메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 37, Issue 1, 2001, Pages 20-48

State Policy and Guanxi Network Adaptation in China: Local Bureaucratic Rent-Seeking

(1)  Jieh Min, Wu a  

a NONE

Author keywords

China; Guanxi network; Local government; Renting seeking; State

Indexed keywords


EID: 0346485990     PISSN: 10132511     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (15)

References (121)
  • 1
    • 85037139488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Xizhu, a code name for a prosperous city in the Pearl River delta, hosts thousands of factories that are supported by foreign capital, mostly from Hong Kong and Taiwan. Most industries in Xizhu are labor-intensive and export-oriented. Xizhu is a typical region in Southeast China that has utilized foreign capital for rapid rural industrialization. Townships and villages have thrived and have also urbanized in a somewhat crude way thanks to these processing and assembly-type investments. The author conducted interviews in Taiwan, Hong Kong, the Pearl River delta, and other regions of China in the period 1994-96. Most of the names, institutes, and locales are coded in order to protect informants in the field.
  • 2
    • 0001074042 scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business: The Family Firm in Taiwan
    • See, for example: Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business: The Family Firm in Taiwan," Comparative Social Research 12 (1990): 95-112; Alan Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi: A Reconsideration of Bourdieu's Social Capital," Cultural Anthropology 8, no. 3 (1993): 388-408; David L. Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism: Guanxi and Private Business in a South China City," The China Quarterly, no. 147 (September 1996): 820-38; and Macro Orru, Nicole Woolsey Biggart, and Gary Hamilton, eds., The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997).
    • (1990) Comparative Social Research , vol.12 , pp. 95-112
    • Hamilton, G.1    Shu, K.C.2
  • 3
    • 21144465983 scopus 로고
    • Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi: A Reconsideration of Bourdieu's Social Capital
    • See, for example: Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business: The Family Firm in Taiwan," Comparative Social Research 12 (1990): 95-112; Alan Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi: A Reconsideration of Bourdieu's Social Capital," Cultural Anthropology 8, no. 3 (1993): 388-408; David L. Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism: Guanxi and Private Business in a South China City," The China Quarterly, no. 147 (September 1996): 820-38; and Macro Orru, Nicole Woolsey Biggart, and Gary Hamilton, eds., The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997).
    • (1993) Cultural Anthropology , vol.8 , Issue.3 , pp. 388-408
    • Smart, A.1
  • 4
    • 0001112338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism: Guanxi and Private Business in a South China City
    • September
    • See, for example: Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business: The Family Firm in Taiwan," Comparative Social Research 12 (1990): 95-112; Alan Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi: A Reconsideration of Bourdieu's Social Capital," Cultural Anthropology 8, no. 3 (1993): 388-408; David L. Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism: Guanxi and Private Business in a South China City," The China Quarterly, no. 147 (September 1996): 820-38; and Macro Orru, Nicole Woolsey Biggart, and Gary Hamilton, eds., The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997).
    • (1996) The China Quarterly , Issue.147 , pp. 820-838
    • Wank, D.L.1
  • 5
    • 0003693725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: Sage
    • See, for example: Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business: The Family Firm in Taiwan," Comparative Social Research 12 (1990): 95-112; Alan Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi: A Reconsideration of Bourdieu's Social Capital," Cultural Anthropology 8, no. 3 (1993): 388-408; David L. Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism: Guanxi and Private Business in a South China City," The China Quarterly, no. 147 (September 1996): 820-38; and Macro Orru, Nicole Woolsey Biggart, and Gary Hamilton, eds., The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997).
    • (1997) The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism
    • Orru, M.1    Biggart, N.W.2    Hamilton, G.3
  • 6
    • 0039730722 scopus 로고
    • Hong Kong: Oxford University Press
    • The allusive and vague notion of "being a Chinese" has been a focus of academic debate. It is further complicated by the recent popular use of "Greater China." For the problem of "Chineseness," see Wang Gungwu, The Chineseness of China: Selected Essays (Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1991); Wang Gungwu, "Greater China and the Chinese Overseas," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 926-48; and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Living Tree: The Meaning of Being Chinese Today (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 1994). For a discussion of Greater China, see Harry Harding, "The Concept of 'Greater China': Themes, Variations, and Reservations," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 660-86. Aware of the debate, I technically treat Taiwan in this research as a Chinese society (huaren shehui) for its linguistic and cultural similarity with mainland China. We can thereby make cross-societal comparison among the Chinese societies such as colonial Hong Kong, sovereign Singapore state, and overseas Chinese communities around the world.
    • (1991) The Chineseness of China: Selected Essays
    • Gungwu, W.1
  • 7
    • 84917227015 scopus 로고
    • Greater China and the Chinese Overseas
    • December
    • The allusive and vague notion of "being a Chinese" has been a focus of academic debate. It is further complicated by the recent popular use of "Greater China." For the problem of "Chineseness," see Wang Gungwu, The Chineseness of China: Selected Essays (Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1991); Wang Gungwu, "Greater China and the Chinese Overseas," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 926-48; and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Living Tree: The Meaning of Being Chinese Today (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 1994). For a discussion of Greater China, see Harry Harding, "The Concept of 'Greater China': Themes, Variations, and Reservations," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 660-86. Aware of the debate, I technically treat Taiwan in this research as a Chinese society (huaren shehui) for its linguistic and cultural similarity with mainland China. We can thereby make cross-societal comparison among the Chinese societies such as colonial Hong Kong, sovereign Singapore state, and overseas Chinese communities around the world.
    • (1993) The China Quarterly , Issue.136 , pp. 926-948
    • Gungwu, W.1
  • 8
    • 0003630449 scopus 로고
    • Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press
    • The allusive and vague notion of "being a Chinese" has been a focus of academic debate. It is further complicated by the recent popular use of "Greater China." For the problem of "Chineseness," see Wang Gungwu, The Chineseness of China: Selected Essays (Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1991); Wang Gungwu, "Greater China and the Chinese Overseas," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 926-48; and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Living Tree: The Meaning of Being Chinese Today (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 1994). For a discussion of Greater China, see Harry Harding, "The Concept of 'Greater China': Themes, Variations, and Reservations," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 660-86. Aware of the debate, I technically treat Taiwan in this research as a Chinese society (huaren shehui) for its linguistic and cultural similarity with mainland China. We can thereby make cross-societal comparison among the Chinese societies such as colonial Hong Kong, sovereign Singapore state, and overseas Chinese communities around the world.
    • (1994) The Living Tree: The Meaning of Being Chinese Today
    • Wei-Ming, T.1
  • 9
    • 34248234853 scopus 로고
    • The Concept of 'Greater China': Themes, Variations, and Reservations
    • December
    • The allusive and vague notion of "being a Chinese" has been a focus of academic debate. It is further complicated by the recent popular use of "Greater China." For the problem of "Chineseness," see Wang Gungwu, The Chineseness of China: Selected Essays (Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1991); Wang Gungwu, "Greater China and the Chinese Overseas," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 926-48; and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Living Tree: The Meaning of Being Chinese Today (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 1994). For a discussion of Greater China, see Harry Harding, "The Concept of 'Greater China': Themes, Variations, and Reservations," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 660-86. Aware of the debate, I technically treat Taiwan in this research as a Chinese society (huaren shehui) for its linguistic and cultural similarity with mainland China. We can thereby make cross-societal comparison among the Chinese societies such as colonial Hong Kong, sovereign Singapore state, and overseas Chinese communities around the world.
    • (1993) The China Quarterly , Issue.136 , pp. 660-686
    • Harding, H.1
  • 10
    • 85179189180 scopus 로고
    • Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory
    • ed. Robert Bates Berkeley: University of California Press
    • Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
    • (1988) Toward a Political Economy of Development , pp. 142-175
    • Amsden, A.H.1
  • 11
    • 0004023051 scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
    • Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
    • (1990) Pathways from the Periphery: the Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries
    • Haggard, S.1
  • 12
    • 0004198625 scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
    • Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
    • (1987) The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism
    • Deyo, F.C.1
  • 13
    • 0001350090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan
    • Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
    • The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism , pp. 136-164
    • Johnson, C.1
  • 14
    • 0003515053 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
    • Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
    • (1990) Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization
    • Wade, R.1
  • 15
    • 0003757491 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
    • Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
    • (1990) Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia
    • Gereffi, G.1    Wyman, D.L.2
  • 16
    • 0003675059 scopus 로고
    • London: Sage
    • Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
    • (1992) Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society
    • Whitley, R.1
  • 17
    • 84965572004 scopus 로고
    • Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies
    • Alice H. Amsden, "Taiwan's Economic History: A Case of Etatisme and a Challenge to Dependency Theory," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 142-75; Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Frederic C. Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987); Chalmers Johnson, "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan," ibid., 136-64; Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman, eds., Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990); Richard Whitley, Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets, and Society (London: Sage, 1992); and Richard Whitley, "Dominant Forms of Economic Organization in Market Economies," Organization Studies 15, no. 2 (1994): 153-82.
    • (1994) Organization Studies , vol.15 , Issue.2 , pp. 153-182
    • Whitley, R.1
  • 18
    • 0003593993 scopus 로고
    • New York: Free Press
    • For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
    • (1951) The Religion of China
    • Weber, M.1
  • 19
    • 0346932660 scopus 로고
    • London: Allen and Unwin
    • For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
    • (1930) The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit
  • 20
    • 0011695311 scopus 로고
    • London: Wildwood
    • For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
    • (1987) The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty
    • Berger, P.1
  • 21
    • 0003489278 scopus 로고
    • New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books
    • For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
    • (1988) The Search of an East Asian Development Model
    • Berger, P.1    Hsiao, H.-H.2
  • 22
    • 0005647412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective
    • Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton
    • For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
    • The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism , pp. 3-32
    • Biggart, N.W.1
  • 23
    • 84965904122 scopus 로고
    • Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization
    • For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
    • (1987) International Sociology , vol.2 , Issue.3 , pp. 289-300
    • Hamilton, G.1    Shu, K.C.2
  • 24
    • 84929091572 scopus 로고
    • Berlin: de Gruyter
    • For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
    • (1990) The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism
    • Gordon Redding, S.1
  • 25
    • 0346302562 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
    • For Max Weber's classical arguments for the cultural origins of capitalism and a lack of such cultural and institutional characteristics in China, see Max Weber, The Religion of China (New York: Free Press, 1951) and The Protestant Ethic and the Capitalist Spirit (London: Allen and Unwin, 1930). For the efforts in establishing sociocultural models of East Asian development, see Peter Berger, The Capitalist Revolution: Fifty Propositions about Prosperity, Equity and Liberty (London: Wildwood, 1987); Peter Berger and Hsin-huang Hsiao, eds., The Search of an East Asian Development Model (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1988); Nicole Woolsey Biggart, "Explaining Asian Economic Organization: Towards a Weberian Institutional Perspective," in Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, 3-32; Gary Hamilton and Kao Cheng Shu, "Max Weber and the Analysis of the East Asian Industrialization," International Sociology 2, no. 3 (1987): 289-300; S. Gordon Redding, The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin: de Gruyter, 1990); and Tu Wei-ming, ed., The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995).
    • (1995) The Confucian Dimensions of Industrial East Asia
    • Wei-Ming, T.1
  • 26
    • 85065840141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Families and Networks in Taiwan's Economic Development
    • ed. Edward Winckler and Susan Greenhalgh Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe
    • Susan Greenhalgh, "Families and Networks in Taiwan's Economic Development," in Contending Approaches to the Political Economy of Taiwan, ed. Edward Winckler and Susan Greenhalgh (Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe, 1988), 224-45; Hamilton and Kao, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business" ; and Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism.
    • (1988) Contending Approaches to the Political Economy of Taiwan , pp. 224-245
    • Greenhalgh, S.1
  • 27
    • 85065840141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Susan Greenhalgh, "Families and Networks in Taiwan's Economic Development," in Contending Approaches to the Political Economy of Taiwan, ed. Edward Winckler and Susan Greenhalgh (Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe, 1988), 224-45; Hamilton and Kao, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business" ; and Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism.
    • The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business
    • Hamilton1    Kao2
  • 28
    • 85065840141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Susan Greenhalgh, "Families and Networks in Taiwan's Economic Development," in Contending Approaches to the Political Economy of Taiwan, ed. Edward Winckler and Susan Greenhalgh (Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe, 1988), 224-45; Hamilton and Kao, "The Institutional Foundations of Chinese Business" ; and Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton, The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism.
    • The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism
    • Orru1    Biggart2    Hamilton3
  • 29
    • 0003879862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan
    • See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
    • (1988) The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures
    • Pye, L.W.1
  • 30
    • 0004255770 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
    • See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
    • (1992) The Spirit of Chinese Politics
    • Pye, L.W.1
  • 31
    • 84934563463 scopus 로고
    • Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation
    • See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
    • (1991) Daedalus , vol.120 , Issue.2 , pp. 63-84
    • King, A.1
  • 32
    • 0038496530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
    • Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi
    • Smart1
  • 33
    • 84973970170 scopus 로고
    • The Gift Economy and State Power in China
    • See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
    • (1989) Comparative Studies in Society and History , vol.31 , pp. 25-54
    • Yang, M.1
  • 34
    • 85056593534 scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
    • See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
    • (1994) Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China
    • Yang, M.1
  • 35
    • 0038496529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
    • The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism
    • Wank1
  • 36
    • 6244267602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village
    • January
    • See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
    • (1996) The China Journal , Issue.35 , pp. 1-25
    • Yan, Y.1
  • 37
    • 0029434070 scopus 로고
    • The Social Roots of China's Economic Development
    • December
    • See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999-1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
    • (1995) The China Quarterly , Issue.144 , pp. 999-1019
    • Whyte, M.K.1
  • 38
    • 0030439820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?
    • October
    • See, for example: Lucian W. Pye, The Mandarin and the Cadre: China's Political Cultures (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1988); Lucian W. Pye, The Spirit of Chinese Politics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992); Ambrose King, "Kuan-hsi and Network Building: A Sociological Interpretation," Daedalus 120, no. 2 (1991): 63-84; Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi" ; Mayfair Yang, "The Gift Economy and State Power in China," Comparative Studies in Society and History 31 (1989): 25-54; Mayfair Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994); Wank, "The Institutional Process of Market Clientelism"; and Yunxiang Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," The China Journal, no. 35 (January 1996): 1-25. Whyte has examined the changing views on the Chinese family in regard to economic development. See Martin King Whyte, "The Social Roots of China's Economic Development," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 999- 1019 and "The Chinese Family and Economic Development: Obstacle or Engine?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 44, no. 1 (October 1996): 1-30. Note that it is beyond the author's ability to cite the enormous literature on Chinese culture and history. It suffices to say that the instrumental perspective ofguanxi represents an intellectual reaction to the treatment of Chinese culture and Confucian tradition as "shackles" of modernization, an approach adopted by many of the prior generations of Chinese scholars and writers.
    • (1996) Economic Development and Cultural Change , vol.44 , Issue.1 , pp. 1-30
  • 39
    • 84928834017 scopus 로고
    • Interpersonal Choice and Networks in China
    • Peter M. Blau, Danching Ruan, and Monica Ardelt, "Interpersonal Choice and Networks in China," Social Forces 69 (1991): 1037-62.
    • (1991) Social Forces , vol.69 , pp. 1037-1062
    • Blau, P.M.1    Ruan, D.2    Ardelt, M.3
  • 40
    • 0007908032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Culture, Institutions, and Business in East Asia
    • Barry Wilkinson, "Culture, Institutions, and Business in East Asia," Organization Studies 17, no. 3 (1996): 421-47.
    • (1996) Organization Studies , vol.17 , Issue.3 , pp. 421-447
    • Wilkinson, B.1
  • 42
    • 85055292755 scopus 로고
    • What Explains Chinese Political Behavior? the Debate over Structure and Culture
    • October
    • See Bruce J. Dickson, "What Explains Chinese Political Behavior? The Debate over Structure and Culture," Comparative Politics 25, no. 1 (October 1992): 103-18, for a review of the debate over culture and structure in the explanation of Chinese behavior.
    • (1992) Comparative Politics , vol.25 , Issue.1 , pp. 103-118
    • Dickson, B.J.1
  • 43
    • 4444271495 scopus 로고
    • The Foreign Relations of Greater China
    • December
    • Michael Yahuda, "The Foreign Relations of Greater China," The China Quarterly, no. 136 (December 1993): 688.
    • (1993) The China Quarterly , Issue.136 , pp. 688
    • Yahuda, M.1
  • 45
    • 0003417695 scopus 로고
    • London: Collier-Macmillan
    • For general statements of structural explanation, see Brian Barry, Sociologists, Economists, and Democracy (London: Collier-Macmillan, 1970); Barrington Moore, Jr., Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966); and Theda Skocpol, States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1979).
    • (1970) Sociologists, Economists, and Democracy
    • Barry, B.1
  • 46
    • 0003928609 scopus 로고
    • Boston: Beacon Press
    • For general statements of structural explanation, see Brian Barry, Sociologists, Economists, and Democracy (London: Collier-Macmillan, 1970); Barrington Moore, Jr., Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966); and Theda Skocpol, States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1979).
    • (1966) Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World
    • Moore B., Jr.1
  • 47
    • 84953265768 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
    • For general statements of structural explanation, see Brian Barry, Sociologists, Economists, and Democracy (London: Collier-Macmillan, 1970); Barrington Moore, Jr., Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966); and Theda Skocpol, States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1979).
    • (1979) States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China
    • Skocpol, T.1
  • 48
    • 0002991828 scopus 로고
    • Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action
    • ed. Michael Taylor Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
    • For a definition of thin rational choice theory, see Michael Taylor, "Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action," in Rationality and Revolution, ed. Michael Taylor (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 63-97. For a broader debate of cultural versus structural/institutional perspective, see Thomas A. Koelble, "The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology," Comparative Politics 27, no. 2 (January 1995): 231-44; William H. Sewell, Jr., "Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; Michael Taylor, "Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change," Politics and Society 17, no. 2 (1989): 115-62; and Richard Whittington, "Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency," Journal of Management Studies 29, no. 6 (1992): 693-712.
    • (1988) Rationality and Revolution , pp. 63-97
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 49
    • 0000503455 scopus 로고
    • The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology
    • January
    • For a definition of thin rational choice theory, see Michael Taylor, "Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action," in Rationality and Revolution, ed. Michael Taylor (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 63-97. For a broader debate of cultural versus structural/institutional perspective, see Thomas A. Koelble, "The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology," Comparative Politics 27, no. 2 (January 1995): 231-44; William H. Sewell, Jr., "Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; Michael Taylor, "Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change," Politics and Society 17, no. 2 (1989): 115-62; and Richard Whittington, "Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency," Journal of Management Studies 29, no. 6 (1992): 693-712.
    • (1995) Comparative Politics , vol.27 , Issue.2 , pp. 231-244
    • Koelble, T.A.1
  • 50
    • 0002902691 scopus 로고
    • Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation
    • July
    • For a definition of thin rational choice theory, see Michael Taylor, "Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action," in Rationality and Revolution, ed. Michael Taylor (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 63-97. For a broader debate of cultural versus structural/institutional perspective, see Thomas A. Koelble, "The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology," Comparative Politics 27, no. 2 (January 1995): 231-44; William H. Sewell, Jr., "Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; Michael Taylor, "Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change," Politics and Society 17, no. 2 (1989): 115-62; and Richard Whittington, "Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency," Journal of Management Studies 29, no. 6 (1992): 693-712.
    • (1992) American Journal of Sociology , vol.98 , Issue.1 , pp. 1-29
    • Sewell W.H., Jr.1
  • 51
    • 84970415465 scopus 로고
    • Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change
    • For a definition of thin rational choice theory, see Michael Taylor, "Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action," in Rationality and Revolution, ed. Michael Taylor (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 63-97. For a broader debate of cultural versus structural/institutional perspective, see Thomas A. Koelble, "The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology," Comparative Politics 27, no. 2 (January 1995): 231-44; William H. Sewell, Jr., "Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; Michael Taylor, "Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change," Politics and Society 17, no. 2 (1989): 115-62; and Richard Whittington, "Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency," Journal of Management Studies 29, no. 6 (1992): 693-712.
    • (1989) Politics and Society , vol.17 , Issue.2 , pp. 115-162
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 52
    • 85016697597 scopus 로고
    • Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency
    • For a definition of thin rational choice theory, see Michael Taylor, "Rationality and Revolutionary Collective Action," in Rationality and Revolution, ed. Michael Taylor (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 63-97. For a broader debate of cultural versus structural/institutional perspective, see Thomas A. Koelble, "The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology," Comparative Politics 27, no. 2 (January 1995): 231-44; William H. Sewell, Jr., "Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; Michael Taylor, "Structure, Culture, and Action in the Explanation of Social Change," Politics and Society 17, no. 2 (1989): 115-62; and Richard Whittington, "Putting Giddens into Action: Social Systems and Managerial Agency," Journal of Management Studies 29, no. 6 (1992): 693-712.
    • (1992) Journal of Management Studies , vol.29 , Issue.6 , pp. 693-712
    • Whittington, R.1
  • 53
    • 34248253450 scopus 로고
    • Is Chinese Culture Distinctive? - A Review Article
    • Andrew J. Nathan, "Is Chinese Culture Distinctive? - A Review Article," Journal of Asian Studies 52, no. 4 (1993): 923-36.
    • (1993) Journal of Asian Studies , vol.52 , Issue.4 , pp. 923-936
    • Nathan, A.J.1
  • 59
    • 0003472582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This has been argued in several empirical findings. See Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets, for different meaning of guanxi in Mao's era and in Deng's reform; and Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," proposed that guanxi in the countryside functions dissimilarly than in the urban areas.
    • Gifts, Favors, and Banquets
    • Yang1
  • 60
    • 0038496520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This has been argued in several empirical findings. See Yang, Gifts, Favors, and Banquets, for different meaning of guanxi in Mao's era and in Deng's reform; and Yan, "The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village," proposed that guanxi in the countryside functions dissimilarly than in the urban areas.
    • The Culture of Guanxi in a North China Village
    • Yan1
  • 62
    • 84936823493 scopus 로고
    • Culture in Action: Symbols and Strategies
    • In this sense, culture functions like a "tool kit" for a social actor. See Anne Swidler, "Culture in Action: Symbols and Strategies," American Sociological Review 51 (1986): 273-86.
    • (1986) American Sociological Review , vol.51 , pp. 273-286
    • Swidler, A.1
  • 65
    • 84936824515 scopus 로고
    • New York: Basic Books
    • An end-game situation, like in a one-shot game, tends to encourage noncooperation and defection because there will be no more expected interaction in the future. In contrast, repeated games tend to induce cooperation. See Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984).
    • (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation
    • Axelrod, R.1
  • 66
    • 85037086006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Failure to fulfill an obligation usually signals a withdrawal from a social relationship.
  • 67
    • 0004241720 scopus 로고
    • New York: Norton
    • Cf. Marcel Mauss, The Gift (New York: Norton, 1967). Note that Mauss assumed a "misrecognition" of instrumental motivation involved in gift exchange. Smart has a parallel argument in Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi," 395-97.
    • (1967) The Gift
    • Mauss, M.1
  • 68
    • 0038496530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Marcel Mauss, The Gift (New York: Norton, 1967). Note that Mauss assumed a "misrecognition" of instrumental motivation involved in gift exchange. Smart has a parallel argument in Smart, "Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi," 395-97.
    • Gifts, Bribes, and Guanxi , pp. 395-397
    • Smart1
  • 69
    • 85037071142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If the transaction is not made in cash, the seller of goods at least has to secure some kind of certificate or claim of the equivalent value in return.
  • 71
    • 0003852824 scopus 로고
    • New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1964
    • This is evident when compared with commodity exchange. A credit purchase involves a clear and measurable debt to the merchant. In favor exchange, however, this is not the case. As Peter Blau argued: "Social exchange entails unspecified obligation. There is no contract, and there is no exact price." See Peter M. Blau, Exchange and Power in Social Life (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1986 [1964]), 315.
    • (1986) Exchange and Power in Social Life , pp. 315
    • Blau, P.M.1
  • 73
    • 34247960076 scopus 로고
    • The Strength of Weak Ties
    • n. 2
    • This phenomenon was pointed out by Mark Granovetter: "Ties discussed in this paper are assumed to be positive and symmetric; a comprehensive theory might require discussion of negative and/or asymmetric ties." See Mark Granovetter, "The Strength of Weak Ties," American Journal of Sociology 78, no. 6 (1973): 1361 n. 2.
    • (1973) American Journal of Sociology , vol.78 , Issue.6 , pp. 1361
    • Granovetter, M.1
  • 74
    • 0005102425 scopus 로고
    • Obligation and Control: Employment of Kin in Capitalist Labour Management in China
    • For a case study in kin employment in relation to unexpected problems in such network employment, see Josephine Smart and Alan Smart, "Obligation and Control: Employment of Kin in Capitalist Labour Management in China," Critique of Anthropology 13, no. 1 (1993): 7-31.
    • (1993) Critique of Anthropology , vol.13 , Issue.1 , pp. 7-31
    • Smart, J.1    Smart, A.2
  • 75
    • 0004138811 scopus 로고
    • Amsterdam: North-Holland
    • See Janos Kornai, Economics of Shortage (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1980), for the concept of shortage economy.
    • (1980) Economics of Shortage
    • Kornai, J.1
  • 76
    • 21144475959 scopus 로고
    • Perestroika and Public Choice: The Economies of Autocratic Succession in Rent-Seeking Society
    • Gary M. Anderson and Peter J. Boettke, "Perestroika and Public Choice: The Economies of Autocratic Succession in Rent-Seeking Society," Public Choice 75, no. 1 (1993): 101-18; Andras Nagy, "Institutions and the Transition to a Market Economy," in The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe, ed. Christopher Clague and Gorden C. Rausser (Cambridge, Mass.:
    • (1993) Public Choice , vol.75 , Issue.1 , pp. 101-118
    • Anderson, G.M.1    Boettke, P.J.2
  • 77
    • 21144475959 scopus 로고
    • Institutions and the Transition to a Market Economy
    • ed. Christopher Clague and Gorden C. Rausser Cambridge, Mass.: Basil Blackwell
    • Gary M. Anderson and Peter J. Boettke, "Perestroika and Public Choice: The Economies of Autocratic Succession in Rent-Seeking Society," Public Choice 75, no. 1 (1993): 101- 18; Andras Nagy, "Institutions and the Transition to a Market Economy," in The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe, ed. Christopher Clague and Gorden C. Rausser (Cambridge, Mass.: Basil Blackwell, 1992), 301-7.
    • (1992) The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe , pp. 301-307
    • Nagy, A.1
  • 78
    • 0347563762 scopus 로고
    • New York: Harper & Row
    • For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
    • (1980) Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works
    • D'Encausse, H.C.1
  • 79
    • 0004233028 scopus 로고
    • New York: Doubleday
    • For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
    • (1984) Nomenklatura
    • Voslensky, M.1
  • 80
    • 0000367973 scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society
    • June
    • For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
    • (1974) American Economic Review , vol.64 , Issue.3 , pp. 399-458
    • Krueger, A.O.1
  • 81
    • 0000191844 scopus 로고
    • The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation
    • August
    • For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
    • (1975) Journal of Political Economy , vol.83 , pp. 807-827
    • Posner, R.1
  • 82
    • 0003677921 scopus 로고
    • College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press
    • For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
    • (1980) Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society
    • Buchanan, J.M.1    Tollison, R.D.2    Tullock, G.3
  • 83
    • 0008769819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game
    • For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
    • Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society , pp. 16-37
    • Tullock, G.1
  • 84
    • 0000516192 scopus 로고
    • The Costs of Special Privilege
    • ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle New York: Cambridge University Press
    • For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
    • (1990) Perspectives on Positive Political Economy , pp. 195-211
    • Tullock, G.1
  • 85
    • 84977416001 scopus 로고
    • Rent-Seeking: A Survey
    • For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
    • (1982) Kyklos , vol.35 , Issue.4 , pp. 575-602
    • Tollison, R.D.1
  • 86
    • 0004294469 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, chap. 13.
    • For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
    • (1989) Public Choice II
    • Mueller, D.C.1
  • 87
    • 0003726038 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger
    • For the case of the Soviet Union, see Helene C. D'Encausse, Confiscated Power: How Soviet Russia Really Works (New York: Harper & Row, 1980) and M. Voslensky, Nomenklatura (New York: Doubleday, 1984). For the general problems of rent-seeking, see Anne O. Krueger, "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review 64, no. 3 (June 1974): 399-458; Richard Posner, "The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation," Journal of Political Economy 83 (August 1975): 807-27; James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent- Seeking Society (College Station, Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980); Gordon Tullock, "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game," ibid., 16-37; Gordon Tullock, "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 195-211; and Robert D. Tollison, "Rent-Seeking: A Survey," Kyklos 35, no. 4 (1982): 575-602. Note that I adopt a broad definition of rent-seeking, including revenue-seeking activities through government regulation, tariffs, quota, and contracting. Cf. Dennis C. Mueller, Public Choice II (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 13. These activities are also named "directly unproductive profit-seeking activities (DUP)." See David C. Colander, ed., Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1984).
    • (1984) Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities
    • Colander, D.C.1
  • 88
    • 0003243558 scopus 로고
    • 'Playing to the Provinces': Deng Xiaoping's Political Strategy of Economic Reform
    • Susan L. Shirk, '"Playing to the Provinces': Deng Xiaoping's Political Strategy of Economic Reform," Studies in Comparative Communism 23, no. 3/4 (1990): 227-58.
    • (1990) Studies in Comparative Communism , vol.23 , Issue.3-4 , pp. 227-258
    • Shirk, S.L.1
  • 89
    • 0004309039 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
    • For the characteristics of Chinese economic reform, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Barry Naughton, Growing Out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Carl Riskin, "Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy," in New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution, ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991), 133-52. For political aspects of reform strategy, see Steven M. Goldstein, "China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1105-31; and Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
    • (1992) Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990
    • Lardy, N.R.1
  • 90
    • 85041152254 scopus 로고
    • New York: Cambridge University Press
    • For the characteristics of Chinese economic reform, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Barry Naughton, Growing Out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Carl Riskin, "Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy," in New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution, ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991), 133-52. For political aspects of reform strategy, see Steven M. Goldstein, "China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1105-31; and Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
    • (1995) Growing out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993
    • Naughton, B.1
  • 91
    • 85200178618 scopus 로고
    • Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy
    • ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
    • For the characteristics of Chinese economic reform, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Barry Naughton, Growing Out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Carl Riskin, "Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy," in New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution, ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991), 133-52. For political aspects of reform strategy, see Steven M. Goldstein, "China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1105-31; and Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
    • (1991) New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution , pp. 133-152
    • Riskin, C.1
  • 92
    • 0029434787 scopus 로고
    • China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform
    • December
    • For the characteristics of Chinese economic reform, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Barry Naughton, Growing Out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Carl Riskin, "Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy," in New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution, ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991), 133-52. For political aspects of reform strategy, see Steven M. Goldstein, "China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1105-31; and Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
    • (1995) The China Quarterly , Issue.144 , pp. 1105-1131
    • Goldstein, S.M.1
  • 93
    • 85173411799 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • For the characteristics of Chinese economic reform, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China: 1978-1990 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Barry Naughton, Growing Out of the Plan: China's Economic Reform, 1978-1993 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Carl Riskin, "Neither Plan nor Market: Mao's Political Economy," in New Perspectives on the Cultural Revolution, ed. William A. Joseph, Christine P.W. Wong, and David Zweig (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991), 133-52. For political aspects of reform strategy, see Steven M. Goldstein, "China in Transition: The Political Foundations of Incremental Reform," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1105-31; and Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
    • (1993) The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China
    • Shirk, S.L.1
  • 94
    • 84974307338 scopus 로고
    • The Property Right Paradigm
    • By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
    • (1973) Journal of Economic History , vol.33 , pp. 16-27
    • Alchian, A.A.1    Demsetz, H.2
  • 95
    • 84974307338 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Theory of Property Rights
    • By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
    • (1967) American Economic Review , vol.57 , pp. 347-359
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 96
    • 84974307338 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
    • By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
    • (1990) Economic Behavior and Institutions
    • Eggertsson, T.1
  • 97
    • 0242645648 scopus 로고
    • Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action
    • By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
    • (1995) Theory and Society , vol.24 , pp. 301-354
    • Lin, N.1
  • 98
    • 0027100807 scopus 로고
    • Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China
    • October
    • By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
    • (1992) World Politics , vol.45 , Issue.1 , pp. 99-126
    • Oi, J.C.1
  • 99
    • 0029434989 scopus 로고
    • The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy
    • December
    • By "local property rights regime," this author refers to a system of formal and informal rules within a local jurisdiction that regulates the general assignment of property rights, ownership, and fiscal relationships. This definition also implies that there is more than a unitary local regime in China. Instead, diverse local regimes exist in response to each region's factor endowment and previous institutional arrangements. For the concept of property rights, cf. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Right Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 (1973): 16-27; Horald Demsetz, "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967): 347-59; and Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990). For the role of local government in promoting rural economic development, cf. Nan Lin, "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action," Theory and Society 24 (1995): 301-54; Jean C. Oi, "Fiscal Reform and Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China," World Politics 45, no. 1 (October 1992): 99-126; and Jean C. Oi, "The Role of the Local State in China's Transitional Economy," The China Quarterly, no. 144 (December 1995): 1132-49.
    • (1995) The China Quarterly , Issue.144 , pp. 1132-1149
    • Oi, J.C.1
  • 100
    • 0003788290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions, 278. Also see Douglass C. North, "Three Approaches to the Study of Institutions," in Colander, Neoclassical Political Economy, 33-40, for an insightful synthesis of the two approaches of rent-seeking and property rights.
    • Economic Behavior and Institutions , pp. 278
    • Eggertsson1
  • 101
    • 0008640214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Three Approaches to the Study of Institutions
    • Colander
    • See Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions, 278. Also see Douglass C. North, "Three Approaches to the Study of Institutions," in Colander, Neoclassical Political Economy, 33-40, for an insightful synthesis of the two approaches of rent-seeking and property rights.
    • Neoclassical Political Economy , pp. 33-40
    • North, D.C.1
  • 102
    • 85037068962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Supposing that a special privilege has a price, a "shadow price" so to speak, reasonable is to assume that the returns the official receives from his buyer of privilege would be always lower than its "market value" if such a privilege market existed.
  • 103
    • 0003472582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mayfair Yang, in Gifts, Favors, and Banquets, made a distinction between use-value and exchange-value of guanxi. She argued that exchange-value has prevailed over use-value in the reform era.
    • Gifts, Favors, and Banquets
    • Yang, M.1
  • 105
    • 85037100700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interview in Guangdong, summer 1995.
    • Interview in Guangdong, summer 1995.
  • 106
    • 0003984746 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press
    • The term "transpose" is redefined from William Sewell's "transposability," which is in turn taken from Pierre Bourdieu's "transposable." See Pierre Bourdieu, Outline of a Theory of Practice (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1977). "The verb 'transpose' implies a concrete application of a rule to a new case, but in such a way that the rule will have subtle different forms in each of its applications." See Sewell, "Theory of Structure," 17.
    • (1977) Outline of a Theory of Practice
    • Bourdieu, P.1
  • 107
    • 0141466074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The term "transpose" is redefined from William Sewell's "transposability," which is in turn taken from Pierre Bourdieu's "transposable." See Pierre Bourdieu, Outline of a Theory of Practice (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1977). "The verb 'transpose' implies a concrete application of a rule to a new case, but in such a way that the rule will have subtle different forms in each of its applications." See Sewell, "Theory of Structure," 17.
    • Theory of Structure , pp. 17
    • Sewell1
  • 108
    • 85037090015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is assumed that other overseas Chinese who come from a well-established liberal democracy would not be able to play the guanxi game as adroitly as the Taiwanese.
  • 109
    • 10144244042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strange Bedfellows: Dynamics of Government-Business Relations between Chinese Local Authorities and Taiwanese Investors
    • Below I draw heavily on my prior case study: Wu Jieh-min, "Strange Bedfellows: Dynamics of Government-Business Relations between Chinese Local Authorities and Taiwanese Investors," Journal of Contemporary China 6, no. 15(1997): 319-46.
    • (1997) Journal of Contemporary China , vol.6 , Issue.15 , pp. 319-346
    • Jieh-min, W.1
  • 110
    • 84937273471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1996
    • During the period 1986-94, a total of twenty thousand companies with a capital of US$20 billion had moved from Taiwan to China. For the trends of Taiwan's investment in China, see Tse-kang Leng, The Taiwan-China Connection: Democracy and Development across the Taiwan Straits (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1996); and Chen Xiangming, "Taiwan Investments in China and Southeast Asia: Go West, But Also Go South," Asian Survey 36, no. 5 (May 1996): 447-67.
    • The Taiwan-China Connection: Democracy and Development Across the Taiwan Straits
    • Leng, T.-K.1
  • 111
    • 0030430723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taiwan Investments in China and Southeast Asia: Go West, but Also Go South
    • May
    • During the period 1986-94, a total of twenty thousand companies with a capital of US$20 billion had moved from Taiwan to China. For the trends of Taiwan's investment in China, see Tse-kang Leng, The Taiwan-China Connection: Democracy and Development across the Taiwan Straits (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1996); and Chen Xiangming, "Taiwan Investments in China and Southeast Asia: Go West, But Also Go South," Asian Survey 36, no. 5 (May 1996): 447-67.
    • (1996) Asian Survey , vol.36 , Issue.5 , pp. 447-467
    • Xiangming, C.1
  • 112
    • 85037157889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Take Xizhu, for example: the city realized US$2.3 billion processing fees from 1979 to 1994. Precisely calculating the differences in exchange rates earned by local units over time is difficult due to the complicated foreign exchange retention formula at different stages for different units and the changing official prices of the renminbi. Instead, we can roughly estimate the figure for the city in 1992, two years before the end of the multiple rate. Xizhu received a total remittance of US$390 million. The difference in the two rates was about 0.28 yuan per dollar. Then the local units should have gathered 109 million yuan. By comparison, the government budgetary revenues in the same year were 560 million yuan. This clearly shows the importance of processing fees for local financial income in the region.
  • 113
    • 85037100302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In some places, the term "head tax" also referred to the management fees charged by labor bureaus since the fees were also collected based on the number of workers.
  • 115
    • 85037176454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Many of the joint ventures were in fact "fictive joint ventures" as described above.
  • 118
    • 0348193302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wang Shaoguang Proposal
    • A Report on China's State Capacity
    • Interview in Guangdong, winter 1994. 58 For an influential but controversial argument regarding a declining Chinese central state and the need to reverse the trend, see Wang Shaoguang and Hu Angang, "Wang Shaoguang Proposal" (A Report on China's State Capacity), Chinese Economic Studies 28, nos. 3 and 4 (1996).
    • (1996) Chinese Economic Studies , vol.28 , Issue.3-4
    • Shaoguang, W.1    Angang, H.2
  • 119
    • 85037147597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interview in Guangdong, summer 1995
    • Interview in Guangdong, summer 1995.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.