메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 6, Issue 15, 1997, Pages 319-346

Strange Bedfellows: Dynamics of government-business relations between Chinese local authorities and Taiwanese investors

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 10144244042     PISSN: 10670564     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1080/10670569708724281     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (37)

References (89)
  • 1
    • 0000367973 scopus 로고
    • The political economy of the rent-seeking society
    • See Anne O. Krueger, 'The political economy of the rent-seeking society', American Economic Review 64, (1974), pp. 291-303; Robert D. Tollison, 'Rent seeking: a survey', Kyklos 35, (1982), pp. 575-602; Samuel P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1969);
    • (1974) American Economic Review , vol.64 , pp. 291-303
    • Krueger, A.O.1
  • 2
    • 84977416001 scopus 로고
    • Rent seeking: A survey
    • See Anne O. Krueger, 'The political economy of the rent-seeking society', American Economic Review 64, (1974), pp. 291-303; Robert D. Tollison, 'Rent seeking: a survey', Kyklos 35, (1982), pp. 575-602; Samuel P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1969);
    • (1982) Kyklos , vol.35 , pp. 575-602
    • Tollison, R.D.1
  • 3
    • 0003568437 scopus 로고
    • New Haven: Yale University Press
    • See Anne O. Krueger, 'The political economy of the rent-seeking society', American Economic Review 64, (1974), pp. 291-303; Robert D. Tollison, 'Rent seeking: a survey', Kyklos 35, (1982), pp. 575-602; Samuel P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1969);
    • (1969) Political Order in Changing Societies
    • Huntington, S.P.1
  • 6
    • 84974307338 scopus 로고
    • The property right paradigm
    • See Armen Alchian and Harold Demsetz, 'The property right paradigm', Journal of Economic History 33, (1973), pp. 16-27; Louis De Alessi, 'The economics of property rights: a review of the evidence', Research in Law and Economics, (1980), pp. 1-47; and Gary Libecap, Contracting for Property Rights (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989).
    • (1973) Journal of Economic History , vol.33 , pp. 16-27
    • Alchian, A.1    Demsetz, H.2
  • 7
    • 84974307338 scopus 로고
    • The economics of property rights: A review of the evidence
    • See Armen Alchian and Harold Demsetz, 'The property right paradigm', Journal of Economic History 33, (1973), pp. 16-27; Louis De Alessi, 'The economics of property rights: a review of the evidence', Research in Law and Economics, (1980), pp. 1-47; and Gary Libecap, Contracting for Property Rights (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989).
    • (1980) Research in Law and Economics , pp. 1-47
    • De Alessi, L.1
  • 8
    • 84974307338 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • See Armen Alchian and Harold Demsetz, 'The property right paradigm', Journal of Economic History 33, (1973), pp. 16-27; Louis De Alessi, 'The economics of property rights: a review of the evidence', Research in Law and Economics, (1980), pp. 1-47; and Gary Libecap, Contracting for Property Rights (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989).
    • (1989) Contracting for Property Rights
    • Libecap, G.1
  • 9
    • 0002429294 scopus 로고
    • Enterprise reform in Chinese industry
    • The average annual growth rate in industrial output during 1980-1992 was 13.1%. Taken respectively, the state-run sector was a below-average 7.8%; the collective, 18.4%; and the private, 64.9%. See Gary H. Jefferson and Thomas G. Rawski, 'Enterprise reform in Chinese industry', Journal of Economic Perspectives 8, (1994), pp. 47-70. Moreover, the growth of total factor productivity in the non-state sector has been faster than in state-run enterprises after reform. See Dwight Perkins, 'Completing China's move to the Market', Journal of Economic Perspectives 8, (1994), pp. 23-46. For the industrial growth in the rural area, cf. William Byrd and Qingsong Lin, eds, China's Rural Industry: Structure, Development, and Reform (New York: Oxford University Press, 1990).
    • (1994) Journal of Economic Perspectives , vol.8 , pp. 47-70
    • Jefferson, G.H.1    Rawski, T.G.2
  • 10
    • 0002700423 scopus 로고
    • Completing China's move to the Market
    • The average annual growth rate in industrial output during 1980-1992 was 13.1%. Taken respectively, the state-run sector was a below-average 7.8%; the collective, 18.4%; and the private, 64.9%. See Gary H. Jefferson and Thomas G. Rawski, 'Enterprise reform in Chinese industry', Journal of Economic Perspectives 8, (1994), pp. 47-70. Moreover, the growth of total factor productivity in the non-state sector has been faster than in state-run enterprises after reform. See Dwight Perkins, 'Completing China's move to the Market', Journal of Economic Perspectives 8, (1994), pp. 23-46. For the industrial growth in the rural area, cf. William Byrd and Qingsong Lin, eds, China's Rural Industry: Structure, Development, and Reform (New York: Oxford University Press, 1990).
    • (1994) Journal of Economic Perspectives , vol.8 , pp. 23-46
    • Perkins, D.1
  • 11
    • 85009466411 scopus 로고
    • New York: Oxford University Press
    • The average annual growth rate in industrial output during 1980-1992 was 13.1%. Taken respectively, the state-run sector was a below-average 7.8%; the collective, 18.4%; and the private, 64.9%. See Gary H. Jefferson and Thomas G. Rawski, 'Enterprise reform in Chinese industry', Journal of Economic Perspectives 8, (1994), pp. 47-70. Moreover, the growth of total factor productivity in the non-state sector has been faster than in state-run enterprises after reform. See Dwight Perkins, 'Completing China's move to the Market', Journal of Economic Perspectives 8, (1994), pp. 23-46. For the industrial growth in the rural area, cf. William Byrd and Qingsong Lin, eds, China's Rural Industry: Structure, Development, and Reform (New York: Oxford University Press, 1990).
    • (1990) China's Rural Industry: Structure, Development, and Reform
    • Byrd, W.1    Lin, Q.2
  • 12
    • 84972422026 scopus 로고
    • Foreign investment and economic change in China
    • For the trend in foreign investment and its consequences, see Y. Y. Kueh, 'Foreign investment and economic change in China', China Quarterly 131, (1992), pp. 638-690. See also Table 2 below.
    • (1992) China Quarterly , vol.131 , pp. 638-690
    • Kueh, Y.Y.1
  • 13
    • 84972273436 scopus 로고
    • Reform from below: The private economy and local politics in the rural industrialization of Wenzhou
    • 'Wearing-red-hat' is a local strategy in patronizing private entrepreneurship, which allows private businesses to affiliate with official unit (guahu). It originally developed from Wenzhou area (Zhejiang Province) in the early 1970s when private businesses were illegal. The local governments granted official patronage to private and household units with the title of collective enterprises. See Ya-Ling Liu, 'Reform from below: the private economy and local politics in the rural industrialization of Wenzhou', China Quarterly 130, (1992), pp. 293-316; and Kristen Parris, 'Local initiative and national reform: the Wenzhou model of development', China Quarterly 134, (1993), pp. 242-263. The continued informal institutional arrangement that helped avoid the problems of political legitimacy since then has been emulated everywhere in China with various modifications. It also produced a dynamics in extending its functions from legitimation to other economic benefits.
    • (1992) China Quarterly , vol.130 , pp. 293-316
    • Liu, Y.-L.1
  • 14
    • 0039818013 scopus 로고
    • Local initiative and national reform: The Wenzhou model of development
    • 'Wearing-red-hat' is a local strategy in patronizing private entrepreneurship, which allows private businesses to affiliate with official unit (guahu). It originally developed from Wenzhou area (Zhejiang Province) in the early 1970s when private businesses were illegal. The local governments granted official patronage to private and household units with the title of collective enterprises. See Ya-Ling Liu, 'Reform from below: the private economy and local politics in the rural industrialization of Wenzhou', China Quarterly 130, (1992), pp. 293-316; and Kristen Parris, 'Local initiative and national reform: the Wenzhou model of development', China Quarterly 134, (1993), pp. 242-263. The continued informal institutional arrangement that helped avoid the problems of political legitimacy since then has been emulated everywhere in China with various modifications. It also produced a dynamics in extending its functions from legitimation to other economic benefits.
    • (1993) China Quarterly , vol.134 , pp. 242-263
    • Parris, K.1
  • 15
    • 84936824245 scopus 로고
    • Organizational dynamics of market transition: Hybrid forms, property rights, and mixed economy in China
    • Fuzzy property rights or hybrid forms of ownership are often seen in the context of socialist reform. The boundaries along various forms of property are vaguely delineated, particularly of the distinction between public and private property. In an enterprise, there may have a complex combination of state, communal and private sources of capital. The phenomena is common in China since reform. Cf. Victor Nee, Organizational dynamics of market transition: hybrid forms, property rights, and mixed economy in China', Administrative Science Quarterly 37, (1992), pp. 1-27.
    • (1992) Administrative Science Quarterly , vol.37 , pp. 1-27
    • Nee, V.1
  • 16
    • 0003540038 scopus 로고
    • New York: Cambridge University Press
    • By path dependence, I mean the situation in which the choice set for a specific actor is constrained by preexisting institutions and rules when encountering a new environment. See Douglass North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), for an original theory. For empirical applications in the marketized socialist economies, see Dorothy Solinger, 'Urban reform and relational contracting in post-Mao China: an interpretation of the transition from plan to market', in Richard Baum, ed., Reform and Reaction in Post-Mao China: the Road to Tiananmen (New York: Routledge, 1991); David Stark, 'Path dependence and privatization strategies in Eastern Europe', Eastern European Politics and Societies 6, (1992), pp. 17-54; and Simon Johnson and Heidi Kroll, 'Managerial strategies for spontaneous srivatization', Soviet Economy 7, (1991), pp. 281-316.
    • (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance
    • North, D.1
  • 17
    • 1542480464 scopus 로고
    • Urban reform and relational contracting in post-Mao China: An interpretation of the transition from plan to market
    • Richard Baum, ed., New York: Routledge
    • By path dependence, I mean the situation in which the choice set for a specific actor is constrained by preexisting institutions and rules when encountering a new environment. See Douglass North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), for an original theory. For empirical applications in the marketized socialist economies, see Dorothy Solinger, 'Urban reform and relational contracting in post-Mao China: an interpretation of the transition from plan to market', in Richard Baum, ed., Reform and Reaction in Post-Mao China: the Road to Tiananmen (New York: Routledge, 1991); David Stark, 'Path dependence and privatization strategies in Eastern Europe', Eastern European Politics and Societies 6, (1992), pp. 17-54; and Simon Johnson and Heidi Kroll, 'Managerial strategies for spontaneous srivatization', Soviet Economy 7, (1991), pp. 281-316.
    • (1991) Reform and Reaction in Post-Mao China: The Road to Tiananmen
    • Solinger, D.1
  • 18
    • 84976926662 scopus 로고
    • Path dependence and privatization strategies in Eastern Europe
    • By path dependence, I mean the situation in which the choice set for a specific actor is constrained by preexisting institutions and rules when encountering a new environment. See Douglass North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), for an original theory. For empirical applications in the marketized socialist economies, see Dorothy Solinger, 'Urban reform and relational contracting in post-Mao China: an interpretation of the transition from plan to market', in Richard Baum, ed., Reform and Reaction in Post-Mao China: the Road to Tiananmen (New York: Routledge, 1991); David Stark, 'Path dependence and privatization strategies in Eastern Europe', Eastern European Politics and Societies 6, (1992), pp. 17-54; and Simon Johnson and Heidi Kroll, 'Managerial strategies for spontaneous srivatization', Soviet Economy 7, (1991), pp. 281-316.
    • (1992) Eastern European Politics and Societies , vol.6 , pp. 17-54
    • Stark, D.1
  • 19
    • 84960653096 scopus 로고
    • Managerial strategies for spontaneous srivatization
    • By path dependence, I mean the situation in which the choice set for a specific actor is constrained by preexisting institutions and rules when encountering a new environment. See Douglass North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), for an original theory. For empirical applications in the marketized socialist economies, see Dorothy Solinger, 'Urban reform and relational contracting in post-Mao China: an interpretation of the transition from plan to market', in Richard Baum, ed., Reform and Reaction in Post-Mao China: the Road to Tiananmen (New York: Routledge, 1991); David Stark, 'Path dependence and privatization strategies in Eastern Europe', Eastern European Politics and Societies 6, (1992), pp. 17-54; and Simon Johnson and Heidi Kroll, 'Managerial strategies for spontaneous srivatization', Soviet Economy 7, (1991), pp. 281-316.
    • (1991) Soviet Economy , vol.7 , pp. 281-316
    • Johnson, S.1    Kroll, H.2
  • 20
    • 84972011919 scopus 로고
    • Central-local relations in an era of fiscal decline: The paradox of fiscal decentralization in post-Mao China
    • See Christine P. W. Wong, 'Central-local relations in an era of fiscal decline: the paradox of fiscal decentralization in post-Mao China', China Quarterly 128, (1991), pp. 691-715. The major institutional arrangement for financial decentralization is a nation-wide fiscal responsibility system between the center and local governments.
    • (1991) China Quarterly , vol.128 , pp. 691-715
    • Wong, C.P.W.1
  • 21
    • 0000449214 scopus 로고
    • Resource-constrained versus demand-constrained systems
    • For the concept of soft budget constraint, see Janos Kornai, 'Resource-constrained versus demand-constrained systems', Economica 47, (1979), pp. 801-819.
    • (1979) Economica , vol.47 , pp. 801-819
    • Kornai, J.1
  • 22
    • 85033290936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Chinese economic reform can be divided into two phases. The first stage spanned from 1978 to 1991. The second began from 1992, a significant year in marking new dynamics of Open Door. The reform had been in the doldrums since the price and urban reform failed in 1988. In early 1992, the 'conductor of the Chinese reform' Deng Xiaoping traveled to the southern provinces to boost further reform. A series of further opening and institutional reform have been under way since then.
  • 23
    • 85173411799 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • Roughly, partial reform represents a contrast approach to 'shock therapy'. It implies an incremental, piecemeal, and gradual approach in reforming the existing system. Cf. Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993). The Chinese government once considered using the method of blitzkrieg to cancel the dual price system in 1988, but failed to implement it due to a soaring inflation and consumer panic beforehand. For economic arguments for incremental reform, see Peter Murrell, 'Evolution in economics and in the economic reform of the centrally planned economics', in Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, The Emergence of Market Economics in Eastern Europe (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1992), pp. 35-53; Ronald I. McKinnon, The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to Market Economy (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1991); and idem, 'Taxation, money, and credit in a liberalizing socialist economy', in Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, pp. 109-127. See David Lipton and Jeffrey Sachs, 'Creating a market economy in Eastern Europe: the case of Poland', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, (1990), for the rationale and procedures of the rapid transition approach needed for Eastern Europe.
    • (1993) The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China
    • Shirk, S.L.1
  • 24
    • 0001898001 scopus 로고
    • Evolution in economics and in the economic reform of the centrally planned economics
    • Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell
    • Roughly, partial reform represents a contrast approach to 'shock therapy'. It implies an incremental, piecemeal, and gradual approach in reforming the existing system. Cf. Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993). The Chinese government once considered using the method of blitzkrieg to cancel the dual price system in 1988, but failed to implement it due to a soaring inflation and consumer panic beforehand. For economic arguments for incremental reform, see Peter Murrell, 'Evolution in economics and in the economic reform of the centrally planned economics', in Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, The Emergence of Market Economics in Eastern Europe (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1992), pp. 35-53; Ronald I. McKinnon, The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to Market Economy (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1991); and idem, 'Taxation, money, and credit in a liberalizing socialist economy', in Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, pp. 109-127. See David Lipton and Jeffrey Sachs, 'Creating a market economy in Eastern Europe: the case of Poland', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, (1990), for the rationale and procedures of the rapid transition approach needed for Eastern Europe.
    • (1992) The Emergence of Market Economics in Eastern Europe , pp. 35-53
    • Murrell, P.1
  • 25
    • 0003959408 scopus 로고
    • Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press
    • Roughly, partial reform represents a contrast approach to 'shock therapy'. It implies an incremental, piecemeal, and gradual approach in reforming the existing system. Cf. Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993). The Chinese government once considered using the method of blitzkrieg to cancel the dual price system in 1988, but failed to implement it due to a soaring inflation and consumer panic beforehand. For economic arguments for incremental reform, see Peter Murrell, 'Evolution in economics and in the economic reform of the centrally planned economics', in Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, The Emergence of Market Economics in Eastern Europe (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1992), pp. 35-53; Ronald I. McKinnon, The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to Market Economy (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1991); and idem, 'Taxation, money, and credit in a liberalizing socialist economy', in Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, pp. 109-127. See David Lipton and Jeffrey Sachs, 'Creating a market economy in Eastern Europe: the case of Poland', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, (1990), for the rationale and procedures of the rapid transition approach needed for Eastern Europe.
    • (1991) The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to Market Economy
    • McKinnon, R.I.1
  • 26
    • 0000625147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds
    • Roughly, partial reform represents a contrast approach to 'shock therapy'. It implies an incremental, piecemeal, and gradual approach in reforming the existing system. Cf. Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993). The Chinese government once considered using the method of blitzkrieg to cancel the dual price system in 1988, but failed to implement it due to a soaring inflation and consumer panic beforehand. For economic arguments for incremental reform, see Peter Murrell, 'Evolution in economics and in the economic reform of the centrally planned economics', in Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, The Emergence of Market Economics in Eastern Europe (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1992), pp. 35-53; Ronald I. McKinnon, The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to Market Economy (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1991); and idem, 'Taxation, money, and credit in a liberalizing socialist economy', in Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, pp. 109-127. See David Lipton and Jeffrey Sachs, 'Creating a market economy in Eastern Europe: the case of Poland', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, (1990), for the rationale and procedures of the rapid transition approach needed for Eastern Europe.
    • Taxation, Money, and Credit in a Liberalizing Socialist Economy , pp. 109-127
    • McKinnon, R.I.1
  • 27
    • 0001881265 scopus 로고
    • Creating a market economy in Eastern Europe: The case of Poland
    • Roughly, partial reform represents a contrast approach to 'shock therapy'. It implies an incremental, piecemeal, and gradual approach in reforming the existing system. Cf. Susan L. Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993). The Chinese government once considered using the method of blitzkrieg to cancel the dual price system in 1988, but failed to implement it due to a soaring inflation and consumer panic beforehand. For economic arguments for incremental reform, see Peter Murrell, 'Evolution in economics and in the economic reform of the centrally planned economics', in Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, The Emergence of Market Economics in Eastern Europe (Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1992), pp. 35-53; Ronald I. McKinnon, The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to Market Economy (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1991); and idem, 'Taxation, money, and credit in a liberalizing socialist economy', in Christopher Clague and Gordon Rausser, eds, pp. 109-127. See David Lipton and Jeffrey Sachs, 'Creating a market economy in Eastern Europe: the case of Poland', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, (1990), for the rationale and procedures of the rapid transition approach needed for Eastern Europe.
    • (1990) Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , vol.1
    • Lipton, D.1    Sachs, J.2
  • 28
    • 85040895351 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, UK: The Press Syndicate of the University of Cambridge
    • For example, cross-regional variation in decentralization of foreign trade and foreign exchange has made the Special Economic Zones (SEZs) enjoy better terms of trade in exporting goods vis-à-vis other areas. See Yun-Wing Sung, The China-Hong Kong Connection: The Key to China's Open-Door Policy (Cambridge, UK: The Press Syndicate of the University of Cambridge, 1991). Hence, to specialize in manufacturing export-led goods is a comparative advantage for the SEZs.
    • (1991) The China-Hong Kong Connection: The Key to China's Open-Door Policy
    • Sung, Y.-W.1
  • 29
    • 0003788290 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press
    • Cf. Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 277-280; and James M. Buchanan et al., eds, Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society (College Station, TX: Texas A & M University Press, 1980).
    • (1990) Economic Behavior and Institutions , pp. 277-280
    • Eggertsson, T.1
  • 30
    • 0003677921 scopus 로고
    • College Station, TX: Texas A & M University Press
    • Cf. Thrainn Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 277-280; and James M. Buchanan et al., eds, Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society (College Station, TX: Texas A & M University Press, 1980).
    • (1980) Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society
    • Buchanan, J.M.1
  • 31
    • 84978565356 scopus 로고
    • The political economy of rent-seeking in a Chinese factory town
    • For a parallel finding based on fieldwork in China, see Alan Smart, 'The political economy of rent-seeking in a Chinese factory town', Anthropology of Work Review 14, (1993), pp. 15-19.
    • (1993) Anthropology of Work Review , vol.14 , pp. 15-19
    • Smart, A.1
  • 33
    • 0242645648 scopus 로고
    • Local market socialism: Local corporatism in action in rural China
    • Cf. Nan Lin, 'Local market socialism: local corporatism in action in rural China', Theory and Society 24, (1995), pp. 301-354; and Jean C. Oi, 'Fiscal reform and the economic foundations of local state corporatism in China', World Politics 45, (1992), pp. 99-126. Oi links fiscal reform to 'local state corporatism' in which local officials play the leading role in rural industrialization. Although her argument is basically consistent with the research, it does not take account of the regional variation adequately. Oi and Lin have tried to build up a single model of local state corporatism. As argued in the article, differences in regional decentralization, local endowments and international linkage have made it difficult to see the local developments in China as moving on a uniform path. They also downplayed the regional differences in institutional making.
    • (1995) Theory and Society , vol.24 , pp. 301-354
    • Lin, N.1
  • 34
    • 0027100807 scopus 로고
    • Fiscal reform and the economic foundations of local state corporatism in China
    • Cf. Nan Lin, 'Local market socialism: local corporatism in action in rural China', Theory and Society 24, (1995), pp. 301-354; and Jean C. Oi, 'Fiscal reform and the economic foundations of local state corporatism in China', World Politics 45, (1992), pp. 99-126. Oi links fiscal reform to 'local state corporatism' in which local officials play the leading role in rural industrialization. Although her argument is basically consistent with the research, it does not take account of the regional variation adequately. Oi and Lin have tried to build up a single model of local state corporatism. As argued in the article, differences in regional decentralization, local endowments and international linkage have made it difficult to see the local developments in China as moving on a uniform path. They also downplayed the regional differences in institutional making.
    • (1992) World Politics , vol.45 , pp. 99-126
    • Oi, J.C.1
  • 35
    • 21144465983 scopus 로고
    • Gifts, bribes, and Guanxi: A reconsideration of Bourdieu's social capital
    • For the concept of social capital in contrast to economic capital, see Bourdieu (1986). Cf. Alan Smart, 'Gifts, bribes, and Guanxi: a reconsideration of Bourdieu's social capital', Cultural Anthropology 8, (1993), pp. 388-408.
    • (1993) Cultural Anthropology , vol.8 , pp. 388-408
    • Smart, A.1
  • 36
    • 0003461404 scopus 로고
    • New Haven: Yale University Press
    • Cf. Mancur Olson, The Rise and Decline of Nations (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1982), for the problems of the interest group.
    • (1982) The Rise and Decline of Nations
    • Olson, M.1
  • 37
    • 85033318818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The second drive of reform, beginning from 1992, has emphasized on non-preferential policy, more or less. It includes granting the inland area similar conditions like those in the coastal area to solicit foreign capital (1992); unifying the multiple foreign exchange rates (1994); launching a comprehensive tax reform and establishing a nation-wide framework for collecting the central government taxes (1994); a new policy for land appropriation and development (1995); and a more rigorous labor policy (1995).
  • 38
    • 0004309039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, particularly
    • For a comparison of Guangdong's economic structure with other regions, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China, 1978-1990 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992), particularly pp. 126-136. For an account of the disadvantages of interior areas under preferential policies, see Dorothy Solinger, 'Despite decentralization: disadvantages, dependence and ongoing central power in the inland - the case of Wuhan', China Quarterly 145, (1996), pp. 1-34.
    • (1992) Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China, 1978-1990 , pp. 126-136
    • Lardy, N.R.1
  • 39
    • 0030389965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Despite decentralization: Disadvantages, dependence and ongoing central power in the inland - The case of Wuhan
    • For a comparison of Guangdong's economic structure with other regions, cf. Nicholas R. Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China, 1978-1990 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992), particularly pp. 126-136. For an account of the disadvantages of interior areas under preferential policies, see Dorothy Solinger, 'Despite decentralization: disadvantages, dependence and ongoing central power in the inland - the case of Wuhan', China Quarterly 145, (1996), pp. 1-34.
    • (1996) China Quarterly , vol.145 , pp. 1-34
    • Solinger, D.1
  • 40
    • 10144257688 scopus 로고
    • Beijing: Zhonghua Chubanshe
    • It is interesting to find that at the time when Guangdong was welcoming the sunset industries from outside, the rural southern Jiangsu was receiving aged manufacturing equipment from state-owned and collective enterprises in urban Shanghai. See Philip Huang, The Peasant Family and Rural Development in the Yangtzi Delta, 1350-1988 (Chinese translation) (Beijing: Zhonghua Chubanshe, 1992), ch. 12, for a description of the process.
    • (1992) The Peasant Family and Rural Development in the Yangtzi Delta, 1350-1988 (Chinese Translation)
    • Huang, P.1
  • 41
    • 85033287645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although these areas had been opened as early as 1984, they did not attract foreign investment until around the late 1980s. This trend is shown in Table 2.
  • 42
    • 0004116784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the development of indigenous industrialization and its financial results in southern Jiangsu, see Byrd and Lin, China's Rural Industry.
    • China's Rural Industry
    • Byrd1    Lin2
  • 43
    • 85033306223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This observation is based on a fieldwork in 1995 by the author.
  • 44
    • 85033316155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Not surprisingly, competition for foreign investment also happened within the same region, as will be reported later.
  • 45
    • 0010628036 scopus 로고
    • Non-institutional economic integration via cultural affinity
    • July Hong Kong Institute of Asia-Pacific Studies, The Chinese University of Hong Kong
    • For a study of Chinese economic integration with other economies, see Yun-Wing Sung, 'Non-institutional economic integration via cultural affinity', Occasional Paper No. 13, (July 1992) of the Hong Kong Institute of Asia-Pacific Studies, The Chinese University of Hong Kong; and idem, 'Explaining China's export drive: the only success among command economies', Occasional Paper No. 5, (May 1991) of the Hong Kong Institute of Asia-Pacific Studies, The Chinese University of Hong Kong. Remarkably, 'cultural affinity' has influenced the way in which China's open-door policy was carried out. Most of the foreign investments came from Hong Kong and overseas Chinese. Taiwanese capital also played an important role despite that its significance was underestimated due to disguise in registration. Although the Chinese government did not regard these 'overseas Chinese' investments as 'foreign' for political reasons, they were actually treated as foreign capital in policy implementation.
    • (1992) Occasional Paper No. 13
    • Sung, Y.-W.1
  • 46
    • 0010558282 scopus 로고
    • Explaining China's export drive: The only success among command economies
    • May Hong Kong Institute of Asia-Pacific Studies, The Chinese University of Hong Kong
    • For a study of Chinese economic integration with other economies, see Yun-Wing Sung, 'Non-institutional economic integration via cultural affinity', Occasional Paper No. 13, (July 1992) of the Hong Kong Institute of Asia-Pacific Studies, The Chinese University of Hong Kong; and idem, 'Explaining China's export drive: the only success among command economies', Occasional Paper No. 5, (May 1991) of the Hong Kong Institute of Asia-Pacific Studies, The Chinese University of Hong Kong. Remarkably, 'cultural affinity' has influenced the way in which China's open-door policy was carried out. Most of the foreign investments came from Hong Kong and overseas Chinese. Taiwanese capital also played an important role despite that its significance was underestimated due to disguise in registration. Although the Chinese government did not regard these 'overseas Chinese' investments as 'foreign' for political reasons, they were actually treated as foreign capital in policy implementation.
    • (1991) Occasional Paper No. 5
    • Sung, Y.-W.1
  • 47
    • 85033310779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Both 'Tai-Yang' and 'Xizhu' are pseudonyms as are all the companies, personal names, and locations used below.
  • 48
    • 85033324319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • On paper, the company's chairman of the board of directors and vice president are appointed by Xi Light while the Taiwanese side holds the positions of vice chairman and president. For more information about Xi Light, see below.
  • 49
    • 85033292653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See below for more details about the corporation
    • See below for more details about the corporation.
  • 51
    • 0003653812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One time when I traveled on the ferry with Lee from Hong Kong to Xizhu, he carried 3 million yuan in his luggage. We passed the customs checkpoint easily because of his good relations with the officials, yet he said that nobody really can be sure that they will not someday search his bag, although to his knowledge this has rarely happened before. A manager of a shoes company seems more intelligent as he told me that he never directly buys renminbi from black markets in China or Hong Kong for political safety, not to mention other risks. He pays foreign currency to the 'dealers' at Hong Kong, and then get the renminbi in China. Regarding the foreign exchange black market in China, similar stories are reported in Sung, The China-Hong Kong Connection, p. 60. For a more systematic study of the problem, see Wen-Hung Chen, The Problems of Foreign Exchange in China (in Chinese) (Hong Kong: Wide Angle Press, 1989), final chapter in particular.
    • The China-Hong Kong Connection , pp. 60
    • Sung1
  • 52
    • 85033290513 scopus 로고
    • Hong Kong: Wide Angle Press
    • One time when I traveled on the ferry with Lee from Hong Kong to Xizhu, he carried 3 million yuan in his luggage. We passed the customs checkpoint easily because of his good relations with the officials, yet he said that nobody really can be sure that they will not someday search his bag, although to his knowledge this has rarely happened before. A manager of a shoes company seems more intelligent as he told me that he never directly buys renminbi from black markets in China or Hong Kong for political safety, not to mention other risks. He pays foreign currency to the 'dealers' at Hong Kong, and then get the renminbi in China. Regarding the foreign exchange black market in China, similar stories are reported in Sung, The China-Hong Kong Connection, p. 60. For a more systematic study of the problem, see Wen-Hung Chen, The Problems of Foreign Exchange in China (in Chinese) (Hong Kong: Wide Angle Press, 1989), final chapter in particular.
    • (1989) The Problems of Foreign Exchange in China (in Chinese)
    • Chen, W.-H.1
  • 53
    • 85033307381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 14.4 million × 24% × 1/2 = 1.728 million
    • 14.4 million × 24% × 1/2 = 1.728 million.
  • 54
    • 0004309039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ch. 3 and 4
    • For a detailed discussion of Chinese foreign trade system and foreign exchange policy during reforms, see Lardy, Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China, ch. 3 and 4.
    • Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China
    • Lardy1
  • 55
    • 85033306894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Guang Light retains a portion of entitlement and turns over the remaining to the government.
  • 56
    • 0003653812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that the average price of foreign exchange entitlement is always a little lower than that of foreign currency. See Sung, The China-Hong Kong Connection, p. 53.
    • The China-Hong Kong Connection , pp. 53
    • Sung1
  • 57
    • 85033304194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The People's Bank of China in 1994 devaluated the renminbi drastically. The value of renminbi fell from 0.74 yuan per HK dollar in 1993 to 1.11 yuan per HK dollar in 1994
    • The People's Bank of China in 1994 devaluated the renminbi drastically. The value of renminbi fell from 0.74 yuan per HK dollar in 1993 to 1.11 yuan per HK dollar in 1994.
  • 58
    • 85033288390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This fee is called 'shouxu fei' (procedural fees, a kind of administrative surcharge) in the document
    • This fee is called 'shouxu fei' (procedural fees, a kind of administrative surcharge) in the document.
  • 59
    • 85033287852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This amount roughly equals the amount gained from the previous formula of remittance.
  • 60
    • 85033313535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Guanliqu is the lowest level of administration in Guangdong. It is equivalent to xingzhengcun (administrative village) that usually comprises one to several natural villages in other provinces. In Guangdong the size of Guanliqu is often larger than that of Xingzhengcun. Nafu is composed of twelve natural villages, with about 4,800 permanent residents and 2,600 immigrant workers and their dependents as of mid-1994. The district office has seven collective-owned enterprises, all of which have been leased out. There are also 20 foreign enterprises. They all pay rentoushui to the office.
  • 61
    • 85033321662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In legal terms, lands in China cannot be sold. So Tai-Yang leased the land for 50 years
    • In legal terms, lands in China cannot be sold. So Tai-Yang leased the land for 50 years.
  • 62
    • 6044236619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See for example Liu, 'Reform from below'; and Parris, 'Local initiative and national reform', for Wenzhou; David Zweig, "'Developmental communities" on China's coast: the impact of trade, investment, and transnational alliances', Comparative Politics, (April 1995), pp. 253-274, for southern Jiangsu; and Jieh-min Wu, 'A tale of two villages: deconstructing the developmentalist image of Chinese rural industrialization', Paper presented at the Second Annual Meeting of the Taiwanese Political Science Association, Taipei, (23-24 December 1995), for Zhengzhou.
    • Reform from below
    • Liu1
  • 63
    • 0039818034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • for Wenzhou
    • See for example Liu, 'Reform from below'; and Parris, 'Local initiative and national reform', for Wenzhou; David Zweig, "'Developmental communities" on China's coast: the impact of trade, investment, and transnational alliances', Comparative Politics, (April 1995), pp. 253-274, for southern Jiangsu; and Jieh-min Wu, 'A tale of two villages: deconstructing the developmentalist image of Chinese rural industrialization', Paper presented at the Second Annual Meeting of the Taiwanese Political Science Association, Taipei, (23-24 December 1995), for Zhengzhou.
    • Local Initiative and National Reform
    • Parris1
  • 64
    • 84937283950 scopus 로고
    • "Developmental communities" on China's coast: The impact of trade, investment, and transnational alliances
    • April
    • See for example Liu, 'Reform from below'; and Parris, 'Local initiative and national reform', for Wenzhou; David Zweig, "'Developmental communities" on China's coast: the impact of trade, investment, and transnational alliances', Comparative Politics, (April 1995), pp. 253-274, for southern Jiangsu; and Jieh-min Wu, 'A tale of two villages: deconstructing the developmentalist image of Chinese rural industrialization', Paper presented at the Second Annual Meeting of the Taiwanese Political Science Association, Taipei, (23-24 December 1995), for Zhengzhou.
    • (1995) Comparative Politics , pp. 253-274
    • Zweig, D.1
  • 65
    • 85033314884 scopus 로고
    • A tale of two villages: Deconstructing the developmentalist image of Chinese rural industrialization
    • Paper presented Taipei, 23-24 December for Zhengzhou
    • See for example Liu, 'Reform from below'; and Parris, 'Local initiative and national reform', for Wenzhou; David Zweig, "'Developmental communities" on China's coast: the impact of trade, investment, and transnational alliances', Comparative Politics, (April 1995), pp. 253-274, for southern Jiangsu; and Jieh-min Wu, 'A tale of two villages: deconstructing the developmentalist image of Chinese rural industrialization', Paper presented at the Second Annual Meeting of the Taiwanese Political Science Association, Taipei, (23-24 December 1995), for Zhengzhou.
    • (1995) Second Annual Meeting of the Taiwanese Political Science Association
    • Wu, J.-M.1
  • 66
    • 85033321416 scopus 로고
    • Taipei, 25 July
    • A catchphrase for this tactic is known as yongzu zhengce, which means utmost use of state policy. Guangdong, particularly in recent years, has become the target of criticism for locally-centered behavior and abuse of state policy. The Chinese vice premier Zhu Rongji was reported to have harshly criticized Guangdong for tax evasions and illegal tax returns for exported commodities. See China Times (in Chinese, Taipei), (25 July 1995).
    • (1995) China Times in Chinese
  • 67
    • 85033318697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Technically, lailiao jiagong is a kind of original equipment manufacturing (OEM) in the international division of labor. According to the Chinese development strategy, it belongs to a more general concept called sanlai yibu (processing, assembly, and compensation trade). In contrast, foreign direct investment is called sanzi qiye that includes equity and contractual joint venture, wholly-owned investment, and joint exploration.
  • 68
    • 85033291703 scopus 로고
    • Hong Kong: Nan-Yang Commercial Bank
    • Cf. Bo-Wei Liao et al., Chinese Reform and Economic Development In the Pearl River Delta Area (in Chinese) (Hong Kong: Nan-Yang Commercial Bank, 1992), pp. 52-54. Liao found that there is little difference between the two kinds of investment by comparing their average capital inputs. A Chinese study also confirms the argument, see Ming-Jun Shao, An Introduction to the Taxation in Special Economic Zones (in Chinese) (Beijing: Zhongguo Jingji Chubanshe, 1992), ch. 23.
    • (1992) Chinese Reform and Economic Development in the Pearl River Delta Area (in Chinese) , pp. 52-54
    • Liao, B.-W.1
  • 69
    • 85033300724 scopus 로고
    • Beijing: Zhongguo Jingji Chubanshe, ch. 23
    • Cf. Bo-Wei Liao et al., Chinese Reform and Economic Development In the Pearl River Delta Area (in Chinese) (Hong Kong: Nan-Yang Commercial Bank, 1992), pp. 52-54. Liao found that there is little difference between the two kinds of investment by comparing their average capital inputs. A Chinese study also confirms the argument, see Ming-Jun Shao, An Introduction to the Taxation in Special Economic Zones (in Chinese) (Beijing: Zhongguo Jingji Chubanshe, 1992), ch. 23.
    • (1992) An Introduction to the Taxation in Special Economic Zones (in Chinese)
    • Shao, M.-J.1
  • 70
    • 84933489492 scopus 로고
    • China's foreign trade
    • The general trend of labor-intensity in China's export drive is confirmed by Lardy. He identified, by taking into account the processed exports, a strong inverse correlation between export performance and capital intensity in production in the period 1985-1990. See Nicholas Lardy, 'China's foreign trade', China Quarterly 131, (1992), pp. 691-720.
    • (1992) China Quarterly , vol.131 , pp. 691-720
    • Lardy, N.1
  • 71
    • 84866202104 scopus 로고
    • Seriously implement the "2 Articles" (for encouraging foreign investment)
    • CCP Guangdong Provincial Committee Office, ed., internal circulation document
    • The central leadership seemed to have understood the point quite well. In 1986, Gu Mu, then a State Councilor in charge of Special Economic Zones, opposed to raise wages at that time when he came to meet Guangdong officials: 'Low costs of labor is an advantage in attracting foreign investment. Our competitive edge would be gone if labor costs are raised'. See Gu, 'Seriously implement the "2 Articles" (for encouraging foreign investment)', in CCP Guangdong Provincial Committee Office, ed., A Collection of the Center's Work Directives to Guangdong (in Chinese) (internal circulation document, 1988), pp. 228-234.
    • (1988) A Collection of the Center's Work Directives to Guangdong (in Chinese) , pp. 228-234
    • Gu1
  • 72
    • 84919317450 scopus 로고
    • China's urban transients in the transition from socialism and the collapse of the communist "urban public goods regime"
    • Cf. Dorothy Solinger, 'China's urban transients in the transition from socialism and the collapse of the communist "urban public goods regime",' Comparative Politics 27, (1995), pp. 127-146. Local governments often issue temporary residence cards to the floating population. Some kind of the residence card is called 'green card' in Wenzhou where the system of temporary residence first developed. But unlike Wenzhou's prevailing household workshops and individual-based economy, the factory workers in the Pearl River Delta are collectively organized. The enterprises usually apply the temporary residence on behalf of the workers and hold their residence cards. This has been a very important social control in the coastal factories.
    • (1995) Comparative Politics , vol.27 , pp. 127-146
    • Solinger, D.1
  • 73
    • 85033292774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Chinese survey points out that the foreign firms in Shenzhen enjoyed an average 20% rebate of the remittance of processing fees. The monthly remittance should be HK$600 per worker for the factories in Baoan county, and HK$700-800 in the special economic zone according to the official guidelines. See Shao, An Introduction to the Taxation in Special Economic Zones, p. 550.
    • An Introduction to the Taxation in Special Economic Zones , pp. 550
    • Shao1
  • 75
    • 85033285754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The following data of Xizhu have been compiled from internal documents.
  • 76
    • 85040894451 scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development
    • For the problems of the fiscal system, see World Bank's report, China: Revenue Mobilization and Tax Policy (Washington, DC: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1990).
    • (1990) China: Revenue Mobilization and Tax Policy
  • 77
    • 0025162685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why industrialize? The incentives for rural community governments
    • Byrd and Lin
    • According to a study on township finance in Wuxi County, administrative fees in a sample township constitute about 20% of the total government revenues. See William Byrd and Alan Gelb, 'Why industrialize? The incentives for rural community governments', in Byrd and Lin, China's Rural Industry, pp. 358-388. A major difference between the management fees and the head tax lies in that the former is collected against enterprise sales (rate varies across regions and industries; usually set at 0.5-2%) while the latter is counted on the number of workers.
    • China's Rural Industry , pp. 358-388
    • Byrd, W.1    Gelb, A.2
  • 78
    • 84973941991 scopus 로고
    • State involution: A study of local finance in North China, 1911-1935
    • Cf. Prasenjit Duara, 'State involution: a study of local finance in North China, 1911-1935', Comparative Study of History and Society, (1987), pp. 132-161, for a study of local finance in North China.
    • (1987) Comparative Study of History and Society , pp. 132-161
    • Duara, P.1
  • 80
    • 0003585913 scopus 로고
    • Ibid. The figures include formal budgets and extrabudgetary funds. Contrary to general allegation that the center's financial strength has been declining during the reform era, the central government's share of the total revenues has shown an average annual increase of 15.5% in the period from 1983 to 1992, which is higher than the 13.6% of the subnational governments.
    • (1995) China Statistics Yearbook , pp. 222-223
  • 83
    • 44649197264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure
    • For a classical definition of principal-agent (agency) relationship, see Michael C. Jensen and William H. Meckling, 'Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure', Journal of Financial Economics 3, (1976), pp. 305-360. Cf. Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions; and Steven L. Solnick, 'The breakdown of hierarchies in the Soviet Union and China: a neoinstitutional perspective', World Politics 48, (1996), pp. 209-238.
    • (1976) Journal of Financial Economics , vol.3 , pp. 305-360
    • Jensen, M.C.1    Meckling, W.H.2
  • 84
    • 44649197264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a classical definition of principal-agent (agency) relationship, see Michael C. Jensen and William H. Meckling, 'Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure', Journal of Financial Economics 3, (1976), pp. 305-360. Cf. Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions; and Steven L. Solnick, 'The breakdown of hierarchies in the Soviet Union and China: a neoinstitutional perspective', World Politics 48, (1996), pp. 209-238.
    • Economic Behavior and Institutions
    • Eggertsson1
  • 85
    • 0029755944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The breakdown of hierarchies in the Soviet Union and China: A neoinstitutional perspective
    • For a classical definition of principal-agent (agency) relationship, see Michael C. Jensen and William H. Meckling, 'Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure', Journal of Financial Economics 3, (1976), pp. 305-360. Cf. Eggertsson, Economic Behavior and Institutions; and Steven L. Solnick, 'The breakdown of hierarchies in the Soviet Union and China: a neoinstitutional perspective', World Politics 48, (1996), pp. 209-238.
    • (1996) World Politics , vol.48 , pp. 209-238
    • Solnick, S.L.1
  • 86
    • 85033320328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note that value-added tax is a powerful tool for double-checking the truthfulness of enterprise accountings.
  • 87
    • 0003585913 scopus 로고
    • The above figures are computed from data in China Statistics Yearbook, (1995), pp. 222-223.
    • (1995) China Statistics Yearbook , pp. 222-223
  • 88


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.