메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 76, Issue 3, 2001, Pages 825-872

Democracy, taxes, and wealth

(1)  Repetti, James R a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 26444526808     PISSN: 00287881     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (29)

References (343)
  • 1
    • 26444602928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • House Fails to Override Clinton Veto of Estate Tax Repeal Bill
    • Congress passed a bill repealing the estate tax in 1999. Death Tax Elimination Act, H.R. 8, 106th Cong. (1999). However, President Clinton vetoed the bill and House Republicans failed to override the veto. Ryan J. Donmoyer, House Fails to Override Clinton Veto of Estate Tax Repeal Bill, 88 Tax Notes 1292, 1292 (2000).
    • (2000) Tax Notes , vol.88 , pp. 1292
    • Donmoyer, R.J.1
  • 2
    • 26444509721 scopus 로고
    • (June 19, 1935), in H.R. Rep. No. 74-1681
    • Franklin D. Roosevelt, Message to Congress (June 19, 1935), in H.R. Rep. No. 74-1681, at 2 (1935).
    • (1935) Message to Congress , pp. 2
    • Roosevelt, F.D.1
  • 3
    • 0004256579 scopus 로고
    • app. tbl.A-1
    • Edward N. Wolff, Top Heavy app. at 62 tbl.A-1 (1995).
    • (1995) Top Heavy , pp. 62
    • Wolff, E.N.1
  • 4
    • 57649148134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. Net worth is defined as the value of real estate, securities, cash and demand deposits, pension plans, unincorporated businesses, and interests in trusts, less debt. Id. at 1.
  • 5
    • 0001174205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Economic Growth since 1870: One Big Wave?
    • The growth rate of multifactor productivity for the period 1929-1996 was as follows: 1928-1950 1.90% 1950-1964 2.35% 1964-1972 2.07% 1972-1979 1.12% 1979-1988 0.90% 1988-1996 0.67% Robert J. Gordon, U.S. Economic Growth Since 1870: One Big Wave?, 89 Am. Econ. Rev. 123, 124 (1999).
    • (1999) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 123
    • Gordon, R.J.1
  • 6
    • 57649184164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wolff, supra note 3, app. at 62 tbl.A-1
    • Wolff, supra note 3, app. at 62 tbl.A-1.
  • 7
    • 0000851789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent Trends in the Size Distribution of Household Wealth
    • Summer
    • Edward N. Wolff, Recent Trends in the Size Distribution of Household Wealth, J. Econ. Persp., Summer 1998, at 131, 135.
    • (1998) J. Econ. Persp. , pp. 131
    • Wolff, E.N.1
  • 8
    • 57649206425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 149
    • Id. at 149.
  • 9
    • 0004178193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Wolff, supra note 3, at 23 fig.5-1 (comparing wealth distribution in United States and United Kingdom from 1920 to 1990)
    • Bruce Ackerman & Anne Alstott, The Stakeholder Society 95 (1999); see also Wolff, supra note 3, at 23 fig.5-1 (comparing wealth distribution in United States and United Kingdom from 1920 to 1990).
    • (1999) The Stakeholder Society , pp. 95
    • Ackerman, B.1    Alstott, A.2
  • 10
    • 0346094963 scopus 로고
    • Curtailing Inherited Wealth
    • For reviews of various justifications for the estate tax, see, for example, Mark L. Ascher, Curtailing Inherited Wealth, 89 Mich. L. Rev. 69, 87-99 (1990) (reviewing reasons to curtail inheritance, including leveling playing field and increasing charitable giving);
    • (1990) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 69
    • Ascher, M.L.1
  • 11
    • 0041049952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enlivening the Death-Tax Death-Talk
    • Charles Davenport & Jay A. Soled, Enlivening the Death-Tax Death-Talk, 84 Tax Notes 591, 597-602 (1999) (reviewing justifications for estate tax, including raising revenue, progressivity, and diminishing concentrations of wealth);
    • (1999) Tax Notes , vol.84 , pp. 591
    • Davenport, C.1    Soled, J.A.2
  • 12
    • 26444468419 scopus 로고
    • The Rise and Decline of the Estate Tax
    • Louis Eisenstein, The Rise and Decline of the Estate Tax, 11 Tax L. Rev. 223, 235-36 (1956) (describing Roosevelt's justification for estate tax as means of preventing overconcentration of wealth);
    • (1956) Tax L. Rev. , vol.11 , pp. 223
    • Eisenstein, L.1
  • 13
    • 84926274019 scopus 로고
    • To Praise the Estate Tax, Not to Bury It
    • Michael J. Graetz, To Praise the Estate Tax, Not to Bury It, 93 Yale L.J. 259, 269-73 (1983) (describing role of estate tax in providing progressivity in tax system);
    • (1983) Yale L.J. , vol.93 , pp. 259
    • Graetz, M.J.1
  • 14
    • 84926272562 scopus 로고
    • Reforming Federal Wealth Transfer Taxes after ERTA
    • Harry L. Gutman, Reforming Federal Wealth Transfer Taxes After ERTA, 69 Va. L. Rev. 1183, 1190-92 (1983) (discussing role of estate tax in ensuring that wealth derived from tax-preferred sources is subject to tax);
    • (1983) Va. L. Rev. , vol.69 , pp. 1183
    • Gutman, H.L.1
  • 15
    • 0039271322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for the Estate and Gift Tax
    • James R. Repetti, The Case for the Estate and Gift Tax, 86 Tax Notes 1493, 1494-1500 (2000) (reviewing estate tax objectives of raising revenues, preventing wealth concentration and family dynasties, encouraging charitable contributions, and making income tax more progressive).
    • (2000) Tax Notes , vol.86 , pp. 1493
    • Repetti, J.R.1
  • 16
    • 57649227222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Parts I.B.3 and I.B.4
    • See infra Parts I.B.3 and I.B.4.
  • 17
    • 57649152925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I.C
    • See infra Part I.C.
  • 18
    • 57649143979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra note 142
    • See infra note 142.
  • 19
    • 57649220733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 39-48 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 39-48 and accompanying text.
  • 20
    • 57649219065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra part I.C.2
    • See infra part I.C.2.
  • 21
    • 57649149589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra note 142
    • See infra note 142.
  • 22
    • 0040349512 scopus 로고
    • Ascher, supra note 10, at 76-84
    • For excellent discussions of this debate, see Ronald Chester, Inheritance, Wealth, and Society 11-33 (1982); Ascher, supra note 10, at 76-84.
    • (1982) Inheritance, Wealth, and Society , pp. 11-33
    • Chester, R.1
  • 23
    • 0347568479 scopus 로고
    • Peter Laslett ed., Cambridge Univ. Press
    • John Locke, Two Treatises of Government 206-07, 210 (Peter Laslett ed., Cambridge Univ. Press 1988) (1690);
    • (1988) Two Treatises of Government , Issue.1690 , pp. 206-207
    • Locke, J.1
  • 24
    • 0042621234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Taxation of Inheritance and Wealth Transfers
    • Robert K. Miller, Jr. & Stephen J. McNamee eds.
    • see also Barry W. Johnson & Martha Britton Eller, Federal Taxation of Inheritance and Wealth Transfers, in Inheritance and Wealth in America 61, 62 (Robert K. Miller, Jr. & Stephen J. McNamee eds., 1998) (summarizing Locke's theories on property inheritance).
    • (1998) Inheritance and Wealth in America , pp. 61
    • Johnson, B.W.1    Eller, M.B.2
  • 25
    • 57649220208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Chester, supra note 17, at 13-14 (explaining Locke's theories)
    • See Chester, supra note 17, at 13-14 (explaining Locke's theories).
  • 26
    • 0041702381 scopus 로고
    • Principles of the Civil Code
    • C.K. Ogden ed., Harcourt, Brace & Co.
    • Jeremy Bentham, Principles of the Civil Code, in The Theory of Legislation 88, 122 (C.K. Ogden ed., Harcourt, Brace & Co. 1931) (1802).
    • (1931) The Theory of Legislation , Issue.1802 , pp. 88
    • Bentham, J.1
  • 27
    • 0003764649 scopus 로고
    • W.J. Ashley ed. Longmans, Green & Co.
    • John Stuart Mill, Principles of Political Economy 808 (W.J. Ashley ed. Longmans, Green & Co. 1923) (1848).
    • (1923) Principles of Political Economy , Issue.1848 , pp. 808
    • Mill, J.S.1
  • 28
    • 57649218025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2 William Blackstone, Commentaries *10-*13; see also Chester, supra note 17, at 19 (noting Blackstone's criticism of natural law argument).
  • 30
    • 84902727641 scopus 로고
    • The Uneasy Case for Wealth Transfer Taxation
    • Edward J. McCaffery, The Uneasy Case for Wealth Transfer Taxation, 104 Yale L.J. 283, 295-96 (1994). In the text I place quotation marks around the word "liberal" because, as Eric Rakowski has stated, "[l]iberalism is a woolly doctrine, a canopy sheltering a colorful array of theories . . . ."
    • (1994) Yale L.J. , vol.104 , pp. 283
    • McCaffery, E.J.1
  • 31
    • 0345876860 scopus 로고
    • Transferring Wealth Liberally
    • Eric Rakowski, Transferring Wealth Liberally, 51 Tax L. Rev. 419, 419 (1995). See infra Part II.C for a discussion of the empirical evidence that suggests that taxation has a minimal effect on saving.
    • (1995) Tax L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 419
    • Rakowski, E.1
  • 34
    • 0040455935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Death Tax: Investments, Employment, and Entrepreneurs
    • E.g., Douglas Holtz-Eakin, The Death Tax: Investments, Employment, and Entrepreneurs, 84 Tax Notes 782 (1999) (arguing that estate taxes adversely affect entrepreneurial activity).
    • (1999) Tax Notes , vol.84 , pp. 782
    • Holtz-Eakin, D.1
  • 35
    • 26444554420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Entrepreneurs and the Estate Tax
    • But see James R. Repetti, Entrepreneurs and the Estate Tax, 84 Tax Notes 1541 (1999) (arguing that Holtz-Eakin's methodology in fact shows that estate taxes do not materially affect saving and entrepreneurial activity).
    • (1999) Tax Notes , vol.84 , pp. 1541
    • Repetti, J.R.1
  • 37
    • 0040097456 scopus 로고
    • A Note on Subsidizing Gifts
    • See generally Louis Kaplow, A Note on Subsidizing Gifts, 58 J. Pub. Econ. 469 (1995).
    • (1995) J. Pub. Econ. , vol.58 , pp. 469
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 38
    • 1642449290 scopus 로고
    • Henry Reeve trans., Alfred A. Knopf
    • Alexis de Tocqueville, 1 Democracy in America 48 (Henry Reeve trans., Alfred A. Knopf 1945) (1835).
    • (1945) Democracy in America , vol.1 , Issue.1835 , pp. 48
    • De Tocqueville, A.1
  • 39
    • 26444573634 scopus 로고
    • Letter from Thomas Jefferson to James Madison (Sept. 6, 1789), in 5 The Writings Of Thomas Jefferson 115-16 (Paul Leicester Ford ed., 1895) (quotation marks omitted).
    • (1895) The Writings of Thomas Jefferson , vol.5 , pp. 115-116
    • Ford, P.L.1
  • 41
    • 84896248668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Should Men Leave Great Fortunes to Their Children?
    • supra note 18
    • Peter Dobkin Hall & George E. Marcus, Why Should Men Leave Great Fortunes to Their Children?, in Inheritance and Wealth in America, supra note 18 at 139, 142.
    • Inheritance and Wealth in America , pp. 139
    • Hall, P.D.1    Marcus, G.E.2
  • 42
    • 57649220219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prescott v. Tarbell, 1 Mass. (1 Will.) 204, 208 (1804)
    • Prescott v. Tarbell, 1 Mass. (1 Will.) 204, 208 (1804).
  • 43
    • 57649203107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mass. Gen. Laws ch. 87 § 1 (1818); see also Hall & Marcus, supra note 33, at 145 (noting enactment of trust legislation in Massachusetts)
    • Mass. Gen. Laws ch. 87 § 1 (1818); see also Hall & Marcus, supra note 33, at 145 (noting enactment of trust legislation in Massachusetts).
  • 45
    • 57649171911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Act of September 8, 1916, ch. 463, 39 Stat. 777-780, 1002 (1916)
    • Act of September 8, 1916, ch. 463, 39 Stat. 777-780, 1002 (1916).
  • 46
    • 25644451787 scopus 로고
    • Some Impending National Problems
    • Irving Fisher, Some Impending National Problems, 24 J. Pol. Econ. 694, 711 (1916).
    • (1916) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.24 , pp. 694
    • Fisher, I.1
  • 47
    • 0008896494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inequality and Economic Growth: The Perspective of the New Growth Theories
    • Philippe Aghion et al., Inequality and Economic Growth: The Perspective of the New Growth Theories, 37 J. Econ. Lit. 1615, 1617 (1999).
    • (1999) J. Econ. Lit. , vol.37 , pp. 1615
    • Aghion, P.1
  • 48
    • 1542527134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the Data Say
    • E.g., Aghion et al., supra note 39, at 1617-18; Roberto Perotti, Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the Data Say, 1 J. Econ. Growth 149, 154 (1996).
    • (1996) J. Econ. Growth , vol.1 , pp. 149
    • Perotti, R.1
  • 49
    • 0002639451 scopus 로고
    • Distribution, Political Conflict and Economic Growth: A Simple Theory and Some Empirical Evidence
    • Alex Cukierman et al. eds., hereinafter Alesina & Rodrik, Distribution
    • E.g., Alberto Alesina & Dani Rodrik, Distribution, Political Conflict and Economic Growth: A Simple Theory and Some Empirical Evidence, in Political Economy, Growth, and Business Cycles 23, 34 (Alex Cukierman et al. eds., 1992) [hereinafter Alesina & Rodrik, Distribution] (describing results of model where increases in income shares of wealthiest population segments are associated with decreases in growth);
    • (1992) Political Economy, Growth, and Business Cycles , pp. 23
    • Alesina, A.1    Rodrik, D.2
  • 50
    • 84942834707 scopus 로고
    • Distributive Politics and Economic Growth
    • hereinafter Alesina & Rodrik, Distributive Politics
    • Alberto Alesina & Dani Rodrik, Distributive Politics and Economic Growth, 109 Q.J. Econ. 465, 481 (1994) [hereinafter Alesina & Rodrik, Distributive Politics] (summarizing results of study as indicating that income inequality and subsequent growth are negatively correlated);
    • (1994) Q.J. Econ. , vol.109 , pp. 465
    • Alesina, A.1    Rodrik, D.2
  • 51
    • 0041009953 scopus 로고
    • Growth, Distribution, and Human Resources
    • Gustav Ranis ed.
    • François Bourguignon, Growth, Distribution, and Human Resources, in En Route to Modern Growth: Latin America in the 1990s at 43, 58 (Gustav Ranis ed., 1994) (describing inverse relationship between income inequality and growth suggested by study);
    • (1994) En Route to Modern Growth: Latin America in the 1990s , pp. 43
    • Bourguignon, F.1
  • 52
    • 0002277070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Growth, Distribution, and Politics
    • supra, hereinafter Persson & Tabellini, Growth
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 159 (finding that growth is positively associated with income equality); Torsten Persson & Guido Tabellini, Growth, Distribution, and Politics, in Political Economy, Growth, and Business Cycles, supra, at 11-15, 18 [hereinafter Persson & Tabellini, Growth] (concluding that income inequality is bad for growth);
    • Political Economy, Growth, and Business Cycles , pp. 11-15
    • Persson, T.1    Tabellini, G.2
  • 53
    • 0028591926 scopus 로고
    • Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?
    • hereinafter Persson & Tabellini, Inequality
    • Torsten Persson & Guido Tabellini, Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?, 84 Am. Econ. Rev. 600, 607, 617 (1994) [hereinafter Persson & Tabellini, Inequality] (same). It is important to note that rapid growth occasionally can occur, even with high concentrations of income, because many factors influence growth. For example, one commentator has suggested that the rapid growth in the late 1990s was attributable to an explosive increase in the use of computers. Pam Woodall, Survey: The New Economy, The Economist, Sept. 23, 2000, insert after 66, at 11-19. The studies of twenty-five years or more obviously span periods of both rapid growth and recession. The authors of the studies constructed multiple regression models that included several factors, in addition to income concentration, that may impact growth. The authors then tested their models using empirical data for the periods. The results of the regression models in all the studies show that there is statistically significant negative correlation between income concentration at the beginning of the period and subsequent growth. That is, high income concentration appears to be related to poor growth during the period, accounting for all other parameters included in the regression models. The findings of the long-term studies suggest that even in periods of rapid productivity growth, high concentrations of income cause slower growth than it otherwise would have been. Thus, wealth concentration is a serious matter, even during periods of high growth.
    • (1994) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 600
    • Persson, T.1    Tabellini, G.2
  • 59
    • 0032464748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Ways of Looking at Old Issues: Inequality and Growth
    • see also Klaus Deininger & Lyn Squire, New Ways of Looking at Old Issues: Inequality and Growth, 57 J. Dev. Econ. 259, 266-69 (1998) (finding that inequality in initial land distribution in 1960 correlated with poor economic growth for period 1960-1992).
    • (1998) J. Dev. Econ. , vol.57 , pp. 259
    • Deininger, K.1    Squire, L.2
  • 60
    • 57649190741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 182
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 182.
  • 61
    • 57649151536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Persson & Tabellini, Inequality, supra note 41
    • Persson & Tabellini, Inequality, supra note 41.
  • 62
    • 0029487977 scopus 로고
    • More Evidence on Income Distribution and Growth
    • George R.G. Clarke, More Evidence on Income Distribution and Growth, 47 J. Dev. Econ. 403, 422-24 (1995).
    • (1995) J. Dev. Econ. , vol.47 , pp. 403
    • Clarke, G.R.G.1
  • 64
    • 57649190792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 3 (reprinting data from World Bank and Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development)
    • Id. at 3 (reprinting data from World Bank and Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development).
  • 65
    • 0004261523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res., Working Paper No. 7038
    • Robert J. Barro, Inequality, Growth, and Investment 32 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res., Working Paper No. 7038, 1999).
    • (1999) Inequality, Growth, and Investment , pp. 32
    • Barro, R.J.1
  • 67
    • 0345262783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Income Distribution and Growth in Industrial Countries
    • Vito Tanzi & Ke-young Chu eds.
    • Andrea Brandolini & Nicola Rossi, Income Distribution and Growth in Industrial Countries, in Income Distribution and High-Quality Growth 69, 87-89 (Vito Tanzi & Ke-young Chu eds., 1998);
    • (1998) Income Distribution and High-Quality Growth , pp. 69
    • Brandolini, A.1    Rossi, N.2
  • 68
    • 0345059314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Income Inequality is Not Harmful for Growth: Theory and Evidence
    • Hongyi Li & Heng-Fu Zou, Income Inequality is Not Harmful for Growth: Theory and Evidence, 2 Rev. Dev. Econ. 318, 327 (1998) (finding "significant, positive association" between income inequality and economic growth).
    • (1998) Rev. Dev. Econ. , vol.2 , pp. 318
    • Li, H.1    Zou, H.-F.2
  • 69
    • 57649156723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Banerjee & Duflo, supra note 51, at 17-18
    • Banerjee & Duflo, supra note 51, at 17-18.
  • 70
    • 57649159934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aghion et al., supra note 39, at 1615
    • Aghion et al., supra note 39, at 1615.
  • 71
    • 57649193812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1620
    • Id. at 1620.
  • 72
    • 0002129055 scopus 로고
    • Economic Growth and Income Inequality
    • Simon Kuznets, Economic Growth and Income Inequality, 45 Am. Econ. Rev. 1, 7-8, 12-18 (1955);
    • (1955) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.45 , pp. 1
    • Kuznets, S.1
  • 73
    • 0002531516 scopus 로고
    • Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of Nations: Distribution of Income by Size
    • Jan. [hereinafter Kuznets, Quantitative Aspects]
    • see also Simon Kuznets, Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of Nations: Distribution of Income by Size, 11 Econ. Dev. & Cultural Change, Jan. 1963, Part II, at 1, 67-69 [hereinafter Kuznets, Quantitative Aspects].
    • (1963) Econ. Dev. & Cultural Change , vol.11 , Issue.2 PART , pp. 1
    • Kuznets, S.1
  • 75
    • 26444602877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inst. for Empirical Res. in Econ., Univ. of Zurich, Working Paper No. 31, Jan.
    • See Josef Zweimüller, Inequality, Redistribution, and Economic Growth 3-5 (Inst. for Empirical Res. in Econ., Univ. of Zurich, Working Paper No. 31, Jan. 2000) (noting increase in wealth concentration in industrialized countries); Deininger & Squire, supra note 44, at 275-76 (noting that inequality in several industrial countries has increased recently); supra text accompanying notes 3-9 (discussing same in United States).
    • (2000) Inequality, Redistribution, and Economic Growth , pp. 3-5
    • Zweimüller, J.1
  • 76
    • 57649209117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Zweimüller, supra note 58, at 3-5; Deininger & Squire, supra note 44, at 278
    • E.g., Zweimüller, supra note 58, at 3-5; Deininger & Squire, supra note 44, at 278.
  • 77
    • 26444485349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 41
    • Alesina & Rodrik, Distribution, supra note 41, at 23 (arguing that concentrated wealth in democracies leads to lower growth because growth-enhancing capital resources are taxed);
    • Distribution , pp. 23
    • Alesina1    Rodrik2
  • 78
    • 26444495984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 41
    • Persson & Tabellini, Growth, supra note 41, at 9 (discussing theory that higher taxes discourage investment, and that investment is prediction for growth);
    • Growth , pp. 9
    • Persson1    Tabellini2
  • 79
    • 26444537845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 41
    • Persson & Tabellini, Inequality, supra note 41, at 600 (presenting theory that policies like taxation that result in less private accumulation of capital also result in less growth);
    • Inequality , pp. 600
    • Persson1    Tabellini2
  • 80
    • 0000633783 scopus 로고
    • Factor Shares and Savings in Endogenous Growth
    • see also Giuseppe Bertola, Factor Shares and Savings in Endogenous Growth, 83 Am. Econ. Rev. 1184, 1191-92 (1993) (noting effects of distribution of wealth on fiscal policy and growth).
    • (1993) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 1184
    • Bertola, G.1
  • 84
    • 84977330059 scopus 로고
    • Taxation, Aggregate Activity and Economic Growth: Further Cross-Country Evidence on Some Supply-Side Hypotheses
    • Charles Garrison & Feng-Yao Lee, Taxation, Aggregate Activity and Economic Growth: Further Cross-Country Evidence on Some Supply-Side Hypotheses, 30 Econ. Inquiry 172 (1992).
    • (1992) Econ. Inquiry , vol.30 , pp. 172
    • Garrison, C.1    Lee, F.-Y.2
  • 85
    • 57649206918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 171
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 171.
  • 86
    • 84977367019 scopus 로고
    • Taxation, Aggregate Activity and Economic Growth: Cross-Country Evidence on Some Supply-Side Hypotheses
    • Id. at 170-71. One controversial study has found statistical support for the argument that higher marginal taxes are responsible for negative effects on the level of economic activity in countries with concentrated wealth. Reinhard B. Koester & Roger C. Kormendi, Taxation, Aggregate Activity and Economic Growth: Cross-Country Evidence on Some Supply-Side Hypotheses, 27 Econ. Inquiry 367 (1989). However, Charles Garrison and Feng-Yao Lee have concluded that the study's findings are the result of skewed data. Garrison & Lee, supra note 63, at 172.
    • (1989) Econ. Inquiry , vol.27 , pp. 367
    • Koester, R.B.1    Kormendi, R.C.2
  • 87
    • 84960558311 scopus 로고
    • Political Equilibrium, Income Distribution, and Growth
    • Roberto Perotti, Political Equilibrium, Income Distribution, and Growth, 60 Rev. Econ. Stud. 755, 771-72 (1993).
    • (1993) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.60 , pp. 755
    • Perotti, R.1
  • 88
    • 0000186801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Income Distribution, Redistributive Politics, and Economic Growth
    • See Aghion et al., supra note 39, at 1622, 1648-49 (suggesting that redistribution of wealth from rich to poor increases productivity, because marginal productivity of investment for rich is lower than that for poor, particularly for investment in education); Woojin Lee & John E. Roemer, Income Distribution, Redistributive Politics, and Economic Growth, 3 J. Econ. Growth 217, 233 (1998) (arguing that, although high tax rate theoretically could reduce private investment, it also boosts public investment in activities, such as education, that promote productivity);
    • (1998) J. Econ. Growth , vol.3 , pp. 217
    • Lee, W.1    Roemer, J.E.2
  • 89
    • 0001055209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inequality, Redistribution and Growth: A Challenge to the Conventional Political Economy Approach
    • see also Gilles Saint Paul & Thierry Verdier, Inequality, Redistribution and Growth: A Challenge to the Conventional Political Economy Approach, 40 Eur. Econ. Rev. 719, 725-26 (1996) (noting that redistribution via public education and crime reduction is not necessarily harmful for growth);
    • (1996) Eur. Econ. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 719
    • Paul, G.S.1    Verdier, T.2
  • 90
    • 43949166039 scopus 로고
    • Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation
    • cf. William Easterly & Sergio Rebelo, Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation, 32 J. Monetary Econ., 417, 419, 421-22 (1993) (observing that public investment in transportation and communications positively affects growth rates but noting that effects of income tax are difficult to isolate empirically).
    • (1993) J. Monetary Econ. , vol.32 , pp. 417
    • Easterly, W.1    Rebelo, S.2
  • 91
    • 57649150610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 171-72
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 171-72.
  • 92
    • 0004090919 scopus 로고
    • Ackerman & Alstott, supra note 9, at 160. For studies supporting this summary, see Robert Haveman & Barbara Wolfe, Succeeding Generations: On the Effects of Investments in Children 188 (1994) (noting "high correlation between being a teenage unmarried mother and a wide variety of indicators of low achievement (e.g., failing to complete high school, being on welfare, being poor, and being out of the labor force)");
    • (1994) Succeeding Generations: on the Effects of Investments in Children , pp. 188
    • Haveman, R.1    Wolfe, B.2
  • 95
    • 0003010524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Poor Families, Poor Outcomes: The Well-Being of Children and Youth
    • Greg J. Duncan & Jeanne Brooks-Gunn eds.
    • Jeanne Brooks-Gunn, Greg J. Duncan & Nancy Maritato, Poor Families, Poor Outcomes: The Well-Being of Children and Youth, in Consequences of Growing Up Poor 1, 10 (Greg J. Duncan & Jeanne Brooks-Gunn eds., 1997) (citing study showing that "income's effects on intelligence and verbal test scores [in the early childhood years] are quite large - about one-third of a standard deviation");
    • (1997) Consequences of Growing Up Poor , pp. 1
    • Brooks-Gunn, J.1    Duncan, G.J.2    Maritato, N.3
  • 96
    • 0001555787 scopus 로고
    • The Determinants of Children's Attainments: A Review of Methods and Findings
    • Robert Haveman & Barbara Wolfe, The Determinants of Children's Attainments: A Review of Methods and Findings, 33 J. Econ. Literature 1829, 1855-63 (1995) (describing studies that show strong correlation between family income level and child education as well as likelihood of teenage pregnancy);
    • (1995) J. Econ. Literature , vol.33 , pp. 1829
    • Haveman, R.1    Wolfe, B.2
  • 97
    • 0002104117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Effects of Long-Term Poverty on Physical Health of Children in the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth
    • supra
    • cf. Sanders Korenman & Jane Miller, Effects of Long-Term Poverty on Physical Health of Children in the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth, in Consequences of Growing up Poor, supra, at 70, 97-98 (finding correlation between poverty and poor physical health).
    • Consequences of Growing Up Poor , pp. 70
    • Korenman, S.1    Miller, J.2
  • 98
    • 0026956612 scopus 로고
    • Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States
    • Gary Solon, Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States, 82 Am. Econ. Rev. 393, 403-04 (1992);
    • (1992) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 393
    • Solon, G.1
  • 99
    • 0000306271 scopus 로고
    • Regression Toward Mediocrity in Economic Stature
    • David J. Zimmerman, Regression Toward Mediocrity in Economic Stature, 82 Am. Econ. Rev. 409, 427 (1992).
    • (1992) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 409
    • Zimmerman, D.J.1
  • 100
    • 84960609976 scopus 로고
    • Income Distribution and Macroeconomics
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 152
    • Oded Galor & Joseph Zeira, Income Distribution and Macroeconomics, 60 Rev. Econ. Stud. 35, 40 (1993); Perotti, supra note 40, at 152.
    • (1993) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.60 , pp. 35
    • Galor, O.1    Zeira, J.2
  • 101
    • 57649162887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Galor & Zeira, supra note 71, at 41, 43; Perotti, supra note 40, at 152
    • Galor & Zeira, supra note 71, at 41, 43; Perotti, supra note 40, at 152.
  • 102
    • 57649159933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 177-82
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 177-82.
  • 103
    • 57649206919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 104
    • 57649196793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 105
    • 57649206920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 106
    • 57649150609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 173-77
    • Id. at 173-77.
  • 107
    • 0000878939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social Conflict and Growth
    • Id. at 151; see also Jess Benhabib & Aldo Rustichini, Social Conflict and Growth, 1 J. Econ. Growth 125, 125-26 (1996) (noting study that found that investment rates are negatively correlated with political instability).
    • (1996) J. Econ. Growth , vol.1 , pp. 125
    • Benhabib, J.1    Rustichini, A.2
  • 108
    • 57649161792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 173-75, 182
    • Perotti, supra note 40, at 173-75, 182.
  • 109
    • 84937302717 scopus 로고
    • Equal-Dollars-Per-Voter: A Constitutional Principle of Campaign Finance
    • For articles asserting that an objective of democracy is to give all participants an equal voice, see, for example, Edward B. Foley, Equal-Dollars-Per-Voter: A Constitutional Principle of Campaign Finance, 94 Colum. L. Rev. 1204, 1204 (1994);
    • (1994) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 1204
    • Foley, E.B.1
  • 110
    • 0346097347 scopus 로고
    • Corruption, Equality, and Campaign Finance Reform
    • David A. Strauss, Corruption, Equality, and Campaign Finance Reform, 94 Colum. L. Rev. 1369, 1382 (1994).
    • (1994) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 1369
    • Strauss, D.A.1
  • 112
    • 57649214981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11
    • Id. at 11.
  • 113
    • 57649189332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 12
    • Id. at 12.
  • 114
    • 57649141265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 115
    • 57649214980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11-12
    • Id. at 11-12.
  • 116
    • 57649168872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11
    • Id. at 11.
  • 117
    • 0004146246 scopus 로고
    • E.g., id.; see also Robert A. Dahl, Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City 227 (1961) (describing how numerous old American cities have undergone political revolution whereby government became controlled by nonelite);
    • (1961) Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City , pp. 227
    • Dahl, R.A.1
  • 118
    • 0003939043 scopus 로고
    • cf. John P. Heinz et al., The Hollow Core: Private Interests in National Policy Making 392-93 (1993) (asserting that elites prefer policy decisions to be minimally acceptable to potential participants to keep them inactive and to prevent dilution of their own influence).
    • (1993) The Hollow Core: Private Interests in National Policy Making , pp. 392-393
    • Heinz, J.P.1
  • 119
    • 57649159929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 11-12
    • Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 11-12.
  • 120
    • 0348137741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Money and Institutional Power
    • Stephen Ansolabehere & James M. Snyder, Jr., Money and Institutional Power, 77 Tex. L. Rev. 1673, 1676-77 (1999) (explaining arguments that wealth is power and that campaign contributions buy influence);
    • (1999) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 1673
    • Ansolabehere, S.1    Snyder Jr., J.M.2
  • 121
    • 0003407509 scopus 로고
    • see also Nelson W. Polsby, Community Power and Political Theory 88 (1963) (noting strong political influence of one member of economic elite but speculating that this person's influence grew from political experience, not economic status).
    • (1963) Community Power and Political Theory , pp. 88
    • Polsby, N.W.1
  • 122
    • 26444468356 scopus 로고
    • How They're Doing in Muncie
    • Apr. 18, § 7 (Book Reviews)
    • Though not identified at the time of publication, it was later revealed that Muncie, Indiana was the setting for the Middletown studies. See, e.g., John Herbers, How They're Doing in Muncie, Ind., N.Y. Times, Apr. 18, 1982, § 7 (Book Reviews), at 11
    • (1982) Ind., N.Y. Times , pp. 11
    • Herbers, J.1
  • 126
    • 0004015158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5th ed.
    • Others also have argued that wealthy individuals and corporations exert too much influence over the media in their communities. E.g., Ben H. Bagdikian, The Media Monopoly 5-6 (5th ed. 1997) ("'Market dominant' corporations in the mass media have dominant influence over the public's news, information, public ideas, popular culture, and political attitudes.");
    • (1997) The Media Monopoly , pp. 5-6
    • Bagdikian, B.H.1
  • 128
    • 26444509326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Minority Discounts, Fair Market Value, and the Culture of Estate Taxation
    • For example, it is alleged that the Dupont family suppressed stories and editorials when they owned the largest newspapers in Delaware. Bagdikian, supra, at 42. Hollywood has expressed the theme as well. Frank Capra's classic movie It's a Wonderful Life portrayed a wealthy miser inflicting misery on his community. It's a Wonderful Life (Liberty Films 1946); see also William S. Blatt, Minority Discounts, Fair Market Value, and the Culture of Estate Taxation, 52 Tax L. Rev. 225, 250 (1997) (studying how wealth concentration has surfaced as popular concept and pointing to It's a Wonderful Life).
    • (1997) Tax L. Rev. , vol.52 , pp. 225
    • Blatt, W.S.1
  • 129
    • 57649172939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lynd & Lynd, supra note 91, at 475 (footnote omitted)
    • Lynd & Lynd, supra note 91, at 475 (footnote omitted).
  • 130
    • 57649214972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 476
    • Id. at 476.
  • 131
    • 57649193800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lynd & Lynd, supra note 92, at 360-61 (footnote omitted)
    • Lynd & Lynd, supra note 92, at 360-61 (footnote omitted).
  • 132
    • 57649172938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying note 110
    • See infra text accompanying note 110.
  • 133
    • 57649196785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 104-141
    • See infra text accompanying notes 104-141.
  • 134
    • 57649212357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 U.S.C. § 441b (1994)
    • 2 U.S.C. § 441b (1994).
  • 135
    • 57649209108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 441a(a)(1)(A)
    • Id. § 441a(a)(1)(A).
  • 136
    • 57649196784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 441a(a)(2)(A)
    • Id. § 441a(a)(2)(A).
  • 137
    • 57649159923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 11 C.F.R. §§ 114.1, 114.6 (2000)
    • 11 C.F.R. §§ 114.1, 114.6 (2000).
  • 138
    • 57649190774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. §§ 114.5(b)-(d)
    • Id. §§ 114.5(b)-(d).
  • 139
    • 57649190779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Buckley v. Valeo, 424 U.S. 1, 39-51 (1976) (per curiam) (holding unconstitutional, inter alia, $1000 limit on expenditures "relative" to political candidates).
  • 141
    • 26444444508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FEC Advisory Opinion 1976-72
    • reprinted Brookings Inst. eds.
    • FEC Advisory Opinion 1976-72, reprinted in Campaign Finance Reform: A Sourcebook 187-89 (Anthony Corrado et al., Brookings Inst. eds. 1997), available at http:// www.brook.edu/gs/cf/sourcebk/chap6.pdf; see also Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 45 (noting effects of congressional amendments to Federal Election Commission Act and FEC advisory opinions).
    • (1997) Campaign Finance Reform: A Sourcebook , pp. 187-189
    • Corrado, A.1
  • 142
    • 57649189322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 45
    • Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 45.
  • 143
    • 57649190775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (footnote omitted)
    • Id. (footnote omitted).
  • 145
    • 57649161791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at Who Paid for This Election?, http://www.opensecrets.org/pubs/bigpicture2000/overview/ who_paid.ihtml (last visited Apr. 13, 2001).
    • Who Paid for This Election?
  • 147
    • 57649182193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 148
    • 57649144367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 60
    • Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 60.
  • 149
    • 84971790739 scopus 로고
    • Explaining Senate Election Outcomes
    • E.g., Alan I. Abramowitz, Explaining Senate Election Outcomes, 82 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 385 (1988);
    • (1988) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 385
    • Abramowitz, A.I.1
  • 150
    • 84928846758 scopus 로고
    • A Sequential Model of U.S. Senate Elections
    • Charles Stewart III, A Sequential Model of U.S. Senate Elections, 14 Legis. Stud. Q. 567 (1989).
    • (1989) Legis. Stud. Q. , vol.14 , pp. 567
    • Stewart III, C.1
  • 151
    • 84930560736 scopus 로고
    • Money Versus Party Effort: Nominating for Governor
    • E.g., Sarah M. Morehouse, Money Versus Party Effort: Nominating for Governor, 34 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 706 (1990);
    • (1990) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.34 , pp. 706
    • Morehouse, S.M.1
  • 152
    • 0000068007 scopus 로고
    • Campaign Spending in Contests for Governor
    • Samuel C. Patterson, Campaign Spending in Contests for Governor, 35 W. Pol. Q. 457, 475-76 (1982).
    • (1982) W. Pol. Q. , vol.35 , pp. 457
    • Patterson, S.C.1
  • 153
    • 0010152973 scopus 로고
    • Bringing Home the Votes: Electoral Outcomes in State Legislative Races
    • E.g., Gregory A. Caldeira & Samuel C. Patterson, Bringing Home the Votes: Electoral Outcomes in State Legislative Races, 4 Pol. Behav. 33 (1982) (discussing elections in California and Iowa);
    • (1982) Pol. Behav. , vol.4 , pp. 33
    • Caldeira, G.A.1    Patterson, S.C.2
  • 154
    • 0013488189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legislative Elections and the Importance of Money
    • Anthony Gierzynski & David Breaux, Legislative Elections and the Importance of Money, 21 Legis. Stud. Q. 337 (1996) (analyzing twelve state legislative elections);
    • (1996) Legis. Stud. Q. , vol.21 , pp. 337
    • Gierzynski, A.1    Breaux, D.2
  • 155
    • 84934095749 scopus 로고
    • Campaign Expenditures and Legislative Elections in Florida
    • Michael W. Giles & Anita Pritchard, Campaign Expenditures and Legislative Elections in Florida, 10 Legis. Stud. Q. 71 (1985) (examining Florida House elections).
    • (1985) Legis. Stud. Q. , vol.10 , pp. 71
    • Giles, M.W.1    Pritchard, A.2
  • 156
    • 57649151580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abramowitz, supra note 112, at 397
    • Abramowitz, supra note 112, at 397.
  • 157
    • 57649150597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 158
    • 57649190765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Morehouse, supra note 113, at 722
    • Morehouse, supra note 113, at 722.
  • 160
    • 0002233951 scopus 로고
    • Interest Group Influence in the U.S. Congress
    • Richard A. Smith, Interest Group Influence in the U.S. Congress, 20 Legis. Stud. Q. 89 (1995) (same).
    • (1995) Legis. Stud. Q. , vol.20 , pp. 89
    • Smith, R.A.1
  • 161
    • 57649182183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Grenzke, supra note 118, at 150-51 (summarizing studies)
    • See Grenzke, supra note 118, at 150-51 (summarizing studies).
  • 162
    • 84934095019 scopus 로고
    • Issue Visibility and the Effects of PAC Money
    • Woodrow Jones, Jr. & K. Robert Keiser, Issue Visibility and the Effects of PAC Money, 68 Soc. Sci. Q. 170, 170 (1987) (citing Senate vote on deregulation of trucking industry as example of closer association between campaign contributions and legislative results).
    • (1987) Soc. Sci. Q. , vol.68 , pp. 170
    • Jones Jr., W.1    Keiser, K.R.2
  • 163
    • 57649168855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H.R. 4040, 97th Cong. (1981)
    • H.R. 4040, 97th Cong. (1981).
  • 164
    • 84934563728 scopus 로고
    • Campaign Contributions and Legislative Outcomes
    • Jean Reith Schroedel, Campaign Contributions and Legislative Outcomes, 39 W. Pol. Q. 371, 373-74, 383 (1986).
    • (1986) W. Pol. Q. , vol.39 , pp. 371
    • Schroedel, J.R.1
  • 165
    • 0027249785 scopus 로고
    • The Tobacco Industry, State Politics, and Tobacco Education in California
    • E.g., Michael Evans Begay, Michael Traynor & Stanton A. Glantz, The Tobacco Industry, State Politics, and Tobacco Education in California, 83 Am. J. Pub. Health 1214 (1993) (examining tobacco industry's influence on California legislature);
    • (1993) Am. J. Pub. Health , vol.83 , pp. 1214
    • Begay, M.E.1    Traynor, M.2    Glantz, S.A.3
  • 166
    • 0028074836 scopus 로고
    • Tobacco Industry Campaign Contributions Are Affecting Tobacco Control Policymaking in California
    • Stanton A. Glantz & Michael E. Begay, Tobacco Industry Campaign Contributions Are Affecting Tobacco Control Policymaking in California, 272 JAMA 1176 (1994) (same);
    • (1994) JAMA , vol.272 , pp. 1176
    • Glantz, S.A.1    Begay, M.E.2
  • 167
    • 0031779447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are Tobacco Industry Campaign Contributions Influencing State Legislative Behavior?
    • Fred Monardi & Stanton A. Glantz, Are Tobacco Industry Campaign Contributions Influencing State Legislative Behavior?, 88 Am. J. Pub. Health 918 (1998) (examining tobacco industry's influence on state legislatures in six states).
    • (1998) Am. J. Pub. Health , vol.88 , pp. 918
    • Monardi, F.1    Glantz, S.A.2
  • 168
    • 84976926667 scopus 로고
    • Campaign Contributions and Legislative Voting in the California Assembly
    • But see Jay K. Dow & James W. Endersby, Campaign Contributions and Legislative Voting in the California Assembly, 22 Am. Pol. Q. 334 (1994) (finding no effect of contributions by business groups or labor unions on California legislators).
    • (1994) Am. Pol. Q. , vol.22 , pp. 334
    • Dow, J.K.1    Endersby, J.W.2
  • 169
    • 84935413114 scopus 로고
    • Money and Access: Some Empirical Evidence
    • Laura I. Langbein, Money and Access: Some Empirical Evidence, 48 J. Pol. 1052, 1057-61 (1986) (suggesting relationship between contribution size and access).
    • (1986) J. Pol. , vol.48 , pp. 1052
    • Langbein, L.I.1
  • 170
    • 57649162880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1060-61
    • Id. at 1060-61.
  • 171
    • 84935976948 scopus 로고
    • What Makes PACs Tick? An Analysis of the Allocation Patterns of Economic Interest Groups
    • E.g., J. David Gopoian, What Makes PACs Tick? An Analysis of the Allocation Patterns of Economic Interest Groups, 28 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 259, 262-63 (1984) (discussing PAC desire to garner and maintain access); see also Smith, supra note 118, at 93-97 (summarizing studies evaluating influence of interest group contributions on voting discussions).
    • (1984) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.28 , pp. 259
    • Gopoian, J.D.1
  • 172
    • 0347806508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Market for Congressional Votes: Is Timing of Contributions Everything?
    • Thomas Stratmann, The Market for Congressional Votes: Is Timing of Contributions Everything?, 41 J.L. & Econ. 85, 109-10 (1998) (summarizing results of study that show that date of legislative event and motivation to influence congressional voting are important determinants of contribution timing).
    • (1998) J.L. & Econ. , vol.41 , pp. 85
    • Stratmann, T.1
  • 173
    • 0032272469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political Action Committee Spending and Senate Roll Call Voting
    • Peter T. Calcagno & John D. Jackson, Political Action Committee Spending and Senate Roll Call Voting, 97 Pub. Choice 569, 582 (1998) (concluding that Senate voting participation is increasing because of PAC contributions).
    • (1998) Pub. Choice , vol.97 , pp. 569
    • Calcagno, P.T.1    Jackson, J.D.2
  • 174
    • 57649196777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 582
    • Id. at 582.
  • 175
    • 0007146588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • All in a Day's Work: The Financial Rewards of Legislative Effectiveness
    • Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier & J. Tobin Grant, All in a Day's Work: The Financial Rewards of Legislative Effectiveness, 24 Legis. Stud. Q. 511, 519 (1999).
    • (1999) Legis. Stud. Q. , vol.24 , pp. 511
    • Box-Steffensmeier, J.M.1    Grant, J.T.2
  • 176
    • 57649151569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.R.C. § 1 et seq. (1994)
    • I.R.C. § 1 et seq. (1994).
  • 177
    • 57649168853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 86
    • Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 86.
  • 178
    • 0031498338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Electoral and Financial Effects of Changes in Committee Power: The Gramm-Rudman-Hollings Budget Reform, the Tax Reform Act of 1986, and the Money Committees in the House
    • Jeffrey Milyo, Electoral and Financial Effects of Changes in Committee Power: The Gramm-Rudman-Hollings Budget Reform, The Tax Reform Act of 1986, and the Money Committees in the House, 40 J.L. & Econ. 93, 97 (1997).
    • (1997) J.L. & Econ. , vol.40 , pp. 93
    • Milyo, J.1
  • 179
    • 57649206898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. 98-180, 97 Stat. 1128 (1983)
    • Pub. L. 98-180, 97 Stat. 1128 (1983).
  • 180
    • 57649212346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. 97-300, 96 Stat. 1322 (1982)
    • Pub. L. 97-300, 96 Stat. 1322 (1982).
  • 181
    • 57649193793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H.R. 4277, 98th Cong. (1984)
    • H.R. 4277, 98th Cong. (1984).
  • 182
    • 84971690586 scopus 로고
    • Buying Time: Moneyed Interests and the Mobilization of Bias in Congressional Committees
    • Richard L. Hall & Frank W. Wayman, Buying Time: Moneyed Interests and the Mobilization of Bias in Congressional Committees, 84 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 797 (1990).
    • (1990) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 797
    • Hall, R.L.1    Wayman, F.W.2
  • 183
    • 0030536409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Before the Roll Call: Interest Group Lobbying and Public Outcomes in House Committees
    • Id. at 809-10, 813-15; see also Diana Evans, Before the Roll Call: Interest Group Lobbying and Public Outcomes in House Committees, 49 Pol. Res. Q. 287 (1996) (examining relationship between interest group contributions and congressional committee activities).
    • (1996) Pol. Res. Q. , vol.49 , pp. 287
    • Evans, D.1
  • 184
    • 57649156707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hall & Wayman, supra note 137, at 810-11
    • Hall & Wayman, supra note 137, at 810-11.
  • 185
    • 57649151568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 86
    • Gierzynski, supra note 81, at 86.
  • 186
    • 0000018705 scopus 로고
    • Ballot Propositions and Information Costs: Direct Democracy and the Fatigued Voter
    • Shaun Bowler et al., Ballot Propositions and Information Costs: Direct Democracy and the Fatigued Voter, 45 W. Pol. Q. 559, 564 (1992) (stating that study of ballot initiatives in California indicates positive correlation between campaign spending against proposition and percentage of vote against proposition).
    • (1992) W. Pol. Q. , vol.45 , pp. 559
    • Bowler, S.1
  • 187
    • 0039271351 scopus 로고
    • Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes
    • Henry J. Aaron & Alicia H. Munnell, Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes, 45 Nat'l Tax J. 119, 131 (1992) (finding that fifty-two percent of wealth is inherited based on life-cycle saving approach);
    • (1992) Nat'l Tax J. , vol.45 , pp. 119
    • Aaron, H.J.1    Munnell, A.H.2
  • 188
    • 0001397830 scopus 로고
    • Intergenerational Transfers and Accumulation of Wealth
    • Fall
    • William G. Gale & John Karl Scholz, Intergenerational Transfers and Accumulation of Wealth, J. Econ. Persp., Fall 1994, at 145, 156-57 (finding that inheritance accounts for at least fifty-one percent of net worth accumulation when bequests are included);
    • (1994) J. Econ. Persp. , pp. 145
    • Gale, W.G.1    Scholz, J.K.2
  • 189
    • 0000100854 scopus 로고
    • The Role of Intergenerational Transfers in Aggregate Capital Accumulation
    • Laurence J. Kotlikoff & Lawrence H. Summers, The Role of Intergenerational Transfers in Aggregate Capital Accumulation, 89 J. Pol. Econ. 706, 722 (1981) (determining that majority of wealth held in 1974 was inherited).
    • (1981) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.89 , pp. 706
    • Kotlikoff, L.J.1    Summers, L.H.2
  • 190
    • 0001860237 scopus 로고
    • The Role of Intergenerational Transfers and Life Cycle Saving in the Accumulation of Wealth
    • Spring
    • But see Franco Modigliani, The Role of Intergenerational Transfers and Life Cycle Saving in the Accumulation of Wealth, J. Econ. Persp., Spring 1988, at 15, 18-19 (summarizing studies that show inherited wealth is less than twenty percent of individuals' total wealth).
    • (1988) J. Econ. Persp. , pp. 15
    • Modigliani, F.1
  • 192
    • 57649150590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 193
    • 26444616033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 48
    • See Paul Ryan, Inheritance: Symbols and Illusion, in Paying for Inequality, supra note 48, at 196-97 (arguing that when family businesses are passed down, adverse outcomes are likely in successor generations, since energy and ability of founder-owner are gone).
    • Inheritance: Symbols and Illusion, in Paying for Inequality , pp. 196-197
    • Ryan, P.1
  • 195
    • 0012041643 scopus 로고
    • Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged
    • This parallels one of the concerns that motivated adoption of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. § 41 (1994). Legislators were concerned that businesses controlling large amounts of wealth would use it to the detriment of citizens. See, e.g., Robert H. Lande, Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged, 34 Hastings L.J. 65, 118-119 (1982) (describing legislators' fears regarding power of big business to dominate democracy).
    • (1982) Hastings L.J. , vol.34 , pp. 65
    • Lande, R.H.1
  • 196
    • 84937294351 scopus 로고
    • "Them That's Got Shall Get": Inheritance and Achievement in Wealth Accumulation
    • Richard E. Ratcliff et al. eds.
    • Melvin L. Oliver et al., "Them That's Got Shall Get": Inheritance and Achievement in Wealth Accumulation, in 5 Research in Politics and Society: The Politics of Wealth and Inequality 69, 73-74 (Richard E. Ratcliff et al. eds., 1995)
    • (1995) Research in Politics and Society: The Politics of Wealth and Inequality , vol.5 , pp. 69
    • Oliver, M.L.1
  • 197
    • 0003984012 scopus 로고
    • app. 5 London: Saunders & Otley
    • (attributing quote to Alexis de Tocqueville, 2 Democracy in America app. 5 (London: Saunders & Otley, 1835)).
    • (1835) Democracy in America , vol.2
    • De Tocqueville, A.1
  • 198
    • 0039033335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Winner-Take-All Markets: Easing the Case for Progressive Taxation
    • The foregoing review of the harmful effects of wealth also might support a highly progressive income tax to reduce the wealth of those creating it. However, I favor a wealth transfer tax because it probably has less of an impact on savings than a highly progressive income tax. See text accompanying notes 221-233. For an excellent analysis of the role of a progressive income tax, see generally Martin J. McMahon, Jr. & Alice A. Abreu, Winner-Take-All Markets: Easing the Case for Progressive Taxation, 4 Fla. Tax Rev. 1, 12-21 (1998).
    • (1998) Fla. Tax Rev. , vol.4 , pp. 1
    • McMahon Jr., M.J.1    Abreu, A.A.2
  • 199
    • 57649144356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 66-67, 69-69 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 66-67, 69-69 and accompanying text.
  • 200
    • 0347040788 scopus 로고
    • A Brief for the Abolition of All Transfer Taxes
    • E.g., Joel C. Dobris, A Brief for the Abolition of All Transfer Taxes, 35 Syracuse L. Rev. 1215 (1984);
    • (1984) Syracuse L. Rev. , vol.35 , pp. 1215
    • Dobris, J.C.1
  • 201
    • 26444508323 scopus 로고
    • The Future of Transfer Taxation: Repeal, Restructuring and Refinement, or Replacement
    • John E. Donaldson, The Future of Transfer Taxation: Repeal, Restructuring and Refinement, or Replacement, 50 Wash. & Lee L. Rev. 539 (1993);
    • (1993) Wash. & Lee L. Rev. , vol.50 , pp. 539
    • Donaldson, J.E.1
  • 202
    • 0345779384 scopus 로고
    • To Bury the Estate Tax, Not to Praise It
    • McCaffery, supra note 24
    • Charles O. Galvin, To Bury the Estate Tax, Not To Praise It, 52 Tax Notes 1413 (1991); McCaffery, supra note 24.
    • (1991) Tax Notes , vol.52 , pp. 1413
    • Galvin, C.O.1
  • 203
    • 26444604267 scopus 로고
    • Beyond Estate and Gift Tax Reform: Including Gifts and Bequests in Income
    • E.g., Joseph M. Dodge, Beyond Estate and Gift Tax Reform: Including Gifts and Bequests in Income, 91 Harv. L. Rev. 1177 (1978).
    • (1978) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.91 , pp. 1177
    • Dodge, J.M.1
  • 204
    • 26444594740 scopus 로고
    • The Accessions Tax Proposal
    • E.g., William D. Andrews, The Accessions Tax Proposal, 22 Tax. L. Rev. 589 (1967).
    • (1967) Tax. L. Rev. , vol.22 , pp. 589
    • Andrews, W.D.1
  • 205
    • 1642285935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Comprehensive Wealth Tax
    • E.g., David Shakow & Reed Shuldiner, A Comprehensive Wealth Tax, 53 Tax L. Rev. 499 (2000).
    • (2000) Tax L. Rev. , vol.53 , pp. 499
    • Shakow, D.1    Shuldiner, R.2
  • 206
    • 26444554381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Remember the Alamo: The IRS Needs Ammunition in Its Fight Against the FLP
    • See, e.g., Laura E. Cunningham, Remember the Alamo: The IRS Needs Ammunition in Its Fight Against the FLP, 86 Tax Notes 1461, 1461-63 (2000) (discussing methods by which estate planners exploit current transfer tax system, including family limited partnerships);
    • (2000) Tax Notes , vol.86 , pp. 1461
    • Cunningham, L.E.1
  • 207
    • 26444539335 scopus 로고
    • Redoing the Estate and Gift Taxes Along Easy-to-Value Lines
    • Joseph M. Dodge, Redoing the Estate and Gift Taxes Along Easy-to-Value Lines, 43 Tax L. Rev. 241, 244 (1988) (outlining loopholes existing in current transfer tax system and proposing reforms to prevent undervaluation of gratuitous transfers); Gutman, supra note 10, at 1262-69 (discussing problems in current structure such as deferral of estate tax and special use valuation).
    • (1988) Tax L. Rev. , vol.43 , pp. 241
    • Dodge, J.M.1
  • 208
    • 57649161779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., McCaffery, supra note 24, at 320 (stating that for very wealthy, economic effects of estate tax regime favor consumption over savings).
  • 209
    • 57649168851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Office of Mgmt. and Budget, Budget of the United States Government, Historical Tables 41 tbl.2.5 (2000).
  • 210
    • 26444436678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Individual Income Tax Returns, 1998
    • Fall
    • The 1999 revenues from the estate and gift tax were $27.8 billion. Office of Mgmt. and Budget, supra note 157, at 41 tbl.2.5. Data found in David Campbell, Michael Parisi, and Brian Balkovic, Individual Income Tax Returns, 1998, in IRS, Statistics of Income Bulletin, Fall 2000, at 8, 34-38 tbl.2 [hereinafter IRS Bulletin], shows the total 1998 tax liability of individuals with adjusted gross income from $1 to $15,000 was $7.8 billion, and the total 1998 tax liability of individuals with adjusted gross incomes between $15,000 and $30,000 was $40.8 billion. Statistics for the 1999 individual income tax were not available at the time this article was written.
    • (2000) IRS, Statistics of Income Bulletin , pp. 8
    • Campbell, D.1    Parisi, M.2    Balkovic, B.3
  • 211
    • 0007092546 scopus 로고
    • Does the Estate Tax Raise Revenues?
    • Lawrence H. Summers ed.
    • B. Douglas Bernheim, Does the Estate Tax Raise Revenues?, in 1 Tax Policy and the Economy 113, 135 (Lawrence H. Summers ed., 1987).
    • (1987) Tax Policy and the Economy , vol.1 , pp. 113
    • Bernheim, B.D.1
  • 212
    • 57649162878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 124-26
    • Id. at 124-26.
  • 213
    • 57649212344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 126-31
    • Id. at 126-31.
  • 214
    • 57649156704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 126
    • Id. at 126.
  • 215
    • 57649214958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 127
    • Id. at 127.
  • 218
    • 57649190762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I.R.C. § 2503(b) (1994 & West Supp. 2001) excludes gifts of up to $10,000 per donee that a taxpayer makes each year.
  • 219
    • 57649150585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Poterba, supra note 165, at 15, 18
    • Poterba, supra note 165, at 15, 18.
  • 220
    • 0040901808 scopus 로고
    • tbl.11D Off. of Tax Analysis, U.S. Dept. of the Treasury, Paper No. 71, Aug.
    • A study found that in 1981, the average adjusted gross income of the children of decedents who died in 1982 with gross estates exceeding $10 million was $271,254 in 1981 dollars. David Joulfaian, The Distribution and Division of Bequests: Evidence from the Collation Study 42 tbl.11D (Off. of Tax Analysis, U.S. Dept. of the Treasury, Paper No. 71, Aug. 1994).
    • (1994) The Distribution and Division of Bequests: Evidence from the Collation Study , pp. 42
    • Joulfaian, D.1
  • 221
    • 57649150588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I.R.C. § 1(g) (1994 & West Supp. 2000); Rev. Proc. 99-42, 1999-46 I.R.B. 568 (providing cost-of-living adjustments for 2000).
  • 222
    • 57649182181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I.R.C. § 1(e) (1994 & West Supp. 2000); Rev. Proc. 99-42, 1999-46 I.R.B. 568 (providing cost-of-living adjustments for 2000).
  • 223
    • 57649172923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bernheim, supra note 159, at 131-32
    • Bernheim, supra note 159, at 131-32.
  • 224
    • 57649159917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 131
    • Id. at 131.
  • 225
    • 57649141240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 127 tbl.2, 131-32
    • Id. at 127 tbl.2, 131-32.
  • 227
    • 0003784868 scopus 로고
    • See Mervyn A. King & Dan Fullerton, The Taxation of Income from Capital 221-22 (1984) (explaining common assumption that nominal capital gains tax rate should be halved due to deferral advantage and halved again due to increase of basis at death and selective realization of losses); see also The Capital Gains Controversy, supra note 174, at 1 (noting that accrued gains disappear upon death).
    • (1984) The Taxation of Income from Capital , pp. 221-222
    • King, M.A.1    Fullerton, D.2
  • 228
    • 26444590305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Taxation of Capital Income and the Choice of Tax Base
    • See, e.g., Noël B. Cunningham, The Taxation of Capital Income and the Choice of Tax Base, 52 Tax L. Rev. 17, 41 (1996) (demonstrating how investors can reduce burden of normative income tax on capital income to amount equal to borrowing rate on net capital investment times tax rate).
    • (1996) Tax L. Rev. , vol.52 , pp. 17
    • Cunningham, N.B.1
  • 229
    • 57649193789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joulfaian, supra note 164, at 31
    • Joulfaian, supra note 164, at 31.
  • 230
    • 57649189311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 231
    • 57649212340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Joulfaian, supra note 164, tbl.24. Joulfaian computed the figures from the 1982 Estate Collation File. Id.
  • 232
    • 57649203722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 233
    • 57649214952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 157 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 157 and accompanying text.
  • 235
    • 0039271351 scopus 로고
    • Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes
    • Henry J. Aaron & Alicia H. Munnell, Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes, 45 Nat'l Tax J. 119, 131 (1992) (noting that statistics support finding that 52% of wealth is inherited); see also Kotlikoff & Summers, supra note 142, at 721, 730 (determining that 78% of wealth is inherited). But see Modigliani, supra note 142, at 21 (arguing that only 15.5% to 18.5% of total wealth is inherited).
    • (1992) Nat'l Tax J. , vol.45 , pp. 119
    • Aaron, H.J.1    Munnell, A.H.2
  • 236
    • 57649161774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 6-7
    • See supra text accompanying notes 6-7.
  • 237
    • 26444542273 scopus 로고
    • Do Estate and Gift Taxes Affect Wealth Distribution? Part I
    • But see G.P. Verbit, Do Estate and Gift Taxes Affect Wealth Distribution? Part I, 117 Tr. & Est. 598, 598 (1978) (arguing that since wealth concentration has not changed, estate tax has no effect).
    • (1978) Tr. & Est. , vol.117 , pp. 598
    • Verbit, G.P.1
  • 239
    • 57649190761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Laitner, supra note 185, at 2
    • Laitner, supra note 185, at 2.
  • 240
    • 26444599489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Estate Tax Returns, 1995-1997
    • supra note 158, tbl.1c
    • The net estate tax paid with respect to 1997 taxable returns was $16.63 billion, and the aggregate taxable estates reported on such returns was $68.14 billion. Barry Johnson & Jacob Mikow, Federal Estate Tax Returns, 1995-1997, in IRS Bulletin, supra note 158, at 107-08 tbl.1c.
    • IRS Bulletin , pp. 107-108
    • Johnson, B.1    Mikow, J.2
  • 242
    • 0029687063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charitable Contributions and Intergenerational Transfers
    • Gerald Auten & David Joulfaian, Charitable Contributions and Intergenerational Transfers, 59 J. Pub. Econ. 55 (1996);
    • (1996) J. Pub. Econ. , vol.59 , pp. 55
    • Auten, G.1    Joulfaian, D.2
  • 243
    • 0001123607 scopus 로고
    • Charitable Bequests and Estate Taxes
    • David Joulfaian, Charitable Bequests and Estate Taxes, 44 Nat'l Tax J. 169 (1991). It is important to note, however, that estimates of price elasticities, which measure the percentage change in charitable giving to the percentage change in the after-tax cost of making the gift, vary considerably. Id. at 173-75 (attributing range of elasticity to factors including wealth, type of charity, marital status, age, and sex). Joulfaian suggests that the sensitivity of charitable contributions to the estate tax depends on the nature of the recipient. He found that bequests to religious organizations and schools are the most sensitive to the presence of the estate tax, while bequests to foundations and the arts and humanities are the least sensitive. Id. at 174-75.
    • (1991) Nat'l Tax J. , vol.44 , pp. 169
    • Joulfaian, D.1
  • 244
    • 57649206893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Columns 4 and 6 are the author's calculations. Columns 1, 2, 3, and 5 are from Johnson & Mikow, supra note 187, at 103-06 tbl.1c.
  • 245
    • 57649214951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joulfaian, supra note 168, at 6
    • Joulfaian, supra note 168, at 6.
  • 246
    • 57649196771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11
    • Id. at 11.
  • 247
    • 57649144355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 42
    • Id. at 42.
  • 248
    • 57649214953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An important exception to this rule is contained in I.R.C. § 2503(b) (1994 & West Supp. 2000), which exempts annual gifts of $10,000 or less per donee.
  • 249
    • 57649212338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., McCaffery, supra note 24, at 320 ("[F]or the very wealthy, economic effects of any estate tax regime favor consumption over savings . . . .").
  • 250
    • 57649209095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 182 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 182 and accompanying text.
  • 251
    • 0003875983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res., Working Paper No. 7061, Mar.
    • B. Douglas Bernheim, Taxation and Saving 5 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res., Working Paper No. 7061, Mar. 1999).
    • (1999) Taxation and Saving , pp. 5
    • Bernheim, B.D.1
  • 252
    • 57649141238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 253
    • 57649150580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., id. ("There is no theoretical presumption that either effect dominates.")
    • E.g., id. ("There is no theoretical presumption that either effect dominates.").
  • 254
    • 0040965654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do Estate Taxes Reduce Saving?
    • forthcoming
    • William G. Gale & Maria G. Perozek, Do Estate Taxes Reduce Saving?, in Rethinking Estate and Gift Taxation (forthcoming 2001) (manuscript at 6, on file with New York University Law Review);
    • (2001) Rethinking Estate and Gift Taxation
    • Gale, W.G.1    Perozek, M.G.2
  • 255
    • 0001576333 scopus 로고
    • Mortality Risk and Bequests
    • see also Michael D. Hurd, Mortality Risk and Bequests, 57 Econometrica 779, 797-802 (1989) (finding that most bequests "are accidental, the result of mortality risk").
    • (1989) Econometrica , vol.57 , pp. 779
    • Hurd, M.D.1
  • 256
    • 0000796597 scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Social Interactions
    • E.g., Gary S. Becker, A Theory of Social Interactions, 82 J. Pol. Econ. 1063, 1079 (1974) ("[A] 'family's' utility function is the same as that of one of its members not because this member has dictatorial power over other members, but because he (or she!) cares sufficiently about all other members to transfer resources voluntarily to them.").
    • (1974) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.82 , pp. 1063
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 257
    • 84936527308 scopus 로고
    • The Strategic Bequest Motive
    • E.g., B. Douglas Bernheim, Andrei Shleifer & Lawrence H. Summers, The Strategic Bequest Motive, 93 J. Pol. Econ. 1045, 1046 (1985) ("[T]estators use bequests to influence the behavior of potential beneficiaries. Such influence may be overt, as when parents threaten to disinherit miscreant offspring, or more subtle, as when parents reward more attentive children with family heirlooms.").
    • (1985) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.93 , pp. 1045
    • Bernheim, B.D.1    Shleifer, A.2    Summers, L.H.3
  • 259
    • 0011125585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do the Rich Save so Much?
    • Joel B. Slemrod ed.
    • Christopher D. Carroll, Why Do the Rich Save So Much?, in Does Atlas Shrug? The Economic Consequences of Taxing the Rich 465, 466 (Joel B. Slemrod ed., 2000) (concluding that "direct wealth accumulation motive is indispensable in explaining at least some of the observed [saving] behavior of the very wealthy").
    • (2000) Does Atlas Shrug? The Economic Consequences of Taxing the Rich , pp. 465
    • Carroll, C.D.1
  • 260
    • 57649206885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bernheim, supra note 196, at 29-31
    • Bernheim, supra note 196, at 29-31.
  • 261
    • 57649150583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. In this regard it should be noted, however, that in the 1992 Survey of Consumer Finance, only two percent of wealthy households stated that providing an inheritance was the most important reason to save, and only four percent of wealthy households indicated that providing an inheritance was among the top five reasons for saving. Carroll, supra note 202, at 472.
  • 262
    • 57649209093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gale & Perozek, supra note 199, at 21-28
    • Gale & Perozek, supra note 199, at 21-28.
  • 263
    • 57649144354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 32
    • Id. at 32.
  • 264
    • 57649172916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Becker, supra note 200, at 1077; Gale & Perozek, supra note 199, at 32
    • Becker, supra note 200, at 1077; Gale & Perozek, supra note 199, at 32.
  • 266
    • 0038629813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Impact of the Estate Tax on the Wealth Accumulation and Avoidance Behavior of Donors
    • forthcoming
    • Wojciech Kopczuk & Joel Slemrod, The Impact of the Estate Tax on the Wealth Accumulation and Avoidance Behavior of Donors, in Rethinking Estate and Gift Taxation (forthcoming 2001) (manuscript at 16-21, on file with New York University Law Review).
    • (2001) Rethinking Estate and Gift Taxation
    • Kopczuk, W.1    Slemrod, J.2
  • 267
    • 57649144352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 32
    • Id. at 32.
  • 268
    • 26444503511 scopus 로고
    • The Implications of Minority Interest and Stock Restrictions in Valuing Closely-Held Shares
    • For descriptions of various techniques to reduce value, see, for example, Cunni ngham, supra note 155, at 1461-62 (discussing how wealth can disappear through use of family limited partnerships); Alan L. Feld, The Implications of Minority Interest and Stock Restrictions in Valuing Closely-Held Shares, 122 U. Pa. L. Rev. 934 (1974) (discussing discounts available for minority stock interests and shares subject to transfer restrictions);
    • (1974) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.122 , pp. 934
    • Feld, A.L.1
  • 269
    • 26444555305 scopus 로고
    • Valuing Close Corporations for Federal Wealth Transfer Taxes: A Statutory Solution to the Disappearing Wealth Syndrome
    • Mary Louise Fellows & William H. Painter, Valuing Close Corporations for Federal Wealth Transfer Taxes: A Statutory Solution to the Disappearing Wealth Syndrome, 30 Stan. L. Rev. 895 (1978) (explaining transfer of minority shares of close corporations as tax avoidance strategy).
    • (1978) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.30 , pp. 895
    • Fellows, M.L.1    Painter, W.H.2
  • 270
    • 57649156697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cunningham, supra note 155, at 1464-65
    • Cunningham, supra note 155, at 1464-65.
  • 271
    • 0000801478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economic Effects of the Tax Reform Act of 1986
    • See, e.g., Alan J. Auerback & Joel Slemrod, The Economic Effects of the Tax Reform Act of 1986, 35 J. Econ. Literature 589, 615-18 (1997) (discussing evidence of income shifting rather than income creation);
    • (1997) J. Econ. Literature , vol.35 , pp. 589
    • Auerback, A.J.1    Slemrod, J.2
  • 272
    • 0008100455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax Reforms and Labor Supply
    • James M. Poterba ed.
    • Nada Eissa, Tax Reforms and Labor Supply, in 10 Tax Policy and the Economy 119, 147 (James M. Poterba ed., 1996) (explaining that "income response observed in the tax return data is due more to factors other than labor market participation, such as shifting of income and compensation decisions");
    • (1996) Tax Policy and the Economy , vol.10 , pp. 119
    • Eissa, N.1
  • 274
    • 0009319047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res., Working Paper No. 5759, Sept.
    • See, e.g., Eric M. Engen, William G. Gale & John Karl Scholz, The Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Saving and Wealth 46 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res., Working Paper No. 5759, Sept. 1996) (finding that "less than ten percent of 401(k) contributions represent new saving"); Auerback & Slemrod, supra note 213, at 603-04 (finding low saving response to high after-tax rate of return).
    • (1996) The Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Saving and Wealth , pp. 46
    • Engen, E.M.1    Gale, W.G.2    Scholz, J.K.3
  • 275
    • 0002851489 scopus 로고
    • The Impact of the 1986 Tax Reform on Personal Saving
    • Joel Slemrod ed.
    • Engen et al., supra note 214, at 45-48 (concluding that tax incentives for savings have little or no effect on level of saving); Jonathan Skinner & Daniel Feenberg, The Impact of the 1986 Tax Reform on Personal Saving, in Do Taxes Matter? The Impact of the Tax Reform Act of 1986, at 50, 72-73 (Joel Slemrod ed., 1990) (concluding that "link between the aftertax rate of return and personal saving is weak" and finding tax effects on types of saving instead);
    • (1990) Do Taxes Matter? The Impact of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 , pp. 50
    • Skinner, J.1    Feenberg, D.2
  • 276
    • 0011400726 scopus 로고
    • The Measurement and Determination of Loanable-Funds Saving
    • Arthur M. Okin & George L. Perry eds.
    • see also Bernheim, supra note 196, at 47-48 (providing excellent survey of studies); E. Philip Howrey & Saul M. Hymans, The Measurement and Determination of Loanable-Funds Saving, in 3 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 662, 663-67 (Arthur M. Okin & George L. Perry eds., 1978) (demonstrating that one study's finding of "positive and significant saving elasticity . . . [was] extremely sensitive" to sample period and modeling features).
    • (1978) Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , vol.3 , pp. 662
    • Howrey, E.P.1    Hymans, S.M.2
  • 277
    • 0001898935 scopus 로고
    • Taxation, Saving, and the Rate of Interest
    • But see Michael J. Boskin, Taxation, Saving, and the Rate of Interest, 86 J. Pol. Econ. S3 (1978) (finding that income tax rates influence saving).
    • (1978) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.86
    • Boskin, M.J.1
  • 278
    • 57649189303 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Skinner & Feenberg, supra note 215, at 72
    • Skinner & Feenberg, supra note 215, at 72.
  • 279
    • 0346413273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taxation and Savings
    • Michael P. Devereaux ed.
    • See Bernheim, supra note 196, at 50 ("[T]he assumptions required for valid aggregation are extremely restrictive."); Robin Broadway & David Wildasin, Taxation and Savings, in The Economics of Tax Policy 55, 73 (Michael P. Devereaux ed., 1996) ("Overall, it would be fair to say that empirical analysis of aggregate consumption data has been inconclusive in its findings about the effects of interest rates on savings.").
    • (1996) The Economics of Tax Policy , pp. 55
    • Broadway, R.1    Wildasin, D.2
  • 280
    • 0010959287 scopus 로고
    • Distribution Effects and the Aggregate Consumption Function
    • Alan S. Blinder, Distribution Effects and the Aggregate Consumption Function, 83 J. Pol. Econ. 447, 472 (1975) (finding that greater income equalization will have little or no effect on aggregate consumption);
    • (1975) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.83 , pp. 447
    • Blinder, A.S.1
  • 281
    • 0001274822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumption, Income, and Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence
    • John Y. Campbell & N. Gregory Mankiw, Consumption, Income, and Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence, in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989, at 185, 186 (Olivier Jean Blanchard & Stanley Fisher eds., 1989) (finding that "predictable movements . . . in consumption cannot be explained as a rational response to movements in real interest rates");
    • NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989 , pp. 185
    • Campbell, J.Y.1    Mankiw, N.G.2
  • 282
    • 84936526550 scopus 로고
    • Intertemporal Substitution in Consumption
    • Robert E. Hall, Intertemporal Substitution in Consumption, 96 J. Pol. Econ. 339, 350-51 (1988) (explaining that "consumption growth has generally stuck fairly close to its average value no matter what has happened to real interest rates").
    • (1988) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.96 , pp. 339
    • Hall, R.E.1
  • 283
    • 0001654817 scopus 로고
    • Consumption Growth, the Interest Rate and Aggregation
    • E.g., Orazio P. Attanasio & Guglielmo Weber, Consumption Growth, the Interest Rate and Aggregation, 60 Rev. Econ. Stud. 631, 632 (1993) (identifying sources of aggregation bias and finding "substantial differences between estimates of intertemporal substitution obtained from aggregate and average cohort data").
    • (1993) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.60 , pp. 631
    • Attanasio, O.P.1    Weber, G.2
  • 284
    • 0001765626 scopus 로고
    • Consumption over the Life Cycle and over the Business Cycle
    • Bernheim, supra note 196, at 50. For examples of studies using household data, see Orazio P. Attanasio & Martin Browning, Consumption over the Life Cycle and over the Business Cycle, 85 Am. Econ. Rev. 1118, 1119 (1995) (concluding that household-specific factors "have an important influence on intertemporal-allocation decisions");
    • (1995) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.85 , pp. 1118
    • Attanasio, O.P.1    Browning, M.2
  • 285
    • 85050784774 scopus 로고
    • How Prudent Are Consumers?
    • Orazio P. Attanasio & Karen E. Dynan, How Prudent Are Consumers?, 101 J. Pol. Econ. 1104, 1109 (1993) (finding little evidence of "precautionary motive" in consumer saving behavior);
    • (1993) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.101 , pp. 1104
    • Attanasio, O.P.1    Dynan, K.E.2
  • 286
    • 84935643419 scopus 로고
    • Poverty and the Rate of Time Preference: Evidence from Panel Data
    • Attanasio & Weber, supra note 219, at 647 (finding higher elasticity of intertemporal substitution using average cohort data rather than aggregate data); Emily C. Lawrance, Poverty and the Rate of Time Preference: Evidence from Panel Data, 99 J. Pol. Econ. 54, 72 (1991) (finding strong differential effects based on household income and time preference rates);
    • (1991) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.99 , pp. 54
    • Lawrance, E.C.1
  • 287
    • 44949275901 scopus 로고
    • Liquidity Constraints and the Permanent-Income Hypothesis: Evidence from Panel Data
    • David E. Runkle, Liquidity Constraints and the Permanent-Income Hypothesis: Evidence from Panel Data, 27 J. Monetary Econ. 73, 90-91 (1991) (arguing that panel data model supports permanent-income hypothesis);
    • (1991) J. Monetary Econ. , vol.27 , pp. 73
    • Runkle, D.E.1
  • 288
    • 0001976595 scopus 로고
    • The Permanent Income Hypothesis and the Real Interest Rate: Some Evidence from Panel Data
    • Matthew D. Shapiro, The Permanent Income Hypothesis and the Real Interest Rate: Some Evidence from Panel Data, 14 Econ. Letters 93, 98-99 (1984) (explaining rejection of permanent income hypothesis as problem of liquidity constraints);
    • (1984) Econ. Letters , vol.14 , pp. 93
    • Shapiro, M.D.1
  • 289
    • 84936047538 scopus 로고
    • Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation
    • Stephen P. Zeldes, Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation, 97 J. Pol. Econ. 305, 338 (1989) (finding that borrowing constraints affect consumption).
    • (1989) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.97 , pp. 305
    • Zeldes, S.P.1
  • 290
    • 57649161767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bernheim, supra note 196, at 50
    • Bernheim, supra note 196, at 50.
  • 291
    • 77957025376 scopus 로고
    • A Terror Management Theory of Social Behavior: The Psychological Functions of Self-Esteem and Cultural Worldviews
    • Mark P. Zanna ed.
    • See, e.g., Sheldon Solomon et al., A Terror Management Theory of Social Behavior: The Psychological Functions of Self-Esteem and Cultural Worldviews, in 24 Advances in Experimental Social Psychology 93, 101-02 (Mark P. Zanna ed., 1991) (describing cultural strategies that help repress anxiety about one's mortality).
    • (1991) Advances in Experimental Social Psychology , vol.24 , pp. 93
    • Solomon, S.1
  • 292
    • 4243515672 scopus 로고
    • Thoughts for the Times on War and Death (1915)
    • reprinted Ernest Jones ed., Joan Riviere trans.
    • See, e.g., Sigmund Freud, Thoughts for the Times on War and Death (1915), reprinted in 4 Collected Papers 288, 304 (Ernest Jones ed., Joan Riviere trans., 1959) (describing attitude toward death as "unmistakable tendency to 'shelve' death, to eliminate it from life");
    • (1959) Collected Papers , vol.4 , pp. 288
    • Freud, S.1
  • 294
    • 0006037671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Self-Control and Saving for Retirement
    • William C. Brainard & George L. Perry eds.
    • Economists also have noted that people tend heavily to discount future events. David I. Laibson et al., Self-Control and Saving for Retirement, in 1 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 91 (William C. Brainard & George L. Perry eds., 1998).
    • (1998) Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , vol.1 , pp. 91
    • Laibson, D.I.1
  • 296
    • 26444491949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns
    • supra note 202
    • James M. Poterba, The Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns, in Does Atlas Shrug?, supra note 202, at 330.
    • Does Atlas Shrug? , pp. 330
    • Poterba, J.M.1
  • 297
    • 57649193783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Poterba, supra note 225, at 339 tbl.10.6
    • Poterba, supra note 225, at 339 tbl.10.6.
  • 298
    • 57649144347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 299
    • 57649193785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 300
    • 57649162867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 338
    • Id. at 338.
  • 301
    • 0010333135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2d ed.
    • Stephen F. Davis & Joseph J. Palladino, Psychology 457 (2d ed. 1997) (observing that young adults "rarely think of their own death," while older adults do).
    • (1997) Psychology , pp. 457
    • Davis, S.F.1    Palladino, J.J.2
  • 302
    • 57649168833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carroll, supra note 202, at 472
    • Carroll, supra note 202, at 472.
  • 303
    • 26444561261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • hereinafter 1997 Family Business Survey
    • See 1997 Research Findings: The Arthur Andersen/MassMutual American Family Business Survey '97 [hereinafter 1997 Family Business Survey], at http:// www.massmutual.com/fbn (last visited Apr. 12, 2001) (reporting that 23.8% of respondents have only "some" or no understanding of estate tax due upon their deaths).
    • 1997 Research Findings: the Arthur Andersen/MassMutual American Family Business Survey '97
  • 304
    • 57649206882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 305
    • 26444612502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res., Working Paper No. 7360, Sept.
    • See Douglas Holtz-Eakin et al., Estate Taxes, Life Insurance, and Small Business 1-2 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res., Working Paper No. 7360, Sept. 1999) (summarizing criticisms).
    • (1999) Estate Taxes, Life Insurance, and Small Business , pp. 1-2
    • Holtz-Eakin, D.1
  • 306
    • 57649189302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 307
    • 57649203712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 1997 Family Business Survey, supra note 232 (noting that sixty-seven percent of respondents reported that life insurance represents primary source of funds to cover estate taxes).
  • 308
    • 57649206873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Holtz-Eakin et al., supra note 234, at 23
    • Holtz-Eakin et al., supra note 234, at 23.
  • 309
    • 57649196765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 8
    • Id. at 8.
  • 310
    • 57649214947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 8, 10-11. The percentage rate varied depending on how "liquid assets" were defined. Id. at tbl.1.
  • 311
    • 57649206880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 9, 25 n.16 (noting that "there are many ways to avoid estate tax" and describing provisions for tax deferral and "phenomenon" of businesses being undervalued when passing through probate).
  • 312
    • 57649156684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.R.C. § 2057(a)(1)-(2) (1994 & Supp. IV 1998)
    • I.R.C. § 2057(a)(1)-(2) (1994 & Supp. IV 1998).
  • 313
    • 57649214939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. §§ 2010 (1994 & Supp. IV 1998), 2057(a)(3)(A) (West 2000)
    • Id. §§ 2010 (1994 & Supp. IV 1998), 2057(a)(3)(A) (West 2000).
  • 314
    • 57649144345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I.R.C. § 2057(a)(3)(A) limits the unified credit exclusion amount to a maximum deduction of $625,000 where the maximum deduction of $675,000 is claimed under I.R.C. § 2057. Id. § 2057(a)(3)(A) (West 2000).
  • 315
    • 0039615790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Estate Taxes and the Angel of Death Loophole
    • Leonard E. Burman, Estate Taxes and the Angel of Death Loophole, 76 Tax Notes 675, 675 (1997) ("The estate tax is an exclusive tax, directly affecting fewer than 2 percent of decedents. Most owners of small businesses . . . do not pay it . . . .").
    • (1997) Tax Notes , vol.76 , pp. 675
    • Burman, L.E.1
  • 316
    • 57649203711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Author's calculations based on Johnson & Mikow, supra note 187, at 102-06 tbl.1c.
  • 317
    • 57649203699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.R.C. § 2032A (1994 & Supp. IV 1998)
    • I.R.C. § 2032A (1994 & Supp. IV 1998).
  • 318
    • 57649141225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. § 2032A(a)(2). For estates in which decedents died after 1998, the $750,000 may be adjusted for inflation. Id. § 2032A(a)(3).
  • 319
    • 57649156688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Despite the benefit of § 2032A, it is interesting to note that in 1995 only 0.6% of all returns for decedents used § 2032A. Johnson & Mikow, supra note 187, at 79. It is also interesting that only 0.4% of the gross assets reported in all 1997 estate tax returns were farm assets. Id. at 102 tbl.1c.
  • 320
    • 57649214940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Johnson & Mikow, supra note 187, at 79 fig.I
    • Johnson & Mikow, supra note 187, at 79 fig.I.
  • 321
    • 57649182168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.R.C. § 6166 (Supp. IV 1998)
    • I.R.C. § 6166 (Supp. IV 1998).
  • 322
    • 57649144331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 6601(j)(1)(A), (j)(2) (1994 & Supp. IV 1998)
    • Id. § 6601(j)(1)(A), (j)(2) (1994 & Supp. IV 1998).
  • 323
    • 57649168832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 6601(j)(1)(B)
    • Id. § 6601(j)(1)(B).
  • 324
    • 0002806715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Taxation of Wealth Transfers, 1992-1995
    • supra note 158
    • Martha Britton Eller, Federal Taxation of Wealth Transfers, 1992-1995, in 1RS Bulletin, supra note 158, at 8, 15.
    • 1RS Bulletin , pp. 8
    • Eller, M.B.1
  • 325
    • 79953306684 scopus 로고
    • Minority Discounts: The Alchemy in Estate and Gift Taxation
    • James R. Repetti, Minority Discounts: The Alchemy in Estate and Gift Taxation, 50 Tax L. Rev. 415, 424-25, 427, 429 (1995).
    • (1995) Tax L. Rev. , vol.50 , pp. 415
    • Repetti, J.R.1
  • 326
    • 57649209086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 428-29
    • Id. at 428-29.
  • 327
    • 57649212327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Davenport & Soled, supra note 10, at 614
    • Davenport & Soled, supra note 10, at 614.
  • 328
    • 57649190742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Johnson & Mikow, supra note 187, at 102, 104 tbl.1c
    • Johnson & Mikow, supra note 187, at 102, 104 tbl.1c.
  • 329
    • 57649141223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., Holtz-Eakin, supra note 27, at 790 (concluding that "substantial evidence suggests the estate tax imposes considerable compliance and administrative costs").
  • 330
    • 57649172893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 155, 211-12 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 155, 211-12 and accompanying text.
  • 331
    • 57649182165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Davenport & Soled, supra note 10, at 619
    • Davenport & Soled, supra note 10, at 619.
  • 332
    • 0040455922 scopus 로고
    • Wealth Transfer Taxation: The Relative Role for Estate and Income Taxes
    • Nov./ Dec.
    • Id. at 621 ("Determining the amount that could possibly be attributed to the estate tax is difficult."); see also Alicia H. Munnell & C. Nicole Ernsberger, Wealth Transfer Taxation: The Relative Role for Estate and Income Taxes, New Eng. Econ. Rev., Nov./ Dec. 1988, at 3, 19 (attempting to estimate compliance costs).
    • (1988) New Eng. Econ. Rev. , pp. 3
    • Munnell, A.H.1    Ernsberger, C.N.2
  • 333
    • 57649141222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Davenport & Soled, supra note 10, at 622-24 (comparing their own research estimate that estate tax compliance costs equal $6000 per person with another study finding average spending of $19,908 in legal fees, $11,940 in accounting fees, and $11,212 on other advisers for estate planning).
  • 334
    • 0005264898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Effect of Estate Taxes on Family Business: Survey Results
    • Joseph H. Astrachan & Roger Tutterow, The Effect of Estate Taxes on Family Business: Survey Results, 9 Fam. Bus. Rev. 303, 303, 304 (1998).
    • (1998) Fam. Bus. Rev. , vol.9 , pp. 303
    • Astrachan, J.H.1    Tutterow, R.2
  • 335
    • 57649196757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 306 tbl.2
    • Id. at 306 tbl.2.
  • 336
    • 26444616012 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Craig Aronoff & John Ward, Succession: The Final Test of Greatness 1 (1992) ("[S]uccession planning is the most critical task to secure the future of private enterprise in America. . . . [T]he failure to plan for succession is the greatest current threat to the survival of family business.");
    • (1992) Succession: The Final Test of Greatness , pp. 1
    • Aronoff, C.1    Ward, J.2
  • 338
    • 57649141218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Most of the practitioners are members of a luncheon group in Boston that meets monthly at the Boston Union Club to discuss issues in tax law and estate planning.
  • 339
    • 57649189278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 264 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 264 and accompanying text.
  • 340
    • 57649150572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The way that family limited partnerships result in low valuations is quite simple. An asset placed into a partnership normally has a reduced value because each partner's access to, and control over, the asset is limited by the existence of the partnership. This is particularly true for limited partners who have little voice in the conduct of the partnership. Of course, all partners acting in concert could eliminate obstacles to access and control. But our current method of valuation does not permit the identity of co-owners or the likelihood that they will cooperate with one another to be considered in valuing the assets that are placed into a partnership. Repetti, supra note 254, at 444, 452. The result is that placing a business into a family limited partnership can reduce significantly the value of its real estate for estate tax purposes. Id. at 452.
  • 341
    • 57649190748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra notes 211-212 and accompanying text for a description of how family limited partnerships reduce the value of assets placed therein.
  • 342
    • 57649144338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Estate of Bright v. United States, 658 F.2d 999, 1005 (5th Cir. 1981) (en banc) (holding that "family attribution should not apply to lump a decedent's stock with that of related parties for estate tax valuation purposes"); Rev. Rul. 93-12, 1993-1 C.B. 202, 203 (ruling that "a minority discount will not be disallowed solely because a transferred interest, when aggregated with interests held by family members, would be part of a controlling interest").
  • 343
    • 57649150573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Repetti, supra note 254, at 485-86 (arguing for tax provision that includes value of control in valuing certain minority interests in assets).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.