-
1
-
-
84972159336
-
"Rationalist Explanations for War"
-
(Summer)
-
James Fearon, "Rationalist Explanations for War," International Organization 49 (Summer 1995);
-
(1995)
International Organization
, vol.49
-
-
Fearon, J.1
-
3
-
-
0000510636
-
"Strategic Information Transmission"
-
For the seminal study on information transmission, see (November)
-
For the seminal study on information transmission, see Vincent P. Crawford and Joel Sobel, "Strategic Information Transmission," Econometrica 50 (November 1982);
-
(1982)
Econometrica
, vol.50
-
-
Crawford, V.P.1
Sobel, J.2
-
4
-
-
0040600426
-
"Learning in Equilibrium Models of Arbitration"
-
for an example that parallels mediation, see (December)
-
for an example that parallels mediation, see Robert Gibbons, "Learning in Equilibrium Models of Arbitration," American Economic Review 78 (December 1988).
-
(1988)
American Economic Review
, vol.78
-
-
Gibbons, R.1
-
5
-
-
0142230571
-
"Which Side Are You On? Bias, Credibility, and Mediation"
-
(October)
-
Andrew Kydd, "Which Side Are You On? Bias, Credibility, and Mediation," American Journal of Political Science 47 (October 2003).
-
(2003)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.47
-
-
Kydd, A.1
-
6
-
-
0033426706
-
"Rigor or Rigor Mortis? Rational Choice and Security Studies"
-
(Spring)
-
Stephen A Walt, "Rigor or Rigor Mortis? Rational Choice and Security Studies," International Security 23 (Spring 1999).
-
(1999)
International Security
, vol.23
-
-
Walt, S.M.1
-
8
-
-
0004003394
-
-
(Princeton: Princeton University Press,) identify commitment problems along with asymmetric information as a root cause of war. Walter empirically evaluates the commitment problem argument in the context of conflict management
-
and Powell (fn. 1) identify commitment problems along with asymmetric information as a root cause of war. Walter empirically evaluates the commitment problem argument in the context of conflict management.
-
(1999)
In the Shadow of Power: States and Strategies in International Politics
-
-
Powell, R.1
-
9
-
-
0031489756
-
"The Critical Barrier to Civil War Settlement"
-
See (Summer)
-
See Barbara Walter, "The Critical Barrier to Civil War Settlement," International Organization 51 (Summer 1997);
-
(1997)
International Organization
, vol.51
-
-
Walter, B.1
-
12
-
-
33644891871
-
"War as a Commitment Problem"
-
For a comprehensive treatment of commitment problems, see (Winter)
-
For a comprehensive treatment of commitment problems, see Robert Powell, "War as a Commitment Problem," International Organization 60 (Winter 2006).
-
(2006)
International Organization
, vol.60
-
-
Powell, R.1
-
14
-
-
33644891871
-
-
(Princeton: Princeton University Press,) Uncertainty about the other party's resolve stems from private information about a number of important issues, including their war-fighting capabilities, their attitudes toward risk, the degree to which they value the issue in question, their patience, and their willingness to incur various costs. This study assumes that uncertainty is the result of private information concerning the disputants' costs for fighting, which is also a measure of resolve
-
Powell (fn. 1). Uncertainty about the other party's resolve stems from private information about a number of important issues, including their war-fighting capabilities, their attitudes toward risk, the degree to which they value the issue in question, their patience, and their willingness to incur various costs. This study assumes that uncertainty is the result of private information concerning the disputants' costs for fighting, which is also a measure of resolve. 12 For a comprehensive treatment of commitment problems, see Robert Powell, "War as a Commitment Problem," International Organization 60 (Winter 2006).
-
(1999)
In the Shadow of Power: States and Strategies in International Politics
-
-
Powell, R.1
-
15
-
-
84965936657
-
"International Mediation: A Study of Incidence, Strategies, and Conditions of Successful Outcomes"
-
(September)
-
Jacob Bercovitch, "International Mediation: A Study of Incidence, Strategies, and Conditions of Successful Outcomes," Cooperation and Conflict 21 (September 1986);
-
(1986)
Cooperation and Conflict
, vol.21
-
-
Bercovitch, J.1
-
16
-
-
84972651196
-
"Some Conceptual Issues and Empirical Trends in the Study of Successful Mediation in International Relations"
-
(February)
-
Jacob Bercovitch, Theodore Anagnoson, and Donnette L. Wille, "Some Conceptual Issues and Empirical Trends in the Study of Successful Mediation in International Relations," Journal of Peace Research 28 (February 1991);
-
(1991)
Journal of Peace Research
, vol.28
-
-
Bercovitch, J.1
Anagnoson, T.2
Wille, D.L.3
-
17
-
-
0003897143
-
-
Saadia Touval and I. William Zartman, eds., (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press)
-
Saadia Touval and I. William Zartman, eds., International Mediation in Theory and Practice (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1985);
-
(1985)
International Mediation in Theory and Practice
-
-
-
19
-
-
0030494962
-
"Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlements"
-
(Autumn)
-
William J. Dixon, "Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlements," International Organization 50 (Autumn 1996);
-
(1996)
International Organization
, vol.50
-
-
Dixon, W.J.1
-
20
-
-
0034107893
-
"In the Nick of Time: Conflict Management, Mediation Timing, and the Duration of Interstate Disputes"
-
(June)
-
Patrick M. Regan and Allan C. Stam, "In the Nick of Time: Conflict Management, Mediation Timing, and the Duration of Interstate Disputes," International Studies Quarterly 44 (June 2000).
-
(2000)
International Studies Quarterly
, vol.44
-
-
Regan, P.M.1
Stam, A.C.2
-
21
-
-
33644966854
-
"Mediation Style and Crisis Outcomes"
-
Cf. (February) Beardesley et al. represent one of the few efforts to develop and specify more carefully the theories from which mediation hypotheses are derived
-
Cf. Kyle C. Beardesley, David M. Quinn, Bidisha Biswas, and Jonathan Witkenfield, "Mediation Style and Crisis Outcomes," Journal of Conflict Resolution 50 (February 2006). Beardesley et al. represent one of the few efforts to develop and specify more carefully the theories from which mediation hypotheses are derived.
-
(2006)
Journal of Conflict Resolution
, vol.50
-
-
Beardesley, K.C.1
Quinn, D.M.2
Biswas, B.3
Wilkenfield, J.4
-
22
-
-
31444449431
-
"Choosing to Intervene: Outside Interventions in Internal Conflicts"
-
(August)
-
Patrick M. Regan, "Choosing to Intervene: Outside Interventions in Internal Conflicts," Journal of Politics 60 (August 1998);
-
(1998)
Journal of Politics
, vol.60
-
-
Regan, P.M.1
-
23
-
-
27744533749
-
"Stepping into the Fray: When Do Mediators Mediate?"
-
(April)
-
Michael J. Greig, "Stepping into the Fray: When Do Mediators Mediate?" American Journal of Political Science 49 (April 2004);
-
(2004)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.49
-
-
Greig, M.J.1
-
24
-
-
25144524610
-
"Rational Mediation: A Theory and a Test"
-
(September)
-
Lesley G. Terris and Zeev Maoz, "Rational Mediation: A Theory and a Test," Journal of Peace Research 42 (September 2005).
-
(2005)
Journal of Peace Research
, vol.42
-
-
Terris, L.G.1
Maoz, Z.2
-
26
-
-
0004260374
-
-
(Princeton: Princeton University Press) Bercovitch also comes to the conclusion that mediators may help disputants "achieve some convergence of expectations by reducing distortion, ignorance, misperception, or unrealistic perceptions"; Bercovitch also comes to the conclusion that mediators may help disputants "achieve some convergence of expectations by reducing distortion, ignorance, misperception, or unrealistic perceptions"
-
Ibid., 26. Bercovitch also comes to the conclusion that mediators may help disputants "achieve some convergence of expectations by reducing distortion, ignorance, misperception, or unrealistic perceptions";
-
(1992)
Intermediaries in International Conflict
, pp. 26
-
-
Princen, T.1
-
27
-
-
33750211521
-
-
see Bercovitch (fn. 8)
-
see Bercovitch (fn. 8), 98.
-
-
-
-
28
-
-
0003393578
-
-
For the seminal work on misperception and war, see (Princeton: Princeton University Press)
-
For the seminal work on misperception and war, see Robert Jervis, Perception and Misperception in International Politics (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1976).
-
(1976)
Perception and Misperception in International Politics
-
-
Jervis, R.1
-
29
-
-
0004260374
-
-
Note that other parts of Princen's analysis (Princeton: Princeton University Press) do fall squarely under a rationalist approach. For example, see the discussion of bargaining ranges and the use of mediator leverage (chap. 3). There is also an interesting discussion of how information can be "pooled" to create a bargaining chip that mediators may use as leverage (pp. 41-43)
-
Note that other parts of Princen's analysis (fn. 10) do fall squarely under a rationalist approach. For example, see the discussion of bargaining ranges and the use of mediator leverage (chap. 3). There is also an interesting discussion of how information can be "pooled" to create a bargaining chip that mediators may use as leverage (pp. 41-43). 24 Thomas Princen, Intermediaries in International Conflict (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992), 26.
-
(1992)
Intermediaries in International Conflict
, pp. 26
-
-
Princen, T.1
-
30
-
-
0001156293
-
"Explaining Bargaining Impasse: The Role of Self-Serving Biases"
-
Experimental economists have also explored how self-serving biases may prevent information from being processed in a way that allows beliefs to update in a manner consistent with Bayesian updating. For one example, see (Winter)
-
Experimental economists have also explored how self-serving biases may prevent information from being processed in a way that allows beliefs to update in a manner consistent with Bayesian updating. For one example, see Linda Babcock and George Loewenstein, "Explaining Bargaining Impasse: The Role of Self-Serving Biases," Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (Winter 1997).
-
(1997)
Journal of Economic Perspectives
, vol.11
-
-
Babcock, L.1
Loewenstein, G.2
-
32
-
-
33750216253
-
"When Can Mediators Build Trust?"
-
Cf. (forthcoming, August) Here Kydd argues that mediator reputation and repeated play may provide alternative explanations for why impartial mediators may prove effective
-
Cf. Andrew Kydd, "When Can Mediators Build Trust?" American Political Science Review (forthcoming, August 2006). Here Kydd argues that mediator reputation and repeated play may provide alternative explanations for why impartial mediators may prove effective.
-
(2006)
American Political Science Review
-
-
Kydd, A.1
-
35
-
-
84972159336
-
"Rationalist Explanations for War"
-
This assumption is consistent with (Summer)
-
This assumption is consistent with Fearon (fn. 1)
-
(1995)
International Organization
, vol.49
-
-
Fearon, J.1
-
37
-
-
33750215488
-
"Bargaining and Fighting while Learning"
-
The key issue under examination here is how mediation impacts crisis bargaining in the shadow of war. Thus, it makes sense to bracket the process of war analytically. Some of the insights developed in this analysis may nevertheless extend to bargaining during war, but this issue would benefit from additional analytic and empirical treatment. For a formal model that examines two players that bargain while fighting, see (April)
-
The key issue under examination here is how mediation impacts crisis bargaining in the shadow of war. Thus, it makes sense to bracket the process of war analytically. Some of the insights developed in this analysis may nevertheless extend to bargaining during war, but this issue would benefit from additional analytic and empirical treatment. For a formal model that examines two players that bargain while fighting, see Robert Powell, "Bargaining and Fighting while Learning," American Journal of Political Science 48 (April 2004).
-
(2004)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.48
-
-
Powell, R.1
-
38
-
-
0037309160
-
"The Power to Hurt: Costly Conflict with Completely Informed States"
-
See also (March)
-
See also Branislav L. Slantchev, "The Power to Hurt: Costly Conflict with Completely Informed States," American Political Science Review 47 (March 2003).
-
(2003)
American Political Science Review
, vol.47
-
-
Slantchev, B.L.1
-
39
-
-
84972159336
-
"Rationalist Explanations for War"
-
This is consistent with a wide range of models in international relations. See, for example (Summer)
-
This is consistent with a wide range of models in international relations. See, for example, Fearon (fn. 1)
-
(1995)
International Organization
, vol.49
-
-
Fearon, J.1
-
41
-
-
33750219464
-
-
note
-
H
-
-
-
-
42
-
-
33750216945
-
-
note
-
L.
-
-
-
-
43
-
-
0142230571
-
"Which Side Are You On? Bias, Credibility, and Mediation"
-
This decision is in keeping with and other previous efforts at producing a formal model of the effects of information sharing. (October)
-
This decision is in keeping with Kydd (fn. 3) and other previous efforts at producing a formal model of the effects of information sharing.
-
(2003)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.47
-
-
Kydd, A.1
-
44
-
-
0000510636
-
"Strategic Information Transmission"
-
For other models that treat the root source of information as exogenous to the model, see (November)
-
For other models that treat the root source of information as exogenous to the model, see Crawford and Sobel (fn. 2);
-
(1982)
Econometrica
, vol.50
-
-
Crawford, V.P.1
Sobel, J.2
-
45
-
-
84974269569
-
"The Value of Biased Information: A Rational Choice Model of Political Advice"
-
and (May)
-
and Randall L. Calvert, "The Value of Biased Information: A Rational Choice Model of Political Advice," Journal of Politics 47 (May 1985).
-
(1985)
Journal of Politics
, vol.47
-
-
Calvert, R.L.1
-
46
-
-
33750224049
-
-
note
-
The situation is quite different for more intrusive forms of third-party intervention. When third parties possess sticks, they can force their way into negotiations. Similarly, if they have carrots, they can buy their way into the negotiations by promising to finance or underwrite the settlement.
-
-
-
-
48
-
-
0040600426
-
"Learning in Equilibrium Models of Arbitration"
-
Economists have also examined how information may be revealed through arbitration. See, for example, (December)
-
Economists have also examined how information may be revealed through arbitration. See, for example, Gibbons (fn. 2)
-
(1988)
American Economic Review
, vol.78
-
-
Gibbns, R.1
-
49
-
-
33750220523
-
-
note
-
For the information to be deemed independent, all that is required is that the third party is receiving the information from some source other than Player C. Otherwise the third party would simply be repeating or playing back the same information to Player C.
-
-
-
-
51
-
-
31444449431
-
"Choosing to Intervene: Outside Interventions in Internal Conflicts"
-
This issue is especially interesting when one considers that the disputants will have strategic reasons to misrepresent information to the third party. A related question concerns the decision to mediate in the first place. For three recent studies that explain the reason why third parties decide to mediate, see (August)
-
This issue is especially interesting when one considers that the disputants will have strategic reasons to misrepresent information to the third party. A related question concerns the decision to mediate in the first place. For three recent studies that explain the reason why third parties decide to mediate, see Regan (fn. 9);
-
(1998)
Journal of Politics
, pp. 60
-
-
Regan, P.M.1
-
54
-
-
5944256163
-
"Negotiator Behavior under Arbitration"
-
Economists have also explored this question in relation to arbitration. For example, see (May)
-
Economists have also explored this question in relation to arbitration. For example, see David E. Bloom and Christopher L. Cavanagh, "Negotiator Behavior under Arbitration," American Economic Review 77 (May 1987).
-
(1987)
American Economic Review
, pp. 77
-
-
Bloom, D.E.1
Cavanagh, C.L.2
-
55
-
-
33750204604
-
-
note
-
To solve the model, these dimensions will be collapsed to create four ideal types. Two of the ideal types match the strictly neutral and strictly biased third parties examined in Kydd's study. The other two ideal types are new and help explain why impartial mediators may outperform biased ones.
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
33750214966
-
-
note
-
H). Rather than capturing an essential feature of the environment, this definition is heavily influenced by the model's take-it-or-leave-it structure and the assumption that Player D comes in only one of two types. Similarly, definition 3 means that impartiality occurs only at one precise point on a continuum. Thus, being just .01 off this mark means that the third party is already starting to exhibit bias. For the following analysis, definition 2 is adopted because it is reasonable to assume that impartiality, given the structure of this model, means that the third party's ideal point is somewhere in between the two negotiated settlements that are under consideration. All points within this range are considered equally impartial.
-
-
-
-
57
-
-
0142230571
-
"Which Side Are You On? Bias, Credibility, and Mediation"
-
For our purposes, solving for a truth-telling equilibrium is sufficient; 599 (October)
-
For our purposes, solving for a truth-telling equilibrium is sufficient; Kydd (fn. 3), 599, 608.
-
(2003)
American Journal of Political Science
, pp. 608
-
-
Kydd, A.1
-
58
-
-
0000510636
-
"Strategic Information Transmission"
-
For the seminal study on information transmission, see (November)
-
See also Crawford and Sobel (fn. 2);
-
(1982)
Econometrica
, pp. 50
-
-
Crawford, V.P.1
Sobel, J.2
-
59
-
-
84974269569
-
"The Value of Biased Information: A Rational Choice Model of Political Advice"
-
and (May) and Future studies of mediation and conflict management may benefit from introducing uncertainty about the third party's preferences and considering equilibriums for lying
-
and Calvert (fn. 19). Future studies of mediation and conflict management may benefit from introducing uncertainty about the third party's preferences and considering equilibriums for lying.
-
(1985)
Journal of Politics
, vol.47
-
-
Calvert, R.L.1
-
60
-
-
33750201212
-
-
note
-
This biased third party is essentially the same as the strictly biased third party examined by Kydd. A strictly biased third party has the same ideal point as the challenger. However, note that in this study, the third party does not share the identical utility function as either of the disputants (that is, the third party does not share the disputants' costs for fighting).
-
-
-
-
61
-
-
33750217683
-
-
note
-
Note that if λ = 1, then the value of β does not matter. This type of third party may in theory be biased toward either player or impartial, but as his dominant concern is avoiding war, the specific preferences over different settlements does not matter.
-
-
-
-
68
-
-
0030494962
-
"Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlement"
-
see also the studies cited (Autumn)
-
see also the studies cited in fn. 8.
-
(1996)
International Organization
, vol.50
-
-
Dixon, W.J.1
-
69
-
-
0000750938
-
"The Other Lesson of Rwanda: Mediators Sometimes Do More Damage Than Good"
-
For an alternative viewpoint, see (Winter-Spring)
-
For an alternative viewpoint, see Alan J. Kuperman, "The Other Lesson of Rwanda: Mediators Sometimes Do More Damage Than Good," SAIS Review 16 (Winter-Spring 1996);
-
(1996)
SAIS Review
, vol.16
-
-
Kuperman, A.J.1
-
71
-
-
33750217064
-
"Conflict Management and the Misapplication of Moral Hazard Theory"
-
For a critique of the application of moral hazard theory to third-party intervention, see in Timothy W. Crawford and Alan J. Kuperman, (New York: Routledge)
-
For a critique of the application of moral hazard theory to third-party intervention, see Robert W. Rauchhaus, "Conflict Management and the Misapplication of Moral Hazard Theory," in Timothy W. Crawford and Alan J. Kuperman, Gambling on Humanitarian Intervention: Moral Hazard, Rebellion and Civil War (New York: Routledge, 2006).
-
(2006)
Gambling on Humanitarian Intervention: Moral Hazard, Rebellion and Civil War
-
-
Rauchhaus, R.W.1
-
72
-
-
0002613863
-
"The Methodology of Positive Economics"
-
On the futility of asking whether assumptions are true or false, see in Milton Friedman, ed., (Chicago: University of Chicago Press)
-
On the futility of asking whether assumptions are true or false, see Milton Friedman, "The Methodology of Positive Economics," in Milton Friedman, ed., Essays in Positive Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953);
-
(1953)
Essays in Positive Economics
-
-
Friedman, M.1
-
75
-
-
0001979679
-
"SHERFACS: A Cross-Paradigm, Hierarchical and Contextually Sensitive Conflict Management Data Set"
-
(January-March)
-
Frank L. Sherman, "SHERFACS: A Cross-Paradigm, Hierarchical and Contextually Sensitive Conflict Management Data Set," International Interactions 20 (January-March 1994).
-
(1994)
International Interactions
, vol.20
-
-
Sherman, F.L.1
-
76
-
-
0039944000
-
"Collective Security-Seeking Practices since 1945"
-
The data set is available for download at the University of Michigan's Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research; www.icpsr.umich.edu. Since SHERFACS is less well known than the Correlates of War (COW) project or International Crisis Behavior (ICB) data, a few words are in order. The SHERFACs data set subsumes and extends a number of other conflict-management data sets. The most recent study on which it builds is in Daniel Frei, ed., (Beverly Hills, Calif: Sage)
-
The data set is available for download at the University of Michigan's Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research; www.icpsr.umich.edu. Since SHERFACS is less well known than the Correlates of War (COW) project or International Crisis Behavior (ICB) data, a few words are in order. The SHERFACs data set subsumes and extends a number of other conflict-management data sets. The most recent study on which it builds is Hayward R. Alker and Frank L. Sherman, "Collective Security-Seeking Practices since 1945," in Daniel Frei, ed., Managing International Crises (Beverly Hills, Calif: Sage, 1982).
-
(1982)
Managing International Crises
-
-
Alker, H.R.1
Sherman, F.L.2
-
77
-
-
0040875334
-
-
Earlier studies along this research line include (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies)
-
Earlier studies along this research line include Ernst B. Haas, Why We Still Need the United Nations (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, 1986);
-
(1986)
Why We Still Need the United Nations
-
-
Haas, E.B.1
-
81
-
-
0010186812
-
-
(Boston: Little, Brown and Company)
-
Joseph S. Nye, Peace in Parts (Boston: Little, Brown and Company, 1968);
-
(1968)
Peace in Parts
-
-
Nye, J.S.1
-
82
-
-
33750220752
-
-
Monograph Series in World Affairs, (Denver, Colo.: University of Denver)
-
Ernst B. Haas, Collective Security and the Future International System, Monograph Series in World Affairs, vol. 5, no. 1 (Denver, Colo.: University of Denver, 1968).
-
(1968)
Collective Security and the Future International System
, vol.5
, Issue.1
-
-
Haas, E.B.1
-
83
-
-
0040799677
-
"An Empirical Test of the Audience Cost Proposition: Democracy Speaks Louder than Words"
-
For another study that uses SHERFACS and offers a thorough discussion of its origins and evolution, see (December)
-
For another study that uses SHERFACS and offers a thorough discussion of its origins and evolution, see Joe Eyerman and Robert A. Hart, Jr., "An Empirical Test of the Audience Cost Proposition: Democracy Speaks Louder than Words," Journal of Conflict Resolution 40 (December 1996).
-
(1996)
Journal of Conflict Resolution
, vol.40
-
-
Eyerman, J.1
Hart Jr., R.A.2
-
84
-
-
0030494962
-
"Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlements"
-
SHERFACs breaks disputes down into discrete phases and allows analysts to track the varying intensity of disputes over time. Efforts to evaluate conflict management against most other data sets can run into problems because, in addition to the lack of information on competing conflict-managing activities, the data set provides only aggregate dispute characteristics. This makes it difficult to determine whether intervention is causally related to the intensity or duration of a dispute. (Autumn). is one of the only studies to date to Use SHERFACs' burdensome phase-related structure. To allow for comparison between the studies, the same coding and testing procedures are adopted wherever possible. Because the studies have different purposes, however, it is necessary to make a number of modifications, which are discussed in detail below
-
SHERFACs breaks disputes down into discrete phases and allows analysts to track the varying intensity of disputes over time. Efforts to evaluate conflict management against most other data sets can run into problems because, in addition to the lack of information on competing conflict-managing activities, the data set provides only aggregate dispute characteristics. This makes it difficult to determine whether intervention is causally related to the intensity or duration of a dispute. Dixon (fn. 8) is one of the only studies to date to Use SHERFACs' burdensome phase-related structure. To allow for comparison between the studies, the same coding and testing procedures are adopted wherever possible. Because the studies have different purposes, however, it is necessary to make a number of modifications, which are discussed in detail below.
-
(1996)
International Organization
, pp. 50
-
-
Dixon, W.J.1
-
86
-
-
84965905136
-
"Peaceful Settlement of Disputes by the United Nations and Other Intergovernmental Bodies"
-
(September). Studies define and operationalize mediation in a myriad of ways. To complicate matters, the type of mediation examined in Kydd's study is not the same as the mediation examined in Dixon's study. To avoid confusing the different types of mediation and create consistency across these studies, some of the variables are renamed. Mediation in Dixon's study is relabeled Heavy Mediation. Dixon's communication variable, which is in keeping with what Kydd generally refers to as mediation, is relabeled here as Light Mediation
-
Kjell Skjelsbæk, "Peaceful Settlement of Disputes by the United Nations and Other Intergovernmental Bodies," Cooperation and Conflict 21 (September 1986). Studies define and operationalize mediation in a myriad of ways. To complicate matters, the type of mediation examined in Kydd's study is not the same as the mediation examined in Dixon's study. To avoid confusing the different types of mediation and create consistency across these studies, some of the variables are renamed. Mediation in Dixon's study is relabeled Heavy Mediation. Dixon's communication variable, which is in keeping with what Kydd generally refers to as mediation, is relabeled here as Light Mediation.
-
(1986)
Cooperation and Conflict
, vol.21
-
-
Skjelsbæk, K.1
-
87
-
-
0030494962
-
"Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlements"
-
(Autumn)
-
Dixon (fn. 8), 658;
-
(1996)
International Organization
, vol.50
, pp. 658
-
-
Dixon, W.J.1
-
88
-
-
84965905136
-
"Peaceful Settlement of Disputes by the United Nations and Other Intergovernmental Bodies"
-
(September). Studies define and operationalize mediation in a myriad of ways. To complicate matters, the type of mediation examined in Kydd's study is not the same as the mediation examined in Dixon's study. To avoid confusing the different types of mediation and create consistency across these studies, some of the variables are renamed. Mediation in Dixon's study is relabeled Heavy Mediation. Dixon's communication variable, which is in keeping with what Kydd generally refers to as mediation, is relabeled here as Light Mediation
-
and Skjelsbæk (fn. 38), 148.
-
(1986)
Cooperation and Conflict
, pp. 148
-
-
Skjelsbæk, K.1
-
89
-
-
0030494962
-
"Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlements"
-
In light mediation (communication) consists of the provision of good offices and the enunciation of key issues. Heavy mediation, by contrast, involves three types of third-party activity: arbitration, conciliation, and traditional mediation. Having gained a more nuanced understanding of light mediation as a result of the formal model developed in the previous section, it is necessary to modify the light mediation variable to ensure that it is measuring the correct empirical phenomenon. To that end, in this article conciliation is removed from heavy mediation and instead treated as a form of light mediation. This is done because conciliation is very limited in its scope. According to Merrills, conciliation includes the exchange and verification of information and the "examination of the dispute and attempts to define the terms of a settlement." (Autumn)
-
In Dixon (fn. 8), light mediation (communication) consists of the provision of good offices and the enunciation of key issues. Heavy mediation, by contrast, involves three types of third-party activity: arbitration, conciliation, and traditional mediation. Having gained a more nuanced understanding of light mediation as a result of the formal model developed in the previous section, it is necessary to modify the light mediation variable to ensure that it is measuring the correct empirical phenomenon. To that end, in this article conciliation is removed from heavy mediation and instead treated as a form of light mediation. This is done because conciliation is very limited in its scope. According to Merrills, conciliation includes the exchange and verification of information and the "examination of the dispute and attempts to define the terms of a settlement."
-
(1996)
International Organization
, vol.50
, pp. 50
-
-
Dixon, W.J.1
-
90
-
-
0003243199
-
-
See 2nd ed. (Cambridge, U.K.: Grotius Press) Heavy mediation, by contrast, includes activities such as "the drafting and promotion of plans for conflict resolution"
-
See John G. Merrills, International Dispute Settlement, 2nd ed. (Cambridge, U.K.: Grotius Press, 1991), 39. Heavy mediation, by contrast, includes activities such as "the drafting and promotion of plans for conflict resolution."
-
(1991)
International Dispute Settlement
, pp. 39
-
-
Merrills, J.G.1
-
91
-
-
84965905136
-
"Peaceful Settlement of Disputes by the United Nations and Other Intergovernmental Bodies"
-
Clearly, this is not the point of conciliation, which is limited to the facilitation of communication and other efforts to define the terms of a potential settlement. As we will see, this reclassification does not significantly change the number of observations associated with light or heavy mediation. Moreover, since conciliation was the "lightest" form of heavy mediation in Dixon's study, reclassifying it should increase, rather than decrease, the substantive impact of heavy mediation, given that this lighter form of conflict management is not expected to have much impact. The other five conflict-management variables - coercive intervention, adjudication, observation, humanitarian aid, and public appeals - remain unchanged. (September). Studies define and operationalize mediation in a myriad of ways. To complicate matters, the type of mediation examined in Kydd's study is not the same as the mediation examined in Dixon's study
-
See Skjelsbæk (fn. 38), 13. Clearly, this is not the point of conciliation, which is limited to the facilitation of communication and other efforts to define the terms of a potential settlement. As we will see, this reclassification does not significantly change the number of observations associated with light or heavy mediation. Moreover, since conciliation was the "lightest" form of heavy mediation in Dixon's study, reclassifying it should increase, rather than decrease, the substantive impact of heavy mediation, given that this lighter form of conflict management is not expected to have much impact. The other five conflict-management variables - coercive intervention, adjudication, observation, humanitarian aid, and public appeals - remain unchanged. 89 Kjell Skjelsbæk, "Peaceful Settlement of Disputes by the United Nations and Other Intergovernmental Bodies," Cooperation and Conflict 21 (September 1986). Studies define and operationalize mediation in a myriad of ways. To complicate matters, the type of mediation examined in Kydd's study is not the same as the mediation examined in Dixon's study. To avoid confusing the different types of mediation and create consistency across these studies, some of the variables are renamed. Mediation in Dixon's study is relabeled Heavy Mediation. Dixon's communication variable, which is in keeping with what Kydd generally refers to as mediation, is relabeled here as Light Mediation.
-
(1986)
Cooperation and Conflict
, vol.21
, pp. 13
-
-
Skjelsbæk, K.1
-
92
-
-
0001979679
-
"SHERFACS: A Cross-Paradigm, Hierarchical and Contextually Sensitive Conflict Management Data Set"
-
The table is derived from (January-March)
-
The table is derived from Sherman (fn. 35)
-
(1994)
International Interactions
, vol.20
-
-
Sherman, F.L.1
-
93
-
-
0030494962
-
"Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlements"
-
Disputes can transition through any number of phases and may do so in any order, with two exceptions: first, if a dispute makes the transition to phase 3, it can never go back to phase 1 or phase 2. This rule makes sense given that once hostilities have taken place, it is impossible to be in phase 1 or phase 2, which, by definition, is a situation where force has never been employed. Similarly, once a dispute transitions to phase 6, it is by definition over and cannot return to another phase. Aside form these two rules, disputes may move between these phase types in any order. Disputes can start with phase 1, phase 2, or phase 3. Those that begin as phase 1 or phase 2 may move between phase 1 and phase 2 one or more times. Disputes may also move between phases 3, 4, and 5 in any order, any number of times. Lastly, disputes may end by reaching phase 6, or they may end in any phase without ever moving to phase 6. (Autumn)
-
and Dixon (fn. 8). Disputes can transition through any number of phases and may do so in any order, with two exceptions: first, if a dispute makes the transition to phase 3, it can never go back to phase 1 or phase 2. This rule makes sense given that once hostilities have taken place, it is impossible to be in phase 1 or phase 2, which, by definition, is a situation where force has never been employed. Similarly, once a dispute transitions to phase 6, it is by definition over and cannot return to another phase. Aside form these two rules, disputes may move between these phase types in any order. Disputes can start with phase 1, phase 2, or phase 3. Those that begin as phase 1 or phase 2 may move between phase 1 and phase 2 one or more times. Disputes may also move between phases 3, 4, and 5 in any order, any number of times. Lastly, disputes may end by reaching phase 6, or they may end in any phase without ever moving to phase 6.
-
(1996)
International Organization
, vol.50
-
-
Dixon, W.J.1
-
95
-
-
0030494962
-
"Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlements"
-
(Autumn)
-
Dixon (fn. 8), 661.
-
(1996)
International Organization
, vol.50
, pp. 661
-
-
Dixon, W.J.1
-
96
-
-
33947394134
-
"Collective Conflict Management: Evidence for a New World Order?"
-
in Thomas G. Weiss, ed., (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner)
-
Ernst B. Hass, "Collective Conflict Management: Evidence for a New World Order?" in Thomas G. Weiss, ed., Collective Security in a Changing World (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1993).
-
(1993)
Collective Security in a Changing World
-
-
Hass, E.B.1
-
97
-
-
0030494962
-
"Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlements"
-
(Autumn)
-
Dixon (fn. 8), 674.
-
(1996)
International Organization
, pp. 674
-
-
Dixon, W.J.1
-
98
-
-
0030494962
-
"Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlements"
-
(Autumn)
-
Ibid., 669-70.
-
(1996)
International Organization
, pp. 669-670
-
-
Dixon, W.J.1
-
99
-
-
0002262761
-
-
The coding criterion in SHERFACS is consistent with In many instances, it is not difficult for researchers to determine relative bias because a third party will provide visible economic, political, or military aid to one of the parties. Bias is often also easy to determine because of public statements or declaratory policy. However, in other instances, determining bias is more difficult and may rely on the third party's past relations with the disputants. Following criteria established by Haas, Butter-worth, and Nye, SHERFACS ranks the relative bias or impartiality of third parties on a 5-point scale. (Morristown, N.J.: General Learning Press)
-
The coding criterion in SHERFACS is consistent with Haas, Butter-worth, and Nye (fn. 35). In many instances, it is not difficult for researchers to determine relative bias because a third party will provide visible economic, political, or military aid to one of the parties. Bias is often also easy to determine because of public statements or declaratory policy. However, in other instances, determining bias is more difficult and may rely on the third party's past relations with the disputants. Following criteria established by Haas, Butter-worth, and Nye, SHERFACS ranks the relative bias or impartiality of third parties on a 5-point scale.
-
(1972)
Conflict Management By International Organization
-
-
Haas, E.B.1
Butterworth, R.L.2
Nye, J.S.3
-
100
-
-
0030494962
-
"Third-Party Techniques for Preventing Conflict Escalation and Promoting Peaceful Settlements"
-
(Autumn)
-
Dixon (fn. 8), 661.
-
(1996)
International Organization
, pp. 661
-
-
Dixon, W.J.1
-
101
-
-
0000750938
-
"The Other Lesson of Rwanda: Mediators Sometimes Do More Damage Than Good"
-
(Winter-Spring)
-
Kuperman (fn. 32).
-
(1996)
SAIS Review
, pp. 16
-
-
Kuperman, A.J.1
-
102
-
-
84889568763
-
"The Vatican Mediation of the Beagle Channel Dispute: Crisis Intervention and Forum Building"
-
Although it was necessary to include multiple conflict-management techniques for the statistical analysis, this study does offer a theory or formal model that explains or predicts how the other conflict-management techniques work. One can speculate that the relationship between adjudication and war is either spurious or causal. For example, one might conclude that the relationship is merely the result of a spurious correlation stemming from the fact that most attempts to go before the court are often last-ditch efforts when war is inevitable. Thus, it may make sense that these cases are associated with both higher rates of fighting and an increased likelihood of peaceful settlement. However, there is at least one explanation of why adjudication may cause fighting. Unlike mediation or other bargaining processes that are political in nature, legal decisions by international courts may produce decisions that do not reflect political realities
-
Although it was necessary to include multiple conflict-management techniques for the statistical analysis, this study does offer a theory or formal model that explains or predicts how the other conflict-management techniques work. One can speculate that the relationship between adjudication and war is either spurious or causal. For example, one might conclude that the relationship is merely the result of a spurious correlation stemming from the fact that most attempts to go before the court are often last-ditch efforts when war is inevitable. Thus, it may make sense that these cases are associated with both higher rates of fighting and an increased likelihood of peaceful settlement. However, there is at least one explanation of why adjudication may cause fighting. Unlike mediation or other bargaining processes that are political in nature, legal decisions by international courts may produce decisions that do not reflect political realities. Thus, courts may make rulings that fully legitimate one side's claims and propose an unsustainable settlement. A report issued by the Carnegie Commission on Preventing Deadly Conflict inadvertently provides some support for this hypothesis. See Mark Laudy, "The Vatican Mediation of the Beagle Channel Dispute: Crisis Intervention and Forum Building," in Melanie C. Greenberg, John H. Barton, and Margaret E. McGuinness, eds., Words over War: Mediation and Arbitration to Prevent Deadly Conflict (Lanham, Md.: Rowman and Littlefield, 2000).
-
(2000)
Words over War: Mediation and Arbitration to Prevent Deadly Conflict
-
-
Laudy, M.1
-
103
-
-
33750200201
-
-
note
-
With p=.5, the expected payoff for all types of third party equals.5. If the value of p is greater or less than.5, then the expected payoff will depend on the balance of power and the third party's relative bias.
-
-
-
-
104
-
-
33750206950
-
-
note
-
As stated above, this analysis does not assume that the third party pays the same cost for fighting as the disputants. Third parties, when serving as mediators, do not normally use military force, nor are they the targets of military force. A future study may benefit from relaxing this assumption. If the third party's costs for fighting are included as a variable, then as the costs approach the disputant's costs for fighting (or perhaps even exceed them because of reputation or other costs), the "provocateur effect" will diminish and ultimately collapse.
-
-
-
-
105
-
-
33750215727
-
-
note
-
Future analyses might relax the assumption that p=.5 and examine how different distributions of power will influence the behavior of third parties with different degrees of bias.
-
-
-
|