-
1
-
-
85037139488
-
-
note
-
Xizhu, a code name for a prosperous city in the Pearl River delta, hosts thousands of factories that are supported by foreign capital, mostly from Hong Kong and Taiwan. Most industries in Xizhu are labor-intensive and export-oriented. Xizhu is a typical region in Southeast China that has utilized foreign capital for rapid rural industrialization. Townships and villages have thrived and have also urbanized in a somewhat crude way thanks to these processing and assembly-type investments. The author conducted interviews in Taiwan, Hong Kong, the Pearl River delta, and other regions of China in the period 1994-96. Most of the names, institutes, and locales are coded in order to protect informants in the field.
-
-
-
-
2
-
-
0001074042
-
The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business: The Family Firm in Taiwan
-
See, for example: Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business: The Family Firm in Taiwan," Comparative Social Research 12 (1990): 95-112; Alan Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi: A Reconsideration of Bourdieu's Social Capital," Cultural Anthropology 8, no. 3 (1993): 388-408; David L. Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism: Guanxi and Private Business in a South China City," The China Quarterly, no. 147 (September 1996): 820-38; and Macro Orru, Nicole Woolsey Biggart, and Gary Hamilton, eds., The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997).
-
(1990)
Comparative Social Research
, vol.12
, pp. 95-112
-
-
Hamilton, G.1
Shu, K.C.2
-
3
-
-
21144465983
-
Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi: A Reconsideration of Bourdieu's Social Capital
-
See, for example: Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business: The Family Firm in Taiwan," Comparative Social Research 12 (1990): 95-112; Alan Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi: A Reconsideration of Bourdieu's Social Capital," Cultural Anthropology 8, no. 3 (1993): 388-408; David L. Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism: Guanxi and Private Business in a South China City," The China Quarterly, no. 147 (September 1996): 820-38; and Macro Orru, Nicole Woolsey Biggart, and Gary Hamilton, eds., The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997).
-
(1993)
Cultural Anthropology
, vol.8
, Issue.3
, pp. 388-408
-
-
Smart, A.1
-
4
-
-
0001112338
-
The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism: Guanxi and Private Business in a South China City
-
September
-
See, for example: Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business: The Family Firm in Taiwan," Comparative Social Research 12 (1990): 95-112; Alan Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi: A Reconsideration of Bourdieu's Social Capital," Cultural Anthropology 8, no. 3 (1993): 388-408; David L. Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism: Guanxi and Private Business in a South China City," The China Quarterly, no. 147 (September 1996): 820-38; and Macro Orru, Nicole Woolsey Biggart, and Gary Hamilton, eds., The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997).
-
(1996)
The China Quarterly
, Issue.147
, pp. 820-838
-
-
Wank, D.L.1
-
5
-
-
0003693725
-
-
London: Sage
-
See, for example: Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business: The Family Firm in Taiwan," Comparative Social Research 12 (1990): 95-112; Alan Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi: A Reconsideration of Bourdieu's Social Capital," Cultural Anthropology 8, no. 3 (1993): 388-408; David L. Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism: Guanxi and Private Business in a South China City," The China Quarterly, no. 147 (September 1996): 820-38; and Macro Orru, Nicole Woolsey Biggart, and Gary Hamilton, eds., The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997).
-
(1997)
The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism
-
-
Orru, M.1
Biggart, N.W.2
Hamilton, G.3
-
6
-
-
0039730722
-
-
Hong Kong: Oxford University Press
-
The allusive and vague notion of "being a Chinese" has been a focus of academic debate. It is further complicated by the recent popular use of "Greater China." For the problem of "Chineseness," see Wang Gungwu, The Chineseness of China: Selected Essays (Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1991); Wang Gungwu, "Greater China and the Chinese Overseas," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 926-48; and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Living Tree: The Meaning of Being Chinese Today (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 1994). For a discussion of Greater China, see Harry Harding, "The Concept of 'Greater China': Themes, Variations, and Reservations," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 660-86. Aware of the debate, I technically treat Taiwan in this research as a Chinese society (huaren shehui) for its linguistic and cultural similarity with mainland China. We can thereby make cross-societal comparison among the Chinese societies such as colonial Hong Kong, sovereign Singapore state, and overseas Chinese communities around the world.
-
(1991)
The Chineseness of China: Selected Essays
-
-
Gungwu, W.1
-
7
-
-
84917227015
-
Greater China and the Chinese Overseas
-
December
-
The allusive and vague notion of "being a Chinese" has been a focus of academic debate. It is further complicated by the recent popular use of "Greater China." For the problem of "Chineseness," see Wang Gungwu, The Chineseness of China: Selected Essays (Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1991); Wang Gungwu, "Greater China and the Chinese Overseas," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 926-48; and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Living Tree: The Meaning of Being Chinese Today (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 1994). For a discussion of Greater China, see Harry Harding, "The Concept of 'Greater China': Themes, Variations, and Reservations," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 660-86. Aware of the debate, I technically treat Taiwan in this research as a Chinese society (huaren shehui) for its linguistic and cultural similarity with mainland China. We can thereby make cross-societal comparison among the Chinese societies such as colonial Hong Kong, sovereign Singapore state, and overseas Chinese communities around the world.
-
(1993)
The China Quarterly
, Issue.136
, pp. 926-948
-
-
Gungwu, W.1
-
8
-
-
0003630449
-
-
Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press
-
The allusive and vague notion of "being a Chinese" has been a focus of academic debate. It is further complicated by the recent popular use of "Greater China." For the problem of "Chineseness," see Wang Gungwu, The Chineseness of China: Selected Essays (Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1991); Wang Gungwu, "Greater China and the Chinese Overseas," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 926-48; and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Living Tree: The Meaning of Being Chinese Today (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 1994). For a discussion of Greater China, see Harry Harding, "The Concept of 'Greater China': Themes, Variations, and Reservations," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 660-86. Aware of the debate, I technically treat Taiwan in this research as a Chinese society (huaren shehui) for its linguistic and cultural similarity with mainland China. We can thereby make cross-societal comparison among the Chinese societies such as colonial Hong Kong, sovereign Singapore state, and overseas Chinese communities around the world.
-
(1994)
The Living Tree: The Meaning of Being Chinese Today
-
-
Wei-Ming, T.1
-
9
-
-
34248234853
-
The Concept of 'Greater China': Themes, Variations, and Reservations
-
December
-
The allusive and vague notion of "being a Chinese" has been a focus of academic debate. It is further complicated by the recent popular use of "Greater China." For the problem of "Chineseness," see Wang Gungwu, The Chineseness of China: Selected Essays (Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1991); Wang Gungwu, "Greater China and the Chinese Overseas," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 926-48; and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Living Tree: The Meaning of Being Chinese Today (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 1994). For a discussion of Greater China, see Harry Harding, "The Concept of 'Greater China': Themes, Variations, and Reservations," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 660-86. Aware of the debate, I technically treat Taiwan in this research as a Chinese society (huaren shehui) for its linguistic and cultural similarity with mainland China. We can thereby make cross-societal comparison among the Chinese societies such as colonial Hong Kong, sovereign Singapore state, and overseas Chinese communities around the world.
-
(1993)
The China Quarterly
, Issue.136
, pp. 660-686
-
-
Harding, H.1
-
10
-
-
85179189180
-
Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory
-
ed. Robert Bates Berkeley: University of California Press
-
Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
-
(1988)
Toward a Political Economy of Development
, pp. 142-175
-
-
Amsden, A.H.1
-
11
-
-
0004023051
-
-
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
-
Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
-
(1990)
Pathways from the Periphery: the Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries
-
-
Haggard, S.1
-
12
-
-
0004198625
-
-
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
-
Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
-
(1987)
The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism
-
-
Deyo, F.C.1
-
13
-
-
0001350090
-
Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan
-
Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
-
The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism
, pp. 136-164
-
-
Johnson, C.1
-
14
-
-
0003515053
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
-
(1990)
Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization
-
-
Wade, R.1
-
15
-
-
0003757491
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
-
(1990)
Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia
-
-
Gereffi, G.1
Wyman, D.L.2
-
16
-
-
0003675059
-
-
London: Sage
-
Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
-
(1992)
Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society
-
-
Whitley, R.1
-
17
-
-
84965572004
-
Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies
-
Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
-
(1994)
Organization Studies
, vol.15
, Issue.2
, pp. 153-182
-
-
Whitley, R.1
-
18
-
-
0003593993
-
-
New York: Free Press
-
For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
-
(1951)
The Religion of China
-
-
Weber, M.1
-
19
-
-
0346932660
-
-
London: Allen and Unwin
-
For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
-
(1930)
The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit
-
-
-
20
-
-
0011695311
-
-
London: Wildwood
-
For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
-
(1987)
The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty
-
-
Berger, P.1
-
21
-
-
0003489278
-
-
New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books
-
For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
-
(1988)
The Search of an East Asian Development Model
-
-
Berger, P.1
Hsiao, H.-H.2
-
22
-
-
0005647412
-
Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective
-
Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton
-
For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
-
The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism
, pp. 3-32
-
-
Biggart, N.W.1
-
23
-
-
84965904122
-
Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization
-
For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
-
(1987)
International Sociology
, vol.2
, Issue.3
, pp. 289-300
-
-
Hamilton, G.1
Shu, K.C.2
-
24
-
-
84929091572
-
-
Berlin: de Gruyter
-
For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
-
(1990)
The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism
-
-
Gordon Redding, S.1
-
25
-
-
0346302562
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
-
For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
-
(1995)
The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia
-
-
Wei-Ming, T.1
-
26
-
-
85065840141
-
Families and Networks in Taiwan's Economic Development
-
ed. Edward Winckler and Susan Greenhalgh Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe
-
Susan Greenhalgh, "Families and Networks in Taiwan's Economic Development," in Contending Approaches to the Political Economy of Taiwan, ed. Edward Winckler and Susan Greenhalgh (Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe, 1988), 224-45; Hamilton and Kao, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business" ; and Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism.
-
(1988)
Contending Approaches to the Political Economy of Taiwan
, pp. 224-245
-
-
Greenhalgh, S.1
-
27
-
-
85065840141
-
-
Susan Greenhalgh, "Families and Networks in Taiwan's Economic Development," in Contending Approaches to the Political Economy of Taiwan, ed. Edward Winckler and Susan Greenhalgh (Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe, 1988), 224-45; Hamilton and Kao, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business" ; and Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism.
-
The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business
-
-
Hamilton1
Kao2
-
28
-
-
85065840141
-
-
Susan Greenhalgh, "Families and Networks in Taiwan's Economic Development," in Contending Approaches to the Political Economy of Taiwan, ed. Edward Winckler and Susan Greenhalgh (Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe, 1988), 224-45; Hamilton and Kao, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business" ; and Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism.
-
The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism
-
-
Orru1
Biggart2
Hamilton3
-
29
-
-
0003879862
-
-
Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan
-
See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
-
(1988)
The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures
-
-
Pye, L.W.1
-
30
-
-
0004255770
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
-
See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
-
(1992)
The Spirit of Chinese Politics
-
-
Pye, L.W.1
-
31
-
-
84934563463
-
Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation
-
See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
-
(1991)
Daedalus
, vol.120
, Issue.2
, pp. 63-84
-
-
King, A.1
-
32
-
-
0038496530
-
-
See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
-
Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi
-
-
Smart1
-
33
-
-
84973970170
-
The Gift Economy and State Power in China
-
See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
-
(1989)
Comparative Studies in Society and History
, vol.31
, pp. 25-54
-
-
Yang, M.1
-
34
-
-
85056593534
-
-
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
-
See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
-
(1994)
Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China
-
-
Yang, M.1
-
35
-
-
0038496529
-
-
See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
-
The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism
-
-
Wank1
-
36
-
-
6244267602
-
The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village
-
January
-
See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
-
(1996)
The China Journal
, Issue.35
, pp. 1-25
-
-
Yan, Y.1
-
37
-
-
0029434070
-
The Social Roots of China's Economic Development
-
December
-
See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999-1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
-
(1995)
The China Quarterly
, Issue.144
, pp. 999-1019
-
-
Whyte, M.K.1
-
38
-
-
0030439820
-
The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?
-
October
-
See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
-
(1996)
Economic Development and Cultural Change
, vol.44
, Issue.1
, pp. 1-30
-
-
-
39
-
-
84928834017
-
Interpersonal Choice and Networks in China
-
Peter M. Blau, Danching Ruan, and Monica Ardelt, "Interpersonal Choice and Networks in China," Social Forces 69 (1991): 1037-62.
-
(1991)
Social Forces
, vol.69
, pp. 1037-1062
-
-
Blau, P.M.1
Ruan, D.2
Ardelt, M.3
-
40
-
-
0007908032
-
Culture, Institutions, and Business in East Asia
-
Barry Wilkinson, "Culture, Institutions, and Business in East Asia," Organization Studies 17, no. 3 (1996): 421-47.
-
(1996)
Organization Studies
, vol.17
, Issue.3
, pp. 421-447
-
-
Wilkinson, B.1
-
42
-
-
85055292755
-
What Explains Chinese Political Behavior? the Debate over Structure and Culture
-
October
-
See Bruce J. Dickson, "What Explains Chinese Political Behavior? The Debate over Structure and Culture," Comparative Politics 25, no. 1 (October 1992): 103-18, for a review of the debate over culture and structure in the explanation of Chinese behavior.
-
(1992)
Comparative Politics
, vol.25
, Issue.1
, pp. 103-118
-
-
Dickson, B.J.1
-
43
-
-
4444271495
-
The Foreign Relations of Greater China
-
December
-
Michael Yahuda, "The Foreign Relations of Greater China," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 688.
-
(1993)
The China Quarterly
, Issue.136
, pp. 688
-
-
Yahuda, M.1
-
45
-
-
0003417695
-
-
London: Collier-Macmillan
-
For general statements of structural explanation, see Brian Barry, Sociologists, Economists, and Democracy (London: Collier-Macmillan, 1970); Barrington Moore, Jr., Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966); and Theda Skocpol, States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1979).
-
(1970)
Sociologists, Economists, and Democracy
-
-
Barry, B.1
-
46
-
-
0003928609
-
-
Boston: Beacon Press
-
For general statements of structural explanation, see Brian Barry, Sociologists, Economists, and Democracy (London: Collier-Macmillan, 1970); Barrington Moore, Jr., Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966); and Theda Skocpol, States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1979).
-
(1966)
Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World
-
-
Moore B., Jr.1
-
47
-
-
84953265768
-
-
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
-
For general statements of structural explanation, see Brian Barry, Sociologists, Economists, and Democracy (London: Collier-Macmillan, 1970); Barrington Moore, Jr., Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966); and Theda Skocpol, States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1979).
-
(1979)
States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China
-
-
Skocpol, T.1
-
48
-
-
0002991828
-
Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action
-
ed. Michael Taylor Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
-
For a definition of thin rational choice theory, see Michael Taylor, "Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action," in Rationality and Revolution, ed. Michael Taylor (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 63-97. For a broader debate of cultural versus structural/institutional perspective, see Thomas A. Koelble, "The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology," Comparative Politics 27, no. 2 (January 1995): 231-44; William H. Sewell, Jr., "Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; Michael Taylor, "Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change," Politics and Society 17, no. 2 (1989): 115-62; and Richard Whittington, "Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency," Journal of Management Studies 29, no. 6 (1992): 693-712.
-
(1988)
Rationality and Revolution
, pp. 63-97
-
-
Taylor, M.1
-
49
-
-
0000503455
-
The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology
-
January
-
For a definition of thin rational choice theory, see Michael Taylor, "Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action," in Rationality and Revolution, ed. Michael Taylor (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 63-97. For a broader debate of cultural versus structural/institutional perspective, see Thomas A. Koelble, "The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology," Comparative Politics 27, no. 2 (January 1995): 231-44; William H. Sewell, Jr., "Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; Michael Taylor, "Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change," Politics and Society 17, no. 2 (1989): 115-62; and Richard Whittington, "Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency," Journal of Management Studies 29, no. 6 (1992): 693-712.
-
(1995)
Comparative Politics
, vol.27
, Issue.2
, pp. 231-244
-
-
Koelble, T.A.1
-
50
-
-
0002902691
-
Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation
-
July
-
For a definition of thin rational choice theory, see Michael Taylor, "Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action," in Rationality and Revolution, ed. Michael Taylor (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 63-97. For a broader debate of cultural versus structural/institutional perspective, see Thomas A. Koelble, "The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology," Comparative Politics 27, no. 2 (January 1995): 231-44; William H. Sewell, Jr., "Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; Michael Taylor, "Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change," Politics and Society 17, no. 2 (1989): 115-62; and Richard Whittington, "Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency," Journal of Management Studies 29, no. 6 (1992): 693-712.
-
(1992)
American Journal of Sociology
, vol.98
, Issue.1
, pp. 1-29
-
-
Sewell W.H., Jr.1
-
51
-
-
84970415465
-
Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change
-
For a definition of thin rational choice theory, see Michael Taylor, "Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action," in Rationality and Revolution, ed. Michael Taylor (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 63-97. For a broader debate of cultural versus structural/institutional perspective, see Thomas A. Koelble, "The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology," Comparative Politics 27, no. 2 (January 1995): 231-44; William H. Sewell, Jr., "Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; Michael Taylor, "Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change," Politics and Society 17, no. 2 (1989): 115-62; and Richard Whittington, "Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency," Journal of Management Studies 29, no. 6 (1992): 693-712.
-
(1989)
Politics and Society
, vol.17
, Issue.2
, pp. 115-162
-
-
Taylor, M.1
-
52
-
-
85016697597
-
Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency
-
For a definition of thin rational choice theory, see Michael Taylor, "Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action," in Rationality and Revolution, ed. Michael Taylor (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 63-97. For a broader debate of cultural versus structural/institutional perspective, see Thomas A. Koelble, "The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology," Comparative Politics 27, no. 2 (January 1995): 231-44; William H. Sewell, Jr., "Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; Michael Taylor, "Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change," Politics and Society 17, no. 2 (1989): 115-62; and Richard Whittington, "Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency," Journal of Management Studies 29, no. 6 (1992): 693-712.
-
(1992)
Journal of Management Studies
, vol.29
, Issue.6
, pp. 693-712
-
-
Whittington, R.1
-
53
-
-
34248253450
-
Is Chinese Culture Distinctive? - A Review Article
-
Andrew J. Nathan, "Is Chinese Culture Distinctive? - A Review Article," Journal of Asian Studies 52, no. 4 (1993): 923-36.
-
(1993)
Journal of Asian Studies
, vol.52
, Issue.4
, pp. 923-936
-
-
Nathan, A.J.1
-
59
-
-
0003472582
-
-
This has been argued in several empirical findings. See Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets, for different meaning of guanxi in Mao's era and in Deng's reform; and Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," proposed that guanxi in the countryside functions dissimilarly than in the urban areas.
-
Gifts, Favors, and Banquets
-
-
Yang1
-
60
-
-
0038496520
-
-
This has been argued in several empirical findings. See Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets, for different meaning of guanxi in Mao's era and in Deng's reform; and Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," proposed that guanxi in the countryside functions dissimilarly than in the urban areas.
-
The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village
-
-
Yan1
-
61
-
-
0003540038
-
-
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
-
Douglass C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 95.
-
(1990)
Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance
, pp. 95
-
-
North, D.C.1
-
62
-
-
84936823493
-
Culture in Action: Symbols and Strategies
-
In this sense, culture functions like a "tool kit" for a social actor. See Anne Swidler, "Culture in Action: Symbols and Strategies," American Sociological Review 51 (1986): 273-86.
-
(1986)
American Sociological Review
, vol.51
, pp. 273-286
-
-
Swidler, A.1
-
65
-
-
84936824515
-
-
New York: Basic Books
-
An end-game situation, like in a one-shot game, tends to encourage noncooperation and defection because there will be no more expected interaction in the future. In contrast, repeated games tend to induce cooperation. See Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984).
-
(1984)
The Evolution of Cooperation
-
-
Axelrod, R.1
-
66
-
-
85037086006
-
-
note
-
Failure to fulfill an obligation usually signals a withdrawal from a social relationship.
-
-
-
-
67
-
-
0004241720
-
-
New York: Norton
-
Cf. Marcel Mauss, The Gift (New York: Norton, 1967). Note that Mauss assumed a "misrecognition" of instrumental motivation involved in gift exchange. Smart has a parallel argument in Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi," 395-97.
-
(1967)
The Gift
-
-
Mauss, M.1
-
68
-
-
0038496530
-
-
Cf. Marcel Mauss, The Gift (New York: Norton, 1967). Note that Mauss assumed a "misrecognition" of instrumental motivation involved in gift exchange. Smart has a parallel argument in Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi," 395-97.
-
Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi
, pp. 395-397
-
-
Smart1
-
69
-
-
85037071142
-
-
note
-
If the transaction is not made in cash, the seller of goods at least has to secure some kind of certificate or claim of the equivalent value in return.
-
-
-
-
71
-
-
0003852824
-
-
New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1964
-
This is evident when compared with commodity exchange. A credit purchase involves a clear and measurable debt to the merchant. In favor exchange, however, this is not the case. As Peter Blau argued: "Social exchange entails unspecified obligation. There is no contract, and there is no exact price." See Peter M. Blau, Exchange and Power in Social Life (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1986 [1964]), 315.
-
(1986)
Exchange and Power in Social Life
, pp. 315
-
-
Blau, P.M.1
-
73
-
-
34247960076
-
The Strength of Weak Ties
-
n. 2
-
This phenomenon was pointed out by Mark Granovetter: "Ties discussed in this paper are assumed to be positive and symmetric; a comprehensive theory might require discussion of negative and/or asymmetric ties." See Mark Granovetter, "The Strength of Weak Ties," American Journal of Sociology 78, no. 6 (1973): 1361 n. 2.
-
(1973)
American Journal of Sociology
, vol.78
, Issue.6
, pp. 1361
-
-
Granovetter, M.1
-
74
-
-
0005102425
-
Obligation and Control: Employment of Kin in Capitalist Labour Management in China
-
For a case study in kin employment in relation to unexpected problems in such network employment, see Josephine Smart and Alan Smart, "Obligation and Control: Employment of Kin in Capitalist Labour Management in China," Critique of Anthropology 13, no. 1 (1993): 7-31.
-
(1993)
Critique of Anthropology
, vol.13
, Issue.1
, pp. 7-31
-
-
Smart, J.1
Smart, A.2
-
75
-
-
0004138811
-
-
Amsterdam: North-Holland
-
See Janos Kornai, Economics of Shortage (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1980), for the concept of shortage economy.
-
(1980)
Economics of Shortage
-
-
Kornai, J.1
-
76
-
-
21144475959
-
Perestroika and Public Choice: The Economies of Autocratic Succession in Rent-Seeking Society
-
Gary M. Anderson and Peter J. Boettke, "Perestroika and Public Choice: The Economies of Autocratic Succession in Rent-Seeking Society," Public Choice 75, no. 1 (1993): 101-18; Andras Nagy, "Institutions and the Transition to a Market Economy," in The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe, ed. Christopher Clague and Gorden C. Rausser (Cambridge, Mass.:
-
(1993)
Public Choice
, vol.75
, Issue.1
, pp. 101-118
-
-
Anderson, G.M.1
Boettke, P.J.2
-
77
-
-
21144475959
-
Institutions and the Transition to a Market Economy
-
ed. Christopher Clague and Gorden C. Rausser Cambridge, Mass.: Basil Blackwell
-
Gary M. Anderson and Peter J. Boettke, "Perestroika and Public Choice: The Economies of Autocratic Succession in Rent-Seeking Society," Public Choice 75, no. 1 (1993): 101- 18; Andras Nagy, "Institutions and the Transition to a Market Economy," in The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe, ed. Christopher Clague and Gorden C. Rausser (Cambridge, Mass.: Basil Blackwell, 1992), 301-7.
-
(1992)
The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe
, pp. 301-307
-
-
Nagy, A.1
-
78
-
-
0347563762
-
-
New York: Harper & Row
-
For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
-
(1980)
Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works
-
-
D'Encausse, H.C.1
-
79
-
-
0004233028
-
-
New York: Doubleday
-
For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
-
(1984)
Nomenklatura
-
-
Voslensky, M.1
-
80
-
-
0000367973
-
The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society
-
June
-
For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
-
(1974)
American Economic Review
, vol.64
, Issue.3
, pp. 399-458
-
-
Krueger, A.O.1
-
81
-
-
0000191844
-
The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation
-
August
-
For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
-
(1975)
Journal of Political Economy
, vol.83
, pp. 807-827
-
-
Posner, R.1
-
82
-
-
0003677921
-
-
College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press
-
For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
-
(1980)
Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society
-
-
Buchanan, J.M.1
Tollison, R.D.2
Tullock, G.3
-
83
-
-
0008769819
-
Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game
-
For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
-
Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society
, pp. 16-37
-
-
Tullock, G.1
-
84
-
-
0000516192
-
The Costs of Special Privilege
-
ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle New York: Cambridge University Press
-
For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
-
(1990)
Perspectives on Positive Political Economy
, pp. 195-211
-
-
Tullock, G.1
-
85
-
-
84977416001
-
Rent-Seeking: A Survey
-
For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
-
(1982)
Kyklos
, vol.35
, Issue.4
, pp. 575-602
-
-
Tollison, R.D.1
-
86
-
-
0004294469
-
-
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, chap. 13.
-
For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
-
(1989)
Public Choice II
-
-
Mueller, D.C.1
-
87
-
-
0003726038
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger
-
For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
-
(1984)
Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities
-
-
Colander, D.C.1
-
88
-
-
0003243558
-
'Playing to the Provinces': Deng Xiaoping's Political Strategy of Economic Reform
-
Susan L. Shirk, '"Playing to the Provinces': Deng Xiaoping's Political Strategy of Economic Reform," Studies in Comparative Communism 23, no. 3/4 (1990): 227-58.
-
(1990)
Studies in Comparative Communism
, vol.23
, Issue.3-4
, pp. 227-258
-
-
Shirk, S.L.1
-
89
-
-
0004309039
-
-
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
-
For the characteristics of Chinese economic reform, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Barry Naughton, Growing Out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Carl Riskin, "Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy," in New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution, ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991), 133-52. For political aspects of reform strategy, see Steven M. Goldstein, "China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1105-31; and Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
-
(1992)
Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990
-
-
Lardy, N.R.1
-
90
-
-
85041152254
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
For the characteristics of Chinese economic reform, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Barry Naughton, Growing Out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Carl Riskin, "Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy," in New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution, ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991), 133-52. For political aspects of reform strategy, see Steven M. Goldstein, "China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1105-31; and Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
-
(1995)
Growing out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993
-
-
Naughton, B.1
-
91
-
-
85200178618
-
Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy
-
ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
-
For the characteristics of Chinese economic reform, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Barry Naughton, Growing Out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Carl Riskin, "Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy," in New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution, ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991), 133-52. For political aspects of reform strategy, see Steven M. Goldstein, "China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1105-31; and Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
-
(1991)
New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution
, pp. 133-152
-
-
Riskin, C.1
-
92
-
-
0029434787
-
China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform
-
December
-
For the characteristics of Chinese economic reform, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Barry Naughton, Growing Out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Carl Riskin, "Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy," in New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution, ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991), 133-52. For political aspects of reform strategy, see Steven M. Goldstein, "China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1105-31; and Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
-
(1995)
The China Quarterly
, Issue.144
, pp. 1105-1131
-
-
Goldstein, S.M.1
-
93
-
-
85173411799
-
-
Berkeley: University of California Press
-
For the characteristics of Chinese economic reform, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Barry Naughton, Growing Out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Carl Riskin, "Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy," in New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution, ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991), 133-52. For political aspects of reform strategy, see Steven M. Goldstein, "China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1105-31; and Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
-
(1993)
The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China
-
-
Shirk, S.L.1
-
94
-
-
84974307338
-
The Property Right Paradigm
-
By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
-
(1973)
Journal of Economic History
, vol.33
, pp. 16-27
-
-
Alchian, A.A.1
Demsetz, H.2
-
95
-
-
84974307338
-
Toward a Theory of Property Rights
-
By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
-
(1967)
American Economic Review
, vol.57
, pp. 347-359
-
-
Demsetz, H.1
-
96
-
-
84974307338
-
-
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
-
By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
-
(1990)
Economic Behavior and Institutions
-
-
Eggertsson, T.1
-
97
-
-
0242645648
-
Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action
-
By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
-
(1995)
Theory and Society
, vol.24
, pp. 301-354
-
-
Lin, N.1
-
98
-
-
0027100807
-
Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China
-
October
-
By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
-
(1992)
World Politics
, vol.45
, Issue.1
, pp. 99-126
-
-
Oi, J.C.1
-
99
-
-
0029434989
-
The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy
-
December
-
By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
-
(1995)
The China Quarterly
, Issue.144
, pp. 1132-1149
-
-
Oi, J.C.1
-
100
-
-
0003788290
-
-
See Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions, 278. Also see Douglass C. North, "Three Approaches to the Study of Institutions," in Colander, Neoclassical Political Economy, 33-40, for an insightful synthesis of the two approaches of rent-seeking and property rights.
-
Economic Behavior and Institutions
, pp. 278
-
-
Eggertsson1
-
101
-
-
0008640214
-
Three Approaches to the Study of Institutions
-
Colander
-
See Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions, 278. Also see Douglass C. North, "Three Approaches to the Study of Institutions," in Colander, Neoclassical Political Economy, 33-40, for an insightful synthesis of the two approaches of rent-seeking and property rights.
-
Neoclassical Political Economy
, pp. 33-40
-
-
North, D.C.1
-
102
-
-
85037068962
-
-
note
-
Supposing that a special privilege has a price, a "shadow price" so to speak, reasonable is to assume that the returns the official receives from his buyer of privilege would be always lower than its "market value" if such a privilege market existed.
-
-
-
-
103
-
-
0003472582
-
-
Mayfair Yang, in Gifts, Favors, and Banquets, made a distinction between use-value and exchange-value of guanxi. She argued that exchange-value has prevailed over use-value in the reform era.
-
Gifts, Favors, and Banquets
-
-
Yang, M.1
-
104
-
-
84993794458
-
-
The primary ties here refer to those that originate in families, kinship, classmates, etc. For a discussion of behavioral assumptions of economic theory, see North, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, 20-26.
-
Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance
, pp. 20-26
-
-
North1
-
105
-
-
85037100700
-
-
Interview in Guangdong, summer 1995.
-
Interview in Guangdong, summer 1995.
-
-
-
-
106
-
-
0003984746
-
-
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
-
The term "transpose" is redefined from William Sewell's "transposability," which is in turn taken from Pierre Bourdieu's "transposable." See Pierre Bourdieu, Outline of a Theory of Practice (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1977). "The verb 'transpose' implies a concrete application of a rule to a new case, but in such a way that the rule will have subtle different forms in each of its applications." See Sewell, "Theory of Structure," 17.
-
(1977)
Outline of a Theory of Practice
-
-
Bourdieu, P.1
-
107
-
-
0141466074
-
-
The term "transpose" is redefined from William Sewell's "transposability," which is in turn taken from Pierre Bourdieu's "transposable." See Pierre Bourdieu, Outline of a Theory of Practice (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1977). "The verb 'transpose' implies a concrete application of a rule to a new case, but in such a way that the rule will have subtle different forms in each of its applications." See Sewell, "Theory of Structure," 17.
-
Theory of Structure
, pp. 17
-
-
Sewell1
-
108
-
-
85037090015
-
-
note
-
It is assumed that other overseas Chinese who come from a well-established liberal democracy would not be able to play the guanxi game as adroitly as the Taiwanese.
-
-
-
-
109
-
-
10144244042
-
Strange Bedfellows: Dynamics of Government-Business Relations between Chinese Local Authorities and Taiwanese Investors
-
Below I draw heavily on my prior case study: Wu Jieh-min, "Strange Bedfellows: Dynamics of Government-Business Relations between Chinese Local Authorities and Taiwanese Investors," Journal of Contemporary China 6, no. 15(1997): 319-46.
-
(1997)
Journal of Contemporary China
, vol.6
, Issue.15
, pp. 319-346
-
-
Jieh-min, W.1
-
110
-
-
84937273471
-
-
Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1996
-
During the period 1986-94, a total of twenty thousand companies with a capital of US$20 billion had moved from Taiwan to China. For the trends of Taiwan's investment in China, see Tse-kang Leng, The Taiwan-China Connection: Democracy and Development across the Taiwan Straits (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1996); and Chen Xiangming, "Taiwan Investments in China and Southeast Asia: Go West, But Also Go South," Asian Survey 36, no. 5 (May 1996): 447-67.
-
The Taiwan-China Connection: Democracy and Development Across the Taiwan Straits
-
-
Leng, T.-K.1
-
111
-
-
0030430723
-
Taiwan Investments in China and Southeast Asia: Go West, but Also Go South
-
May
-
During the period 1986-94, a total of twenty thousand companies with a capital of US$20 billion had moved from Taiwan to China. For the trends of Taiwan's investment in China, see Tse-kang Leng, The Taiwan-China Connection: Democracy and Development across the Taiwan Straits (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1996); and Chen Xiangming, "Taiwan Investments in China and Southeast Asia: Go West, But Also Go South," Asian Survey 36, no. 5 (May 1996): 447-67.
-
(1996)
Asian Survey
, vol.36
, Issue.5
, pp. 447-467
-
-
Xiangming, C.1
-
112
-
-
85037157889
-
-
note
-
Take Xizhu, for example: the city realized US$2.3 billion processing fees from 1979 to 1994. Precisely calculating the differences in exchange rates earned by local units over time is difficult due to the complicated foreign exchange retention formula at different stages for different units and the changing official prices of the renminbi. Instead, we can roughly estimate the figure for the city in 1992, two years before the end of the multiple rate. Xizhu received a total remittance of US$390 million. The difference in the two rates was about 0.28 yuan per dollar. Then the local units should have gathered 109 million yuan. By comparison, the government budgetary revenues in the same year were 560 million yuan. This clearly shows the importance of processing fees for local financial income in the region.
-
-
-
-
113
-
-
85037100302
-
-
note
-
In some places, the term "head tax" also referred to the management fees charged by labor bureaus since the fees were also collected based on the number of workers.
-
-
-
-
115
-
-
85037176454
-
-
note
-
Many of the joint ventures were in fact "fictive joint ventures" as described above.
-
-
-
-
118
-
-
0348193302
-
Wang Shaoguang Proposal
-
A Report on China's State Capacity
-
Interview in Guangdong, winter 1994. 58 For an influential but controversial argument regarding a declining Chinese central state and the need to reverse the trend, see Wang Shaoguang and Hu Angang, "Wang Shaoguang Proposal" (A Report on China's State Capacity), Chinese Economic Studies 28, nos. 3 and 4 (1996).
-
(1996)
Chinese Economic Studies
, vol.28
, Issue.3-4
-
-
Shaoguang, W.1
Angang, H.2
-
119
-
-
85037147597
-
-
Interview in Guangdong, summer 1995
-
Interview in Guangdong, summer 1995.
-
-
-
|