메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 57, Issue 3, 2005, Pages 365-395

Electoral control in new democracies: The perverse incentives of fluid party systems

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

DEMOCRACY; ELECTION; PARTY POLITICS;

EID: 33645117875     PISSN: 00438871     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1353/wp.2006.0006     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (61)

References (102)
  • 1
    • 0041624338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Patterns of Political Instability: Affiliation Patterns of Politicians and Voters in Postcommunist Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania"
    • For Eastern Europe, (Summer)
    • For Eastern Europe, see Marcus Kreuzer and Vello Pettai, "Patterns of Political Instability: Affiliation Patterns of Politicians and Voters in Postcommunist Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania," Studies in Comparative Development 3 (Summer 2003);
    • (2003) Studies in Comparative Development , pp. 3
    • Kreuzer, M.1    Pettai, V.2
  • 2
    • 33645123449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Calculus of Party Affiliation in Post-Communist Democracies: Party Switching, Fusions, Fissions and the Institutionalization of Party Systems"
    • (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, August 28-31)
    • idem, "The Calculus of Party Affiliation in Post-Communist Democracies: Party Switching, Fusions, Fissions and the Institutionalization of Party Systems" (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, August 28-31, 2003);
    • (2003)
    • Kreuzer, M.1    Pettai, V.2
  • 3
    • 0036070113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Causes and Consequences of Fluid Factional Membership in Ukraine"
    • (June)
    • Erik S. Herron, "The Causes and Consequences of Fluid Factional Membership in Ukraine," Europe-Asia Studies 54 (June 2002);
    • (2002) Europe-Asia Studies , pp. 54
    • Herron, E.S.1
  • 5
    • 0141873027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Parliamentary Elections in Ukraine, March 2002"
    • (September)
    • idem, "The Parliamentary Elections in Ukraine, March 2002," Electoral Studies 22 (September 2003);
    • (2003) Electoral Studies , pp. 22
    • Birch, S.1
  • 7
    • 1642348228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Interparty Mobility among Parliamentary Candidates in Post-communist East-Central Europe"
    • and (March)
    • and Goldie Shabad and Kazimierz M. Slomczynski, "Interparty Mobility among Parliamentary Candidates in Post-communist East-Central Europe," Party Politics 10 (March 2004);
    • (2004) Party Politics , pp. 10
    • Shabad, G.1    Slomczynski, K.M.2
  • 10
    • 3242748930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Parties for Rent? Ambition, Ideology, and Party Switching in Brazil's Chamber of Deputies"
    • and (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, University of Arizona, Tucson)
    • and Scott Desposato, "Parties for Rent? Ambition, Ideology, and Party Switching in Brazil's Chamber of Deputies" (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, University of Arizona, Tucson, 2002);
    • (2002)
    • Desposato, S.1
  • 11
    • 3242748930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Parties for Rent? Ambition, Ideology, and Party Switching in Brazil's Chambers of Deputies"
    • (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, University of Arizona, Tucson)
    • Desposato (fn.1).
    • (2002)
    • Desposato, S.1
  • 13
    • 31344440815 scopus 로고
    • "Control over Politicians: An Economic Model"
    • (Spring)
    • See, for example, Robert J. Barro, "Control over Politicians: An Economic Model," Public Choice 17 (Spring 1973);
    • (1973) Public Choice , pp. 17
    • Barro, R.J.1
  • 14
    • 34248428827 scopus 로고
    • "Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control"
    • (Fall)
    • John Ferejohn, "Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control," Public Choice 30 (Fall 1986);
    • (1986) Public Choice , pp. 30
    • Ferejohn, J.1
  • 15
    • 0001274092 scopus 로고
    • "Electoral Accountability and Incumbency"
    • Peter C. Ordeshook, ed., (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press)
    • David Austen-Smith and Jeffrey Banks, "Electoral Accountability and Incumbency," in Peter C. Ordeshook, ed., Models of Strategic Choice in Politics (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1989);
    • (1989) Models of Strategic Choice in Politics
    • Austen-Smith, D.1    Banks, J.2
  • 16
    • 0011865477 scopus 로고
    • "Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard in a Repeated Election Model"
    • William A. Barnett, Melvin J. Hinich, and Norman J. Schoenfeld, eds., (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
    • Jeffrey Banks and Rangarajan K. Sundaram, "Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard in a Repeated Election Model," in William A. Barnett, Melvin J. Hinich, and Norman J. Schoenfeld, eds., Political Economy: Institutions, Competition and Representation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993);
    • (1993) Political Economy: Institutions, Competition and Representation
    • Banks, J.1    Sundaram, R.K.2
  • 17
    • 0002322389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance"
    • and Przeworski, Stokes, and Manin (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
    • and James D. Fearon, "Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance," in Przeworski, Stokes, and Manin (fn. 3).
    • (1999) Democracy, Accountability and Representation
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 19
    • 84971914975 scopus 로고
    • "Presidential Popularity from Truman to Johnson"
    • (March)
    • John E. Mueller, "Presidential Popularity from Truman to Johnson," American Political Science Review 64 (March 1970);
    • (1970) American Political Science Review , pp. 64
    • Mueller, J.E.1
  • 20
    • 0000163134 scopus 로고
    • "Short-term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896-1964"
    • (March)
    • Gerald H. Kramer, "Short-term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896-1964," American Political Science Review 65 (March 1971);
    • (1971) American Political Science Review , pp. 65
    • Kramer, G.H.1
  • 22
    • 0001837106 scopus 로고
    • "How Robust Is the Vote Function: A Study of Seventeen Nations over Four Decades"
    • For Western Europe, Helmut Norpoth, Michael S. Lewis Beck, and Jean-Dominique Lafay, eds., (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press)
    • For Western Europe, see Martin Paldam, "How Robust Is the Vote Function: A Study of Seventeen Nations over Four Decades," in Helmut Norpoth, Michael S. Lewis Beck, and Jean-Dominique Lafay, eds., Economics and Politics: The Calculus of Support (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991);
    • (1991) Economics and Politics: The Calculus of Support
    • Paldam, M.1
  • 23
    • 84888712512 scopus 로고
    • "A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of Political Context"
    • (May)
    • G. Bingham Powell, Jr., and Guy D. Whitten, "A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of Political Context," American Journal of Political Science 37 (May 1993);
    • (1993) American Journal of Political Science , pp. 37
    • Bingham Powell Jr., G.1    Whitten, G.D.2
  • 25
    • 84937314505 scopus 로고
    • "Macroeconomic Conditions and Electoral Politics in East-Central Europe"
    • For Eastern Europe, (August)
    • For Eastern Europe, see Alexander C. Pacek, "Macroeconomic Conditions and Electoral Politics in East-Central Europe," American Journal of Political Science 38 (August 1994);
    • (1994) American Journal of Political Science , pp. 38
    • Pacek, A.C.1
  • 26
    • 84858558921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Taking Account of Institutional Effects: How Institutions Mediate the Effect of Economic Conditions on Election Results - Evidence from Russia, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia and the Czech Republic, 1990-1996"
    • (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C., August 31-September 3)
    • Joshua A. Tucker, "Taking Account of Institutional Effects: How Institutions Mediate the Effect of Economic Conditions on Election Results - Evidence from Russia, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia and the Czech Republic, 1990-1996" (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C., August 31-September 3, 2000);
    • (2000)
    • Tucker, J.A.1
  • 27
    • 84858559639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Transitional Economic Voting: Economic Conditions and Election Results in Russia, Poland, Hungary, Slovakia and the Czech Republic from 1990-1999"
    • (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Association for the Advancement of Slavic Studies, Boston, November)
    • idem, "Transitional Economic Voting: Economic Conditions and Election Results in Russia, Poland, Hungary, Slovakia and the Czech Republic from 1990-1999" (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Association for the Advancement of Slavic Studies, Boston, November 2004);
    • (2004)
    • Tucker, J.A.1
  • 28
    • 0029509416 scopus 로고
    • "Economic Influences on the Political Support for Market Reform in Post-communist Transitions: Some Evidence from the 1993 Polish Parliamentary Elections"
    • (July)
    • John Gibson and Anna Cielecka, "Economic Influences on the Political Support for Market Reform in Post-communist Transitions: Some Evidence from the 1993 Polish Parliamentary Elections," Europe-Asia Studies 47 (July 1995);
    • (1995) Europe-Asia Studies , pp. 47
    • Gibson, J.1    Cielecka, A.2
  • 29
    • 0031390093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Unemployment Matters: Voting Patterns during the Economic Transition in Poland, 1990-1995"
    • (November)
    • Janice Bell, "Unemployment Matters: Voting Patterns during the Economic Transition in Poland, 1990-1995," Europe-Asia Studies 49 (November 1997);
    • (1997) Europe-Asia Studies , pp. 49
    • Bell, J.1
  • 30
    • 0033995963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Economic Voting in Post-communist Countries"
    • and (June)
    • and Jan Fidrmuc, "Economic Voting in Post-communist Countries," Electoral Studies 19 (June 2000).
    • (2000) Electoral Studies , pp. 19
    • Fidrmuc, J.1
  • 31
    • 0004129494 scopus 로고
    • For Western Europe, (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press)
    • For Western Europe, see Michael S. Lewis-Beck, Economics and Elections (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1988);
    • (1988) Economics and Elections
    • Lewis-Beck, M.S.1
  • 32
    • 0034001953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Economic Voting and Political Context: A Comparative Perspective"
    • and (June)
    • and Christopher Anderson, "Economic Voting and Political Context: A Comparative Perspective," Electoral Studies 19 (June 2000);
    • (2000) Electoral Studies , pp. 19
    • Anderson, C.1
  • 33
    • 0030504854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Public Support for Economic Reform in Poland"
    • for Eastern Europe, (October)
    • for Eastern Europe, see Adam Przeworski, "Public Support for Economic Reform in Poland," Comparative Political Studies 29 (October 1996);
    • (1996) Comparative Political Studies , pp. 29
    • Przeworski, A.1
  • 34
    • 0031286439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Echoes from the Past: The Relationship between Satisfaction with Economic Reforms and Voting Behavior in Poland"
    • (September)
    • Denise V. Powers and James H. Cox, "Echoes from the Past: The Relationship between Satisfaction with Economic Reforms and Voting Behavior in Poland," American Political Science Review (September 1997);
    • (1997) American Political Science Review
    • Powers, D.V.1    Cox, J.H.2
  • 35
    • 0035543619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "A Developmental Model of Heterogeneous Economic Voting in New Democracies"
    • and (December)
    • and Raymond Duch, "A Developmental Model of Heterogeneous Economic Voting in New Democracies," American Political Science Review 95 (December 2001).
    • (2001) American Political Science Review , pp. 95
    • Duch, R.1
  • 36
    • 84992810952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Public Opinion and Market Reforms: The Limits of Economic Voting"
    • For Latin America, (October)
    • For Latin America, see Susan C. Stokes, "Public Opinion and Market Reforms: The Limits of Economic Voting," Comparative Political Studies 29 (October (1996).
    • (1996) Comparative Political Studies , pp. 29
    • Stokes, S.C.1
  • 37
    • 0034360816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Economic Determinants of Electoral Outcomes
    • For a thorough review of the findings of the literature on economic voting, (June)
    • For a thorough review of the findings of the literature on economic voting, see Michael S. Lewis-Beck and Mary Stegmaier, "Economic Determinants of Electoral Outcomes, "Annual Review of Political Science 3 (June 2000).
    • (2000) "Annual Review of Political Science , pp. 3
    • Lewis-Beck, M.S.1    Stegmaier, M.2
  • 38
    • 0036406631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The First Decade of Post-communist Elections and Voting: What Have We Studied and How Have We Studied It?"
    • For a similarly thorough review of findings related to Eastern Europe, (June)
    • For a similarly thorough review of findings related to Eastern Europe, see Joshua A. Tucker, "The First Decade of Post-communist Elections and Voting: What Have We Studied and How Have We Studied It?" Annual Review of Political Science 5 (June 2002).
    • (2002) Annual Review of Political Science , pp. 5
    • Tucker, J.A.1
  • 39
    • 33645130751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The original arguments about political control are explicit about the importance of individual-level incentives. Thomas Hobbes, for instance, stresses that representatives are "naturall Persons" who pursue their private interests and argues that in order to create a good government these private interests must be aligned with the interest of the public;
  • 40
    • 0004287799 scopus 로고
    • (London: Penguin Group)
    • see Hobbes, Leviathan (London: Penguin Group, 1985).
    • (1985) Leviathan
    • Hobbes, T.1
  • 41
    • 0346172486 scopus 로고
    • Federalist No. 57
    • James Madison, in turn, argues that repeated elections align private and public interests because they keep individual politicians dependent on their constituents for reelection; Clinton Rossiter, ed., (New York: New American Library)
    • James Madison, in turn, argues that repeated elections align private and public interests because they keep individual politicians dependent on their constituents for reelection; see Madison, Federalist No. 57, in Clinton Rossiter, ed., The Federalist Papers (New York: New American Library, 1961).
    • (1961) The Federalist Papers
    • Madison, J.1
  • 42
    • 0031286439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Echoes from the Past: The Relationship between Satisfaction with Economic Reforms and Voting Behavior in Poland"
    • The link between performance and reelection certainly depends upon the degree to which voters attribute responsibility for performance to incumbents of various elected offices (executive, legislative, or subnational) or to other actors (September)
    • The link between performance and reelection certainly depends upon the degree to which voters attribute responsibility for performance to incumbents of various elected offices (executive, legislative, or subnational) or to other actors; see Powers and Cox (fn.7);
    • (1997) American Political Science Review
    • Powers, D.V.1    Cox, J.H.2
  • 43
    • 0142168530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Who's Responsible for the Economy? The Formation and Consequences of Responsibility Attributions"
    • and (October)
    • and Thomas J. Rudolph, "Who's Responsible for the Economy? The Formation and Consequences of Responsibility Attributions," American Journal of Political Science 47 (October 2003).
    • (2003) American Journal of Political Science , pp. 47
    • Rudolph, T.J.1
  • 44
    • 84888712512 scopus 로고
    • "A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of Political Context"
    • Formal institutional arrangements and the nature of the party system (its fluidity and fragmentation) affect the clarity of responsibility for performance by making it "objectively" easier or more difficult for voters to know which set of elected officials to hold accountable for governmental performance - if in fact they do hold elected officials responsible rather than other actors (May)
    • Formal institutional arrangements and the nature of the party system (its fluidity and fragmentation) affect the clarity of responsibility for performance by making it "objectively" easier or more difficult for voters to know which set of elected officials to hold accountable for governmental performance - if in fact they do hold elected officials responsible rather than other actors; see Powell and Whitten (fn.6);
    • (1993) American Journal of Political Science , pp. 37
    • Powell Jr., G.B.1    Whitten, G.D.2
  • 46
    • 84858560312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Democratic Regimes and Accountability for the Economy in Comparative Perspective"
    • and (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, September 1-4)
    • and David Samuels and Timothy Hellwig, "Democratic Regimes and Accountability for the Economy in Comparative Perspective" (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, September 1-4, 2004.
    • (2004)
    • Samuels, D.1    Hellwig, T.2
  • 47
    • 33645129408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Formal institutional arrangements and the nature of the party system also affect clarity of resposibility by making it easier or more difficult for politicians to take the credit for good performance and to blame others for poor performance and thus to undermine further the ability of voters to figure out whom to hold responsible. These are important questions related to electoral control. To address these issues adequately, however, would require survey data pertaining to perceptions of and attributions of responsibility for good and bad performance.
  • 49
    • 17044378419 scopus 로고
    • "Speech to the Electors of Bristol"
    • For exemplars of this debate, Ross J.S. Hoffman and Paul Levack, eds., (New York: A. A. Knopf)
    • For exemplars of this debate, see Edmund Burke, "Speech to the Electors of Bristol," in Ross J.S. Hoffman and Paul Levack, eds., Burke's Politics: Selected Writings and Speeches (New York: A. A. Knopf, 1949);
    • (1949) Burke's Politics: Selected Writings and Speeches
    • Burke, E.1
  • 51
  • 52
    • 0004295760 scopus 로고
    • For various articulations of the concept of prospective voting, (New York: Harper)
    • For various articulations of the concept of prospective voting, see Joseph A. Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy (New York: Harper, 1942);
    • (1942) Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy
    • Schumpeter, J.A.1
  • 55
  • 56
    • 34248132481 scopus 로고
    • "Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: A Rank Ordering of Electoral Formulas"
    • For a discussion of the distinction between the two, (December)
    • For a discussion of the distinction between the two, see John M. Carey and Matthew S. Shugart, "Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: A Rank Ordering of Electoral Formulas," Electoral Studies 14 (December 1995).
    • (1995) Electoral Studies , vol.14
    • Carey, J.M.1    Shugart, M.S.2
  • 59
    • 3242748930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Parties for Rent? Ambition Ideology, and Party Switching in Brazil's Chamber of Deputies"
    • (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, University of Arizona, Tucson)
    • and Desposato (fn. 1).
    • (2002)
    • Desposato, S.1
  • 60
    • 33645126558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is not to say that the type of reputation politicians develop (personal versus party) is unimportant to the student of electoral accountability. To the contrary, there are good reasons to suspect that reputation type most likely affects the degree of electoral accountability. For example, it might very well be the case that the relationship between policy outcomes and probability of reelection is much more pronounced in democracies where politicians cultivate strong party reputations than in democracies where they develop strong personal reputations. Our point is simply that the notion of a personal vote is conceptually distinct from the study of individual-level electoral incentives.
  • 62
    • 33645131149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although the 1997 constitution introduced a number of revisions to the constitutional arrangements that emerged after the roundtable negotiations of 1989, these basic contours remained unchanged.
  • 63
    • 33645125013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although the specific details of these rules were changed on several occasions, this basic structure of open-list proportional representation remained unaltered.
  • 64
    • 84924460246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It should be noted that, according to the findings of the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems, 1996-2000, 62 percent of respondents in Poland could not remember the name of any candidate for the Sejm who ran in their electoral district; (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), Under closed-list proportional representation, voters can influence only the distribution of seats among political parties. Under this arrangement, the distribution of seats to specific candidates is based on their list placement rather than on their vote totals
    • It should be noted that, according to the findings of the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems, 1996-2000, 62 percent of respondents in Poland could not remember the name of any candidate for the Sejm who ran in their electoral district; see Pippa Norris, Electoral Engineering: Voting Rules and Political Behavior (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004), 239. Under closed-list proportional representation, voters can influence only the distribution of seats among political parties. Under this arrangement, the distribution of seats to specific candidates is based on their list placement rather than on their vote totals.
    • (2004) Electoral Engineering: Voting Rules and Political Behavior , pp. 239
    • Norris, P.1
  • 65
    • 33645119732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • t is a vote share received by party i at time t, and I = {1,2, ... n} is the set of all parties.
  • 66
    • 33645118151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In 1993 the following parties were new: Center Alliance, Catholic Electoral Committee/Fatherland, Non-party Bloc for Support of Reforms, Self-Defense, Coalition for the Republic, Democratic Women's Forum. In 1997 new parties were Block for Poland, National Pensioners' and Retired Persons' Alliance, National Party of Pensioners and Retired Persons, Solidarity Electoral Action, Movement for Reconstruction of Poland. Finally, in 2001 the list of new parties included Law and Justice, Citizen Platform, League of Polish Families, Alternative Social Movement.
  • 67
    • 33645125577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In 1991 governing parties were Democratic Union, Democratic Party, Peasant Alliance. In 1993 governing parties were Democratic Union, Liberal-Democratic Congress, Polish Economic Alliance business lobby, Peasant Alliance, and Catholic Electoral Action Fatherland (Christian/ National Union, Christian Peasant Alliance, Christian Democratic Party). In 1997 governing parties were Union of Democratic Left (SLD) and Polish Agrarian Party (PSL). In 2001 governing parties were Solidarity Electoral Action (AWS) and Freedom Union (UW). (Our results are robust to different classification criteria.).
  • 68
    • 33645118706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Since all incumbents who run on the national list also run in their districts, we observe Δu for these candidates as well.
  • 69
    • 33645120777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • j,). Ours is not a sample but the inventory (record) of the appropriate units of observation. Thus, an inferential statistic, p value in particular, has only hypothetical (counterfactual) interpretation. Moreover, since some parliamentarians run more than once, the units of observation are not independent. Using various versions of mixed-effects logistic regression models and different procedures for controlling for a subset of dependent observations convinced us that the results presented here are relatively robust and solid.
  • 70
    • 33645129511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The inclusion of candidates from the national list biases our analysis against the hypothesis that elections function as a mechanism of accountability. Since candidates whose names appear on the national list may be able to enter the parliament even though they lose in their districts, they are frequently reelected, although Δu is high. As a result, the conclusion that elections function as a mechanism of accountability is based on a conservative test.
  • 71
    • 33645125899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In addition regression models, we used two other variables, besides unemployment, that are related to economic performance: inflation rate (on the national level) and change in earnings per capita (at the district level). The effects of each of these variables taken alone and in the interaction terms are substantively similar to the effects of unemployment, but the estimated coefficients have large standard errors, thus making them statistically insignificant. In this article we focus on unemployment to make our statistical models as parsimonious as possible. We think that fruitful extensions of our models would take into account noneconomic measures of performance (such as corruption) rather than supplementary measures of economic performance (such as inflation). However, such data are not yet available at the district level.
  • 72
    • 18044370385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Party Fluidity and Legislators' Vote Choices: The Italian Chamber of Deputies, 1996-2000"
    • In addition to references (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, August 30-September 2)
    • In addition to references cited in fn. 1, see Carol Mershon and William B. Heller, "Party Fluidity and Legislators' Vote Choices: The Italian Chamber of Deputies, 1996-2000" (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, August 30-September 2, 2001);
    • (2001)
    • Mershon, C.1    Heller, W.B.2
  • 73
    • 46449108676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Switching in Parliamentary Parties: Exits and Entries in Parliamentary Groups in the Italian Chamber of Deputies, 1995-2001"
    • (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, August 28-31)
    • William B. Heller and Carol Mershon, "Switching in Parliamentary Parties: Exits and Entries in Parliamentary Groups in the Italian Chamber of Deputies, 1995-2001" (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, August 28-31, 2003);
    • (2003)
    • Heller, W.B.1    Mershon, C.2
  • 74
    • 84858568855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Party Switching and Political Careers in the Spanish Congress of Deputies, 1982-1996"
    • (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, April 3-6)
    • Carol Mershon and William B. Heller, "Party Switching and Political Careers in the Spanish Congress of Deputies, 1982-1996" (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, April 3-6,2003);
    • (2003)
    • Mershon, C.1    Heller, W.B.2
  • 75
    • 84858554371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Impact of Party Switching on Legislative Behavior in Brazil's Chamber of Deputies"
    • (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, University of Arizona, Tucson)
    • and Scott W. Desposato, "The Impact of Party Switching on Legislative Behavior in Brazil's Chamber of Deputies" (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, University of Arizona, Tucson, 2004).
    • (2004)
    • Desposato, S.W.1
  • 76
    • 3242748930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Parties for Rent? Ambition, Ideology, and Party Switching in Brazil's Chamber of Deputies"
    • (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, University of Arizona, Tucson)
    • See Desposato (fn. 1);
    • (2002)
    • Desposato, S.1
  • 77
    • 2942748491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Electoral Consequences of Party Switching by Incumbent Members of Congress, 1947-2000"
    • (February)
    • Christian R. Grose and Antoine Yoshinaka, "The Electoral Consequences of Party Switching by Incumbent Members of Congress, 1947-2000," Legislative Studies Quarterly 28 (February 2003);
    • (2003) Legislative Studies Quarterly , vol.28
    • Grose, C.R.1    Yoshinaka, A.2
  • 78
    • 0038608601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Successful Re-election Strategies in Brazil: The Electoral Impact of District Institutional Incentives"
    • (September)
    • and Carlos Pereira and Lucio Renno, "Successful Re-election Strategies in Brazil: The Electoral Impact of District Institutional Incentives," Electoral Studies 22 (September 2003).
    • (2003) Electoral Studies , vol.22
    • Pereira, C.1    Renno, L.2
  • 81
    • 18044370385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Party Fluidity and Legislators' Vote Choices: The Italian Chamber of Deputies, 1996-2000"
    • (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Sciences Association, San Francisco, August 30-September 2)
    • Mershon and Heller (fn. 27, 2001);
    • (2001)
    • Mershon, C.1    Heller, W.B.2
  • 82
    • 84858554371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Impact of Party Switching on Legislative Behavior in Brazil's Chamber of Deputies"
    • (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, University of Arizona, Tucson)
    • and Desposato (fn. 27).
    • (2004)
    • Desposato, S.W.1
  • 83
    • 33645112885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This model does not include g and g x Δu because the information on membership in a governing party is contained in s and s x Δu.
  • 85
    • 0003347306 scopus 로고
    • "The Leninist Legacy,"
    • Ivo Banac, ed., (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press)
    • Kenneth Jowitt, "The Leninist Legacy," in Ivo Banac, ed., Eastern Europe in Revolution (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1992);
    • (1992) Eastern Europe in Revolution
    • Jowitt, K.1
  • 86
    • 84965432251 scopus 로고
    • "The Place of 'Party'in Post-communist Europe,"
    • Matthew Wyman, Stephen White, Bill Miller, and Paul Heywood, "The Place of 'Party'in Post-communist Europe," Party Politics 1, no. 4 (1995);
    • (1995) Party Politics , vol.1 , Issue.4
    • Wyman, M.1    White, S.2    Miller, B.3    Heywood, P.4
  • 87
    • 0001983983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Parliamentary and Electoral Politics in Poland"
    • Paul Lewis, ed., (Cheltanham: Edward Elgar)
    • Stanislaw Gebethner, "Parliamentary and Electoral Politics in Poland," in Paul Lewis, ed., Party Structure and Organization in East-Central Europe (Cheltanham: Edward Elgar, 1996);
    • (1996) Party Structure and Organization in East-Central Europe
    • Gebethner, S.1
  • 90
    • 84858555830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Legislative Accountability in a New Presidential Democracy: Analysis of the Single Member District Elections to the Russian State Duma"
    • For similar findings, (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, The Ohio State University, Columbus)
    • For similar findings, see Dinissa Duvanova, "Legislative Accountability in a New Presidential Democracy: Analysis of the Single Member District Elections to the Russian State Duma" (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, The Ohio State University, Columbus, 2004);
    • (2004)
    • Duvanova, D.1
  • 91
    • 84858566452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Fluid Party Systems, Electoral Rules and Accountability of Legislators in Emerging Democracies: The Case of Ukraine"
    • and for Ukraine, (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, September 1-4)
    • and for Ukraine, see Kazimierz M. Slomczynski, Goldie Shabad, and Jakub Zielinski, "Fluid Party Systems, Electoral Rules and Accountability of Legislators in Emerging Democracies: The Case of Ukraine" (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, September 1-4, 2004).
    • (2004)
    • Slomczynski, K.M.1    Shabad, G.2    Zielinski, J.3
  • 94
    • 26444599068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Patterns of Party Competition and Electoral Accountability in Latin America: An Overview"
    • (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, August 28-31)
    • and Herbert Kitschelt and Elizabeth Zechmeister, "Patterns of Party Competition and Electoral Accountability in Latin America: An Overview" (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, August 28-31, 2003).
    • (2003)
    • Kitschelt, H.1    Zechmeister, Z.2
  • 95
    • 84888712512 scopus 로고
    • "A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of Political Context"
    • For discussions of the relationship between institutions that promote clarity of responsibility and electoral accountability, (May)
    • For discussions of the relationship between institutions that promote clarity of responsibility and electoral accountability, see Powell and Whitten (fn. 6);
    • (1993) American Journal of Political Science , vol.35
    • Powell Jr., G.B.1    Whitten, G.D.2
  • 102
    • 84858560312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Democratic Regimes and Accountability for the Economy in Comparative Perspective"
    • (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, September 1-4)
    • and Samuels and Hellwig (fn. 10).
    • (2004)
    • Samuels, D.1    Hellwig, T.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.