements with potential competitors that would help "forestall the wasteful investment." Kitch, supra note 9, at 279. Kitch, however, acknowledged that "the patent holder cannot offer discounts to everyone who threatens to look for a substitute."
  • 91
    • 40749103972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 92
    • 40749151254 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 499-500
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 499-500.
  • 93
    • 40749141336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.A. 1.
    • See infra Part II.A. 1.
  • 94
    • 0042361801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Limiting Patentees' Market Power Without Reducing Innovation Incentives: The Perverse Benefits of Uncertainty and Non-Injunctive Remedies, 97
    • suggesting a duopoly auction in which the patentee would receive the revenues from an auction for a complete license to the patent, as a way of ensuring some degree of competition within the patent system, See
    • See Ian Ayres & Paul Klemperer, Limiting Patentees' Market Power Without Reducing Innovation Incentives: The Perverse Benefits of Uncertainty and Non-Injunctive Remedies, 97 MICH. L. REV. 985, 1031-32 (1999) (suggesting a "duopoly auction" in which the patentee would receive the revenues from an auction for a complete license to the patent, as a way of ensuring some degree of competition within the patent system);
    • (1999) MICH. L. REV , vol.985 , pp. 1031-1032
    • Ayres, I.1    Klemperer, P.2
  • 95
    • 0009009362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael Kremer, Patent Buyouts: A Mechanism for Encouraging Innovation, 113 Q.J. ECON. 1137 (1998) (suggesting an auction that would be consummated only some of the time, with the information from the bids used the rest of the time to buy out the patentee and place the patent into the public domain).
    • Michael Kremer, Patent Buyouts: A Mechanism for Encouraging Innovation, 113 Q.J. ECON. 1137 (1998) (suggesting an auction that would be consummated only some of the time, with the information from the bids used the rest of the time to buy out the patentee and place the patent into the public domain).
  • 96
    • 32244435314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Gideon Parchomovsky, A Marketplace for Ideas?, 84 TEX. L. REV. 395, 419 (2005). Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky also suggested that under certain circumstances, it might be optimal instead to allow anyone to develop the idea, subject to a liability rule compulsory license regime.
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Gideon Parchomovsky, A Marketplace for Ideas?, 84 TEX. L. REV. 395, 419 (2005). Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky also suggested that under certain circumstances, it might be optimal instead to allow anyone to develop the idea, subject to a liability rule compulsory license regime.
  • 97
    • 40749150421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 412-17.
    • See id. at 412-17.
  • 98
    • 40749087826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, idea registrants would have to satisfy the traditional criteria of usefulness, novelty, and nonobviousness. Id. at 426. The inventors would also have to demonstrate developability, i.e, that the invention constitutes a material contribution to the innovative process, and does not fit within the category of fanciful ideas i.e, those deemed undevelopable by a person skilled in the technological field to which the idea belongs
    • For example, idea registrants would have to satisfy the traditional criteria of usefulness, novelty, and nonobviousness. Id. at 426. The inventors would also have to demonstrate "developability," i.e., that the invention "constitutes a material contribution to the innovative process," and does not fit within the category of "fanciful ideas (i.e., those deemed undevelopable by a person skilled in the technological field to which the idea belongs)."
  • 100
    • 40749117808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (Importantly, developability is more lenient than implementability. Ideas, as opposed to patents, need not be readily implementable. By its very nature, an idea lacks the detail required for implementation.).
    • See id. ("Importantly, developability is more lenient than implementability. Ideas, as opposed to patents, need not be readily implementable. By its very nature, an idea lacks the detail required for implementation.").
  • 104
    • 40749149329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 418 n.70. Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky suggest that this will prevent idea conceivers [from] bidding token amounts on their own ideas just to prevent them from falling into the public domain.
    • Id. at 418 n.70. Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky suggest that this will prevent "idea conceivers [from] bidding token amounts on their own ideas just to prevent them from falling into the public domain."
  • 106
    • 40749126544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.C. Thus, some care must be taken in setting the appropriate level of the minimum bid
    • See supra Part I.C. Thus, some care must be taken in setting the appropriate level of the minimum bid.
  • 107
    • 40749139204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bar-Gill & Parchomovsky, supra note 68, at 421. Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky do not explicitly say that failure to develop would lead to development rights being placed in the public domain. This is the most natural reading of their proposal, but they say only that the entitlement would be strip[ped] away.
    • Bar-Gill & Parchomovsky, supra note 68, at 421. Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky do not explicitly say that failure to develop would lead to development rights being placed in the public domain. This is the most natural reading of their proposal, but they say only that the entitlement would be "strip[ped] away."
  • 108
    • 40749119484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. In theory, the entitlement could be reauctioned if development did not occur.
    • Id. In theory, the entitlement could be reauctioned if development did not occur.
  • 110
    • 40749134749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 404
    • Id. at 404.
  • 111
    • 40749108218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 408-09
    • Id. at 408-09.
  • 112
    • 40749148257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 417
    • Id. at 417.
  • 113
    • 40749123371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky concede this point but respond that the privately optimal auction design will generally diverge from the socially optimal auction design. Id. at 417 n.66. They do not, however, explain what the divergence would be, or justify the conclusion that a one-size-fits-all auction design chosen by the government will be more socially optimal than the design chosen by individual idea registrants.
    • Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky concede this point but respond that "the privately optimal auction design will generally diverge from the socially optimal auction design." Id. at 417 n.66. They do not, however, explain what the divergence would be, or justify the conclusion that a one-size-fits-all auction design chosen by the government will be more socially optimal than the design chosen by individual idea registrants.
  • 114
    • 1542532493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sometimes individualized negotiation might be more efficient than an auction because an auction requires all participants to research the invention, even though at most one will win the right to develop it. But cf. Jeremy Bulow & Paul Klemperer, Auctions Versus Negotiations, 86 AM. ECON. REV. 180 1996, offering a model showing that an auction generally will be more efficient than a negotiation with one less participant
    • Sometimes individualized negotiation might be more efficient than an auction because an auction requires all participants to research the invention, even though at most one will win the right to develop it. But cf. Jeremy Bulow & Paul Klemperer, Auctions Versus Negotiations, 86 AM. ECON. REV. 180 (1996) (offering a model showing that an auction generally will be more efficient than a negotiation with one less participant).
  • 115
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 50 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 50 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 116
    • 40749084165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the European approach to compulsory licensing, see Ronald E. Myrick, Influences Affecting the Licensing of Rights in a Unitary European Market, 4 FORDHAM INTELL. PROP. MEDIA & ENT. L.J. 81, 95 (1993).
    • For a discussion of the European approach to compulsory licensing, see Ronald E. Myrick, Influences Affecting the Licensing of Rights in a Unitary European Market, 4 FORDHAM INTELL. PROP. MEDIA & ENT. L.J. 81, 95 (1993).
  • 117
    • 40749146949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky recognize the difficulty of enforcing this approach. Bar-Gill & Parchomovsky, supra note 68, at 421-22. ([Verifying whether the development requirement has been satisfied might be costly, perhaps prohibitively so.). One problem is what should count as a patent or product sufficient to avoid the invention being placed in the public domain. A firm might produce a useless patent or product simply to avoid losing patent rights. That would not only be wasteful, but would also evade the Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky rule, which does not require continued development after a patent or product is initially produced.
    • Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky recognize the difficulty of enforcing this approach. Bar-Gill & Parchomovsky, supra note 68, at 421-22. ("[Verifying whether the development requirement has been satisfied might be costly, perhaps prohibitively so."). One problem is what should count as a patent or product sufficient to avoid the invention being placed in the public domain. A firm might produce a useless patent or product simply to avoid losing patent rights. That would not only be wasteful, but would also evade the Bar-Gill and Parchomovsky rule, which does not require continued development after a patent or product is initially produced.
  • 118
    • 40749113339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Others make similar assumptions. For example, Mark Lemley argues that once an intellectual property right expires, many companies can compete to make the good, and they will do so only so long as they can manufacture and distribute it for less money than people will pay to buy it. Lemley, supra note 11, at 136. Professor Lemley recognizes the counterargument that some form of intellectual property right may be necessary to provide adequate incentives to improve on an existing work.
    • Others make similar assumptions. For example, Mark Lemley argues that "once an intellectual property right expires, many companies can compete to make the good, and they will do so only so long as they can manufacture and distribute it for less money than people will pay to buy it." Lemley, supra note 11, at 136. Professor Lemley recognizes the counterargument that some form of intellectual property right may be necessary to provide "adequate incentives to improve on an existing work."
  • 120
    • 40749131900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • may need to be developed in ways that, at least under current doctrine, are nonpatentable
    • Id. at 139. Patents, however, may need to be developed in ways that, at least under current doctrine, are nonpatentable.
    • at 139. Patents, however
  • 121
    • 40749135199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 50, at 1098-103 (discussing development activities that do not themselves entitle developers to additional intellectual property protection). It is not easy to see, for example, even how a hypothetical intellectual property regime would provide a reward to someone who markets a product without giving some right over the product itself. In a world in which some development and improvement of patented technologies does not receive the benefit of independent intellectual property protection, the placement of inventions into the public domain has at least the potential to harm ex post efficiency. Indeed, Lemley concedes that there are some circumstances in which prospecting rights may be justified.
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 50, at 1098-103 (discussing development activities that do not themselves entitle developers to additional intellectual property protection). It is not easy to see, for example, even how a hypothetical intellectual property regime would provide a reward to someone who markets a product without giving some right over the product itself. In a world in which some development and improvement of patented technologies does not receive the benefit of independent intellectual property protection, the placement of inventions into the public domain has at least the potential to harm ex post efficiency. Indeed, Lemley concedes that there are some circumstances in which prospecting rights may be justified.
  • 122
    • 40749122281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley, supra note 11, at 141 (Prospect theory is needed when control over subsequent development is a necessary part of the incentive to produce the pioneering invention in the first place, as is arguably true with pharmaceuticals.).
    • See Lemley, supra note 11, at 141 ("Prospect theory is needed when control over subsequent development is a necessary part of the incentive to produce the pioneering invention in the first place, as is arguably true with pharmaceuticals.").
  • 123
    • 40749134748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Such a justification may not be straightforward. A threat to deprive a would-be developer of a patent right for failure to develop might inefficiently accelerate invention efforts. See Barzel, supra note 30, at 348 (showing that innovation may occur inefficiently early).
    • Such a justification may not be straightforward. A threat to deprive a would-be developer of a patent right for failure to develop might inefficiently accelerate invention efforts. See Barzel, supra note 30, at 348 (showing that innovation may occur inefficiently early).
  • 124
    • 40749131011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.A.
    • See supra Part I.A.
  • 125
    • 40749133921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See F.M. Scherer, Nordhaus' Theory of Optimal Patent Life: A Geometric Reinterpretation, 62 AM. ECON. REV. 422, 424 1972
    • See F.M. Scherer, Nordhaus' Theory of Optimal Patent Life: A Geometric Reinterpretation, 62 AM. ECON. REV. 422, 424 (1972).
  • 126
    • 40749148667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., WILLIAM M. LANDES & RICHARD A. POSNER, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW 421 (2003) (noting that transaction costs may provide a justification for narrowing intellectual property rights).
    • See, e.g., WILLIAM M. LANDES & RICHARD A. POSNER, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW 421 (2003) (noting that transaction costs may provide a justification for narrowing intellectual property rights).
  • 127
    • 40749154122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nonetheless, in the absence of exogenous shocks, Duffy's argument suggests that we should gradually transition to a longer and longer term. See John F. Duffy, A Minimum Optimal Patent Term (2003, unpublished manuscript, available at http://www.ssrn.com/abstract=354282 explaining that a dynamic model of invention suggests that the patent term should be no less than a particular length
    • Nonetheless, in the absence of exogenous shocks, Duffy's argument suggests that we should gradually transition to a longer and longer term. See John F. Duffy, A Minimum Optimal Patent Term (2003) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.ssrn.com/abstract=354282 (explaining that a dynamic model of invention suggests that the patent term should be no less than a particular length).
  • 128
    • 40749136758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.C.
    • See supra Part I.C.
  • 129
    • 0012093990 scopus 로고
    • Molecular Manufacturing: Adding Positional Control to Chemical Synthesis
    • For example, the right might be to any process providing for positional control in chemical synthesis. See, Sept.-Oct, at
    • For example, the right might be to any process providing for positional control in chemical synthesis. See Ralph C. Merkle, Molecular Manufacturing: Adding Positional Control to Chemical Synthesis, CHEMICAL DESIGN AUTOMATION NEWS, Sept.-Oct. 1993, at 1.
    • (1993) CHEMICAL DESIGN AUTOMATION NEWS , pp. 1
    • Merkle, R.C.1
  • 130
    • 0345984391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Improvement in Intellectual Property Law, 75
    • discussing patent doctrines related to improvement patents, See
    • See Mark A. Lemley, The Economics of Improvement in Intellectual Property Law, 75 TEX. L. REV. 989, 1000-13 (1997) (discussing patent doctrines related to improvement patents).
    • (1997) TEX. L. REV , vol.989 , pp. 1000-1013
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 131
    • 40749096172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A rule of first possession also will tend to emerge because it is easy for a court to recognize. See, e.g., Richard A. Epstein, Possession as the Root of Title, 13 GA. L. REV. 1221, 1222-23 (1979). An auction regime requires some type of centralized administrative machinery.
    • A rule of first possession also will tend to emerge because it is easy for a court to recognize. See, e.g., Richard A. Epstein, Possession as the Root of Title, 13 GA. L. REV. 1221, 1222-23 (1979). An auction regime requires some type of centralized administrative machinery.
  • 132
    • 84937285008 scopus 로고
    • The Rule of First Possession and the Design of the Law, 38
    • The heterogeneity of potential prospectors will tend to reduce rent dissipation. See, e.g
    • The heterogeneity of potential prospectors will tend to reduce rent dissipation. See, e.g., Dean Lueck, The Rule of First Possession and the Design of the Law, 38 J.L. & ECON. 393, 401 (1995);
    • (1995) J.L. & ECON , vol.393 , pp. 401
    • Lueck, D.1
  • 134
    • 84980096808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally William Vickrey, Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders, 16 J. FIN. 8 1961, introducing the idea of a second-price sealed bid auction, Even in a first-bid auction, a party expecting to be the top bidder will bid somewhat less than its actual valuation to ensure that it will receive some benefit from winning the auction. Thus, there may be some incentive for well-situated potential bidders to lobby for the government to conduct an auction. Nonetheless, bidders are likely to be less heterogeneous with respect to their valuations at auction than with respect to their expected success in prospecting. A slight advantage in a prospecting race can lead to a large difference in the probability of victory, but only a small difference in the amounts that the participants would bid if the right were auctioned
    • See generally William Vickrey, Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders, 16 J. FIN. 8 (1961) (introducing the idea of a second-price sealed bid auction). Even in a first-bid auction, a party expecting to be the top bidder will bid somewhat less than its actual valuation to ensure that it will receive some benefit from winning the auction. Thus, there may be some incentive for well-situated potential bidders to lobby for the government to conduct an auction. Nonetheless, bidders are likely to be less heterogeneous with respect to their valuations at auction than with respect to their expected success in prospecting. A slight advantage in a prospecting race can lead to a large difference in the probability of victory, but only a small difference in the amounts that the participants would bid if the right were auctioned.
  • 135
    • 40749093020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally MANCUR OLSON, THE LOGIC OF COLLECTIVE ACTION: PUBLIC GOODS AND THE THEORY OF GROUPS (1965) (noting the difficulty of organizing and mobilizing diffuse groups, and thus the difficulty these groups have in influencing the legislative process).
    • See generally MANCUR OLSON, THE LOGIC OF COLLECTIVE ACTION: PUBLIC GOODS AND THE THEORY OF GROUPS (1965) (noting the difficulty of organizing and mobilizing diffuse groups, and thus the difficulty these groups have in influencing the legislative process).
  • 136
    • 40749089731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A significant reason for a legislature to enact an auction scheme is because auctions are likely to generate revenue, and thus substitute for taxes or reduced spending in helping to balance budgets. See, e.g, Ellen P. Goodman, Digital Television and the Allure of Auctions: The Birth and Stillbirth of DTV Legislation, 49 FED. COMM. L.J. 517, 526 1997, noting the billions of dollars the government received from spectrum auctions and observing that the temptation to wring auction revenue from the broadcast spectrum was intense, Non-cash auctions are less likely to be politically appealing than cash auctions
    • A significant reason for a legislature to enact an auction scheme is because auctions are likely to generate revenue, and thus substitute for taxes or reduced spending in helping to balance budgets. See, e.g., Ellen P. Goodman, Digital Television and the Allure of Auctions: The Birth and Stillbirth of DTV Legislation, 49 FED. COMM. L.J. 517, 526 (1997) (noting the billions of dollars the government received from spectrum auctions and observing that "the temptation to wring auction revenue from the broadcast spectrum was intense"). Non-cash auctions are less likely to be politically appealing than cash auctions.
  • 137
    • 33846467857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part III
    • See infra Part III.
    • See infra
  • 138
    • 40749097461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.C.
    • See supra Part I.C.
  • 139
    • 40749093019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 469-72 (assuming N identical firms, where N is exogenous to the model).
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 469-72 (assuming "N identical firms," where N is exogenous to the model).
  • 141
    • 40749109136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.A. But, at least under some assumptions, the costs of this delay will be considerably less than the benefits of limiting duplicative effort.
    • See supra Part I.A. But, at least under some assumptions, the costs of this delay will be considerably less than the benefits of limiting duplicative effort.
  • 142
    • 40749107181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 50, at 1084-86 (elaborating on the Duffy model by allowing the appropriability of an invention to vary in a context in which two firms are competing for a patent).
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 50, at 1084-86 (elaborating on the Duffy model by allowing the appropriability of an invention to vary in a context in which two firms are competing for a patent).
  • 143
    • 40749084164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An explicit auction system, however, could exacerbate the risk that inventions will not be commercialized. Suppose, for example, that the government auctions a twenty-year patent term in an emerging technological field, but an inventor is unlikely to be able to develop an invention until at least ten years of development. If the auction system is exclusive and replaces the patent system, then the inventor will have less of a patent term than the inventor otherwise would have had, and therefore not only might not commercialize the invention, but also might not have sufficient incentive to develop the invention in the first place. A nonexclusive auction system that complements the patent system will not produce this risk
    • An explicit auction system, however, could exacerbate the risk that inventions will not be commercialized. Suppose, for example, that the government auctions a twenty-year patent term in an emerging technological field, but an inventor is unlikely to be able to develop an invention until at least ten years of development. If the auction system is exclusive and replaces the patent system, then the inventor will have less of a patent term than the inventor otherwise would have had, and therefore not only might not commercialize the invention, but also might not have sufficient incentive to develop the invention in the first place. A nonexclusive auction system that complements the patent system will not produce this risk.
  • 144
    • 40749092234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Suppose, for example, that a patent is expected to produce $1000 per year in profit and can be commercialized after ten years. Assume a 5% discount rate. With a twenty-year term, the patent in present value terms will be worth $4978. With a thirty-year term, the patent will be worth $9909, almost double.
    • Suppose, for example, that a patent is expected to produce $1000 per year in profit and can be commercialized after ten years. Assume a 5% discount rate. With a twenty-year term, the patent in present value terms will be worth $4978. With a thirty-year term, the patent will be worth $9909, almost double.
  • 145
    • 40749149330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.C Indeed, in a model offered by Duffy, longer nominal patent terms can lead inventions to be placed in the public domain earlier, because the indirect effect of the longer patent term on date of invention can more than compensate for the direct effect of term length.
    • See supra Part I.C Indeed, in a model offered by Duffy, longer nominal patent terms can lead inventions to be placed in the public domain earlier, because the indirect effect of the longer patent term on date of invention can more than compensate for the direct effect of term length.
  • 146
    • 40749099173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Duffy, supra note 86, at 4-5
    • See Duffy, supra note 86, at 4-5.
  • 147
    • 0032076909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Can Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in Biomedical Research, 280
    • For arguments that a patent thicket or anticommons problem may slow innovation even in the existing patent system, see
    • For arguments that a "patent thicket" or anticommons problem may slow innovation even in the existing patent system, see Michael A. Heller & Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Can Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in Biomedical Research, 280 SCIENCE 698 (1998),
    • (1998) SCIENCE , vol.698
    • Heller, M.A.1    Eisenberg, R.S.2
  • 148
    • 40749087404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Arti K. Rai & Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Bayh-Dole Reform and the Progress of Biomedicine, 66 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 289 (2003).
    • and Arti K. Rai & Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Bayh-Dole Reform and the Progress of Biomedicine, 66 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 289 (2003).
  • 149
    • 40749142893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court defines a pioneer invention as covering a function never before performed, a wholly novel device, or one of such novelty and importance as to mark a distinct step in the progress of the art. Westinghouse v. Boyden Power Brake Co., 170 U.S. 537, 561-62 (1898).
    • The Supreme Court defines a "pioneer invention" as "covering a function never before performed, a wholly novel device, or one of such novelty and importance as to mark a distinct step in the progress of the art." Westinghouse v. Boyden Power Brake Co., 170 U.S. 537, 561-62 (1898).
  • 150
    • 84977235066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Question Concerning
    • See, e.g, Patent Law and Pioneer Inventions, 10 HIGH TECH. L.J. 35, 37 1995
    • See, e.g., John R. Thomas, The Question Concerning Patent Law and Pioneer Inventions, 10 HIGH TECH. L.J. 35, 37 (1995).
    • Thomas, J.R.1
  • 151
    • 0345547423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Policy Levers in
    • See, e.g, Patent Law, 89 VA. L. REV. 1575, 1656 2003, The pioneer patent rule has not been invoked by the Federal Circuit in recent years, leading some to consider it moribund, but it provides at least one factor to consider in deciding how broadly to apply the doctrine of equivalents, footnotes omitted
    • See, e.g., Dan L. Burk & Mark A. Lemley, Policy Levers in Patent Law, 89 VA. L. REV. 1575, 1656 (2003) ("The pioneer patent rule has not been invoked by the Federal Circuit in recent years, leading some to consider it moribund, but it provides at least one factor to consider in deciding how broadly to apply the doctrine of equivalents." (footnotes omitted)).
    • Burk, D.L.1    Lemley, M.A.2
  • 152
    • 40749161674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., O'Reilly v. Morse, 56 U.S. (15 How.) 62, 86 (1854) (invalidating one patent claim, purporting to cover the use of electro-magnetism, however developed, for making or printing intelligible characters, letters, or signs, at any distances, because it did not disclose all methods for use of the principle of electromagnetism). For a discussion of O'Reilly and related cases,
    • See, e.g., O'Reilly v. Morse, 56 U.S. (15 How.) 62, 86 (1854) (invalidating one patent claim, purporting to cover the use of
  • 153
    • 40749147821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Merges & Nelson, supra note 11, at 845-51
    • see Merges & Nelson, supra note 11, at 845-51.
  • 154
    • 40749125030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This does not mean that there would not be boundary questions. For example, if the right to all antidepressant drugs were auctioned, then the question would arise as to how a drug with some other primary purpose but also some antidepressant effects should be treated. Conceivably, the holder of the antidepressant patent might have a blocking right to these drugs, or a compulsory license regime might allocate profits in cases in which rights overlap
    • This does not mean that there would not be boundary questions. For example, if the right to all antidepressant drugs were auctioned, then the question would arise as to how a drug with some other primary purpose but also some antidepressant effects should be treated. Conceivably, the holder of the antidepressant patent might have a blocking right to these drugs, or a compulsory license regime might allocate profits in cases in which rights overlap.
  • 155
    • 40749130161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although patent law includes a utility requirement, see 35 U.S.C. §101 2000, the patent office and the courts have interpreted the requirement loosely, considering scientific plausibility rather than efficacy
    • Although patent law includes a utility requirement, see 35 U.S.C. §101 (2000), the patent office and the courts have interpreted the requirement loosely, considering scientific plausibility rather than efficacy.
  • 156
    • 0348225115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Nathan Machin, Prospective Utility: A New Interpretation of the Utility Requirement of Section 101 of the Patent Act, 87 CAL. L. REV. 421, 426-27 1999
    • See, e.g., Nathan Machin, Prospective Utility: A New Interpretation of the Utility Requirement of Section 101 of the Patent Act, 87 CAL. L. REV. 421, 426-27 (1999).
  • 157
    • 40749117072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.A.2.b.
    • See infra Part II.A.2.b.
  • 158
    • 40749092575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.A.
    • See supra Part I.A.
  • 159
    • 0742324003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Patentees sometimes may give away secrets through publication and obtain narrower patents because they want to encourage improvers to improve inventions without worrying about transaction costs. See Oren Bar-Gill & Gideon Parchomovsky, The Value of Giving Away Secrets, 89 VA. L. REV. 1857 2003, offering a theoretical and empirical case for this theory
    • Patentees sometimes may give away secrets through publication and obtain narrower patents because they want to encourage improvers to improve inventions without worrying about transaction costs. See Oren Bar-Gill & Gideon Parchomovsky, The Value of Giving Away Secrets, 89 VA. L. REV. 1857 (2003) (offering a theoretical and empirical case for this theory).
  • 160
    • 40749103074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra notes 11-12.
    • See sources cited supra notes 11-12.
  • 161
    • 40749099174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 470-72;
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 470-72;
  • 163
    • 40749136464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The product differentiation literature shows that excessive entry can occur in competitive markets because each entrant fails to take into account the extent to which its product's sales come at the expense of products that already exist. See, e.g, Avinash K. Dixit & Joseph E. Stiglitz, Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity, 67 AM. ECON. REV. 297 (1977, developing a model in which excess or insufficient entry can occur);
    • The product differentiation literature shows that excessive entry can occur in competitive markets because each entrant fails to take into account the extent to which its product's sales come at the expense of products that already exist. See, e.g., Avinash K. Dixit & Joseph E. Stiglitz, Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity, 67 AM. ECON. REV. 297 (1977) (developing a model in which excess or insufficient entry can occur);
  • 164
    • 0001549798 scopus 로고
    • Monopolistic Competition with Outside Goods, 10
    • developing a model in which excess entry occurs, To the extent that monopoly rights may decrease the number of new inventions, they counterintuitively may enhance efficiency
    • Steven C. Salop, Monopolistic Competition with Outside Goods, 10 BELL J. ECON. 141, 142-45 (1979) (developing a model in which excess entry occurs). To the extent that monopoly rights may decrease the number of new inventions, they counterintuitively may enhance efficiency.
    • (1979) BELL J. ECON , vol.141 , pp. 142-145
    • Salop, S.C.1
  • 165
    • 40749151248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Wu, supra note 12 offering an extended version of this argument
    • See, e.g., Wu, supra note 12 (offering an extended version of this argument).
  • 166
    • 40749109546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We cannot learn much empirically about how patent auctions would work by considering the behavior of firms that have already profited from broad patents. See, e.g., Merges & Nelson, supra note 11, at 884-908 (providing specific examples of firms that slowed the pace of innovation after receiving patents). Inventors who have already covered research expenses many times over might be less efficient than inventors who will need to produce phenomenal results to avoid the costs of an auction.
    • We cannot learn much empirically about how patent auctions would work by considering the behavior of firms that have already profited from broad patents. See, e.g., Merges & Nelson, supra note 11, at 884-908 (providing specific examples of firms that slowed the pace of innovation after receiving patents). Inventors who have already covered research expenses many times over might be less efficient than inventors who will need to produce phenomenal results to avoid the costs of an auction.
  • 167
    • 40749145016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part III.A.
    • See infra Part III.A.
  • 168
    • 40749125452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bar-Gill & Parchomovsky, supra note 110
    • See Bar-Gill & Parchomovsky, supra note 110.
  • 169
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 28 and accompanying text;
    • See supra note 28 and accompanying text;
    • See supra
  • 171
    • 33846467857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part III
    • See infra Part III.
    • See infra
  • 172
    • 40749086530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Genevieve Oger, French Firm Hopes to Get PR Bounce out of Nanotubes in Tennis Rackets, SMALL TIMES, NOV. 7, 2001, http://www.smalltimes.com/document_display.cfm?document_id=2506 (discussing the Babolat tennis racket).
    • Genevieve Oger, French Firm Hopes to Get PR Bounce out of Nanotubes in Tennis Rackets, SMALL TIMES, NOV. 7, 2001, http://www.smalltimes.com/document_display.cfm?document_id=2506 (discussing the Babolat tennis racket).
  • 173
    • 40749121854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Nanobot.info, Report on Nanobots (Nanotechnology Robots), http://www.nanobot.info (trumpeting the possibility that nanomedibots will be able to interact with cells in the treatment of disease);
    • See, e.g., Nanobot.info, Report on Nanobots (Nanotechnology Robots), http://www.nanobot.info (trumpeting the possibility that "nanomedibots" will be able to interact with cells in the treatment of disease);
  • 174
    • 30144441013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Mark A. Lemley, Patenting Nanotechnology, 58 STAN. L. REV. 601, 602 (2005). Lemley notes that patents in nanotechnology have been issuing at a rapid pace for a new technology with few immediate applications.
    • see also Mark A. Lemley, Patenting Nanotechnology, 58 STAN. L. REV. 601, 602 (2005). Lemley notes that patents in nanotechnology have been issuing at a rapid pace for a new technology with few immediate applications.
  • 175
    • 40749146535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 604-05. This suggests that the patent system may well be contributing to incentives to innovate, but these incentives may still be suboptimal.
    • Id. at 604-05. This suggests that the patent system may well be contributing to incentives to innovate, but these incentives may still be suboptimal.
  • 176
    • 40749112494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Lemley, supra note 121, at 628 (Nanotech inventions will require substantial investment that will not be recouped for a long time, if ever.).
    • Cf. Lemley, supra note 121, at 628 ("Nanotech inventions will require substantial investment that will not be recouped for a long time, if ever.").
  • 177
    • 40749105049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another example is anti-aging research. Aubrey de Grey argues that such research might result in dramatic life extension for mice within 20 years, and for humans within 15 to 100 years after that. See Aubrey de Grey, Timeframe for Progress in Life Extension, http://www.sens.org/time.htm. Perhaps this is wildly optimistic. For our purposes, the key point is that even if scientists and entrepreneurs thought that the goal of eliminating aging might be achievable in fifty years, relatively little private capital would be aimed directly at this goal because of the short patent term. The field thus advances only to the extent that it is funded through basic research or as a result of spillovers from other medical research. Auctioning a very long patent on the envisioned anti-aging technologies could do little harm if the technologies seem unlikely to develop in the absence of such a patent anyway
    • Another example is anti-aging research. Aubrey de Grey argues that such research might result in dramatic life extension for mice within 20 years, and for humans within 15 to 100 years after that. See Aubrey de Grey, Timeframe for Progress in Life Extension, http://www.sens.org/time.htm. Perhaps this is wildly optimistic. For our purposes, the key point is that even if scientists and entrepreneurs thought that the goal of eliminating aging might be achievable in fifty years, relatively little private capital would be aimed directly at this goal because of the short patent term. The field thus advances only to the extent that it is funded through basic research or as a result of spillovers from other medical research. Auctioning a very long patent on the envisioned anti-aging technologies could do little harm if the technologies seem unlikely to develop in the absence of such a patent anyway.
  • 178
    • 40749120641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 101 and accompanying text. Lemley suggests that the patent thicket may be a greater problem in nanotechnology than in earlier emerging technologies because of the greater number of patents, some overlapping, on building block inventions.
    • See supra note 101 and accompanying text. Lemley suggests that the patent thicket may be a greater problem in nanotechnology than in earlier emerging technologies because of the greater number of patents, some overlapping, on building block inventions.
  • 179
    • 40749153280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley, supra note 121, at 618-21
    • See Lemley, supra note 121, at 618-21.
  • 180
    • 40749115363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some have argued that patents should be granted only on inventions that would not have been developed in the absence of patent law. See, e.g, A. Samuel Oddi, Beyond Obviousness: Invention Protection in the Twenty-First Century, 38 AM. U. L. REV. 1097, 1101 1989, A problem with such proposals is that it is difficult to determine the extent to which patent law has accelerated an invention
    • Some have argued that patents should be granted only on inventions that would not have been developed in the absence of patent law. See, e.g., A. Samuel Oddi, Beyond Obviousness: Invention Protection in the Twenty-First Century, 38 AM. U. L. REV. 1097, 1101 (1989). A problem with such proposals is that it is difficult to determine the extent to which patent law has accelerated an invention.
  • 181
    • 40749106321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally LANDES & POSNER, supra note 85, at 306-08 (considering whether there is adequate funding for basic research and whether patent law should protect it).
    • See generally LANDES & POSNER, supra note 85, at 306-08 (considering whether there is adequate funding for basic research and whether patent law should protect it).
  • 182
    • 40749108683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Thomas O. McGarity, Peer Review in Awarding Federal Grants in the Arts and Sciences, 9 HIGH TECH. L.J. 1 (1994) (critiquing the peer review system and considering the possibility of radical alternatives to peer review).
    • See generally Thomas O. McGarity, Peer Review in Awarding Federal Grants in the Arts and Sciences, 9 HIGH TECH. L.J. 1 (1994) (critiquing the peer review system and considering the possibility of radical alternatives to peer review).
  • 183
    • 40749106752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When a patentee through amendment narrows a patent application to meet the requirements of the Patent Act, the doctrine of prosecution history estoppel will limit the patentee's ability to claim infringement under the doctrine of equivalents. See Festo Corp. v. Shoketsu Kinzoku Kogyo Kabushiki Co, 535 U.S. 722 2002, clarifying the prosecution history estoppel doctrine, and noting that amendment by itself does not conclusively bar application of the doctrine of equivalents
    • When a patentee through amendment narrows a patent application to meet the requirements of the Patent Act, the doctrine of prosecution history estoppel will limit the patentee's ability to claim infringement under the doctrine of equivalents. See Festo Corp. v. Shoketsu Kinzoku Kogyo Kabushiki Co., 535 U.S. 722 (2002) (clarifying the prosecution history estoppel doctrine, and noting that amendment by itself does not conclusively bar application of the doctrine of equivalents).
  • 184
    • 11144300170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aditya Bamzai, Comment, The Wasteful Duplication Thesis in Natural Monopoly Regulation, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 1525, 1546 (2004).
    • Aditya Bamzai, Comment, The Wasteful Duplication Thesis in Natural Monopoly Regulation, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 1525, 1546 (2004).
  • 185
    • 40749153692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 186
    • 40749083321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The patent scope auctions described below, however, avoid this problem. See infra Part IV.B.
    • The patent scope auctions described below, however, avoid this problem. See infra Part IV.B.
  • 187
    • 84888494968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 106-07
    • See supra text accompanying notes 106-07.
    • See supra
  • 188
    • 84886342665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying note 111
    • See supra text accompanying note 111.
    • See supra
  • 189
    • 40749122731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At least until Duffy's analysis, the modern scholarly consensus was that inventive rivalry accelerates innovation. See supra note 11 noting arguments by Merges and Nelson, as well as by Lemley, This would seem to suggest that auctions, by dampening rivalry, would make things worse. Duffy's model, however, calls into question these analyses
    • At least until Duffy's analysis, the modern scholarly consensus was that inventive rivalry accelerates innovation. See supra note 11 (noting arguments by Merges and Nelson, as well as by Lemley). This would seem to suggest that auctions, by dampening rivalry, would make things worse. Duffy's model, however, calls into question these analyses.
  • 190
    • 40749085810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Duffy, supra note 20. Once a particular technology exists, that technology is likely to be improved faster when it is in the public domain than when a single patent owner has exclusive rights to it. But exclusive rights may lead to faster development of a technology in the first instance by reducing the probability of failure, so auctions potentially can accelerate technological progress. The ultimate question in the auction context is whether auctioning prospects would increase useful inventions.
    • See Duffy, supra note 20. Once a particular technology exists, that technology is likely to be improved faster when it is in the public domain than when a single patent owner has exclusive rights to it. But exclusive rights may lead to faster development of a technology in the first instance by reducing the probability of failure, so auctions potentially can accelerate technological progress. The ultimate question in the auction context is whether auctioning prospects would increase useful inventions.
  • 191
    • 40749156427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.A.2.a.
    • See supra Part II.A.2.a.
  • 192
    • 40749092233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A significant caveat to Duffy's theory is that implicit auctions cannot work when unanticipated exogenous shocks suddenly make attractive an invention that previously seemed unattractive. See infra note 159 and accompanying text. The empirical question is whether the inventive process is ordinarily smooth and predictable, or whether possible inventions often suddenly become apparent, triggering destructive races.
    • A significant caveat to Duffy's theory is that implicit auctions cannot work when unanticipated exogenous shocks suddenly make attractive an invention that previously seemed unattractive. See infra note 159 and accompanying text. The empirical question is whether the inventive process is ordinarily smooth and predictable, or whether possible inventions often suddenly become apparent, triggering destructive races.
  • 193
    • 40749160222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wu, supra note 12 (arguing that centralized decisionmaking about invention might be less efficient than decentralized decisionmaking).
    • See, e.g., Wu, supra note 12 (arguing that centralized decisionmaking about invention might be less efficient than decentralized decisionmaking).
  • 194
    • 40749128212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, one might be more willing to race for a patent if the remainder of the field in the future will be auctioned, because the winner of the race may face fewer substitutes than in a world in which racing begins anew
    • For example, one might be more willing to race for a patent if the remainder of the field in the future will be auctioned, because the winner of the race may face fewer substitutes than in a world in which racing begins anew.
  • 195
    • 40749158907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The sale, however, might be impeded by Arrow's disclosure paradox - that it is difficult to sell information without disclosing it or to disclose information without giving it away. See Kenneth J. Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention, in THE RATE AND DIRECTION OF INVENTIVE ACTIVITY: ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL FACTORS 609 (1962).
    • The sale, however, might be impeded by Arrow's disclosure paradox - that it is difficult to sell information without disclosing it or to disclose information without giving it away. See Kenneth J. Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention, in THE RATE AND DIRECTION OF INVENTIVE ACTIVITY: ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL FACTORS 609 (1962).
  • 196
    • 40749126545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This could be accomplished only if the auctioned right is for an improvement patent only. See supra note 89 and accompanying text
    • This could be accomplished only if the auctioned right is for an improvement patent only. See supra note 89 and accompanying text.
  • 197
    • 40749148251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A drawback is that an auction system might produce less disclosure of the results of invention. Some disclosure would still occur, however, to the extent that patents would be allowed within the scope of the patent grant. There is considerable doubt about how much of a benefit mandated disclosure provides. See Note, The Disclosure Function of the Patent System (or Lack Thereof), 118 HARV. L. REV. 2007 (2005) (arguing that the patent system is failing in the goal of disseminating information). If mandated disclosure is considered a significant benefit, the law might seek to require an auction winner to reveal the results of subsequent research within the patent term.
    • A drawback is that an auction system might produce less disclosure of the results of invention. Some disclosure would still occur, however, to the extent that patents would be allowed within the scope of the patent grant. There is considerable doubt about how much of a benefit mandated disclosure provides. See Note, The Disclosure Function of the Patent System (or Lack Thereof), 118 HARV. L. REV. 2007 (2005) (arguing that the patent system is failing in the goal of disseminating information). If mandated disclosure is considered a significant benefit, the law might seek to require an auction winner to reveal the results of subsequent research within the patent term.
  • 198
    • 40749113338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Duffy, supra note 20, at 488-89 showing that the owner of a blocking right has significantly greater incentive to conduct research within the scope of that right than third parties
    • See Duffy, supra note 20, at 488-89 (showing that the owner of a blocking right has significantly greater incentive to conduct research within the scope of that right than third parties).
  • 199
    • 40749139203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rent seeking is an activity in which the competition for rents, for example from an exclusive government franchise, dissipates the benefits of those rents. See Anne O. Krueger, The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society, 64 AM. ECON. REV. 291 (1974) (introducing the term);
    • Rent seeking is an activity in which the competition for rents, for example from an exclusive government franchise, dissipates the benefits of those rents. See Anne O. Krueger, The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society, 64 AM. ECON. REV. 291 (1974) (introducing the term);
  • 200
    • 84979190207 scopus 로고
    • The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft, 5 W
    • offering an additional seminal treatment
    • Gordon Tullock, The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft, 5 W. ECON. J. 224 (1967) (offering an additional seminal treatment).
    • (1967) ECON. J , vol.224
    • Tullock, G.1
  • 201
    • 0032429077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There may, however, be incentives for an inventor with a chance to win a patent race to lobby against an auction. A system of patent auctions thus might produce costs associated with rent opposition. See Robert D. Cairns & Ngo Van Long, On Opposition to Rent Seeking: Implications for Developing Countries, 2 REV. DEV. ECON. 282 (1998) (noting that the full costs of rent-seeking activity must include the costs of those opposing the granting of rents).
    • There may, however, be incentives for an inventor with a chance to win a patent race to lobby against an auction. A system of patent auctions thus might produce costs associated with rent opposition. See Robert D. Cairns & Ngo Van Long, On Opposition to Rent Seeking: Implications for Developing Countries, 2 REV. DEV. ECON. 282 (1998) (noting that the full costs of rent-seeking activity must include the costs of those opposing the granting of rents).
  • 202
    • 40749154535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview, see INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE: THE TRIPS AGREEMENT (Carlos M. Correa & Abdulqawi A. Yusuf eds., 1998).
    • For an overview, see INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE: THE TRIPS AGREEMENT (Carlos M. Correa & Abdulqawi A. Yusuf eds., 1998).
  • 203
    • 40749128210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DAVID MAMET, THE WATER ENGINE: AN AMERICAN FABLE, AND MR. HAPPINESS (1978). For a plot summary of the televised adaptation, see http://www.imdb.com/title/tt0105788.
    • DAVID MAMET, THE WATER ENGINE: AN AMERICAN FABLE, AND MR. HAPPINESS (1978). For a plot summary of the televised adaptation, see http://www.imdb.com/title/tt0105788.
  • 204
    • 40749156850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Kurt M. Saunders & Linda Levine, Better, Faster, Cheaper - Later: What Happens When Technologies Are Suppressed, 11 MICH. TELECOMM. & TECH. L. REV. 23 (2004), available at http://www.mttlr.org/voleleven/saunders.pdf.
    • See, e.g., Kurt M. Saunders & Linda Levine, Better, Faster, Cheaper - Later: What Happens When Technologies Are Suppressed, 11 MICH. TELECOMM. & TECH. L. REV. 23 (2004), available at http://www.mttlr.org/voleleven/saunders.pdf.
  • 205
    • 40749087405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part III.A.
    • See infra Part III.A.
  • 206
    • 40749142149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 16
    • See supra note 16.
  • 207
    • 40749086529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The product differentiation literature relatedly shows that because of the fixed costs associated with entering a market, excessive entry from a social perspective can occur. See supra note 113 and sources cited therein.
    • The product differentiation literature relatedly shows that because of the fixed costs associated with entering a market, excessive entry from a social perspective can occur. See supra note 113 and sources cited therein.
  • 208
    • 80052884981 scopus 로고
    • The Proper Role of a Target's Management in Responding to a Tender Offer, 94
    • For the classic argument that a target firm's management should be passive in the face of a hostile tender offer, see
    • For the classic argument that a target firm's management should be passive in the face of a hostile tender offer, see Frank H. Easterbrook & Daniel R. Fischel, The Proper Role of a Target's Management in Responding to a Tender Offer, 94 HARV. L. REV. 1161 (1981).
    • (1981) HARV. L. REV , vol.1161
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1    Fischel, D.R.2
  • 209
    • 40749146947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Ivar M. Kaardal, The American Inventors Protection Act, the Independent Inventor's Interest & Consumer Choice in the Market, 84 J. PAT. & TRADEMARK OFF. SOC'Y 503 2002
    • See, e.g., Ivar M. Kaardal, The American Inventors Protection Act, the Independent Inventor's Interest & Consumer Choice in the Market, 84 J. PAT. & TRADEMARK OFF. SOC'Y 503 (2002).
  • 210
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 89 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 89 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 211
    • 40749131899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 11-16 and accompanying text (discussing the issue without taking a position on it).
    • See supra notes 11-16 and accompanying text (discussing the issue without taking a position on it).
  • 212
    • 40749090989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.C.
    • See supra Part I.C.
  • 213
    • 40749092232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Abramowicz, supra note 50, at 1091 (noting that a patentee might obtain a patent for its option value when the probability that commercialization will be worthwhile is low).
    • But see Abramowicz, supra note 50, at 1091 (noting that a patentee might obtain a patent for its option value when the probability that commercialization will be worthwhile is low).
  • 214
    • 40749146948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arguably, it is desirable to provide a single party with an incentive to argue that research and development spending fell short of the promised amount. For example, the government could hold an auction for the right to sue the winning bidder for spending too little. The revenues from this auction would go to the winning bidder of the R&D auction, but a successful suit would result in the funds not spent being allocated to the party that wins the right to sue. In litigation, courts would need to evaluate the degree to which spending really was within the research field
    • Arguably, it is desirable to provide a single party with an incentive to argue that research and development spending fell short of the promised amount. For example, the government could hold an auction for the right to sue the winning bidder for spending too little. The revenues from this auction would go to the winning bidder of the R&D auction, but a successful suit would result in the funds not spent being allocated to the party that wins the right to sue. In litigation, courts would need to evaluate the degree to which spending really was within the research field.
  • 215
    • 1642587169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of some of the difficulties in patent valuation, see F. Russell Denton & Paul J. Heald, Random Walks, Non-Cooperative Games, and the Complex Mathematics of Patent Pricing, 55 RUTGERS L. REV. 1175 (2003). One possible approach is to use a self-assessment mechanism. Third parties could be invited to make bonded offers to purchase the patents, with the highest offeror receiving a reward (some small percentage of the highest bid); this reward, combined with the possibility that the patentee might accept an offer, give incentives for honest third-party valuation.
    • For a discussion of some of the difficulties in patent valuation, see F. Russell Denton & Paul J. Heald, Random Walks, Non-Cooperative Games, and the Complex Mathematics of Patent Pricing, 55 RUTGERS L. REV. 1175 (2003). One possible approach is to use a self-assessment mechanism. Third parties could be invited to make bonded offers to purchase the patents, with the highest offeror receiving a reward (some small percentage of the highest bid); this reward, combined with the possibility that the patentee might accept an offer, give incentives for honest third-party valuation.
  • 216
    • 84925977763 scopus 로고
    • Self-Assessed Valuation Systems for Tort and Other Law, 68
    • devising a similar competitive assessment system for valuing real property, See
    • See Saul Levmore, Self-Assessed Valuation Systems for Tort and Other Law, 68 VA. L. REV. 771, 783-88 (1982) (devising a similar competitive assessment system for valuing real property).
    • (1982) VA. L. REV , vol.771 , pp. 783-788
    • Levmore, S.1
  • 217
    • 40749087827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I am grateful to Sam Dinkin for this suggestion
    • I am grateful to Sam Dinkin for this suggestion.
  • 218
    • 40749142553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 505
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 505.
  • 219
    • 40749121052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Petition for a Writ of Certiorari, KSR Int'l Co. v. Teleflex Inc., 127 S. Ct. 1727 (2005) (No. 04-1350), 2005 WL 835463.
    • Petition for a Writ of Certiorari, KSR Int'l Co. v. Teleflex Inc., 127 S. Ct. 1727 (2005) (No. 04-1350), 2005 WL 835463.
  • 220
    • 40749156851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at *28-29 (The Federal Circuit 'test' ignores that exogenous changes - i.e., economic, regulatory or technological changes not attributable to the work of the alleged inventor - can create new possibilities that can be exploited, or new needs that can be satisfied, with technological trivial combinations of existing technology.). The Federal Circuit had generally insisted that a combination invention would be obvious only when a motivation, suggestion, or teaching for that combination existed in the prior art.
    • Id. at *28-29 ("The Federal Circuit 'test' ignores that exogenous changes - i.e., economic, regulatory or technological changes not attributable to the work of the alleged inventor - can create new possibilities that can be exploited, or new needs that can be satisfied, with technological trivial combinations of existing technology."). The Federal Circuit had generally insisted that a combination invention would be obvious only when a motivation, suggestion, or teaching for that combination existed in the prior art.
  • 221
    • 40749116662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., In re Kotzab, 217 F.3d 1365, 1370 (Fed. Cir. 2000) (holding that to establish obviousness based on a combination of the elements disclosed in the prior art, there must be some motivation, suggestion or teaching of the desirability of making the specific combination that was made by the applicant).
    • See, e.g., In re Kotzab, 217 F.3d 1365, 1370 (Fed. Cir. 2000) (holding that "to establish obviousness based on a combination of the elements disclosed in the prior art, there must be some motivation, suggestion or teaching of the desirability of making the specific combination that was made by the applicant").
  • 222
    • 40749100801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 127 S. Ct. 1727 (2007).
    • 127 S. Ct. 1727 (2007).
  • 223
    • 40749113337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At least three difficult questions about the design of such an auction would remain. First, would the winning bidder be required to perfect the intellectual property right by subsequently filing a patent detailing the combination? An argument against such a requirement is that it would needlessly increase transaction costs. An argument for such a requirement is that it would ensure appropriate disclosure of the best means of achieving the combination. Second, would the winning bidder still be required to show that the combination is nonobvious? This might be difficult to establish, because the mere request for the auction could count as prior art. The danger of not requiring nonobviousness is that the explicit auctions might unnecessarily create patents of at least some finite length, given the requirement that a cash payment accompany the winning bid, leading to deadweight loss. The occurrence of an explicit least-patent-term auction, however, generally makes concerns about obvious in
    • At least three difficult questions about the design of such an auction would remain. First, would the winning bidder be required to perfect the intellectual property right by subsequently filing a patent detailing the combination? An argument against such a requirement is that it would needlessly increase transaction costs. An argument for such a requirement is that it would ensure appropriate disclosure of the best means of achieving the combination. Second, would the winning bidder still be required to show that the combination is nonobvious? This might be difficult to establish, because the mere request for the auction could count as prior art. The danger of not requiring nonobviousness is that the explicit auctions might unnecessarily create patents of at least some finite length, given the requirement that a cash payment accompany the winning bid, leading to deadweight loss. The occurrence of an explicit least-patent-term auction, however, generally makes concerns about obvious inventions less salient, because obvious inventions that require little development will receive relatively short patent terms, and when inventions are obvious but second-mover advantages exist, some patent protection may be optimal. Third, would the auctioned right supersede the rights of inventors who have pending patent applications or who have invented but have not yet filed patent applications? A particular concern is that the auction system might lead inventors to hold off patenting until they have also patented combinations of the original invention and other inventions, lest someone else obtain rights to the combination.
  • 224
    • 40749143753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The cash payment to the government, however, may reduce the need for other taxes, which themselves may cause economic distortions. See, e.g., Charles L. Ballard & Don Fullerton, Distortionary Taxes and the Provision of Public Goods, J. ECON. PERSP., Summer 1992, at 117 (discussing the economic distortion associated with taxation). Nonetheless, this distortion is generally thought to be less than the distortionary effect of monopoly pricing created by patents.
    • The cash payment to the government, however, may reduce the need for other taxes, which themselves may cause economic distortions. See, e.g., Charles L. Ballard & Don Fullerton, Distortionary Taxes and the Provision of Public Goods, J. ECON. PERSP., Summer 1992, at 117 (discussing the economic distortion associated with taxation). Nonetheless, this distortion is generally thought to be less than the distortionary effect of monopoly pricing created by patents.
  • 225
    • 40749153279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 19, at 201-02.
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 19, at 201-02.
  • 226
    • 0002007807 scopus 로고
    • A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation, 37
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., F.P. Ramsey, A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation, 37 ECON. J. 47 (1927).
    • (1927) ECON. J , vol.47
    • Ramsey, F.P.1
  • 227
    • 40749099566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 67, at 989
    • Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 67, at 989.
  • 228
    • 40749099175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 229
    • 40749135198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 230
    • 40749139201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 990, 994-1000.
    • Id. at 990, 994-1000.
  • 231
    • 40749131411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 990-93 (noting that this is an implication of Ramsey, supra note 165, applied intertemporally).
    • See id. at 990-93 (noting that this is an implication of Ramsey, supra note 165, applied intertemporally).
  • 232
    • 40749131010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ayres and Klemperer acknowledge this point implicitly, noting that a patent of infinite duration might not be possible as a pragmatic or political matter. Id. at 1011.
    • Ayres and Klemperer acknowledge this point implicitly, noting that a patent of infinite duration might not be possible as a "pragmatic or political matter." Id. at 1011.
  • 233
    • 40749090576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 478
    • Duffy, supra note 20, at 478.
  • 234
    • 40749150422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 478 n.125
    • Id. at 478 n.125
  • 235
    • 84980255508 scopus 로고
    • A Note on Optimal Taxation and Administrative Costs, 69
    • as presenting an analogous optimal taxation problem, citing
    • (citing Shlomo Yitzhaki, A Note on Optimal Taxation and Administrative Costs, 69 AM. ECON. REV. 475, 475, 480 (1979), as presenting an analogous optimal taxation problem).
    • (1979) AM. ECON. REV , vol.475 , Issue.475 , pp. 480
    • Yitzhaki, S.1
  • 236
    • 40749150188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a careful analysis of perpetual patent terms that rejects the concern about the anticommons, see F. Scott Kieff, Coordination, Property & Intellectual Property: An Unconventional Approach to Anticompetitive Effects and Downstream Access 64-66 (Stanford Law Sch. John M. Olin Program in Law & Econ., Working Paper No. 323, 2006), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=910656.
    • For a careful analysis of perpetual patent terms that rejects the concern about the anticommons, see F. Scott Kieff, Coordination, Property & Intellectual Property: An Unconventional Approach to Anticompetitive Effects and Downstream Access 64-66 (Stanford Law Sch. John M. Olin Program in Law & Econ., Working Paper No. 323, 2006), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=910656.
  • 237
    • 40749121435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II. A. 1.
    • See supra Part II. A. 1.
  • 238
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 101 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 101 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 239
    • 40749155595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Such activities may become more attractive over time for the same reason that invention may become more attractive over time in Barzel's model - that the demand for an invention may increase over time. See Barzel, supra note 30, at 349.
    • Such activities may become more attractive over time for the same reason that invention may become more attractive over time in Barzel's model - that the demand for an invention may increase over time. See Barzel, supra note 30, at 349.
  • 240
    • 40749129459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.B.
    • See supra Part I.B.
  • 241
    • 0038685308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright Law and Price Discrimination, 23
    • For an analysis of the relevance of price discrimination to copyright policy, see
    • For an analysis of the relevance of price discrimination to copyright policy, see Michael J. Meurer, Copyright Law and Price Discrimination, 23 CARDOZO L. REV. 55 (2001).
    • (2001) CARDOZO L. REV , vol.55
    • Meurer, M.J.1
  • 242
    • 40749117807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an empirical analysis purporting to show that compulsory licenses do not deter innovation, see Colleen Chien, Cheap Drugs at What Price to Innovation: Does the Compulsory Licensing of Pharmaceuticals Hurt Innovation?, 18 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 853 (2003). This may be an area, however, in which economic theory is more useful than tentative empirical results. If compulsory licenses lower the return to innovation, there will be less innovation. Even if compulsory licensing does not lower the return to innovation overall, it may change the distribution of innovation, and the case for compulsory licenses then depends on whether the government does better than the market in determining which innovations should be pursued.
    • For an empirical analysis purporting to show that compulsory licenses do not deter innovation, see Colleen Chien, Cheap Drugs at What Price to Innovation: Does the Compulsory Licensing of Pharmaceuticals Hurt Innovation?, 18 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 853 (2003). This may be an area, however, in which economic theory is more useful than tentative empirical results. If compulsory licenses lower the return to innovation, there will be less innovation. Even if compulsory licensing does not lower the return to innovation overall, it may change the distribution of innovation, and the case for compulsory licenses then depends on whether the government does better than the market in determining which innovations should be pursued.
  • 243
    • 40749127337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There are two disadvantages of eliminating injunctive relief. First, some infringers might be judgment-proof. See Developments in the Law - Injunctions, 78 HARV. L. REV. 994, 1001-02 (1965) (arguing that judgment-proof defendants may provide one justification for injunctive relief). An antidote would be to require alleged infringers to obtain bonds ensuring that they will be able to obtain damages. Second, in a liability rule regime, it may be more advantageous to infringe than to negotiate whenever the infringer expects that the courts will underestimate damages or that the patentee will not be able to afford litigation.
    • There are two disadvantages of eliminating injunctive relief. First, some infringers might be judgment-proof. See Developments in the Law - Injunctions, 78 HARV. L. REV. 994, 1001-02 (1965) (arguing that judgment-proof defendants may provide one justification for injunctive relief). An antidote would be to require alleged infringers to obtain bonds ensuring that they will be able to obtain damages. Second, in a liability rule regime, it may be more advantageous to infringe than to negotiate whenever the infringer expects that the courts will underestimate damages or that the patentee will not be able to afford litigation.
  • 244
    • 40749148250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Thomas F. Cotter, An Economic Analysis of Enhanced Damages and Attorney's Fees for Willful Patent Infringement, 14 FED. CIR. B.J. 291, 308-10 2004, noting several reasons that patentees may fail to enforce their rights, A patent regime without injunctive relief, however, might compensate for this by imposing a small damages multiplier fixed in advance, which would then be discounted in an explicit auction
    • Cf. Thomas F. Cotter, An Economic Analysis of Enhanced Damages and Attorney's Fees for Willful Patent Infringement, 14 FED. CIR. B.J. 291, 308-10 (2004) (noting several reasons that patentees may fail to enforce their rights). A patent regime without injunctive relief, however, might compensate for this by imposing a small damages multiplier fixed in advance, which would then be discounted in an explicit auction.
  • 245
    • 40749128211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 67, at 1028-31
    • Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 67, at 1028-31.
  • 246
    • 40749145860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A variant on this approach would be to award full damages but only with some positive probability, and the winning bidder would be the party that offers the lowest probability. The idea of probabilistic patents in which enforcement occurs with less than certainty is Ayres and Klemperer's primary proposal. Id. at 993-1013.
    • A variant on this approach would be to award full damages but only with some positive probability, and the winning bidder would be the party that offers the lowest probability. The idea of "probabilistic patents" in which enforcement occurs with less than certainty is Ayres and Klemperer's primary proposal. Id. at 993-1013.
  • 247
    • 29444451875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Conceivably, it might be more efficient than a regime of reduced damages, if it reduced litigation cost. If that is so, however, the litigation system in general should provide for only probabilistic enforcement of legal rights, with damages set at a multiplier of the usual damages level in the cases in which the rights are enforced. See, e.g., David Rosenberg & Steven Shavell, A Simple Proposal to Halve Litigation Costs, 91 VA. L. REV. 1721 (2005) (offering such a proposal).
    • Conceivably, it might be more efficient than a regime of reduced damages, if it reduced litigation cost. If that is so, however, the litigation system in general should provide for only probabilistic enforcement of legal rights, with damages set at a multiplier of the usual damages level in the cases in which the rights are enforced. See, e.g., David Rosenberg & Steven Shavell, A Simple Proposal to Halve Litigation Costs, 91 VA. L. REV. 1721 (2005) (offering such a proposal).
  • 248
    • 4444322568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A much more ambitious approach might be to use information markets to decide when auctions should occur and to identify the bidder most likely to maximize social benefits. See Michael Abramowicz, Information Markets, Administrative Decisionmaking, and Predictive Cost-Benefit Analysis, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 933 2004, providing an overview of the emerging literature on information markets
    • A much more ambitious approach might be to use information markets to decide when auctions should occur and to identify the bidder most likely to maximize social benefits. See Michael Abramowicz, Information Markets, Administrative Decisionmaking, and Predictive Cost-Benefit Analysis, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 933 (2004) (providing an overview of the emerging literature on information markets).
  • 249
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 5-6 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 5-6 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 250
    • 40749123142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.A.1.b.
    • See supra Part II.A.1.b.
  • 251
    • 40749136465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The assumption of no spillovers does not affect the case for the ultimate proposal. See infra text accompanying note 189.
    • The assumption of no spillovers does not affect the case for the ultimate proposal. See infra text accompanying note 189.
  • 252
    • 40749102682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ayres and Klemperer suggest the possibility of such a duopoly auction as a means of reducing patent pricing and thus deadweight loss. See Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 67, at 1031-32.
    • Ayres and Klemperer suggest the possibility of such a "duopoly auction" as a means of reducing patent pricing and thus deadweight loss. See Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 67, at 1031-32.
  • 253
    • 40749096171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 91 discussing the mechanics and strategy of a second-price auction
    • See supra note 91 (discussing the mechanics and strategy of a second-price auction).
    • See supra
  • 254
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 38 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 38 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 255
    • 84959370683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 50, at, introducing a proposal for patent term extension auctions
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 50, at 1112-19 (introducing a proposal for patent term extension auctions).
    • supra , pp. 1112-1119
    • Abramowicz1
  • 257
    • 40749160221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1115 (It also assures that the difference between the original patentee's valuation and the third party's valuation derives from the benefit of development of the patent within the original patent term and not from some other factor that makes the patent particularly valuable to the patentee.).
    • Id. at 1115 ("It also assures that the difference between the original patentee's valuation and the third party's valuation derives from the benefit of development of the patent within the original patent term and not from some other factor that makes the patent particularly valuable to the patentee.").
  • 258
    • 40749091417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 AM. ECON. REV. (PAPERS & PROC.) 347, 350 (1967) (Increased internalization, in the main, results from changes in economic values, changes which stem from the development of new technology and the opening of new markets, changes to which old property rights are poorly attuned.)
    • Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 AM. ECON. REV. (PAPERS & PROC.) 347, 350 (1967) ("Increased internalization, in the main, results from changes in economic values, changes which stem from the development of new technology and the opening of new markets, changes to which old property rights are poorly attuned.")
  • 259
    • 40749094212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A principal criticism of the Demsetz approach is that it provides no means of aggregating quality and price. Richard Posner proposed that quality might be assessed in combination with price by initially allowing potential suppliers to solicit contracts with consumers and then awarding the contract to the producer who is able to obtain the highest dollar of commitments. See Richard A. Posner, The Appropriate Scope of Regulation in the Cable Television Industry, 3 BELL J. ECON. & MGMT. SCI. 98, 115 1972, suggesting that this might alleviate the difficulty of determining the bid offering the best combination of price and quality, Among the potential challenges of such a scheme is that preventing monopolists from reneging on vague quality commitments may be difficult
    • A principal criticism of the Demsetz approach is that it provides no means of aggregating quality and price. Richard Posner proposed that quality might be assessed in combination with price by initially allowing potential suppliers to solicit contracts with consumers and then awarding the contract to the producer who is able to obtain the highest dollar volume of commitments. See Richard A. Posner, The Appropriate Scope of Regulation in the Cable Television Industry, 3 BELL J. ECON. & MGMT. SCI. 98, 115 (1972) (suggesting that this might alleviate the difficulty of determining the bid offering the best combination of price and quality). Among the potential challenges of such a scheme is that preventing monopolists from reneging on vague quality commitments may be difficult.
  • 260
    • 0016928275 scopus 로고
    • Franchise Bidding for Natural Monopolies - in General and with Respect to CATV, 7
    • discussing the difficulties of ascertaining quality in a Demsetzian auction, See
    • See Oliver E. Williamson, Franchise Bidding for Natural Monopolies - in General and with Respect to CATV, 7 BELL J. ECON. 73, 80-82 (1976) (discussing the difficulties of ascertaining quality in a Demsetzian auction).
    • (1976) BELL J. ECON , vol.73 , pp. 80-82
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 261
    • 0347949042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Intellectual Property Rights and the New Institutional Economics, 53
    • noting that Demsetz assumed that changed conditions would automatically translate into revised property rights, without considering the political process that would effect this translation, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Robert P. Merges, Intellectual Property Rights and the New Institutional Economics, 53 VAND. L. REV. 1857, 1868 (2000) (noting that Demsetz "assumed that changed conditions would automatically translate into revised property rights," without considering the political process that would effect this translation).
    • (2000) VAND. L. REV. 1857 , pp. 1868
    • Merges, R.P.1
  • 262
    • 40749112056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demsetz suggested that changes in property rights have arisen in Western societies largely as a result of gradual changes in social mores and in common law precedents. Demsetz, supra note 193, at 350. This does not provide a direct explanation of how institutions for distributing property rights evolve.
    • Demsetz suggested that changes in property rights "have arisen in Western societies largely as a result of gradual changes in social mores and in common law precedents." Demsetz, supra note 193, at 350. This does not provide a direct explanation of how institutions for distributing property rights evolve.
  • 263
    • 40749162104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even if an auction is efficient, we should not necessarily expect a change from a prospecting system to a Demsetzian auction. See supra text accompanying notes 91-93;
    • Even if an auction is efficient, we should not necessarily expect a change from a prospecting system to a Demsetzian auction. See supra text accompanying notes 91-93;
  • 264
    • 0042671092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also David D. Haddock & Lynne Kiesling, The Black Death and Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S545, S564-65 & S565 n.51 (2002) (noting that Demsetz's analysis leaves the possibility that because of rent seeking, it will not always be the case that resources will be privatized once the benefits exceed the costs).
    • see also David D. Haddock & Lynne Kiesling, The Black Death and Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S545, S564-65 & S565 n.51 (2002) (noting that Demsetz's analysis leaves the possibility that because of rent seeking, it will not always be the case that resources will be privatized once the benefits exceed the costs).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.