메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 101, Issue 3, 2007, Pages 1057-1122

Local redistribution, living wage ordinances, and judicial intervention

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 34548356920     PISSN: 00293571     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (34)

References (288)
  • 1
    • 34548348442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Living Wage Resource Center, Living Wage Wins, http://www.livingwagecampaign.org/index.php?id=1959 (last visited Feb. 1, 2007). A few of the ordinances were enacted and subsequently repealed.
    • See Living Wage Resource Center, Living Wage Wins, http://www.livingwagecampaign.org/index.php?id=1959 (last visited Feb. 1, 2007). A few of the ordinances were enacted and subsequently repealed.
  • 2
    • 34548303334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Daley's Big-Box Veto Holds Up
    • See, Sept. 14, at
    • See Fran Spielman, Daley's Big-Box Veto Holds Up, CHI, SUN TIMES, Sept. 14, 2006, at 8.
    • (2006) CHI, SUN TIMES , pp. 8
    • Spielman, F.1
  • 3
    • 84900695962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 15, Magazine, at
    • See, e.g., Jon Gertner, What is a Living Wage?, N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 15, 2006 (Magazine), at 38;
    • (2006) What is a Living Wage , pp. 38
    • Gertner, J.1
  • 4
    • 34548316682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scott Adams & David Neumark, The Effects of Living Wage Laws: Evidence from Failed and Derailed Living Wage Campaigns 18-25 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 11342, 2005), available at http://papers.nber.org/papers/w11342.pdf (finding that living wages generate enhanced wages for those who obtain jobs, but have negative effects on low-wage worker employment).
    • Scott Adams & David Neumark, The Effects of Living Wage Laws: Evidence from Failed and Derailed Living Wage Campaigns 18-25 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 11342, 2005), available at http://papers.nber.org/papers/w11342.pdf (finding that living wages generate enhanced wages for those who obtain jobs, but have negative effects on low-wage worker employment).
  • 5
    • 34548299199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Mark D. Brenner, The Economic Impact of Living Wage Ordinances 18-28 (Political Econ. Research Inst. Working Paper Series, Paper No. 80, 2004), available at http://www.umass.edu/peri/pdfs/WP80.pdf (arguing that ordinances increase municipal budgets and lead to varied strategies by different employers about laying off workers and passing costs on to customers). For competing studies on the employment effects in one adopting city, Santa Fe,
    • See, e.g., Mark D. Brenner, The Economic Impact of Living Wage Ordinances 18-28 (Political Econ. Research Inst. Working Paper Series, Paper No. 80, 2004), available at http://www.umass.edu/peri/pdfs/WP80.pdf (arguing that ordinances increase municipal budgets and lead to varied strategies by different employers about laying off workers and passing costs on to customers). For competing studies on the employment effects in one adopting city, Santa Fe,
  • 6
    • 34548348443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • compare AARON S. YELOWITZ, EMPLOYMENT POLICIES INST., SANTA FE'S LIVING WAGE ORDINANCE AND THE LABOR MARKET 1-7 (2005), available at http://www.epionline.org/studies/yelowitz_09- 2005.pdf,
    • compare AARON S. YELOWITZ, EMPLOYMENT POLICIES INST., SANTA FE'S LIVING WAGE ORDINANCE AND THE LABOR MARKET 1-7 (2005), available at http://www.epionline.org/studies/yelowitz_09- 2005.pdf,
  • 7
    • 34548306490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • with NICHOLAS POTTER, BUREAU OF BUS. & ECON. RESEARCH, MEASURING THE EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS OF THE LIVING WAGE ORDINANCE IN SANTA FE, NEW MEXICO 5-22 (2006).
    • with NICHOLAS POTTER, BUREAU OF BUS. & ECON. RESEARCH, MEASURING THE EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS OF THE LIVING WAGE ORDINANCE IN SANTA FE, NEW MEXICO 5-22 (2006).
  • 8
    • 34548329201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JOHN CULLIS & PHILIP JONES, PUBLIC FINANCE AND PUBLIC CHOICE 303-05 (2d ed. 1998);
    • See JOHN CULLIS & PHILIP JONES, PUBLIC FINANCE AND PUBLIC CHOICE 303-05 (2d ed. 1998);
  • 9
    • 34548331255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WALLACE E. OATES, FISCAL FEDERALISM 131-40 (1972); PAUL E. PETERSON, CITY LIMITS 182-83 (1981) [hereinafter PETERSON, CITY];
    • WALLACE E. OATES, FISCAL FEDERALISM 131-40 (1972); PAUL E. PETERSON, CITY LIMITS 182-83 (1981) [hereinafter PETERSON, CITY];
  • 10
    • 34548303343 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PAUL E. PETERSON, THE PRICE OF FEDERALISM 27-28 (1995) [hereinafter PETERSON, PRICE]; Richard A. Musgrave, Fiscal Federalism, in JAMES M. BUCHANAN & RICHARD A. MUSGRAVE, PUBLIC FINANCE AND PUBLIC CHOICE 160-61 (2000). For a view that local governments can use income taxes to redistribute wealth without significant migration effects,
    • PAUL E. PETERSON, THE PRICE OF FEDERALISM 27-28 (1995) [hereinafter PETERSON, PRICE]; Richard A. Musgrave, Fiscal Federalism, in JAMES M. BUCHANAN & RICHARD A. MUSGRAVE, PUBLIC FINANCE AND PUBLIC CHOICE 160-61 (2000). For a view that local governments can use income taxes to redistribute wealth without significant migration effects,
  • 11
    • 34548304416 scopus 로고
    • A Re-Examination of the Use of Ability to Pay Taxes by Local Governments, 38
    • see
    • see Timothy J. Goodspeed, A Re-Examination of the Use of Ability to Pay Taxes by Local Governments, 38 J. PUB. ECON. 319 (1989).
    • (1989) J. PUB. ECON , vol.319
    • Goodspeed, T.J.1
  • 12
    • 34548320924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OATES, supra note 5, at 132
    • OATES, supra note 5, at 132.
  • 13
    • 34548358534 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Support for the thesis that high levels of welfare services attracts a high level of beneficiaries is found in PETERSON, PRICE, supra note 5, at 108-28.
    • Support for the thesis that high levels of welfare services attracts a high level of beneficiaries is found in PETERSON, PRICE, supra note 5, at 108-28.
  • 14
    • 0000351334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For more on the debate, see William C. Wheaton, Decentralized Welfare: Will There Be Underprovision?, 48 J. URB. ECON. 536 (2000) (developing model of welfare provision by states when assistance is decentralized and recipients are mobile);
    • For more on the debate, see William C. Wheaton, Decentralized Welfare: Will There Be Underprovision?, 48 J. URB. ECON. 536 (2000) (developing model of welfare provision by states when assistance is decentralized and recipients are mobile);
  • 15
    • 34548350584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Welfare Magnets: The Race for the Top, 5 SUP. CT
    • F.H. Buckley & Margaret F. Brinig, Welfare Magnets: The Race for the Top, 5 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. 141 (1997);
    • (1997) ECON. REV , vol.141
    • Buckley, F.H.1    Brinig, M.F.2
  • 16
    • 34548299192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note, Devolving Welfare Programs to the States: A Public Choice Perspective, 109 HARV. L. REV. 1984 (1996).
    • Note, Devolving Welfare Programs to the States: A Public Choice Perspective, 109 HARV. L. REV. 1984 (1996).
  • 17
    • 34548311648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Orleans Campaign for a Living Wage v. City of New Orleans, 825 So. 2d 1098, 1100-08 (La. 2002).
    • New Orleans Campaign for a Living Wage v. City of New Orleans, 825 So. 2d 1098, 1100-08 (La. 2002).
  • 18
    • 34548316664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rachel I. Rosen, Note, The Rise and Potential Fall of Living Wage Laws: Missouri Hotel & Motel Association v. City of St. Louis, 21 J.L. & COM. 131 (2001).
    • See Rachel I. Rosen, Note, The Rise and Potential Fall of Living Wage Laws: Missouri Hotel & Motel Association v. City of St. Louis, 21 J.L. & COM. 131 (2001).
  • 19
    • 34548336475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Mexicans for Free Enterprise v. City of Santa Fe, 126 P.3d 1149, 1156 (N.M. Ct. App. 2005).
    • New Mexicans for Free Enterprise v. City of Santa Fe, 126 P.3d 1149, 1156 (N.M. Ct. App. 2005).
  • 20
    • 34548299191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Visiting Homemaker Servs. v. Bd. of Chosen Freeholders, 883 A.2d 1074, 1080-85 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2005). These decisions follow earlier approvals of local minimum wage ordinances. See, e.g., Mayor of Bait. v. Sitnick, 255 A.2d 376 (Md. 1969) (approving local minimum wage ordinance); City of Atlanta v. Associated Builders & Contractors, 242 S.E.2d 139 (Ga. 1978) (same).
    • Visiting Homemaker Servs. v. Bd. of Chosen Freeholders, 883 A.2d 1074, 1080-85 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2005). These decisions follow earlier approvals of local minimum wage ordinances. See, e.g., Mayor of Bait. v. Sitnick, 255 A.2d 376 (Md. 1969) (approving local minimum wage ordinance); City of Atlanta v. Associated Builders & Contractors, 242 S.E.2d 139 (Ga. 1978) (same).
  • 22
    • 34548356478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Orleans Campaign for a Living Wage, 825 So. 2d at 1102-08.
    • New Orleans Campaign for a Living Wage, 825 So. 2d at 1102-08.
  • 23
    • 34548313787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Elaine B. Sharp & Steven Maynard-Moody, Theories of the Local Welfare Role, 35 AM. J, POL. SCI. 934, 935 (1991) (documenting significant variance in the redistributive spending from zero to approximately $150,000 per thousand population (in 1977 dollars)).
    • See Elaine B. Sharp & Steven Maynard-Moody, Theories of the Local Welfare Role, 35 AM. J, POL. SCI. 934, 935 (1991) (documenting significant variance in the redistributive spending from zero to approximately $150,000 per thousand population (in 1977 dollars)).
  • 24
    • 34548348428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professors Glaeser and Kahn report that cities with a population in excess of 1 million spend 2.5% of their budget on local welfare expenditures, while localities with populations between 2,500 and 10,000 spend 0.7% of their budget on local welfare expenditures. See Edward L. Glaeser & Matthew E. Kahn, From John Lindsay to Rudy Giuliani: The Decline of the Local Safety Net?, FED. RES. BANK N.Y. ECON. POL'Y REV, Sept. 1999, at 117, 117. One potential explanation for this phenomenon is that redistribution requires an economically diverse population. Larger cities tend to have more economic diversity than smaller localities.
    • Professors Glaeser and Kahn report that cities with a population in excess of 1 million spend 2.5% of their budget on local welfare expenditures, while localities with populations between 2,500 and 10,000 spend 0.7% of their budget on local welfare expenditures. See Edward L. Glaeser & Matthew E. Kahn, From John Lindsay to Rudy Giuliani: The Decline of the Local Safety Net?, FED. RES. BANK N.Y. ECON. POL'Y REV, Sept. 1999, at 117, 117. One potential explanation for this phenomenon is that redistribution requires an economically diverse population. Larger cities tend to have more economic diversity than smaller localities.
  • 25
    • 34548315820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, 2002 CENSUS OF GOVERNMENTS: FINANCES OF MUNICIPAL AND TOWN-SHIP GOVERNMENTS 11 tbl. 6 2005, available at http://www.census.gov/prod/2005pubs/gc024x4.pdf. The explanation of Public Welfare expenditures indicates that they include: any payments for applicable cash benefits in excess of, or supplementary to, those financed with federal or state participation. General relief, which is wholly financed from state and local sources, makes up most other cash assistance. Other public welfare spending includes: vendor payments under various public welfare programs, including the federally supported medical care program commonly known as Medicaid; institutional care for the needy; and administration of welfare activities
    • U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, 2002 CENSUS OF GOVERNMENTS: FINANCES OF MUNICIPAL AND TOWN-SHIP GOVERNMENTS 11 tbl. 6 (2005), available at http://www.census.gov/prod/2005pubs/gc024x4.pdf. The explanation of "Public Welfare" expenditures indicates that they include: any payments for applicable cash benefits in excess of, or supplementary to, those financed with federal or state participation. General relief, which is wholly financed from state and local sources, makes up most other cash assistance. Other public welfare spending includes: vendor payments under various public welfare programs, including the federally supported medical care program commonly known as Medicaid; institutional care for the needy; and administration of welfare activities.
  • 26
    • 34548331240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at ix. Thus, it appears that these figures are net of Federal and state contributions
    • Id. at ix. Thus, it appears that these figures are net of Federal and state contributions.
  • 27
    • 34548315822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 28
    • 34548315823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 11. Total direct expenditures were calculated at $358.6 billion.
    • See id. at 11. Total direct expenditures were calculated at $358.6 billion.
  • 29
    • 34548308546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 30
    • 34548360600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peterson includes within redistributive expenditures all unreimbursed monies spent on pensions (including social security), medicare, welfare assistance, housing, medicaid, food stamps, supplemental social insurance, special educational programs for the disabled, and other programs directed at dependent groups in the population. PETERSON, PRICE, supra note 5, at 64.
    • Peterson includes within "redistributive expenditures" all unreimbursed monies spent on "pensions (including social security), medicare, welfare assistance, housing, medicaid, food stamps, supplemental social insurance, special educational programs for the disabled, and other programs directed at dependent groups in the population." PETERSON, PRICE, supra note 5, at 64.
  • 31
    • 34548306480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peterson omits spending on education on the theory that the main effects of those expenditures are developmental, a category that includes expenditures that assist economic growth and are separate from redistributive expenditures. He contends that educational spending has less to do with student learning than other variables. Id. at 64-67
    • Peterson omits spending on education on the theory that the main effects of those expenditures are developmental, a category that includes expenditures that assist economic growth and are separate from redistributive expenditures. He contends that educational spending has less to do with student learning than other variables. Id. at 64-67.
  • 32
    • 34548336489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 71
    • Id. at 71.
  • 33
    • 34548306477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Few localities impose income taxes, and many of those that do impose taxes at flat rates. Nevertheless, some cities, such as New York City, introduce at least mild progressivity into their income taxes. See New York City Income Tax Information, http://dab.nfc.usda.gov/pubs/docs/taxformulas/formulas/ statecitycounty/taxny-c/taxny-c.html (last visited Feb. 1, 2007).
    • Few localities impose income taxes, and many of those that do impose taxes at flat rates. Nevertheless, some cities, such as New York City, introduce at least mild progressivity into their income taxes. See New York City Income Tax Information, http://dab.nfc.usda.gov/pubs/docs/taxformulas/formulas/ statecitycounty/taxny-c/taxny-c.html (last visited Feb. 1, 2007).
  • 35
  • 36
    • 34548358527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, note 5, at
    • see also PETERSON, CITY, supra note 5, at 43.
    • supra , pp. 43
    • PETERSON, C.1
  • 37
    • 34548297103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Minn. Energy and Econ. Dev. Auth. v. Printy, 351 N.W.2d 319 (Minn. 1984); State ex rel. McLeod v. Riley, 278 S.E.2d 612 (S.C. 1981), overruled by WDW Props, v. City of Sumter, 535 S.E.2d 631 (S.C. 2000).
    • See, e.g., Minn. Energy and Econ. Dev. Auth. v. Printy, 351 N.W.2d 319 (Minn. 1984); State ex rel. McLeod v. Riley, 278 S.E.2d 612 (S.C. 1981), overruled by WDW Props, v. City of Sumter, 535 S.E.2d 631 (S.C. 2000).
  • 38
    • 34548315840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Friends of Parks v. Chi. Parks Dist., 786 N.E.2d 161 (Ill. 2003); Cohen v. City of Phila., 806 A.2d 905 (Pa. Commw. Ct. 2002); CLEAN v. State, 928 P.2d 1054 (Wash. 1996). The presence or absence of local benefits from local subsidies arouses passions among sports fans and economists.
    • See, e.g., Friends of Parks v. Chi. Parks Dist., 786 N.E.2d 161 (Ill. 2003); Cohen v. City of Phila., 806 A.2d 905 (Pa. Commw. Ct. 2002); CLEAN v. State, 928 P.2d 1054 (Wash. 1996). The presence or absence of local benefits from local subsidies arouses passions among sports fans and economists.
  • 39
    • 3242708840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gerald Carlino & N. Edward Coulson, Compensating Differentials and the Social Benefits of the NFL, 56 J. URB. ECON. 25 (2004) [hereinafter Carlino & Coulson, Compensating Differentials] (arguing that public expenditures create quality of life benefits that justify new stadium subsidies);
    • See Gerald Carlino & N. Edward Coulson, Compensating Differentials and the Social Benefits of the NFL, 56 J. URB. ECON. 25 (2004) [hereinafter Carlino & Coulson, Compensating Differentials] (arguing that public expenditures create quality of life benefits that justify new stadium subsidies);
  • 40
    • 33646535063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dennis Coates, Brad R. Humphreys & Andrew Zimbalist, Compensating Differentials and the Social Benefits of the NFL: A Comment, 60 J. URB. ECON. 124 (2006) (arguing that they do not);
    • Dennis Coates, Brad R. Humphreys & Andrew Zimbalist, Compensating Differentials and the Social Benefits of the NFL: A Comment, 60 J. URB. ECON. 124 (2006) (arguing that they do not);
  • 41
    • 33646672925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gerald Carlino & N. Edward Coulson, Compensating Differentials and the Social Benefits of the NFL: Reply, 60 J. URB. ECON. 132 (2006) (arguing that they do);
    • Gerald Carlino & N. Edward Coulson, Compensating Differentials and the Social Benefits of the NFL: Reply, 60 J. URB. ECON. 132 (2006) (arguing that they do);
  • 42
    • 34548297091 scopus 로고
    • DEAN V. BAIM, THE SPORTS STADIUM AS A MUNICIPAL INVESTMENT
    • DEAN V. BAIM, THE SPORTS STADIUM AS A MUNICIPAL INVESTMENT (1994);
    • (1994)
  • 43
    • 0034259597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Donald L. Alexander, William Kern & Jon Neill, Valuing the Consumption Benefits from Professional Sports Franchises, 48 J. URB. ECON. 321 (2000);
    • Donald L. Alexander, William Kern & Jon Neill, Valuing the Consumption Benefits from Professional Sports Franchises, 48 J. URB. ECON. 321 (2000);
  • 44
    • 0037370632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dennis Coates & Brad R. Humphreys, The Effect of Professional Sports on Earnings and Employment in the Services and Retail Sectors in US Cities, 33 REGIONAL SCI. & URB. ECON. 175 (2003).
    • Dennis Coates & Brad R. Humphreys, The Effect of Professional Sports on Earnings and Employment in the Services and Retail Sectors in US Cities, 33 REGIONAL SCI. & URB. ECON. 175 (2003).
  • 45
    • 34548320923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • v. Cuno, 126
    • See DaimlerChrysler Corp
    • See DaimlerChrysler Corp. v. Cuno, 126 S. Ct. 1854 (2006).
    • (2006) S. Ct. 1854
  • 46
    • 34548360602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is a lively debate about the extent to which business incentives actually produce enough economic activity to offset the subsidies that localities provide to attract the beneficiaries of the programs. In addition to the sources cited in supra note 24,
    • There is a lively debate about the extent to which business incentives actually produce enough economic activity to offset the subsidies that localities provide to attract the beneficiaries of the programs. In addition to the sources cited in supra note 24,
  • 47
    • 34548323925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see, for example, the essays included in SPORTS, JOBS, AND TAXES: THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF SPORTS TEAMS AND STADIUMS (Roger G. Noll & Andrew Zimbalist eds., 1997) [hereinafter SPORTS, JOBS, AND TAXES];
    • see, for example, the essays included in SPORTS, JOBS, AND TAXES: THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF SPORTS TEAMS AND STADIUMS (Roger G. Noll & Andrew Zimbalist eds., 1997) [hereinafter SPORTS, JOBS, AND TAXES];
  • 48
    • 34548306481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Timothy J. Bartik, Evaluating the Impacts of Local Economic Development Policies on Local Economic Outcomes: What Has Been Done and What is Doable!, in OECD, EVALUATING LOCAL ECONOMIC AND EMPLOYMENT DEVELOPMENT: How TO ASSESS WHAT WORKS AMONG PROGRAMMES AND POLICIES 113 (2004), available at http://wwwl.oecd.org/ publications/e-book/8404031E.PDF.
    • Timothy J. Bartik, Evaluating the Impacts of Local Economic Development Policies on Local Economic Outcomes: What Has Been Done and What is Doable!, in OECD, EVALUATING LOCAL ECONOMIC AND EMPLOYMENT DEVELOPMENT: How TO ASSESS WHAT WORKS AMONG PROGRAMMES AND POLICIES 113 (2004), available at http://wwwl.oecd.org/ publications/e-book/8404031E.PDF.
  • 49
    • 34548311651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., WILLIAM H. SIMON, THE COMMUNITY ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT MOVEMENT 105-09 (2001).
    • See, e.g., WILLIAM H. SIMON, THE COMMUNITY ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT MOVEMENT 105-09 (2001).
  • 50
    • 34548295010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bartik, supra note 26, at 118
    • See Bartik, supra note 26, at 118.
  • 51
    • 34548311652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 18-19. The local expenditures pale in comparison to redistributive expenditures made by the federal government, which Peterson estimates as increasing from $114.3 billion to $560.7 billion during the same period.
    • See supra text accompanying notes 18-19. The local expenditures pale in comparison to redistributive expenditures made by the federal government, which Peterson estimates as increasing from $114.3 billion to $560.7 billion during the same period.
  • 52
  • 53
    • 34548304421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These local outlays are similarly surpassed by the redistributive expenditures of state governments, which Peterson estimates increased from $34.4 billion to $136.9 billion. Id. at 71
    • These local outlays are similarly surpassed by the redistributive expenditures of state governments, which Peterson estimates increased from $34.4 billion to $136.9 billion. Id. at 71.
  • 54
    • 34548356479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wis. STAT. ANN. § 104.001 (2006).
    • See, e.g., Wis. STAT. ANN. § 104.001 (2006).
  • 55
    • 0043189804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Saving the States from Themselves: Commerce Clause Constraints on State Tax Incentives for Business, 110
    • For an argument to create legal barriers to the creation of business incentives, see
    • For an argument to create legal barriers to the creation of business incentives, see Peter D. Enrich, Saving the States from Themselves: Commerce Clause Constraints on State Tax Incentives for Business, 110 HARV. L. REV. 377 (1996).
    • (1996) HARV. L. REV , vol.377
    • Enrich, P.D.1
  • 56
    • 0347878173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an argument that the competition among localities within a small geographic area may be negative-sum, see Jonathan Schwartz, Note, Prisoners of Proposition 13: Sales Taxes, Property Taxes, and the Fiscalization of Municipal Land Use Decisions, 71 S. CAL. L. REV. 183 1997
    • For an argument that the competition among localities within a small geographic area may be negative-sum, see Jonathan Schwartz, Note, Prisoners of Proposition 13: Sales Taxes, Property Taxes, and the Fiscalization of Municipal Land Use Decisions, 71 S. CAL. L. REV. 183 (1997).
  • 57
    • 0041630879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elsewhere, I have given some reasons to doubt claims that interjurisdictional competition is necessarily negative-sum. See Clayton P. Gillette, Business Incentives, Interstate Competition, and the Commerce Clause, 82 MLNN. L. REV. 447 (1997).
    • Elsewhere, I have given some reasons to doubt claims that interjurisdictional competition is necessarily negative-sum. See Clayton P. Gillette, Business Incentives, Interstate Competition, and the Commerce Clause, 82 MLNN. L. REV. 447 (1997).
  • 58
    • 34548311650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As formulated by its originator, John Dillon, the Rule permitted localities only to exercise those powers expressly granted by the legislature, those powers necessarily . . . implied from express grants, and those powers essential to the accomplishment of the declared . . . purposes of localities. JOHN F. DILLON, 1 COMMENTARIES ON THE LAW OF MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS 448-51 (5th ed. 1911). Any doubt was to be resolved against the exercise of a power. See id.
    • As formulated by its originator, John Dillon, the Rule permitted localities only to exercise those powers expressly granted by the legislature, those powers "necessarily . . . implied" from express grants, and those powers "essential to the accomplishment of the declared . . . purposes" of localities. JOHN F. DILLON, 1 COMMENTARIES ON THE LAW OF MUNICIPAL CORPORATIONS 448-51 (5th ed. 1911). Any doubt was to be resolved against the exercise of a power. See id.
  • 59
    • 34548303342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ERIC H. MONKKONEN, THE LOCAL STATE: PUBLIC MONEY AND AMERICAN CITIES 57-77 (1995).
    • See ERIC H. MONKKONEN, THE LOCAL STATE: PUBLIC MONEY AND AMERICAN CITIES 57-77 (1995).
  • 60
    • 34548304423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lowell v. City of Boston, 111 Mass. 454 (1873) (invalidating bonds proposed to be issued by city of Boston to reconstruct housing destroyed in conflagration).
    • See Lowell v. City of Boston, 111 Mass. 454 (1873) (invalidating bonds proposed to be issued by city of Boston to reconstruct housing destroyed in conflagration).
  • 61
    • 34548308561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Subsequent constitutional restrictions on the state, however, revealed that state legislators could not be trusted to restrain local redistribution. Constitutional amendments that prohibited the legislature from enacting special legislation in favor of one or a few localities became popular in the latter part of the nineteenth century. The legislative enactments targeted by the prohibition had tended to permit specific localities to dedicate local resources to particular groups that apparently had more political support in the legislature than in city councils. JON C. TEAFORD, THE UNHERALDED TRIUMPH: CITY GOVERNMENT IN AMERICA 1870-1900, at 84-94, 105-07 (1984).
    • Subsequent constitutional restrictions on the state, however, revealed that state legislators could not be trusted to restrain local redistribution. Constitutional amendments that prohibited the legislature from enacting "special legislation" in favor of one or a few localities became popular in the latter part of the nineteenth century. The legislative enactments targeted by the prohibition had tended to permit specific localities to dedicate local resources to particular groups that apparently had more political support in the legislature than in city councils. JON C. TEAFORD, THE UNHERALDED TRIUMPH: CITY GOVERNMENT IN AMERICA 1870-1900, at 84-94, 105-07 (1984).
  • 62
    • 34548329200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., City of Miami Beach v. Fleetwood Hotel, Inc., 261 So. 2d 801 (Fla. 1972) (invalidating rent control ordinance).
    • See, e.g., City of Miami Beach v. Fleetwood Hotel, Inc., 261 So. 2d 801 (Fla. 1972) (invalidating rent control ordinance).
  • 63
    • 34548304422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wholesale Laundry Bd. of Trade, Inc. v. City of New York, 234 N.Y.S.2d 862 (N.Y. App. Div. 1962) (invalidating local minimum wage ordinance). But see McMillen v. Browne, 200 N.E.2d 546 (N.Y. 1964) (upholding local minimum wage ordinance).
    • See, e.g., Wholesale Laundry Bd. of Trade, Inc. v. City of New York, 234 N.Y.S.2d 862 (N.Y. App. Div. 1962) (invalidating local minimum wage ordinance). But see McMillen v. Browne, 200 N.E.2d 546 (N.Y. 1964) (upholding local minimum wage ordinance).
  • 64
    • 34548320922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Greater Boston Real Estate Bd. v. City of Boston, 705 N.E.2d 256 (Mass. 1999).
    • See, e.g., Greater Boston Real Estate Bd. v. City of Boston, 705 N.E.2d 256 (Mass. 1999).
  • 65
    • 34548295009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some of these opinions indicated antipathy towards redistribution at more centralized levels of government as well, insofar as they blocked assistance by the state as well as local governments. See, e.g, In re Opinion of the Justices, 98 N.E. 611 (Mass. 1912, public funds could not be used to provide homes to wage-earners, Salisbury Land & Improvement Co. v. Commonwealth, 102 N.E. 619 Mass. 1913
    • Some of these opinions indicated antipathy towards redistribution at more centralized levels of government as well, insofar as they blocked assistance by the state as well as local governments. See, e.g., In re Opinion of the Justices, 98 N.E. 611 (Mass. 1912) (public funds could not be used to provide homes to wage-earners); Salisbury Land & Improvement Co. v. Commonwealth, 102 N.E. 619 (Mass. 1913).
  • 66
    • 34548363381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Mass. Home Mortgage Fin. Agency v. New Eng. Merchs. Nat'l Bank, 382 N.E.2d 1084 (Mass. 1978); Mass. Hous. Fin. Agency v. New Eng. Merchs. Nat'l Bank, 249 N.E.2d 599 (Mass. 1969).
    • See, e.g., Mass. Home Mortgage Fin. Agency v. New Eng. Merchs. Nat'l Bank, 382 N.E.2d 1084 (Mass. 1978); Mass. Hous. Fin. Agency v. New Eng. Merchs. Nat'l Bank, 249 N.E.2d 599 (Mass. 1969).
  • 67
    • 34548323926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., WDW Props, v. City of Sumter, 535 S.E.2d 631 (S.C. 2000); ROBERT S. AMDURSKY & CLAYTON P. GILLETTE, MUNICIPAL DEBT FINANCE LAW: THEORY AND PRACTICE 114-57 (1992); Richard Briffault, Forward: The Disfavored Constitution: State Fiscal Limits and State Constitutional Law, 34 RUTGERS L.J. 907, 910-27 (2003).
    • See, e.g., WDW Props, v. City of Sumter, 535 S.E.2d 631 (S.C. 2000); ROBERT S. AMDURSKY & CLAYTON P. GILLETTE, MUNICIPAL DEBT FINANCE LAW: THEORY AND PRACTICE 114-57 (1992); Richard Briffault, Forward: The Disfavored Constitution: State Fiscal Limits and State Constitutional Law, 34 RUTGERS L.J. 907, 910-27 (2003).
  • 68
    • 34548360619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., In re Okla. Dev. Fin. Auth., 89 P.3d 1075, 1081 (Okla. 2004) (stating that a legislative finding of public purpose should be reversed only upon a clear showing that it was manifestly arbitrary, capricious, or unreasonable).
    • See, e.g., In re Okla. Dev. Fin. Auth., 89 P.3d 1075, 1081 (Okla. 2004) (stating that a legislative finding of public purpose "should be reversed only upon a clear showing that it was manifestly arbitrary, capricious, or unreasonable").
  • 69
    • 34548356464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469 (2005); Clayton P. Gillette, Kelo and the Local Political Process, 34 HOFSTRA L. REV. 13 (2005).
    • See Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469 (2005); Clayton P. Gillette, Kelo and the Local Political Process, 34 HOFSTRA L. REV. 13 (2005).
  • 70
    • 34548331250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These are the issues that have transformed public choice into a growth industry. See, e.g., KENNETH J. ARROW, SOCIAL CHOICE AND INDIVIDUAL VALUES (2d ed. 1963); DENNIS C. MUELLER, PUBLIC CHOICE m (2003); DANIEL FARBER & PHILIP FRICKEY, LAW AND PUBLIC CHOICE (1991).
    • These are the issues that have transformed public choice into a growth industry. See, e.g., KENNETH J. ARROW, SOCIAL CHOICE AND INDIVIDUAL VALUES (2d ed. 1963); DENNIS C. MUELLER, PUBLIC CHOICE m (2003); DANIEL FARBER & PHILIP FRICKEY, LAW AND PUBLIC CHOICE (1991).
  • 71
    • 0348237051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Development and Community Activism, 32
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Georgette C. Poindexter, Economic Development and Community Activism, 32 URB. LAW. 401, 405-06 (2000).
    • (2000) URB. LAW , vol.401 , pp. 405-406
    • Poindexter, G.C.1
  • 72
    • 34548356473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Gary Schwartz, The Logic of Home Rule and the Private Law Exception, 20 UCLA L. REV. 671 (1973) (arguing that the private law exception to expansive home rule power is consistent with desire to reduce effectiveness of local interest groups); Clayton P. Gillette, In Partial Praise of Dillon's Rule, or, Can Public Choice Theory Justify Local Government Law?, 67 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 959 (1991).
    • See, e.g., Gary Schwartz, The Logic of Home Rule and the Private Law Exception, 20 UCLA L. REV. 671 (1973) (arguing that the private law exception to expansive home rule power is consistent with desire to reduce effectiveness of local interest groups); Clayton P. Gillette, In Partial Praise of Dillon's Rule, or, Can Public Choice Theory Justify Local Government Law?, 67 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 959 (1991).
  • 73
    • 17044376328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is obviously a normative element to the conclusion that local preferences should be maximized, since individuals likely do not form their residential preferences after intense, objective consideration and deliberation over alternatives or free of distorting influences. Residential choices may be path-dependent, habitual, or arbitrary. Choices may be further constrained by history, geography, or socioeconomic characteristics of current residents. Some residents will tolerate local characteristics only because they cannot afford their preferred alternatives, suffer from information gaps about available options, or act irrationally in the face of preferences. Where one grows up, what one's peers consider a good place to live, limitations imposed by employment, and socially constructed values about the desirability of urban or suburban life will all affect residential decisions, even without considered reflection. Moreover, attributing preferences to a locality as a whole cannot impl
    • There is obviously a normative element to the conclusion that local preferences should be maximized, since individuals likely do not form their residential preferences after intense, objective consideration and deliberation over alternatives or free of distorting influences. Residential choices may be path-dependent, habitual, or arbitrary. Choices may be further constrained by history, geography, or socioeconomic characteristics of current residents. Some residents will tolerate local characteristics only because they cannot afford their preferred alternatives, suffer from information gaps about available options, or act irrationally in the face of preferences. Where one grows up, what one's peers consider a good place to live, limitations imposed by employment, and socially constructed values about the desirability of urban or suburban life will all affect residential decisions, even without considered reflection. Moreover, attributing preferences to a locality as a whole cannot imply that every resident shares identical preferences or that preferences are perfectly expressed and formed. Residents are likely to disagree over the selection of municipal budgets, ordinances, and governing procedures. Those who prevail may represent those who can best organize rather than those who represent majoritarian preferences or those who feel most strongly about an issue. Localities offer a bundle of services, some of which will be desired by any given resident, some of which will be ignored, and some of which will be disfavored. See, e.g., Lee Anne Fennell, Contracting Communities, 2004 U. ILL. L. REV. 829, 873-77. The impossibility of disaggregating the bundle reduces the likelihood that any part of it accurately reflects constituent preferences. Relatively immobile residents will, by definition, tolerate much more deviation between the local characteristics that they confront and those that they prefer before deciding to vote with their feet. Nevertheless, it is equally unrealistic to assume that the characteristics that distinguish localities from each other do not reflect the deliberate choices of a critical mass of constituents. Given the wide range of goods and services that a locality could provide, and given the incentive of localities to compete for firms and for residents, the choices a locality does make are likely to reflect to a broad extent the characteristics that numerous residents wish to cultivate. Even localities that initially display characteristics that are purely fortuitous are likely subsequently to attract residents for whom those characteristics are salient and desirable, so that evolutionary processes - if not deliberate ones - will cause localities to develop personalities that stick.
  • 74
    • 0000438997 scopus 로고
    • Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory, 58
    • See
    • See Armen A. Alchian, Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory, 58 J. POL. ECON. 211 (1950).
    • (1950) J. POL. ECON , vol.211
    • Alchian, A.A.1
  • 75
    • 34548336485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is unlikely that pure coincidence explains why San Francisco is more responsive to the needs of the homeless than other California localities, see Richard Thompson Ford, Bourgeois Communities: A Review of Gerald Frug's City Making, 56 STAN. L. REV. 231, 243-45 2003, book review, that Sun City Center finances more services for the elderly than communities that do not actively court retirees
    • It is unlikely that pure coincidence explains why San Francisco is more responsive to the needs of the homeless than other California localities, see Richard Thompson Ford, Bourgeois Communities: A Review of Gerald Frug's City Making, 56 STAN. L. REV. 231, 243-45 (2003) (book review), that Sun City Center finances more services for the elderly than communities that do not actively court retirees,
  • 76
    • 34548308560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see FRANCES FITZGERALD, CITIES ON A HILL 203-16 (1987), or that Boston attracts more colleges and universities than Omaha. I cannot warrant whether these distinctions developed from deliberative decisions, But once these characteristics are entrenched, relatively mobile residents and potential residents emigrate from and immigrate to these localities based on their sympathy with those characteristics. It is this very capacity of local government to permit sorting according to preferences that provides many of the efficiency and community-based benefits that are attributed to local government.
    • see FRANCES FITZGERALD, CITIES ON A HILL 203-16 (1987), or that Boston attracts more colleges and universities than Omaha. I cannot warrant whether these distinctions developed from deliberative decisions, But once these characteristics are entrenched, relatively mobile residents and potential residents emigrate from and immigrate to these localities based on their sympathy with those characteristics. It is this very capacity of local government to permit sorting according to preferences that provides many of the efficiency and community-based benefits that are attributed to local government.
  • 77
    • 34548316676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michael W. McConnell, Federalism: Evaluating the Founders ' Design, 54 U. CHI. L. REV. 1484, 1493-94 (1987) (book review). Even to the extent that local characteristics reveal preferences, for my purposes nothing normative necessarily follows. The willingness of localities to signal preferences is also the basis of many of the most unattractive elements of local government, such as exclusionary zoning and ethnic segregation. When sorting falls along lines that offend important social values, law can intervene to preclude discrimination along the offensive metric. Nor does preference satisfaction necessarily entail treating cities simply as objects of consumption.
    • See Michael W. McConnell, Federalism: Evaluating the Founders ' Design, 54 U. CHI. L. REV. 1484, 1493-94 (1987) (book review). Even to the extent that local characteristics reveal preferences, for my purposes nothing normative necessarily follows. The willingness of localities to signal preferences is also the basis of many of the most unattractive elements of local government, such as exclusionary zoning and ethnic segregation. When sorting falls along lines that offend important social values, law can intervene to preclude discrimination along the offensive metric. Nor does preference satisfaction necessarily entail treating cities "simply as objects of consumption."
  • 78
    • 34548320917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See GERALD FRUG, CITY MAKING: BUILDING COMMUNITIES WITHOUT BUILDING WALLS 169 (1999). Individuals may have residential preferences for amenities that are not easily classified as consumable, such as neighbors who are socioeconomically diverse, close-knit identity groups, or open-air spaces.
    • See GERALD FRUG, CITY MAKING: BUILDING COMMUNITIES WITHOUT BUILDING WALLS 169 (1999). Individuals may have residential preferences for amenities that are not easily classified as consumable, such as neighbors who are socioeconomically diverse, close-knit identity groups, or open-air spaces.
  • 79
    • 2442570634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Local Revenue Hills: Evidence from Four U.S. Cities, 86
    • See
    • See Andrew Haughwout, Robert Inman, Steven Craig & Thomas Luce, Local Revenue Hills: Evidence from Four U.S. Cities, 86 REV. ECON. & STAT. 570 (2004).
    • (2004) REV. ECON. & STAT , vol.570
    • Haughwout, A.1    Inman, R.2    Craig, S.3    Luce, T.4
  • 81
    • 34548363391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PETER DREIER, JOHN MOLLENKOPF & TODD SWANSTROM, PLACE MATTERS: METROPOLITICS FOR THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 135 (2001);
    • See PETER DREIER, JOHN MOLLENKOPF & TODD SWANSTROM, PLACE MATTERS: METROPOLITICS FOR THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY 135 (2001);
  • 82
    • 34548358523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 5, at, This is the standard assumption of courts that uphold municipal financing for industrial development
    • PETERSON, CITY, supra note 5, at 41-43. This is the standard assumption of courts that uphold municipal financing for industrial development.
    • CITY, supra , pp. 41-43
    • PETERSON1
  • 83
    • 34548358524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., CLEAN v. State, 928 P.2d 1054 (Wash. 1996); Friends of Parks v. Chi. Parks Dist., 786 N.E.2d 161 (Ill. 2003).
    • See, e.g., CLEAN v. State, 928 P.2d 1054 (Wash. 1996); Friends of Parks v. Chi. Parks Dist., 786 N.E.2d 161 (Ill. 2003).
  • 84
    • 0009170687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition, Benefit Taxes, and Fiscal Federalism, 51
    • See
    • See Timothy J. Goodspeed, Tak Competition, Benefit Taxes, and Fiscal Federalism, 51 NAT'L TAX J. 579 (1998).
    • (1998) NAT'L TAX J , vol.579
    • Timothy, J.1
  • 85
    • 34548315825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Coates & Humphreys, supra note 24
    • See, e.g., Coates & Humphreys, supra note 24.
  • 86
    • 34548308548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Enrich, supra note 31, at 380, 397-401
    • See, e.g., Enrich, supra note 31, at 380, 397-401.
  • 87
    • 34548313776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., THE ECONOMICS AND POLITICS OF SPORTS FACILITIES (Wilbur C. Rich ed., 2000);
    • See, e.g., THE ECONOMICS AND POLITICS OF SPORTS FACILITIES (Wilbur C. Rich ed., 2000);
  • 88
    • 34548360601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SPORTS, JOBS, AND TAXES, supra note 26;
    • SPORTS, JOBS, AND TAXES, supra note 26;
  • 89
    • 0033303812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harrison S. Campbell, Jr., Professional Sports and Urban Development: A Brief Review of Issues and Studies, 29 REV. REGIONAL STUD. 272 (1999). In the case of stadium construction, some of the evidence suggests that sports franchises generate consumption benefits that augment any financial benefit or offset any financial loss to the financing locality.
    • Harrison S. Campbell, Jr., Professional Sports and Urban Development: A Brief Review of Issues and Studies, 29 REV. REGIONAL STUD. 272 (1999). In the case of stadium construction, some of the evidence suggests that sports franchises generate consumption benefits that augment any financial benefit or offset any financial loss to the financing locality.
  • 90
    • 34548295017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Alexander, Kern & Neill, supra note 24;
    • See, e.g., Alexander, Kern & Neill, supra note 24;
  • 91
    • 34548329194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carlino & Coulson, Compensating Differentials, supra note 24. For an argument that localities are likely to use business incentives, i.e., local redistribution to the non-poor, only when expected benefits exceed costs (which is not to say that local officials cannot be overly optimistic in their predictions of benefits),
    • Carlino & Coulson, Compensating Differentials, supra note 24. For an argument that localities are likely to use business incentives, i.e., local redistribution to the non-poor, only when expected benefits exceed costs (which is not to say that local officials cannot be overly optimistic in their predictions of benefits),
  • 92
    • 34548311658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Gillette, supra note 31. Numerous states have offered substantial subsidies in order to attract automobile manufacturers. To date, these programs appear to have had mixed success in terms of generating financial benefits that offset the amount of the subsidy.
    • see Gillette, supra note 31. Numerous states have offered substantial subsidies in order to attract automobile manufacturers. To date, these programs appear to have had mixed success in terms of generating financial benefits that offset the amount of the subsidy.
  • 93
    • 34548329189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Buying Jobs Can be Expensive, THE ECONOMIST, Nov. 29, 2003, at 29, 30. The Alabama Supreme Court declared that part of a bill providing subsidies to attract a Mercedes-Benz plant to that state would violate the state constitution,
    • See Buying Jobs Can be Expensive, THE ECONOMIST, Nov. 29, 2003, at 29, 30. The Alabama Supreme Court declared that part of a bill providing subsidies to attract a Mercedes-Benz plant to that state would violate the state constitution,
  • 94
    • 34548329190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Opinion of the Justices, 665 So. 2d 1357 (Ala. 1995) (advisory opinion).
    • See Opinion of the Justices, 665 So. 2d 1357 (Ala. 1995) (advisory opinion).
  • 95
    • 0034424027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Welfare Reform and the Race to the Bottom: Theory and Evidence, 66
    • For reviews of literature testing the effects of differential welfare benefits, see
    • For reviews of literature testing the effects of differential welfare benefits, see Jan K. Brueckner, Welfare Reform and the Race to the Bottom: Theory and Evidence, 66 S. ECON. J. 505, 514-18 (2000);
    • (2000) S. ECON. J , vol.505 , pp. 514-518
    • Brueckner, J.K.1
  • 96
    • 0002590977 scopus 로고
    • Incentive Effects of the U.S. Welfare System: A Review, 30
    • Robert Moffitt, Incentive Effects of the U.S. Welfare System: A Review, 30 J. ECON. LIT. 1, 31-36 (1992).
    • (1992) J. ECON. LIT , vol.1 , pp. 31-36
    • Moffitt, R.1
  • 97
    • 0031160927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brueckner finds mixed evidence that welfare recipients migrate for higher benefits, but does not speculate about emigration of the rich from those jurisdictions. For an interesting historical study that suggests that the poor did not migrate from one locality to another nearby one that offered more generous welfare benefits, see Kyle D. Kauffman & L. Lynne Kiesling, Was There a Nineteenth Century Welfare Magnet in the United States? Preliminary Results from New York City and Brooklyn, 37 Q. REV. ECON. & FIN. 439 (1997).
    • Brueckner finds mixed evidence that welfare recipients migrate for higher benefits, but does not speculate about emigration of the rich from those jurisdictions. For an interesting historical study that suggests that the poor did not migrate from one locality to another nearby one that offered more generous welfare benefits, see Kyle D. Kauffman & L. Lynne Kiesling, Was There a Nineteenth Century Welfare Magnet in the United States? Preliminary Results from New York City and Brooklyn, 37 Q. REV. ECON. & FIN. 439 (1997).
  • 98
    • 34548320909 scopus 로고
    • Unfunded Mandates, Hidden Taxation, and the Tenth Amendment: On Public Choice, Public Interest, and Public Services, 46
    • See
    • See Edward A. Zelinsky, Unfunded Mandates, Hidden Taxation, and the Tenth Amendment: On Public Choice, Public Interest, and Public Services, 46 VAND. L. REV. 1355 (1993).
    • (1993) VAND. L. REV , vol.1355
    • Zelinsky, E.A.1
  • 99
    • 34548313777 scopus 로고
    • City Welfare: Views from Theory, History, and Practice, 27
    • See
    • See Kirk J. Stark, City Welfare: Views from Theory, History, and Practice, 27 URB. LAW. 495, 517-20 (1995).
    • (1995) URB. LAW , vol.495 , pp. 517-520
    • Stark, K.J.1
  • 100
    • 34548304417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CONN. GEN. STAT. § 17b-116 (repealed 2004).
    • See CONN. GEN. STAT. § 17b-116 (repealed 2004).
  • 101
    • 34548306484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CITIZENS BUDGET COMMISSION, CONFRONTING THE TRADEOFFS IN MEDICAID COST CONTAINMENT 11 (2004).
    • See CITIZENS BUDGET COMMISSION, CONFRONTING THE TRADEOFFS IN MEDICAID COST CONTAINMENT 11 (2004).
  • 102
    • 34548360605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CAL. WELF. & INST. CODE § 17000 (West 2004).
    • CAL. WELF. & INST. CODE § 17000 (West 2004).
  • 103
    • 34548304402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McConnell, supra note 47, at 1493-94;
    • See McConnell, supra note 47, at 1493-94;
  • 104
    • 0000778367 scopus 로고
    • A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures, 64
    • Charles M. Tiebout, A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures, 64 J. POL. ECON. 416 (1956);
    • (1956) J. POL. ECON , vol.416
    • Tiebout, C.M.1
  • 105
    • 34548299194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DREIER ET AL, supra note 50, at 97-98
    • DREIER ET AL., supra note 50, at 97-98.
  • 106
    • 0346296960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Opting Out of Public Provision, 73
    • See
    • See Clayton P. Gillette, Opting Out of Public Provision, 73 DENV. U. L. REV. 1185 (1996).
    • (1996) DENV. U. L. REV , vol.1185
    • Gillette, C.P.1
  • 107
    • 0348223991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Government for Our Time? Business Improvement Districts and Urban Governance, 99
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Richard Briffault, A Government for Our Time? Business Improvement Districts and Urban Governance, 99 COLUM. L. REV. 365 (1999);
    • (1999) COLUM. L. REV , vol.365
    • Briffault, R.1
  • 108
    • 0010944035 scopus 로고
    • Cities and Homeowners Associations, 130
    • Robert C. Ellickson, Cities and Homeowners Associations, 130 U. PA. L. REV. 1519 (1982);
    • (1982) U. PA. L. REV , vol.1519
    • Ellickson, R.C.1
  • 109
    • 0346934925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert C. Ellickson, New Institutions for Old Neighborhoods, 48 DUKE L.J. 75 (1998). The caveat in the text is important. There are cases in which those who can benefit from an increased level of provision will simultaneously attempt to reduce public levels of expenditure from which they don't benefit. But in many of these cases, even those who wish to supplement the baseline level of provision will want that baseline to be high in order to minimize the cost of supplementation.
    • Robert C. Ellickson, New Institutions for Old Neighborhoods, 48 DUKE L.J. 75 (1998). The caveat in the text is important. There are cases in which those who can benefit from an increased level of provision will simultaneously attempt to reduce public levels of expenditure from which they don't benefit. But in many of these cases, even those who wish to supplement the baseline level of provision will want that baseline to be high in order to minimize the cost of supplementation.
  • 110
    • 34548311653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gillette, supra note 62, at 1209-10
    • See Gillette, supra note 62, at 1209-10.
  • 111
    • 0002184350 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mark V. Pauly, Income Redistribution As a Local Public Good, 2 J, PUB. ECON. 35, 38 (1972).
    • See Mark V. Pauly, Income Redistribution As a Local Public Good, 2 J, PUB. ECON. 35, 38 (1972).
  • 113
    • 34548356472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, the services provided by the Cambridge, Massachusetts Department of Human Services, http://www.cambridgema.gov/DHSP2/. The Berkeley, California Municipal Code contains not only a living wage ordinance, but also a rent stabilization ordinance. BERKELEY MUN. CODE ch. 13.27.010-.100, 13.76.010-.190 (1977).
    • See, for example, the services provided by the Cambridge, Massachusetts Department of Human Services, http://www.cambridgema.gov/DHSP2/. The Berkeley, California Municipal Code contains not only a living wage ordinance, but also a rent stabilization ordinance. BERKELEY MUN. CODE ch. 13.27.010-.100, 13.76.010-.190 (1977).
  • 114
    • 34548358527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 5, at
    • PETERSON, PRICE, supra note 5, at 88-89.
    • supra , pp. 88-89
    • PETERSON, P.1
  • 115
    • 34548331242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MICHAEL J. SANDEL, DEMOCRACY'S DISCONTENT 131-32 (1996).
    • MICHAEL J. SANDEL, DEMOCRACY'S DISCONTENT 131-32 (1996).
  • 116
    • 34548318756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Saenz v. Roe, 526 U.S. 489 (1999); Shapiro v. Thompson, 394 U.S. 618 (1969).
    • See Saenz v. Roe, 526 U.S. 489 (1999); Shapiro v. Thompson, 394 U.S. 618 (1969).
  • 117
    • 34548306488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Helen F. Ladd & Fred C. Doolittle, Which Level of Government Should Assist the Poor?, 35 NAT'L TAX. J. 323, 331 (1982).
    • See Helen F. Ladd & Fred C. Doolittle, Which Level of Government Should Assist the Poor?, 35 NAT'L TAX. J. 323, 331 (1982).
  • 118
    • 0000647949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Controlling Chronic Misconduct in City Spaces: Of Panhandlers, Skid Rows, and Public-Space Zoning, 105
    • See
    • See Robert C. Ellickson, Controlling Chronic Misconduct in City Spaces: Of Panhandlers, Skid Rows, and Public-Space Zoning, 105 YALE L.J. 1165 (1996).
    • (1996) YALE L.J , vol.1165
    • Ellickson, R.C.1
  • 119
    • 34548308549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Fifth Ave. Presbyterian Church v. City of New York, 293 F.3d 570 (2d Cir. 2002) (city prohibited from removing homeless persons from church property notwithstanding apparent complaints from church neighbors).
    • See, e.g., Fifth Ave. Presbyterian Church v. City of New York, 293 F.3d 570 (2d Cir. 2002) (city prohibited from removing homeless persons from church property notwithstanding apparent complaints from church neighbors).
  • 120
    • 34548318755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the proposition that relative position is an important motivator of consumption, see ROBERT H. FRANK, LUXURY FEVER 107-21 (1999).
    • For the proposition that relative position is an important motivator of consumption, see ROBERT H. FRANK, LUXURY FEVER 107-21 (1999).
  • 121
    • 0034949589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Group Loyalty and the Taste for Redistribution, 109
    • See
    • See Erzo F.P. Luttmer, Group Loyalty and the Taste for Redistribution, 109 J. POL. ECON. 500 (2001).
    • (2001) J. POL. ECON , vol.500
    • Luttmer, E.F.P.1
  • 122
    • 34548316665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The shift to the Care Not Cash program was mandated by the adoption of Proposition N by the San Francisco electorate in November 2002. For a description of the program, see The Care Not Cash Initiative, S.F. ADMIN. CODE § 20 (as amended).
    • The shift to the "Care Not Cash" program was mandated by the adoption of Proposition N by the San Francisco electorate in November 2002. For a description of the program, see The Care Not Cash Initiative, S.F. ADMIN. CODE § 20 (as amended).
  • 123
    • 34548363383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, some support may also have been attributable to a desire to remove the homeless, or have them remove themselves-from San Francisco if they could no longer receive cash. See Ford, supra note 47, at 243-44. That certainly has been one effect of the program. The San Francisco Department of Human Services reported in July 2005 that its County Adult Assistance Program caseload declined 78% in the first 15 months of the Care Not Cash program
    • Of course, some support may also have been attributable to a desire to remove the homeless - or have them remove themselves-from San Francisco if they could no longer receive cash. See Ford, supra note 47, at 243-44. That certainly has been one effect of the program. The San Francisco Department of Human Services reported in July 2005 that its County Adult Assistance Program caseload declined 78% in the first 15 months of the Care Not Cash program.
  • 124
    • 34548323937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, July, But even that effect suggests the willingness of the relatively wealthy to support programs that decrease what they perceive as disamenities
    • See Care Not Cash Monthly Update (July 2005), http://www.sfgov. org/site/uploadedfiles/dhs/CareNotCashMonthlyUpdateJuly05.pdf. But even that effect suggests the willingness of the relatively wealthy to support programs that decrease what they perceive as disamenities.
    • (2005) Cash Monthly Update
    • Not, C.1
  • 125
    • 34548358530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FRANCES FOX PIVEN & RICHARD A. CLOWARD, REGULATING THE POOR: THE FUNCTIONS OF PUBLIC WELFARE 183-338 (1971).
    • FRANCES FOX PIVEN & RICHARD A. CLOWARD, REGULATING THE POOR: THE FUNCTIONS OF PUBLIC WELFARE 183-338 (1971).
  • 126
    • 0031287961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Conditional Effect of Violence as a Political Tactic: Mass Insurgency, Welfare Generosity, and Electoral Context in the American States, 41
    • See
    • See Richard C. Fording, The Conditional Effect of Violence as a Political Tactic: Mass Insurgency, Welfare Generosity, and Electoral Context in the American States, 41 AM. J. POL. SCI. 1 (1997);
    • (1997) AM. J. POL. SCI , vol.1
    • Fording, R.C.1
  • 127
    • 34548297096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sharp & Maynard-Moody, supra note 14;
    • Sharp & Maynard-Moody, supra note 14;
  • 128
    • 0035529980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joe Soss, Sanford F. Schram, Thomas P. Vartanian & Erin O'Brien, Setting the Terms of Relief: Explaining State Policy Choices in the Devolution Revolution, 45 AM. J. POL. SCI. 378 (2001). For my purposes, these motivations remain benign notwithstanding that they emerge from selfishness rather than altruism. Recall that I classify explanations for redistribution as benign as long as they are consistent with the interests of residents, regardless of what motivates the formation of those interests.
    • Joe Soss, Sanford F. Schram, Thomas P. Vartanian & Erin O'Brien, Setting the Terms of Relief: Explaining State Policy Choices in the Devolution Revolution, 45 AM. J. POL. SCI. 378 (2001). For my purposes, these motivations remain "benign" notwithstanding that they emerge from selfishness rather than altruism. Recall that I classify explanations for redistribution as benign as long as they are consistent with the interests of residents, regardless of what motivates the formation of those interests.
  • 129
    • 34548301163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, the evidence here is mixed. Compare Adams & Neumark, supra note 3
    • Of course, the evidence here is mixed. Compare Adams & Neumark, supra note 3,
  • 130
    • 13944278491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • with Michael Reich, Peter Hall & Ken Jacobs, Living Wage Policies at the San Francisco Airport: Impacts on Workers and Businesses, 44 INDUS, REL. 106, 128-32 (2005) (finding no evidence of employment decline after implementation of living wage policies at San Francisco Airport).
    • with Michael Reich, Peter Hall & Ken Jacobs, Living Wage Policies at the San Francisco Airport: Impacts on Workers and Businesses, 44 INDUS, REL. 106, 128-32 (2005) (finding no evidence of employment decline after implementation of living wage policies at San Francisco Airport).
  • 131
    • 34548308550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John M. Quigley, Urban Diversity and Economic Growth, J. ECON. PERSP., Spring 1998, at 127, 130-32.
    • John M. Quigley, Urban Diversity and Economic Growth, J. ECON. PERSP., Spring 1998, at 127, 130-32.
  • 132
    • 34548316668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FUJITA & JACQUES- FRANCOIS THISSE, ECONOMICS OF AGGLOMERATION: CITIES, INDUSTRIAL LOCATION, AND REGIONAL
    • See
    • See MASAHISA FUJITA & JACQUES- FRANCOIS THISSE, ECONOMICS OF AGGLOMERATION: CITIES, INDUSTRIAL LOCATION, AND REGIONAL GROWTH 172-73 (2002).
    • (2002) GROWTH , vol.172 -73
    • MASAHISA1
  • 133
    • 85040849073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PHILIP D. CURTIN, CROSS-CULTURAL TRADE IN WORLD HISTORY 1 (1984).
    • PHILIP D. CURTIN, CROSS-CULTURAL TRADE IN WORLD HISTORY 1 (1984).
  • 135
    • 34548331244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Quigley, supra note 80, at 131
    • Quigley, supra note 80, at 131.
  • 136
    • 34548303336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 131-32
    • Id. at 131-32.
  • 137
    • 34548358526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Michael Cooper, Business Group Backs Raise in New York Minimum Wage, N.Y. TIMES, July 15, 2004, at B2, (reporting that a business group in New York City seeks an increase in the state minimum wage in order to maintain City's competitive position by attracting high quality workforce).
    • See, e.g., Michael Cooper, Business Group Backs Raise in New York Minimum Wage, N.Y. TIMES, July 15, 2004, at B2, (reporting that a business group in New York City seeks an increase in the state minimum wage in order to maintain City's competitive position by attracting high quality workforce).
  • 138
    • 34548358527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 5, at
    • See PETERSON, CITY, supra note 5, at 43.
    • supra , pp. 43
    • PETERSON, C.1
  • 139
    • 34548316677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Quigley, supra note 80, at 132
    • Quigley, supra note 80, at 132.
  • 140
    • 14744304484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To Fill Gaps, Cities Seek Wave of Immigrants
    • See, May 30, at
    • See Eric Schmitt, To Fill Gaps, Cities Seek Wave of Immigrants, N.Y. TIMES, May 30, 2001, at A1.
    • (2001) N.Y. TIMES
    • Schmitt, E.1
  • 141
    • 34548363384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Stephen Moore, Immigration and the Rise and Decline of American Cities (1997), available at http://www.hoover.org/publications/ epp/epp81.html (finding that high-immigrant cities had double the job creation rate, higher per capita incomes, lower poverty rates and less crime than low-immigrant cities, although they also have high unemployment rates).
    • See, e.g., Stephen Moore, Immigration and the Rise and Decline of American Cities (1997), available at http://www.hoover.org/publications/ epp/epp81.html (finding that high-immigrant cities had double the job creation rate, higher per capita incomes, lower poverty rates and less crime than low-immigrant cities, although they also have high unemployment rates).
  • 142
    • 34548320916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Edward L. Glaeser & Jesse M. Shapiro, City Growth and the 2000 Census: Which Places Grew, and Why, BROOKINGS INST. CTR. ON URB. AND METRO. POL. SURVEY SERIES, May 2001, at 12.
    • See Edward L. Glaeser & Jesse M. Shapiro, City Growth and the 2000 Census: Which Places Grew, and Why, BROOKINGS INST. CTR. ON URB. AND METRO. POL. SURVEY SERIES, May 2001, at 12.
  • 143
    • 34548323936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jennifer S. Vey & Benjamin Forman, Demographic Change in Medium-Sized Cities: Evidence from the 2000 Census, BROOKINGS INST. CTR. ON URB. AND METRO. POL. SURVEY SERIES, July 2002, at 6.
    • Jennifer S. Vey & Benjamin Forman, Demographic Change in Medium-Sized Cities: Evidence from the 2000 Census, BROOKINGS INST. CTR. ON URB. AND METRO. POL. SURVEY SERIES, July 2002, at 6.
  • 144
    • 34548363390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 145
    • 34548318762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some confirmation of this can be found in Roberto Suro & Audrey Singer, Latino Growth in Metropolitan America: Changing Patterns, New Locations, BROOKINGS INST. CTR. ON URB. AND METRO. POL. SURVEY SERIES, July 2002, at 7 (Many Hispanics, by choosing the suburbs, are following the familiar path from city neighborhoods to the urban periphery. In addition, some suburban areas are serving as ports of entry for newly arriving immigrants.).
    • Some confirmation of this can be found in Roberto Suro & Audrey Singer, Latino Growth in Metropolitan America: Changing Patterns, New Locations, BROOKINGS INST. CTR. ON URB. AND METRO. POL. SURVEY SERIES, July 2002, at 7 ("Many Hispanics, by choosing the suburbs, are following the familiar path from city neighborhoods to the urban periphery. In addition, some suburban areas are serving as ports of entry for newly arriving immigrants.").
  • 146
    • 8644225819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Rise of New Immigrant Gateways, BROOKINGS INST
    • LIVING CITIES CENSUS, Feb, at
    • Audrey Singer, The Rise of New Immigrant Gateways, BROOKINGS INST. LIVING CITIES CENSUS SERIES, Feb. 2004, at 1.
    • (2004) SERIES , pp. 1
    • Singer, A.1
  • 147
    • 34548360608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 12-15
    • Id. at 12-15.
  • 148
    • 34548320911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Glaeser & Shapiro, supra note 91, at 12-13
    • Glaeser & Shapiro, supra note 91, at 12-13.
  • 149
    • 34548295016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., ROBERT COOTER, THE STRATEGIC CONSTITUTION 36 (2000).
    • See, e.g., ROBERT COOTER, THE STRATEGIC CONSTITUTION 36 (2000).
  • 150
    • 0033478282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Redistribution and the Income of the Median Voter, 98
    • Phillip Nelson, Redistribution and the Income of the Median Voter, 98 PUB. CHOICE 187, 188 (1999).
    • (1999) PUB. CHOICE , vol.187 , pp. 188
    • Nelson, P.1
  • 151
    • 34548304403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Citizens Budget Commission, Fixing New York State's Fiscal Practices 6 (2003), available at http://www.cbcny.org/fixingnys.pdf. New York City residents pay local taxes approximately 72% higher than the national average, and the City's generous Medicaid payments account for approximately one-quarter of that difference. It is perhaps difficult to explain this significant deviation from the average as an indication of local preference.
    • See Citizens Budget Commission, Fixing New York State's Fiscal Practices 6 (2003), available at http://www.cbcny.org/fixingnys.pdf. New York City residents pay local taxes approximately 72% higher than the national average, and the City's generous Medicaid payments account for approximately one-quarter of that difference. It is perhaps difficult to explain this significant deviation from the average as an indication of local preference.
  • 152
    • 34548363382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In theory, it would be possible to address some of these local redistributive needs by collecting redistributive taxes at the central level, but allocating them in accordance with formulas that consider local needs. The combination of central funding and decentralized implementation would simultaneously discourage exit from the redistributive burden and permit response to idiosyncratic local needs. These effects, however, must be balanced against the costs of centrally identifying and satisfying local needs. One would anticipate that the process of collecting data and evaluating competing applications for funding could be so burdensome and error-prone (in part because the process would be susceptible to politicization, especially if the central and decentralized governments were dominated by different political parties) as to offset losses that arise as a result of local emigration to escape the redistributive burden. The central pool would take on many of the features of a commons, si
    • In theory, it would be possible to address some of these local redistributive needs by collecting redistributive taxes at the central level, but allocating them in accordance with formulas that consider local needs. The combination of central funding and decentralized implementation would simultaneously discourage exit from the redistributive burden and permit response to idiosyncratic local needs. These effects, however, must be balanced against the costs of centrally identifying and satisfying local needs. One would anticipate that the process of collecting data and evaluating competing applications for funding could be so burdensome and error-prone (in part because the process would be susceptible to politicization, especially if the central and decentralized governments were dominated by different political parties) as to offset losses that arise as a result of local emigration to escape the redistributive burden. The central pool would take on many of the features of a commons, since localities would have made payments and would have incentives to overutilize the pool, indifferent to the effects of their use on needier localities.
  • 153
    • 34548303333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This effect, of course, may be reduced if the redistributive burden is partially financed through commuter taxes or exactions that are largely paid by nonresidents, e.g, hotel surcharges, taxes on parking fees, and meal taxes
    • This effect, of course, may be reduced if the redistributive burden is partially financed through commuter taxes or exactions that are largely paid by nonresidents, e.g., hotel surcharges, taxes on parking fees, and meal taxes.
  • 154
    • 34548320915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The use of pre-commitment devices to withhold exercise of authority is a traditional way in which governments spur economic growth by attracting firms who might otherwise fear exploitation once they have made location-specific investments. See WILLIAM FISCHEL, THE HOMEVOTER HYPOTHESIS 35 (2001);
    • The use of pre-commitment devices to withhold exercise of authority is a traditional way in which governments spur economic growth by attracting firms who might otherwise fear exploitation once they have made location-specific investments. See WILLIAM FISCHEL, THE HOMEVOTER HYPOTHESIS 35 (2001);
  • 155
    • 84974486152 scopus 로고
    • Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England, 49
    • Douglass C. North & Barry R. Weingast, Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England, 49 J. ECON. HIST. 803, 803-04 (1989).
    • (1989) J. ECON. HIST , vol.803 , pp. 803-804
    • North, D.C.1    Weingast, B.R.2
  • 156
    • 34548336484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is an example of an endowment effect, which occurs when individuals value a good more highly when they own it than when they do not own it. See RICHARD H. THALER, QUASI RATIONAL ECONOMICS 8, 28 1994
    • This is an example of an "endowment effect," which occurs when individuals value a good more highly when they own it than when they do not own it. See RICHARD H. THALER, QUASI RATIONAL ECONOMICS 8, 28 (1994).
  • 157
    • 34548315835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For empirical support of the endowment effect, see, e.g., Daniel Kahneman, Jack L. Knetsch & Richard H. Thaler, Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem, 98 J. POL. ECON. 1325 (1990).
    • For empirical support of the endowment effect, see, e.g., Daniel Kahneman, Jack L. Knetsch & Richard H. Thaler, Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem, 98 J. POL. ECON. 1325 (1990).
  • 158
    • 34548358529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is not to say that endowment effects are infinite, as evidenced by the Boeing Corporation's decision to leave the Seattle area for Chicago. See Boeing Chooses Chicago: Windy City Beats Out Denver and Dallas in Luring Aircraft Maker from Seattle, CNN MONEY, May 10, 2001, reporting decision to move Boeing's corporate headquarters from Seattle to Chicago
    • This is not to say that endowment effects are infinite, as evidenced by the Boeing Corporation's decision to leave the Seattle area for Chicago. See Boeing Chooses Chicago: Windy City Beats Out Denver and Dallas in Luring Aircraft Maker from Seattle, CNN MONEY, May 10, 2001, http://money.cnn.com/2001/05/10/companies/boeing/index.htm (reporting decision to move Boeing's corporate headquarters from Seattle to Chicago).
  • 159
    • 84923946034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FUJITA & THISSE
    • See, e.g., & FUJITA & THISSE,
    • See, e.g., &
  • 160
    • 0040799900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 81, at 5-9 (2002); Glenn Ellison & Edward L. Glaeser, The
    • supra note 81, at 5-9 (2002); Glenn Ellison & Edward L. Glaeser, The Geographic Concentration of Industry: Does Natural Advantage Explain Agglomeration?, 89 AM. ECON. REV. 311, 315-16 (1999).
  • 161
    • 34548301169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See W. Brian Arthur, Industry Location Patterns and the Importance of History, in INCREASING RETURNS AND PATH DEPENDENCE IN THE ECONOMY 49, at 49-50 (1994).
    • See W. Brian Arthur, Industry Location Patterns and the Importance of History, in INCREASING RETURNS AND PATH DEPENDENCE IN THE ECONOMY 49, at 49-50 (1994).
  • 162
    • 34548363389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DREIER ET AL., supra note 50, at 35 (noting presence of 380 specialized geographical clusters in U.S. economy).
    • See DREIER ET AL., supra note 50, at 35 (noting presence of 380 specialized geographical clusters in U.S. economy).
  • 163
    • 34548348430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Quigley, supra note 80, at 130-32;
    • See Quigley, supra note 80, at 130-32;
  • 164
    • 34548323929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SAXENIAN, supra note 83, at 5-6
    • SAXENIAN, supra note 83, at 5-6.
  • 165
    • 34548356466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Andrew F. Haughwout, Infrastructure and Social Welfare in Metropolitan America, 7 FED. RES. BANK N.Y. ECON. POL'Y REV., Dec. 2001, at 1, 5.
    • See Andrew F. Haughwout, Infrastructure and Social Welfare in Metropolitan America, 7 FED. RES. BANK N.Y. ECON. POL'Y REV., Dec. 2001, at 1, 5.
  • 166
    • 34548360614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Edwin Mills reports that nearly half of the one million jobs located in the city of Chicago are in its CBD [central business district] and 200,000 are located within a mile of the periphery of O'Hare Airport. Edwin S. Mills, Earnings Inequality and Central-City Development, FED. RES. BANK N.Y. ECON. POL'Y REV., Sept. 1999, at 133, 135.
    • Edwin Mills reports that "nearly half of the one million jobs located in the city of Chicago are in its CBD [central business district] and 200,000 are located within a mile of the periphery of O'Hare Airport." Edwin S. Mills, Earnings Inequality and Central-City Development, FED. RES. BANK N.Y. ECON. POL'Y REV., Sept. 1999, at 133, 135.
  • 167
    • 0038692160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geography, Industrial Organization, and Agglomeration, 85
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Stuart S. Rosenthal & William C. Strange, Geography, Industrial Organization, and Agglomeration, 85 REV. ECON. & STAT. 377, 378 (2003).
    • (2003) REV. ECON. & STAT , vol.377 , pp. 378
    • Rosenthal, S.S.1    Strange, W.C.2
  • 168
    • 34548303335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Glaeser & Kahn, supra note 15, at 119
    • Glaeser & Kahn, supra note 15, at 119.
  • 169
    • 34548318752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The locality, however, may be more willing to grant concessions in order to attract residents, including firms, if it is able to externalize some of the costs of compensation. For instance, a locality that issues tax-exempt bonds on behalf of a new firm will not suffer tax collection reductions equal to the benefit conferred on the firm, since the tax-exemption typically provides a subsidy from the state and federal governments, rather than from the locality. The tax-exemption on bonds applies to the interest earned by bondholders. That interest is not included in federal income or state income where the bond is issued by a locality within the state of the bondholders' residence, Since few cities have income taxes, the subsidy comes from federal and state sources, not from local ones. This may mean that the locality is engaged in socially inefficient behavior, but the ability to externalize costs does, at least, reduce the negative effects that ex ante compensation would otherwise im
    • The locality, however, may be more willing to grant concessions in order to attract residents, including firms, if it is able to externalize some of the costs of compensation. For instance, a locality that issues tax-exempt bonds on behalf of a new firm will not suffer tax collection reductions equal to the benefit conferred on the firm, since the tax-exemption typically provides a subsidy from the state and federal governments, rather than from the locality. The tax-exemption on bonds applies to the interest earned by bondholders. That interest is not included in federal income or state income (where the bond is issued by a locality within the state of the bondholders' residence). Since few cities have income taxes, the subsidy comes from federal and state sources, not from local ones. This may mean that the locality is engaged in socially inefficient behavior, but the ability to externalize costs does, at least, reduce the negative effects that ex ante compensation would otherwise impose on the ability of localities to attract potential subsidizers of redistributive taxes.
  • 170
    • 34548348431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JAMES M. BUCHANAN & RICHARD A. MUSGRAVE, PUBLIC FINANCE AND PUBLIC CHOICE 179 (2000);
    • See, e.g., JAMES M. BUCHANAN & RICHARD A. MUSGRAVE, PUBLIC FINANCE AND PUBLIC CHOICE 179 (2000);
  • 171
    • 84928438303 scopus 로고
    • Exit as a Constraint on Land Use Exactions: Rethinking the Unconstitutional Conditions Doctrine, 91
    • Vicki Been, "Exit" as a Constraint on Land Use Exactions: Rethinking the Unconstitutional Conditions Doctrine, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 473, 475-78 (1991).
    • (1991) COLUM. L. REV , vol.473 , pp. 475-478
    • Been, V.1
  • 172
    • 34548299195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ALBERT O. HIRSCHMAN, EXIT, VOICE AND LOYALTY (1970).
    • See ALBERT O. HIRSCHMAN, EXIT, VOICE AND LOYALTY (1970).
  • 173
    • 34548301164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 23
    • Id. at 23.
  • 174
    • 34548316674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., CLEAN v. State, 928 P.2d 1054, 1056-58 (Wash. 1996) (describing efforts of supporters of football stadium to obtain local funding); DOUGLAS W. RAE, CITY: URBANISM AND ITS END 349-50 (2003) (detailing efforts of neighborhood group to obtain funding from city agency).
    • See, e.g., CLEAN v. State, 928 P.2d 1054, 1056-58 (Wash. 1996) (describing efforts of supporters of football stadium to obtain local funding); DOUGLAS W. RAE, CITY: URBANISM AND ITS END 349-50 (2003) (detailing efforts of neighborhood group to obtain funding from city agency).
  • 175
    • 34548304415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Poindexter, supra note 45, at 404-05.
    • See Poindexter, supra note 45, at 404-05.
  • 176
    • 23044527209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regionalization and Interlocal Bargains, 76
    • For a litany of reasons to interpret local autonomy broadly, see
    • For a litany of reasons to interpret local autonomy broadly, see Clayton P. Gillette, Regionalization and Interlocal Bargains, 76 N.Y.U. L. REV. 190, 200-01 (2001).
    • (2001) N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.190 , pp. 200-201
    • Gillette, C.P.1
  • 177
    • 34548331241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is some anecdotal evidence of this phenomenon in the experience of New Orleans residents after Hurricane Katrina. Apparently refugees who had been removed to cities that operated more efficiently than New Orleans, and who had never previously questioned New Orleans services, returned to complain about the inferior services that New Orleans had traditionally provided. See Clifford J. Levy, Seeing Life Outside New Orleans Alters Life Inside It, N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 20, 2005 (Week in Review), at 43.
    • There is some anecdotal evidence of this phenomenon in the experience of New Orleans residents after Hurricane Katrina. Apparently refugees who had been removed to cities that operated more efficiently than New Orleans, and who had never previously questioned New Orleans services, returned to complain about the inferior services that New Orleans had traditionally provided. See Clifford J. Levy, Seeing Life Outside New Orleans Alters Life Inside It, N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 20, 2005 (Week in Review), at 43.
  • 178
    • 34548315829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., 19th Street Assocs, v. N.Y., 593 N.E.2d 265 (N.Y. 1992).
    • See, e.g., 19th Street Assocs, v. N.Y., 593 N.E.2d 265 (N.Y. 1992).
  • 179
    • 34548350587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The prohibition on special legislation which is found in several state constitutions does have an analogue in federal constitutional equal protection analysis. Indeed, some of the living wage ordinances that have been limited in scope to particular industries have been challenged on federal equal protection grounds. See, e.g, RUI One Corp. v. City of Berkeley, 371 F.3d 1137, 1154-56 (9th Cir. 2004);
    • The prohibition on special legislation which is found in several state constitutions does have an analogue in federal constitutional equal protection analysis. Indeed, some of the living wage ordinances that have been limited in scope to particular industries have been challenged on federal equal protection grounds. See, e.g., RUI One Corp. v. City of Berkeley, 371 F.3d 1137, 1154-56 (9th Cir. 2004);
  • 180
    • 34548313780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Visiting Homemaker Serv. of Hudson County v. Bd. of Chosen Freeholders, 883 A.2d 1074, 1081-94 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2005). Some federal constitutional clauses, such as the Takings Clause and the Contracts Clause, are perhaps best understood as warding off interest group grabs in the form of raw majoritarianism. See Richard Epstein, Toward a Revitalization of the Contract Clause, 51 U. CHI. L. REV. 703, 716-17 (1984).
    • Visiting Homemaker Serv. of Hudson County v. Bd. of Chosen Freeholders, 883 A.2d 1074, 1081-94 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2005). Some federal constitutional clauses, such as the Takings Clause and the Contracts Clause, are perhaps best understood as warding off interest group grabs in the form of raw majoritarianism. See Richard Epstein, Toward a Revitalization of the Contract Clause, 51 U. CHI. L. REV. 703, 716-17 (1984).
  • 181
    • 34548304404 scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court, 1983 Term - Foreword: The Court and the Economic System, 98
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Frank H. Easterbrook, The Supreme Court, 1983 Term - Foreword: The Court and the Economic System, 98 HARV. L. REV. 4, 15-18 (1984);
    • (1984) HARV. L. REV , vol.4 , pp. 15-18
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 182
    • 41649114050 scopus 로고
    • Interpreting Statutes in the Regulatory State, 103
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Interpreting Statutes in the Regulatory State, 103 HARV. L. REV. 405, 471, 486-87 (1989).
    • (1989) HARV. L. REV , vol.405 , Issue.471 , pp. 486-487
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 183
    • 34548315834 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Sunstein, supra note 122, at 471 (Designed to ensure a kind of deliberative democracy, the constitutional system is hostile to measures that impose burdens or grant benefits merely because of the political power of private groups.).
    • See, e.g., Sunstein, supra note 122, at 471 ("Designed to ensure a kind of deliberative democracy, the constitutional system is hostile to measures that impose burdens or grant benefits merely because of the political power of private groups.").
  • 184
    • 34548299197 scopus 로고
    • Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review?, 101
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Einer R. Elhauge, Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review?, 101 YALE L.J. 31 (1991).
    • (1991) YALE L.J , vol.31
    • Elhauge, E.R.1
  • 185
    • 34548308558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare, e.g., Jonathan R. Macey, Promoting Public-Regarding Legislation Through Statutory Interpretation: An Interest Group Model, 86 COLUM. L. REV. 223, 227 (1986),
    • Compare, e.g., Jonathan R. Macey, Promoting Public-Regarding Legislation Through Statutory Interpretation: An Interest Group Model, 86 COLUM. L. REV. 223, 227 (1986),
  • 186
    • 0040877579 scopus 로고
    • Politics Without Romance: Implications of Public Choice Theory for Statutory Interpretation, 74
    • with
    • with William N. Eskridge, Jr., Politics Without Romance: Implications of Public Choice Theory for Statutory Interpretation, 74 VA. L. REV. 275, 279 (1988),
    • (1988) VA. L. REV , vol.275 , pp. 279
    • Eskridge Jr., W.N.1
  • 187
    • 33947701989 scopus 로고
    • Statutes ' Domains, 50
    • and
    • and Frank H. Easterbrook, Statutes ' Domains, 50 U. CHI. L. REV. 533, 544 (1983),
    • (1983) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.533 , pp. 544
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 188
    • 34548308551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and JERRY L. MASHAW, GREED, CHAOS, AND GOVERNANCE 81-105 (1997).
    • and JERRY L. MASHAW, GREED, CHAOS, AND GOVERNANCE 81-105 (1997).
  • 189
    • 34548323935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 190
    • 0041330679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State Courts and the "Passive Virtues": Rethinking the Judicial Function, 114
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Helen Hershkoff, State Courts and the "Passive Virtues": Rethinking the Judicial Function, 114 HARV. L. REV. 1833, 1928 (2001);
    • (2001) HARV. L. REV. 1833 , pp. 1928
    • Hershkoff, H.1
  • 191
    • 70349473141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Popular Constitutionalism: Toward a Theory of State Constitutional Meanings, 30
    • Douglas S. Reed, Popular Constitutionalism: Toward a Theory of State Constitutional Meanings, 30 RUTGERS L.J. 871, 872-74 (1999).
    • (1999) RUTGERS L.J , vol.871 , pp. 872-874
    • Reed, D.S.1
  • 192
    • 34548299196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hershkoff, supra note 127, at 1922
    • Hershkoff, supra note 127, at 1922.
  • 193
    • 34548316675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reed, supra note 127, at 887-89
    • Reed, supra note 127, at 887-89.
  • 194
    • 34548311657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stephen Ansolabehere & James M. Snyder, Jr., Party Control of State Government and the Distribution of Public Expenditures (August 2003) (manuscript on file with author) (documenting tendency of state legislatures to allocate expenditures to districts aligned with party in power rather than to swing voter districts);
    • See Stephen Ansolabehere & James M. Snyder, Jr., Party Control of State Government and the Distribution of Public Expenditures (August 2003) (manuscript on file with author) (documenting tendency of state legislatures to allocate expenditures to districts aligned with party in power rather than to swing voter districts);
  • 195
    • 34548356471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hershkoff, supra note 127, at 1928
    • Hershkoff, supra note 127, at 1928.
  • 196
    • 34548331247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Frequently, this concern is expressed as a function of logrolling, in which broad legislation is enacted because different provisions appeal to different groups, none of which could otherwise command a majority. Thus, the legislation as a whole is viewed as an amalgam of provisions intended to benefit particular groups rather than the enacting jurisdiction as a whole. For anti-logrolling interpretations of these constitutional provisions, see, for example, Advisory Opinion to the Attorney General Re Adoption, 902 So. 2d 763 (Fla. 2005, single-subject requirement, Sloan v. Wilkins, 608 S.E.2d 579 & n.6 (S.C. 2005, single-subject requirement, Cuyahoga County Veterans Servs. Comm'n v. State, 823 NE.2d 888, 891 (Ohio App. 2004, single-subject requirement, Rants v. Vilsack, 684 N.W.2d 193, 201 (Iowa 2004, line-item veto, Mun. City of S. Bend v. Kimsey, 781 N.E.2d 683 Ind. 2003
    • Frequently, this concern is expressed as a function of logrolling, in which broad legislation is enacted because different provisions appeal to different groups, none of which could otherwise command a majority. Thus, the legislation as a whole is viewed as an amalgam of provisions intended to benefit particular groups rather than the enacting jurisdiction as a whole. For anti-logrolling interpretations of these constitutional provisions, see, for example, Advisory Opinion to the Attorney General Re Adoption, 902 So. 2d 763 (Fla. 2005) (single-subject requirement); Sloan v. Wilkins, 608 S.E.2d 579 & n.6 (S.C. 2005) (single-subject requirement); Cuyahoga County Veterans Servs. Comm'n v. State, 823 NE.2d 888, 891 (Ohio App. 2004) (single-subject requirement); Rants v. Vilsack, 684 N.W.2d 193, 201 (Iowa 2004) (line-item veto); Mun. City of S. Bend v. Kimsey, 781 N.E.2d 683 (Ind. 2003).
  • 197
    • 34548316669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Pennsylvanians Against Gambling Expansion Fund, Inc. v. Commonwealth, 877 A.2d 383, 394 (Pa. 2005) An enormous growth in the corporate form of business organization led to significant concentrations of wealth and the corruption of numerous legislators. . . . Corruption took the form of special laws legislation, logrolling, and arbitrary favoritism and was met with a demand for reform. . . . The Constitutional Convention of 1872-73 was convened to reform corrupt legislative behavior, and to this end, the result was the constitutional strictures contained in Article III.
    • See, e.g., Pennsylvanians Against Gambling Expansion Fund, Inc. v. Commonwealth, 877 A.2d 383, 394 (Pa. 2005) ("An enormous growth in the corporate form of business organization led to significant concentrations of wealth and the corruption of numerous legislators. . . . Corruption took the form of special laws legislation, logrolling, and arbitrary favoritism and was met with a demand for reform. . . . The Constitutional Convention of 1872-73 was convened to reform corrupt legislative behavior, and to this end, the result was the constitutional strictures contained in Article III.
  • 198
    • 34548331245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See R. BRANNING, PENNSYLVANIA CONSTITUTIONAL DEVELOPMENT 37 1960, Thus, while these changes to the Constitution originated during a unique time of fear of tyrannical corporate power and legislative corruption, these mandates retain their value even today by placing certain constitutional limitations on the legislative process
    • See R. BRANNING, PENNSYLVANIA CONSTITUTIONAL DEVELOPMENT 37 (1960). Thus, while these changes to the Constitution originated during a unique time of fear of tyrannical corporate power and legislative corruption, these mandates retain their value even today by placing certain constitutional limitations on the legislative process.").
  • 199
    • 34548350588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See AMDURSKY & GILLETTE, supra note 41, at 90-96
    • See AMDURSKY & GILLETTE, supra note 41, at 90-96.
  • 200
    • 34548304413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, after the Illinois judiciary generated a series of cases that made the legislature the arbiter of whether proposed legislation was invalid as special, the state constitution was amended to provide explicitly that the question of whether the prohibition had been violated was a matter for judicial determination. See III. CONST, art. IV, § 13; Best v. Taylor Mach. Works, 689 N.E.2d 1057, 1070 (Ill. 1997); Bridgewaterv. Hotz, 281 N.E.2d 317, 322 (Ill. 1972).
    • Indeed, after the Illinois judiciary generated a series of cases that made the legislature the arbiter of whether proposed legislation was invalid as "special," the state constitution was amended to provide explicitly that the question of whether the prohibition had been violated was "a matter for judicial determination." See III. CONST, art. IV, § 13; Best v. Taylor Mach. Works, 689 N.E.2d 1057, 1070 (Ill. 1997); Bridgewaterv. Hotz, 281 N.E.2d 317, 322 (Ill. 1972).
  • 201
    • 34548315831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Best, 689 N.E.2d at 1069-70 (quoting legislative history of clause as embodying principle that Governments were not made to make the 'rich richer and the poor poorer,' nor to advance the interest of the few against the many; but that the weak might be protected from the will of the strong; that the poor might enjoy the same rights with the rich); Vill, of Chatham v. County of Sangamon, 814 N.E.2d 216, 225 (Ill. App. Ct. 2004); Allen v. Woodfield Chevrolet, Inc., 773 N.E.2d 1145 (Ill. App. Ct. 2002); Bd. of Trs. of the Judicial Form Retirement Sys. v. Att'y Gen., 132 S.W.3d 770 (Ky. 2003); World Trade Ctr. Taxing Dist. v. All Taxpayers, 894 So. 2d 1185 (La. Ct. App. 2005); Gillis v. Yount, 748 S.W.2d 357 (Ky. 1988); Lyon v. Burton, 5 P.3d 616, 625 (Utah 2000); Shell v. Metro. Life Co., 181 W. Va. 16 (W. Va. 1989); Soo Line R.R. Co. v. Dep't of Transp., 303 N.W.2d 626, 630 (Wis. 1981).
    • See, e.g., Best, 689 N.E.2d at 1069-70 (quoting legislative history of clause as embodying principle that "Governments were not made to make the 'rich richer and the poor poorer,' nor to advance the interest of the few against the many; but that the weak might be protected from the will of the strong; that the poor might enjoy the same rights with the rich"); Vill, of Chatham v. County of Sangamon, 814 N.E.2d 216, 225 (Ill. App. Ct. 2004); Allen v. Woodfield Chevrolet, Inc., 773 N.E.2d 1145 (Ill. App. Ct. 2002); Bd. of Trs. of the Judicial Form Retirement Sys. v. Att'y Gen., 132 S.W.3d 770 (Ky. 2003); World Trade Ctr. Taxing Dist. v. All Taxpayers, 894 So. 2d 1185 (La. Ct. App. 2005); Gillis v. Yount, 748 S.W.2d 357 (Ky. 1988); Lyon v. Burton, 5 P.3d 616, 625 (Utah 2000); Shell v. Metro. Life Co., 181 W. Va. 16 (W. Va. 1989); Soo Line R.R. Co. v. Dep't of Transp., 303 N.W.2d 626, 630 (Wis. 1981).
  • 202
    • 34548358528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Town of Telluride v. Lot Thirty-Four Venture, 3 P.3d 30 (Colo. 2000) (invalidating rent control ordinance under home rule grant); Wagner v. Mayor and Mun. Council of City of Newark, 132 A.2d 794 (N.J. 1957) (invalidating rent control under a home rule grant). Rent control in New Jersey was subsequently upheld in Inganamort v. Borrough of Fort Lee, 293 A.2d 720 (N.J. Super. Ct. 1972), aff'd, 303 A.2d 298 (N.J. 1973).
    • See Town of Telluride v. Lot Thirty-Four Venture, 3 P.3d 30 (Colo. 2000) (invalidating rent control ordinance under home rule grant); Wagner v. Mayor and Mun. Council of City of Newark, 132 A.2d 794 (N.J. 1957) (invalidating rent control under a home rule grant). Rent control in New Jersey was subsequently upheld in Inganamort v. Borrough of Fort Lee, 293 A.2d 720 (N.J. Super. Ct. 1972), aff'd, 303 A.2d 298 (N.J. 1973).
  • 203
    • 34548304414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A similar reversal occurred under the Florida constitutional home rule provision. Compare City of Miami Beach v. Fleetwood Hotel, Inc., 261 So. 2d 801, 801 (Fla. 1972), with City of Miami Beach v. Forte Towers, Inc. 305 So. 2d 764 (Fla. 1974).
    • A similar reversal occurred under the Florida constitutional home rule provision. Compare City of Miami Beach v. Fleetwood Hotel, Inc., 261 So. 2d 801, 801 (Fla. 1972), with City of Miami Beach v. Forte Towers, Inc. 305 So. 2d 764 (Fla. 1974).
  • 204
    • 34548336477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Idaho Bldg. Contractors Ass'n v. City of Coeur d'Alene, 890 P.2d 326 (Idaho 1995) (invalidating impact fees as improper exercise of municipal police powers); E. Diversified Props., Inc. v. Montgomery County, 570 A.2d 850 (Md. 1990) (invalidating impact fees for home rule municipality); Wielepski v. Harford County, 635 A.2d 43 (Md. Ct. Spec. App. 1994), vacated on other grounds, 648 A.2d 192 (Md. 1994) (invalidating impact fees as improper exercise of police powers).
    • See Idaho Bldg. Contractors Ass'n v. City of Coeur d'Alene, 890 P.2d 326 (Idaho 1995) (invalidating impact fees as improper exercise of municipal police powers); E. Diversified Props., Inc. v. Montgomery County, 570 A.2d 850 (Md. 1990) (invalidating impact fees for home rule municipality); Wielepski v. Harford County, 635 A.2d 43 (Md. Ct. Spec. App. 1994), vacated on other grounds, 648 A.2d 192 (Md. 1994) (invalidating impact fees as improper exercise of police powers).
  • 205
    • 34548303329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., New Mexicans for Free Enter, v. City of Santa Fe, 126 P.3d 1149, 1156 (N.M. Ct. App. 2005). In 2005, the New Jersey legislature explicitly permitted political subdivisions to adopt ordinances setting wage rates higher than those established at the state or federal level.
    • See, e.g., New Mexicans for Free Enter, v. City of Santa Fe, 126 P.3d 1149, 1156 (N.M. Ct. App. 2005). In 2005, the New Jersey legislature explicitly permitted political subdivisions to adopt ordinances setting wage rates higher than those established at the state or federal level.
  • 206
    • 34548297097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See N.J. STAT. ANN. § 34:11-56a4 (West 2005, Thus, the court in Visiting Homemaker Services v. Board of Chosen Freeholders, 883 A.2d 1074 N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2005, concluded that the issue of state preemption and local authority had been rendered moot while the appeal was pending
    • See N.J. STAT. ANN. § 34:11-56a4 (West 2005). Thus, the court in Visiting Homemaker Services v. Board of Chosen Freeholders, 883 A.2d 1074 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2005), concluded that the issue of state preemption and local authority had been rendered moot while the appeal was pending.
  • 207
    • 34548315830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is the standard statement of conflict between state laws and local ordinances. See Miller v. Fabius Twp. Bd, 114 N.W.2d 205 Mich. 1962
    • This is the standard statement of conflict between state laws and local ordinances. See Miller v. Fabius Twp. Bd., 114 N.W.2d 205 (Mich. 1962).
  • 208
    • 34548363386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RUI One Corp. v. City of Berkeley, 371 F.3d 1137, 1172 (9th Cir. 2004) (Bybee, J., dissenting) (quoting Charles B. Hochman, The Supreme Court and the Constitutionality of Retroactive Legislation, 73 HARV. L. REV. 692, 693 (1960)).
    • See RUI One Corp. v. City of Berkeley, 371 F.3d 1137, 1172 (9th Cir. 2004) (Bybee, J., dissenting) (quoting Charles B. Hochman, The Supreme Court and the Constitutionality of Retroactive Legislation, 73 HARV. L. REV. 692, 693 (1960)).
  • 209
    • 34548308559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Elhauge, supra note 124 summarizing arguments to be skeptical of judicial intervention
    • See generally Elhauge, supra note 124 (summarizing arguments to be skeptical of judicial intervention).
  • 210
    • 34548336482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion supra Part I.A.
    • See discussion supra Part I.A.
  • 211
    • 34548360613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For Olson, a group was privileged, in that it could easily organize into an effective lobbying group, if each of its members, or at least one of them, has an incentive to see that the collective good is provided, even if that member must bear the full cost of providing it. See MANCUR OLSON, THE LOGIC OF COLLECTIVE ACTION 49-50 (1971).
    • For Olson, a group was "privileged," in that it could easily organize into an effective lobbying group, if each of its members, or at least one of them, has an incentive to see that the collective good is provided, even if that member must bear the full cost of providing it. See MANCUR OLSON, THE LOGIC OF COLLECTIVE ACTION 49-50 (1971).
  • 212
    • 34548303332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For further analysis of the interplay among different pieces of legislation or different sections of the same legislation, see Clayton P. Gillette, Expropriation and Institutional Design in State and Local Government Law, 80 VA. L. REV. 625, 657-70 1994, discussion of single-subject requirements
    • For further analysis of the interplay among different pieces of legislation or different sections of the same legislation, see Clayton P. Gillette, Expropriation and Institutional Design in State and Local Government Law, 80 VA. L. REV. 625, 657-70 (1994) (discussion of single-subject requirements).
  • 213
    • 0347315064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taming Leviathan: Will the Centralizing Tide of the Twentieth Century Continue into the Twenty-First?, 74
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Robert C. Ellickson, Taming Leviathan: Will the Centralizing Tide of the Twentieth Century Continue into the Twenty-First?, 74 S. CAL. L. REV. 101, 114 (2000);
    • (2000) S. CAL. L. REV , vol.101 , pp. 114
    • Ellickson, R.C.1
  • 214
    • 22444455705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pre dicting When the Uniform Law Process Will Fail: Article 9, Capture, and the Race-to-the-Bottom, 83
    • Edward J. Janger, Pre dicting When the Uniform Law Process Will Fail: Article 9, Capture, and the Race-to-the-Bottom, 83 IOWA L. REV. 569, 586 (1998).
    • (1998) IOWA L. REV , vol.569 , pp. 586
    • Janger, E.J.1
  • 215
    • 34548306487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JERRY MASHAW, GREED, CHAOS, AND GOVERNANCE 94-95 (1997).
    • JERRY MASHAW, GREED, CHAOS, AND GOVERNANCE 94-95 (1997).
  • 216
    • 34548301166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent court decisions have been more receptive to claims that municipal expenditures on behalf of firms satisfy a public purpose. For a review of the history and evidence of that transition in the context of publicly financing sports stadiums, see, for example, Poe v. Hillsborough County, 695 So. 2d 672 (Fla. 1997, Haney v. Dev. Auth. of Bremen, 519 S.E.2d 665 (Ga. 1999, Peacock v. Shinn, 533 S.E.2d 842 (N.C. Ct. App. 2000, appeal dismissed, 546 S.E.2d 110 (N.C. 2000, Ragsdale v. City of Memphis, 70 S.W.3d 56 (Tenn. Ct. App. 2001, Citizens for More Important Things v. King County, 932 P.2d 135 (Wash. 1997, CLEAN v. State, 928 P.2d 1054 (Wash. 1996, Libertarian Party of Wisconsin v. State, 546 N.W.2d 424 Wis. 1996
    • Recent court decisions have been more receptive to claims that municipal expenditures on behalf of firms satisfy a public purpose. For a review of the history and evidence of that transition in the context of publicly financing sports stadiums, see, for example, Poe v. Hillsborough County, 695 So. 2d 672 (Fla. 1997); Haney v. Dev. Auth. of Bremen, 519 S.E.2d 665 (Ga. 1999); Peacock v. Shinn, 533 S.E.2d 842 (N.C. Ct. App. 2000), appeal dismissed, 546 S.E.2d 110 (N.C. 2000); Ragsdale v. City of Memphis, 70 S.W.3d 56 (Tenn. Ct. App. 2001); Citizens for More Important Things v. King County, 932 P.2d 135 (Wash. 1997); CLEAN v. State, 928 P.2d 1054 (Wash. 1996); Libertarian Party of Wisconsin v. State, 546 N.W.2d 424 (Wis. 1996).
  • 217
    • 34548323930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., WDW Props, v. City of Sumter, 535 S,E.2d 631 (S.C. 2000) (suit by business to prevent subsidy to potential competitor).
    • See, e.g., WDW Props, v. City of Sumter, 535 S,E.2d 631 (S.C. 2000) (suit by business to prevent subsidy to potential competitor).
  • 218
    • 34548323931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Glaeser & Kahn, supra note 15, at 119
    • Glaeser & Kahn, supra note 15, at 119.
  • 219
    • 34548313781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The U.S. Census Bureau reports the following statistics for the November 1998 selection: Figure Presented
    • The U.S. Census Bureau reports the following statistics for the November 1998 selection: Figure Presented
  • 220
    • 34548295013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, VOTING AND REGISTRATION IN THE ELECTION OF NOVEMBER 1998, tbl. 9 (2000), available at http://www.census.gov/population/ socdemo/voting/cps 998/tab09.txt.
    • U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, VOTING AND REGISTRATION IN THE ELECTION OF NOVEMBER 1998, tbl. 9 (2000), available at http://www.census.gov/population/ socdemo/voting/cps 998/tab09.txt.
  • 221
    • 34548303330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Poindexter, supra note 45, at 402-03 (describing church-based community organization lobbying on behalf of working poor).
    • See Poindexter, supra note 45, at 402-03 (describing church-based community organization lobbying on behalf of working poor).
  • 222
    • 34548316670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bd. of Chosen Freeholders, 883 A.2d 1074 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2005) (applying living wage ordinance only to industry to which sponsoring union members belonged); Erik Eckholm, City by City, an Antipoverty Group Plants Seeds of Change
    • See, e.g, June 26, at
    • See, e.g., Visiting Homemaker Servs. v. Bd. of Chosen Freeholders, 883 A.2d 1074 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2005) (applying living wage ordinance only to industry to which sponsoring union members belonged); Erik Eckholm, City by City, an Antipoverty Group Plants Seeds of Change, N.Y. TIMES, June 26, 2006, at A12.
    • (2006) N.Y. TIMES
    • Visiting Homemaker Servs1
  • 223
    • 0347607189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Monitoring the Mayor: Will the New Information Technologies Make Local Officials More Responsible?, 32
    • See
    • See Robert C. Ellickson, Monitoring the Mayor: Will the New Information Technologies Make Local Officials More Responsible?, 32 URB. LAW. 391, 396 (2000).
    • (2000) URB. LAW , vol.391 , pp. 396
    • Ellickson, R.C.1
  • 225
    • 0036997622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Districting and Government Overspending, 110
    • Reza Baqir, Districting and Government Overspending, 110 J. POL. ECON. 1318 (2002).
    • (2002) J. POL. ECON , vol.1318
    • Baqir, R.1
  • 226
    • 34548318757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At least this appears to be the result to the extent that malign redistribution correlates with inefficient expenditures. Robert Inman concludes from earlier studies, which indicate that council-only local governments spend more than local governments with mayors who can constrain excess spending, that each extra dollar of council-only spending generates only 33 cents in net economic benefits. See Robert P. Inman, Financing Cities 26-27 Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 11203, 2005, available at
    • At least this appears to be the result to the extent that malign redistribution correlates with inefficient expenditures. Robert Inman concludes from earlier studies, which indicate that council-only local governments spend more than local governments with mayors who can constrain excess spending, that each extra dollar of council-only spending generates only 33 cents in net economic benefits. See Robert P. Inman, Financing Cities 26-27 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 11203, 2005), available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w11203.
  • 227
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 157-59;
    • See infra text accompanying notes 157-59;
    • See infra
  • 228
    • 0347988087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Sheryll D. Cashin, Federalism, Welfare Reform, and the Minority Poor: Accounting for the Tyranny of State Majorities, 99 COLUM. L. REV. 552, 625 &n.313 (1999).
    • see also Sheryll D. Cashin, Federalism, Welfare Reform, and the Minority Poor: Accounting for the Tyranny of State Majorities, 99 COLUM. L. REV. 552, 625 &n.313 (1999).
  • 229
    • 34548336478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrew Haughwout & Robert P. Inman, Should Suburbs Help Their Central City?, in BROOKINGS-WHARTON PAPERS ON URBAN AFFAIRS, 2002, at 45, 60-62.
    • Andrew Haughwout & Robert P. Inman, Should Suburbs Help Their Central City?, in BROOKINGS-WHARTON PAPERS ON URBAN AFFAIRS, 2002, at 45, 60-62.
  • 230
    • 0000530499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Teachers ' Unions Affect Education Production, 11
    • Caroline Minter Hoxby, How Teachers ' Unions Affect Education Production, 11 Q.J. ECON. 671 (1996).
    • (1996) Q.J. ECON , vol.671
    • Minter Hoxby, C.1
  • 231
    • 34548311655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An earlier study, Randall W. Eberts & Joe A. Stone, Teacher Unions and the Productivity of Public Schools, 40 INDUS. & LAB. REL. REV. 354 1987, found that unionization increased student productivity for average students, but reduced it for significantly above- or below-average students. That study, however, did not consider any additional financial costs related to unionization. Thus, it is more difficult to estimate the optimality of expenditures under that study
    • An earlier study, Randall W. Eberts & Joe A. Stone, Teacher Unions and the Productivity of Public Schools, 40 INDUS. & LAB. REL. REV. 354 (1987), found that unionization increased student productivity for average students, but reduced it for significantly above- or below-average students. That study, however, did not consider any additional financial costs related to unionization. Thus, it is more difficult to estimate the optimality of expenditures under that study.
  • 232
    • 21844497458 scopus 로고
    • Fiscal Illusion at the Local Level: Empirical Evidence for the Flemish Municipalities, 80
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Bruno Heyndels & Carine Smolders, Fiscal Illusion at the Local Level: Empirical Evidence for the Flemish Municipalities, 80 PUB. CHOICE 325 (1994);
    • (1994) PUB. CHOICE , vol.325
    • Heyndels, B.1    Smolders, C.2
  • 233
    • 0040635217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geoffrey K. Turnbull, The Overspending and Flypaper Effects of Fiscal Illusion: Theory and Empirical Evidence, 44 J. URB. ECON. 1 (1998).
    • Geoffrey K. Turnbull, The Overspending and Flypaper Effects of Fiscal Illusion: Theory and Empirical Evidence, 44 J. URB. ECON. 1 (1998).
  • 234
    • 34548318759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York City's budget for the 2007 Fiscal Year runs 711 pages, with 3975 pages of supporting schedules. The capital budget runs an additional 546 pages. See The City of New York May 2006 Executive Budget, Fiscal Year 2007 Home Page, http://home2.nyc.gov/html/omb/html/finplan05_06.html.
    • New York City's budget for the 2007 Fiscal Year runs 711 pages, with 3975 pages of supporting schedules. The capital budget runs an additional 546 pages. See The City of New York May 2006 Executive Budget, Fiscal Year 2007 Home Page, http://home2.nyc.gov/html/omb/html/finplan05_06.html.
  • 235
    • 34548304406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bob Ellickson, for instance, cites to articles in the New Haven Register, a newspaper in New Haven, Connecticut, that disclose continual grants to private organizations that purport to serve low-income residents. See Ellickson, supra note 153, at 396-97 n.8.
    • Bob Ellickson, for instance, cites to articles in the New Haven Register, a newspaper in New Haven, Connecticut, that disclose continual grants to private organizations that purport to serve low-income residents. See Ellickson, supra note 153, at 396-97 n.8.
  • 236
    • 34548313782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., People ex rel. Korzen v. Brewster, 304 N.E.2d 46 (Ill. App. Ct. 1973).
    • See, e.g., People ex rel. Korzen v. Brewster, 304 N.E.2d 46 (Ill. App. Ct. 1973).
  • 237
    • 0042693141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Disaggregating Constitutional Torts, 110
    • See
    • See John C. Jeffries, Jr., Disaggregating Constitutional Torts, 110 YALE L.J. 259, 268-69 (2000).
    • (2000) YALE L.J , vol.259 , pp. 268-269
    • Jeffries Jr., J.C.1
  • 238
    • 0347450521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Government Pay: Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs, 67
    • See
    • See Daryl J. Levinson, Making Government Pay: Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 345,347-48 (2000).
    • (2000) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.345 , pp. 347-348
    • Levinson, D.J.1
  • 239
    • 0034259263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alberto Alesina, Reza Baqir & William Easterly, Redistributive Public Employment, 48 J. URB. ECON. 219, 220 (2000).
    • Alberto Alesina, Reza Baqir & William Easterly, Redistributive Public Employment, 48 J. URB. ECON. 219, 220 (2000).
  • 240
    • 34548320914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recall that my definition of benign does not require that redistribution be efficient or supported by the majority of municipal voters
    • Recall that my definition of "benign" does not require that redistribution be efficient or supported by the majority of municipal voters.
  • 241
    • 25844493602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Alesina, Baqir & Easterly, supra note 166; Edward L. Glaeser & Andrei Shleifer, The Curley Effect: The Economics of Shaping the Electorate, 21 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 1 (2005).
    • See Alesina, Baqir & Easterly, supra note 166; Edward L. Glaeser & Andrei Shleifer, The Curley Effect: The Economics of Shaping the Electorate, 21 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 1 (2005).
  • 242
    • 34548315833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Stephen Coate & Stephen Morris, On the Form of Transfers to Special Interests, 103 J. POL. ECON. 1210 (1995) (arguing that politicians may prefer inefficient redistribution with concealed costs in order to avoid detection where same redistribution could be more efficiently achieved, but only with more transparent subsidy);
    • See, e.g., Stephen Coate & Stephen Morris, On the Form of Transfers to Special Interests, 103 J. POL. ECON. 1210 (1995) (arguing that politicians may prefer inefficient redistribution with concealed costs in order to avoid detection where same redistribution could be more efficiently achieved, but only with more transparent subsidy);
  • 243
    • 3142773799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Center for Econ. Pol. Research, Discussion Paper No. 3205, available at
    • James A. Robinson & Thierry Verdier, The Political Economy of Clientelism (Center for Econ. Pol. Research, Discussion Paper No. 3205, 2002), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 303185.
    • (2002) The Political Economy of Clientelism
    • Robinson, J.A.1    Verdier, T.2
  • 244
    • 84894689913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§ 12101-12112b 2000
    • 42 U.S.C. §§ 12101-12112b (2000).
    • 42 U.S.C
  • 245
    • 0347507805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jeffries, supra note 164, at 268; Julie A. Roin, Reconceptualizing Unfunded Mandates and Other Regulations, 93 Nw. U. L. REV. 351, 353 n.6 (1999).
    • See Jeffries, supra note 164, at 268; Julie A. Roin, Reconceptualizing Unfunded Mandates and Other Regulations, 93 Nw. U. L. REV. 351, 353 n.6 (1999).
  • 246
    • 34548356470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pennell v. San Jose, 485 U.S. 1, 15-24 (1988) (Scalia, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
    • Pennell v. San Jose, 485 U.S. 1, 15-24 (1988) (Scalia, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 247
    • 34548304405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 22-23 Scalia, J, concurring in part and dissenting in part, The politically attractive feature of regulation is not that it permits wealth transfers to be achieved that could not be achieved otherwise; but rather that it permits them to be achieved 'off budget, with relative invisibility and thus relative immunity from normal democratic processes. San Jose might, for example, have accomplished something like the result here by simply raising the real estate tax upon rental properties and using the additional revenues thus acquired to pay part of the rents of 'hardship' tenants. It seems to me doubtful, however, whether the citizens of San Jose would allow funds in the municipal treasury, from wherever derived, to be distributed to a family of four with income as high as $ 32,400 a year-the generous maximum necessary to qualify automatically as a 'hardship' tenant under the rental ordinance. The voters might well see other, more pressing, social priorities
    • Id. at 22-23 (Scalia, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part) ("The politically attractive feature of regulation is not that it permits wealth transfers to be achieved that could not be achieved otherwise; but rather that it permits them to be achieved 'off budget,' with relative invisibility and thus relative immunity from normal democratic processes. San Jose might, for example, have accomplished something like the result here by simply raising the real estate tax upon rental properties and using the additional revenues thus acquired to pay part of the rents of 'hardship' tenants. It seems to me doubtful, however, whether the citizens of San Jose would allow funds in the municipal treasury, from wherever derived, to be distributed to a family of four with income as high as $ 32,400 a year-the generous maximum necessary to qualify automatically as a 'hardship' tenant under the rental ordinance. The voters might well see other, more pressing, social priorities. And of course what $ 32,400-a-year renters can acquire through spurious 'regulation,' other groups can acquire as well. Once the door is opened it is not unreasonable to expect price regulations requiring private businesses to give special discounts to senior citizens (no matter how affluent), or to students, the handicapped, or war veterans. Subsidies for these groups may well be a good idea, but because of the operation of the Takings Clause our governmental system has required them to be applied, in general, through the process of taxing and spending, where both economic effects and competing priorities are more evident.");
  • 248
    • 0042602437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Constitution of Collaboration: Protecting Fundamental Values with Second-Look Rules of Interbranch Dialogue, 42
    • see also
    • see also Dan T. Coenen, A Constitution of Collaboration: Protecting Fundamental Values with Second-Look Rules of Interbranch Dialogue, 42 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1575, 1651 (2001).
    • (2001) WM. & MARY L. REV , vol.1575 , pp. 1651
    • Coenen, D.T.1
  • 249
    • 84926273119 scopus 로고
    • Interstate Exploitation and Judicial Intervention, 69
    • Saul Levmore, Interstate Exploitation and Judicial Intervention, 69 VA. L. REV. 563, 584 (1983);
    • (1983) VA. L. REV , vol.563 , pp. 584
    • Levmore, S.1
  • 250
    • 34548304409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Gillette, supra note 31, at 473-74
    • see also Gillette, supra note 31, at 473-74.
  • 251
    • 34548348432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pennell, 485 U.S. at 23.
    • Pennell, 485 U.S. at 23.
  • 252
    • 34548356468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 253
    • 34548360612 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 22-23
    • Id. at 22-23.
  • 254
    • 34548301167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These claims have been forcefully made in the context of unfunded mandates in Roin, supra note 171 demonstrating that unfunded mandates may be superior to other forms of regulation
    • These claims have been forcefully made in the context of unfunded mandates in Roin, supra note 171 (demonstrating that unfunded mandates may be superior to other forms of regulation).
  • 255
    • 34548303331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is not to say that any process in which all are represented will necessarily pass muster. If all municipal residents (except landlords) approved the rent control ordinance, I take it that Justice Scalia could still object on the grounds that it constituted a raw majoritarian grab that violated any of a variety of legal constraints, ranging from state uniformity of taxation clauses to the Takings Clause
    • This is not to say that any process in which all are represented will necessarily pass muster. If all municipal residents (except landlords) approved the rent control ordinance, I take it that Justice Scalia could still object on the grounds that it constituted a raw majoritarian grab that violated any of a variety of legal constraints, ranging from state uniformity of taxation clauses to the Takings Clause.
  • 256
    • 34548301168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Roin, supra note 171, at 357-58
    • See Roin, supra note 171, at 357-58.
  • 257
    • 34548304412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • may be able to pass some of the increased costs to consumers of their goods and services. But unless they can do so costlessly and with certainty, they will continue to bear some of the redistributive burden of regulation
    • Id. at 358. Employers may be able to pass some of the increased costs to consumers of their goods and services. But unless they can do so costlessly and with certainty, they will continue to bear some of the redistributive burden of regulation.
    • at 358. Employers
  • 258
  • 259
    • 34548308557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Visiting Homemaker Servs. v. Bd. of Chosen Freeholders, 883 A.2d 1074, 1077 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2005).
    • See Visiting Homemaker Servs. v. Bd. of Chosen Freeholders, 883 A.2d 1074, 1077 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2005).
  • 261
    • 34548295015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Deanna Bellandi, Chicago Council Passes 'Living Wage'Act, WASHINGTONPOST.COM, July 27, 2006, http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2006/07/27/AR200607 2700197. html.
    • See Deanna Bellandi, Chicago Council Passes 'Living Wage'Act, WASHINGTONPOST.COM, July 27, 2006, http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2006/07/27/AR2006072700197. html.
  • 262
    • 34548336479 scopus 로고
    • Contractors Ass'n v
    • See e.g, P, Idaho
    • See e.g., Idaho Bldg. Contractors Ass'n v. City of Coeur d'Alene, 890 P.2d 326 (Idaho 1995);
    • (1995) City of Coeur d'Alene , vol.890
    • Bldg, I.1
  • 263
    • 34548331248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Jersey Builders Ass'n v. Mayor and Twp. Comm. of Bernards Twp., 528 A.2d 555 (N.J. 1987).
    • New Jersey Builders Ass'n v. Mayor and Twp. Comm. of Bernards Twp., 528 A.2d 555 (N.J. 1987).
  • 264
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 170 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 170 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 265
    • 34548318761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BERKELEY MUN. CODE § 13.27.070(H) (2006).
    • See BERKELEY MUN. CODE § 13.27.070(H) (2006).
  • 266
    • 34548350589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I thank David Barron for this suggestion
    • I thank David Barron for this suggestion.
  • 267
    • 23044518488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Localism, Self-interest, and the Tyranny of the Favored Quarter: Addressing the Barriers to New Regionalism, 88
    • See
    • See Sheryll D. Cashin, Localism, Self-interest, and the Tyranny of the Favored Quarter: Addressing the Barriers to New Regionalism, 88 GEO. L.J. 1985 (2000);
    • (2000) GEO. L.J. 1985
    • Cashin, S.D.1
  • 268
    • 34548311656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gillette, supra note 119
    • Gillette, supra note 119.
  • 269
    • 84859864508 scopus 로고
    • Constitutional Municipal Home Rule Since the AMA (NLC) Model, 17
    • See
    • See Kenneth Vanlandingham, Constitutional Municipal Home Rule Since the AMA (NLC) Model, 17 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1 (1975).
    • (1975) WM. & MARY L. REV , vol.1
    • Vanlandingham, K.1
  • 270
    • 34548360609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Santa Monica City Council Meeting Ordinance 07-10-01, available at, November referendum
    • See Santa Monica City Council Meeting Ordinance 07-10-01, available at http://santamonica.org/cityclerk/Election2002/text_Minwage. htm. The proposal was initially adopted by the City Council, but defeated in a November 2002 referendum.
    • (2002) The proposal was initially adopted by the City Council, but defeated in a
  • 271
    • 34548329193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See New Mexicans for Free Enter, v. City of Santa Fe, 126 P.3d 1149, 1156 (N.M. Ct. App. 2005).
    • See New Mexicans for Free Enter, v. City of Santa Fe, 126 P.3d 1149, 1156 (N.M. Ct. App. 2005).
  • 272
    • 34548316673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ace Rent-A-Car, Inc. v. Indianapolis Airport Auth., 612 N.E.2d 1104 (Ind. Ct. App. 1993) (construing exaction on car rental revenues as a user fee, not a tax);
    • See, e.g., Ace Rent-A-Car, Inc. v. Indianapolis Airport Auth., 612 N.E.2d 1104 (Ind. Ct. App. 1993) (construing exaction on car rental revenues as a user fee, not a tax);
  • 273
    • 34548331249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • City of New York v. State, 730 N.E.2d 920 (N.Y. 2000) (holding that tax on nonresident commuters was not a fee for services provided by the city);
    • City of New York v. State, 730 N.E.2d 920 (N.Y. 2000) (holding that tax on nonresident commuters was not a "fee" for services provided by the city);
  • 274
    • 34548356469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bold Corp. v. County of Lancaster, 801 A.2d 469 (Pa. 2002) (holding that a hotel room rental tax was not invalid where benefits of tax were commensurate with burdens);
    • Bold Corp. v. County of Lancaster, 801 A.2d 469 (Pa. 2002) (holding that a hotel room rental tax was not invalid where benefits of tax were commensurate with burdens);
  • 275
    • 34548331246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cavanaugh v. Town of Narragansett, No. WC 91-0496, 1997 R.I. Super. LEXIS 21 (R.I. Super. Ct. Oct. 10, 1997) (construing higher exaction required of nonresidents for beach access to be a fee, not a tax). The very existence of these cases, of course, reveals that sometimes nonresident litigants can be found who object. That same phenomenon suggests that nonresidents may be virtually represented by residents, such as restaurant owners and garage owners, whose business depends on attracting nonresidents.
    • Cavanaugh v. Town of Narragansett, No. WC 91-0496, 1997 R.I. Super. LEXIS 21 (R.I. Super. Ct. Oct. 10, 1997) (construing higher exaction required of nonresidents for beach access to be a fee, not a tax). The very existence of these cases, of course, reveals that sometimes nonresident litigants can be found who object. That same phenomenon suggests that nonresidents may be virtually represented by residents, such as restaurant owners and garage owners, whose business depends on attracting nonresidents.
  • 276
    • 34548308554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Commuter Tax and the Fiscal Cost of Commuters in New York City, 25 ST
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Howard Chemick & Olesya Tkacheva, The Commuter Tax and the Fiscal Cost of Commuters in New York City, 25 ST. TAX NOTES 451 (2002);
    • (2002) TAX NOTES , vol.451
    • Chemick, H.1    Tkacheva, O.2
  • 277
    • 34548363388 scopus 로고
    • Are Nonresidents Contributing Their Share to Core City Revenues?, 48
    • R.S. Smith, Are Nonresidents Contributing Their Share to Core City Revenues?, 48 LAND ECON. 240 (1972).
    • (1972) LAND ECON , vol.240
    • Smith, R.S.1
  • 278
    • 34548329192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JON ELSTER, LOCAL JUSTICE: HOW INSTITUTIONS ALLOCATE SCARCE GOODS AND NECESSARY BURDENS (1992). For my purposes, local justice involves decisions about allocation of a particular resource at a highly decentralized level, without attention to how the decision in a particular case fits into a more centrally determined decision about allocation of multiple resources, any of which may be traded against another.
    • See JON ELSTER, LOCAL JUSTICE: HOW INSTITUTIONS ALLOCATE SCARCE GOODS AND NECESSARY BURDENS (1992). For my purposes, local justice involves decisions about allocation of a particular resource at a highly decentralized level, without attention to how the decision in a particular case fits into a more centrally determined decision about allocation of multiple resources, any of which may be traded against another.
  • 279
    • 34548308555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nevertheless, the constraints of public purpose requirements have loosened considerably in recent years. See, e.g., Peacock v. Shinn, 533 S.E.2d 842 (N.C. Ct. App. 2000) (upholding payment of operating expenses for professional basketball team playing at municipally funded arena);
    • Nevertheless, the constraints of public purpose requirements have loosened considerably in recent years. See, e.g., Peacock v. Shinn, 533 S.E.2d 842 (N.C. Ct. App. 2000) (upholding payment of "operating expenses" for professional basketball team playing at municipally funded arena);
  • 280
    • 34548308556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WDW Props, v. City of Sumter, 535 S.E.2d 631 (S.C. 2000) (upholding financing for retail and commercial development);
    • WDW Props, v. City of Sumter, 535 S.E.2d 631 (S.C. 2000) (upholding financing for retail and commercial development);
  • 281
    • 34548315832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CLEAN v. State, 928 P.2d 1054 (Wash. 1996) (upholding public financing of baseball stadium).
    • CLEAN v. State, 928 P.2d 1054 (Wash. 1996) (upholding public financing of baseball stadium).
  • 282
    • 34548313784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • THE FEDERALIST NO. 10, at 62-70 (James Madison) (Edward Bourne ed., 1937).
    • THE FEDERALIST NO. 10, at 62-70 (James Madison) (Edward Bourne ed., 1937).
  • 283
    • 34548316672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gillette, supra note 46, at 996-97
    • See Gillette, supra note 46, at 996-97.
  • 284
    • 34548304411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See COOTER, supra note 98, at 185-88
    • See COOTER, supra note 98, at 185-88.
  • 285
    • 34548295014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I ignore for purposes of this example the difficult issue of what it would mean for the rich and the poor to receive pro rata shares of the budget. That is, should the budget be allocated according to tax revenues paid (so that the wealthy receive a greater than per capita share of municipal services) or should the budget be allocated according to need so that the poor receive a greater than per capita share of municipal services, I assume only that the parties have agreed on the allocation that exists
    • I ignore for purposes of this example the difficult issue of what it would mean for the rich and the poor to receive "pro rata" shares of the budget. That is, should the budget be allocated according to tax revenues paid (so that the wealthy receive a greater than per capita share of municipal services) or should the budget be allocated according to need (so that the poor receive a greater than per capita share of municipal services). I assume only that the parties have agreed on the allocation that exists.
  • 286
    • 34548308553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., City of East Orange v. Bd. of Water Comm'rs, 191 A.2d 749, 752-56 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 1963) (invalidating municipal lease of 151 acres for golf course where rent was nominal and city agreed to pay first $1500 of property taxes).
    • See, e.g., City of East Orange v. Bd. of Water Comm'rs, 191 A.2d 749, 752-56 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 1963) (invalidating municipal lease of 151 acres for golf course where rent was nominal and city agreed to pay first $1500 of property taxes).
  • 287
    • 34548323933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Palm Beach County Water Control Dist. v. State, 604 So. 2d 440 (Fla. 1992).
    • N. Palm Beach County Water Control Dist. v. State, 604 So. 2d 440 (Fla. 1992).
  • 288
    • 34548318760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ELSTER, supra note 196, at 189-90
    • See ELSTER, supra note 196, at 189-90.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.