메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 98, Issue 8, 1998, Pages 2574-2614

Private ordering at the world's first futures exchange

(1)  West, Mark D a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0345916211     PISSN: 00262234     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.2307/1290356     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (27)

References (216)
  • 1
    • 0347469796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Origin of the New York Stock Exchange, 1791-1860
    • See. e.g., Stuart Banner, The Origin of the New York Stock Exchange, 1791-1860, 27 J. LEGAL STUD. 113 (1998); Lisa Bernstein, Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 115 (1992); Robert C. Ellickson, A Hypothesis of Wealth-Maximizing Norms: Evidence from the Whaling Industry, 5 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 83 (1989); Stephen Craig Pirrong, The Efficient Scope of Private Transactions-Cost-Reducing Institutions: The Successes and Failures of Commodities Exchanges, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 229 (1995); Mark D. West, Legal Rules and Social Norms in Japan's Secret World of Sumo, 26 J. LEGAL STUD. 165 (1997).
    • (1998) J. Legal Stud. , vol.27 , pp. 113
    • Banner, S.1
  • 2
    • 0347469796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Opting out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry
    • See. e.g., Stuart Banner, The Origin of the New York Stock Exchange, 1791-1860, 27 J. LEGAL STUD. 113 (1998); Lisa Bernstein, Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 115 (1992); Robert C. Ellickson, A Hypothesis of Wealth-Maximizing Norms: Evidence from the Whaling Industry, 5 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 83 (1989); Stephen Craig Pirrong, The Efficient Scope of Private Transactions-Cost-Reducing Institutions: The Successes and Failures of Commodities Exchanges, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 229 (1995); Mark D. West, Legal Rules and Social Norms in Japan's Secret World of Sumo, 26 J. LEGAL STUD. 165 (1997).
    • (1992) J. Legal Stud. , vol.21 , pp. 115
    • Bernstein, L.1
  • 3
    • 0001768405 scopus 로고
    • A Hypothesis of Wealth-Maximizing Norms: Evidence from the Whaling Industry
    • See. e.g., Stuart Banner, The Origin of the New York Stock Exchange, 1791-1860, 27 J. LEGAL STUD. 113 (1998); Lisa Bernstein, Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 115 (1992); Robert C. Ellickson, A Hypothesis of Wealth-Maximizing Norms: Evidence from the Whaling Industry, 5 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 83 (1989); Stephen Craig Pirrong, The Efficient Scope of Private Transactions-Cost-Reducing Institutions: The Successes and Failures of Commodities Exchanges, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 229 (1995); Mark D. West, Legal Rules and Social Norms in Japan's Secret World of Sumo, 26 J. LEGAL STUD. 165 (1997).
    • (1989) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.5 , pp. 83
    • Ellickson, R.C.1
  • 4
    • 0347469796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Efficient Scope of Private Transactions-Cost-Reducing Institutions: The Successes and Failures of Commodities Exchanges
    • See. e.g., Stuart Banner, The Origin of the New York Stock Exchange, 1791-1860, 27 J. LEGAL STUD. 113 (1998); Lisa Bernstein, Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 115 (1992); Robert C. Ellickson, A Hypothesis of Wealth-Maximizing Norms: Evidence from the Whaling Industry, 5 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 83 (1989); Stephen Craig Pirrong, The Efficient Scope of Private Transactions-Cost-Reducing Institutions: The Successes and Failures of Commodities Exchanges, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 229 (1995); Mark D. West, Legal Rules and Social Norms in Japan's Secret World of Sumo, 26 J. LEGAL STUD. 165 (1997).
    • (1995) J. Legal Stud. , vol.24 , pp. 229
    • Pirrong, S.C.1
  • 5
    • 0346880177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal Rules and Social Norms in Japan's Secret World of Sumo
    • See. e.g., Stuart Banner, The Origin of the New York Stock Exchange, 1791-1860, 27 J. LEGAL STUD. 113 (1998); Lisa Bernstein, Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 115 (1992); Robert C. Ellickson, A Hypothesis of Wealth-Maximizing Norms: Evidence from the Whaling Industry, 5 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 83 (1989); Stephen Craig Pirrong, The Efficient Scope of Private Transactions-Cost-Reducing Institutions: The Successes and Failures of Commodities Exchanges, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 229 (1995); Mark D. West, Legal Rules and Social Norms in Japan's Secret World of Sumo, 26 J. LEGAL STUD. 165 (1997).
    • (1997) J. Legal Stud. , vol.26 , pp. 165
    • West, M.D.1
  • 6
    • 0347512704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why the Law Hates Speculators: Regulation and Private Ordering in the Market for OTC Derivatives
    • Lynn A. Stout, Why the Law Hates Speculators: Regulation and Private Ordering in the Market for OTC Derivatives, 48 DUKE L.J. 701, 777-83 (1999).
    • (1999) Duke L.J. , vol.48 , pp. 701
    • Stout, L.A.1
  • 7
    • 0348162836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Greenspan Wants Derivatives Freed Up
    • Feb. 11
    • See Gerard Baker, Greenspan Wants Derivatives Freed Up, FIN. TIMES, Feb. 11, 2000, at 11.
    • (2000) Fin. Times , pp. 11
    • Baker, G.1
  • 8
    • 0013204251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Exchange as Regulator
    • (proposing self-regulation)
    • See, e.g., Paul G. Mahoney, The Exchange as Regulator, 83 VA. L. REV. 1453 (1997) (proposing self-regulation); A.C. Pritchard, Markets as Monitors: A Proposal to Replace Class Actions with Exchanges as Securities Fraud Enforcers, 85 VA. L. REV. 925 (1999) (same); see also Tokushū, Rekishi ni Manabu "Shijō" tai "Kokka" [Special Issue: Lessons from History on the Market Versus the State], PRESIDENT 251 (Nov. 1999) (series of articles focusing on Dojima in Japanese business magazine).
    • (1997) Va. L. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 1453
    • Mahoney, P.G.1
  • 9
    • 0346207527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Markets as Monitors: A Proposal to Replace Class Actions with Exchanges as Securities Fraud Enforcers
    • same
    • See, e.g., Paul G. Mahoney, The Exchange as Regulator, 83 VA. L. REV. 1453 (1997) (proposing self-regulation); A.C. Pritchard, Markets as Monitors: A Proposal to Replace Class Actions with Exchanges as Securities Fraud Enforcers, 85 VA. L. REV. 925 (1999) (same); see also Tokushū, Rekishi ni Manabu "Shijō" tai "Kokka" [Special Issue: Lessons from History on the Market Versus the State], PRESIDENT 251 (Nov. 1999) (series of articles focusing on Dojima in Japanese business magazine).
    • (1999) Va. L. Rev. , vol.85 , pp. 925
    • Pritchard, A.C.1
  • 10
    • 0013204251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rekishi ni Manabu "Shijō" tai "Kokka" [Special Issue: Lessons from History on the Market Versus the State]
    • Nov. (series of articles focusing on Dojima in Japanese business magazine)
    • See, e.g., Paul G. Mahoney, The Exchange as Regulator, 83 VA. L. REV. 1453 (1997) (proposing self-regulation); A.C. Pritchard, Markets as Monitors: A Proposal to Replace Class Actions with Exchanges as Securities Fraud Enforcers, 85 VA. L. REV. 925 (1999) (same); see also Tokushū, Rekishi ni Manabu "Shijō" tai "Kokka" [Special Issue: Lessons from History on the Market Versus the State], PRESIDENT 251 (Nov. 1999) (series of articles focusing on Dojima in Japanese business magazine).
    • (1999) President , pp. 251
    • Tokushu1
  • 11
    • 0002692296 scopus 로고
    • Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules
    • See, e.g., Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 99 YALE L.J. 87 (1989); David Charny, Nonlegal Sanctions in Commercial Relationships, 104 HARV. L. REV. 375, 429-44 (1990).
    • (1989) Yale L.J. , vol.99 , pp. 87
    • Ayres, I.1    Gertner, R.2
  • 12
    • 0039548966 scopus 로고
    • Nonlegal Sanctions in Commercial Relationships
    • See, e.g., Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 99 YALE L.J. 87 (1989); David Charny, Nonlegal Sanctions in Commercial Relationships, 104 HARV. L. REV. 375, 429-44 (1990).
    • (1990) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.104 , pp. 375
    • Charny, D.1
  • 13
    • 0346902399 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., NORITAKA DOHI, KOME TO EDO JIDAI [RICE AND THE TOKUGAWA ERA] (1980); MATAO MIYAMOTO, KINSEI NIHON NO SHIJŌ KEIZAI [EARLY MODERN JAPANESE MARKET ECONOMICS] (1988); TOKUICHI SHIMAMOTO, TOKUGAWA JIDAI NO SHŌKEN SHIJŌ NO KENKYŪ [RESEARCH ON TOKUGAWA ERA SECURITIES MARKETS] (1953); MASAHIKO SUGIE, TŌKI TO SAKIMONO TORIHIKI NO RIRON: WAGA KUNI SAKIMONO TORIHIKI SEIDO NO SEIRITSU NI KANSURU KENKYŪ [THEORY OF SPECULATION AND FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS: RESEARCH ON THE ESTABLISHMENT OF FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS IN JAPAN] (1984); Takatoshi Ito, 18 Seiki, Dojima no Kome Sakimono Shijō no Kōritsusei ni Tsuite [Regarding the Efficiency of the 18th Century Dojima Futures Market], 44 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 339 (1993); Shigeru Wakita, Kinsei Osaka Dojima Kome Sakimono Shijō ni Okeru Gōriteki Kitai no Seiritsu [The Establishment of Rational Expectations in the Early Modern Dojima Rice Futures Market in Osaka], 47 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 238 (1996).
    • (1980) Kome to Edo Jidai [Rice and the Tokugawa Era]
    • Dohi, N.1
  • 14
    • 84969657200 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., NORITAKA DOHI, KOME TO EDO JIDAI [RICE AND THE TOKUGAWA ERA] (1980); MATAO MIYAMOTO, KINSEI NIHON NO SHIJŌ KEIZAI [EARLY MODERN JAPANESE MARKET ECONOMICS] (1988); TOKUICHI SHIMAMOTO, TOKUGAWA JIDAI NO SHŌKEN SHIJŌ NO KENKYŪ [RESEARCH ON TOKUGAWA ERA SECURITIES MARKETS] (1953); MASAHIKO SUGIE, TŌKI TO SAKIMONO TORIHIKI NO RIRON: WAGA KUNI SAKIMONO TORIHIKI SEIDO NO SEIRITSU NI KANSURU KENKYŪ [THEORY OF SPECULATION AND FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS: RESEARCH ON THE ESTABLISHMENT OF FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS IN JAPAN] (1984); Takatoshi Ito, 18 Seiki, Dojima no Kome Sakimono Shijō no Kōritsusei ni Tsuite [Regarding the Efficiency of the 18th Century Dojima Futures Market], 44 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 339 (1993); Shigeru Wakita, Kinsei Osaka Dojima Kome Sakimono Shijō ni Okeru Gōriteki Kitai no Seiritsu [The Establishment of Rational Expectations in the Early Modern Dojima Rice Futures Market in Osaka], 47 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 238 (1996).
    • (1988) Kinsei Nihon no Shijō Keizai [Early Modern Japanese Market Economics]
    • Miyamoto, M.1
  • 15
    • 0347533196 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., NORITAKA DOHI, KOME TO EDO JIDAI [RICE AND THE TOKUGAWA ERA] (1980); MATAO MIYAMOTO, KINSEI NIHON NO SHIJŌ KEIZAI [EARLY MODERN JAPANESE MARKET ECONOMICS] (1988); TOKUICHI SHIMAMOTO, TOKUGAWA JIDAI NO SHŌKEN SHIJŌ NO KENKYŪ [RESEARCH ON TOKUGAWA ERA SECURITIES MARKETS] (1953); MASAHIKO SUGIE, TŌKI TO SAKIMONO TORIHIKI NO RIRON: WAGA KUNI SAKIMONO TORIHIKI SEIDO NO SEIRITSU NI KANSURU KENKYŪ [THEORY OF SPECULATION AND FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS: RESEARCH ON THE ESTABLISHMENT OF FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS IN JAPAN] (1984); Takatoshi Ito, 18 Seiki, Dojima no Kome Sakimono Shijō no Kōritsusei ni Tsuite [Regarding the Efficiency of the 18th Century Dojima Futures Market], 44 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 339 (1993); Shigeru Wakita, Kinsei Osaka Dojima Kome Sakimono Shijō ni Okeru Gōriteki Kitai no Seiritsu [The Establishment of Rational Expectations in the Early Modern Dojima Rice Futures Market in Osaka], 47 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 238 (1996).
    • (1953) Tokugawa Jidai no Shōken Shijō no Kenkyū [Research on Tokugawa Era Securities Markets]
    • Shimamoto, T.1
  • 16
    • 0347533197 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., NORITAKA DOHI, KOME TO EDO JIDAI [RICE AND THE TOKUGAWA ERA] (1980); MATAO MIYAMOTO, KINSEI NIHON NO SHIJŌ KEIZAI [EARLY MODERN JAPANESE MARKET ECONOMICS] (1988); TOKUICHI SHIMAMOTO, TOKUGAWA JIDAI NO SHŌKEN SHIJŌ NO KENKYŪ [RESEARCH ON TOKUGAWA ERA SECURITIES MARKETS] (1953); MASAHIKO SUGIE, TŌKI TO SAKIMONO TORIHIKI NO RIRON: WAGA KUNI SAKIMONO TORIHIKI SEIDO NO SEIRITSU NI KANSURU KENKYŪ [THEORY OF SPECULATION AND FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS: RESEARCH ON THE ESTABLISHMENT OF FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS IN JAPAN] (1984); Takatoshi Ito, 18 Seiki, Dojima no Kome Sakimono Shijō no Kōritsusei ni Tsuite [Regarding the Efficiency of the 18th Century Dojima Futures Market], 44 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 339 (1993); Shigeru Wakita, Kinsei Osaka Dojima Kome Sakimono Shijō ni Okeru Gōriteki Kitai no Seiritsu [The Establishment of Rational Expectations in the Early Modern Dojima Rice Futures Market in Osaka], 47 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 238 (1996).
    • (1984) Tōki to Sakimono Torihiki no Riron: Waga Kuni Sakimono Torihiki Seido no Seiritsu ni Kansuru Kenkyū [Theory of Speculation and Forwards Transactions: Research on the Establishment of Forwards Transactions in Japan]
    • Sugie, M.1
  • 17
    • 0041498262 scopus 로고
    • 18 Seiki, Dojima no Kome Sakimono Shijō no Kōritsusei ni Tsuite
    • See, e.g., NORITAKA DOHI, KOME TO EDO JIDAI [RICE AND THE TOKUGAWA ERA] (1980); MATAO MIYAMOTO, KINSEI NIHON NO SHIJŌ KEIZAI [EARLY MODERN JAPANESE MARKET ECONOMICS] (1988); TOKUICHI SHIMAMOTO, TOKUGAWA JIDAI NO SHŌKEN SHIJŌ NO KENKYŪ [RESEARCH ON TOKUGAWA ERA SECURITIES MARKETS] (1953); MASAHIKO SUGIE, TŌKI TO SAKIMONO TORIHIKI NO RIRON: WAGA KUNI SAKIMONO TORIHIKI SEIDO NO SEIRITSU NI KANSURU KENKYŪ [THEORY OF SPECULATION AND FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS: RESEARCH ON THE ESTABLISHMENT OF FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS IN JAPAN] (1984); Takatoshi Ito, 18 Seiki, Dojima no Kome Sakimono Shijō no Kōritsusei ni Tsuite [Regarding the Efficiency of the 18th Century Dojima Futures Market], 44 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 339 (1993); Shigeru Wakita, Kinsei Osaka Dojima Kome Sakimono Shijō ni Okeru Gōriteki Kitai no Seiritsu [The Establishment of Rational Expectations in the Early Modern Dojima Rice Futures Market in Osaka], 47 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 238 (1996).
    • (1993) Keizai Kenkyū , vol.44 , pp. 339
    • Ito, T.1
  • 18
    • 0041498263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kinsei Osaka Dojima Kome Sakimono Shijō ni Okeru Gōriteki Kitai no Seiritsu
    • See, e.g., NORITAKA DOHI, KOME TO EDO JIDAI [RICE AND THE TOKUGAWA ERA] (1980); MATAO MIYAMOTO, KINSEI NIHON NO SHIJŌ KEIZAI [EARLY MODERN JAPANESE MARKET ECONOMICS] (1988); TOKUICHI SHIMAMOTO, TOKUGAWA JIDAI NO SHŌKEN SHIJŌ NO KENKYŪ [RESEARCH ON TOKUGAWA ERA SECURITIES MARKETS] (1953); MASAHIKO SUGIE, TŌKI TO SAKIMONO TORIHIKI NO RIRON: WAGA KUNI SAKIMONO TORIHIKI SEIDO NO SEIRITSU NI KANSURU KENKYŪ [THEORY OF SPECULATION AND FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS: RESEARCH ON THE ESTABLISHMENT OF FORWARDS TRANSACTIONS IN JAPAN] (1984); Takatoshi Ito, 18 Seiki, Dojima no Kome Sakimono Shijō no Kōritsusei ni Tsuite [Regarding the Efficiency of the 18th Century Dojima Futures Market], 44 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 339 (1993); Shigeru Wakita, Kinsei Osaka Dojima Kome Sakimono Shijō ni Okeru Gōriteki Kitai no Seiritsu [The Establishment of Rational Expectations in the Early Modern Dojima Rice Futures Market in Osaka], 47 KEIZAI KENKYŪ 238 (1996).
    • (1996) Keizai Kenkyū , vol.47 , pp. 238
    • Wakita, S.1
  • 19
    • 38249007228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Forwards and Futures in Tokugawa-Period Japan: A New Perspective on the Dōjima Rice Market
    • A search of U.S. scholarship reveals only one article: Ulrike Schaede, Forwards and Futures in Tokugawa-Period Japan: A New Perspective on the Dōjima Rice Market, 13 J. BANK. & FIN. 487 (1989) [hereinafter Schaede, Forwards and Futures]. A slightly different version appears as Ulrike Schaede, The Development of Organized Futures Trading: The Osaka Rice Bill Market of 1730, in JAPANESE FINANCIAL MARKET RESEARCH 339 (W.T. Ziemba et al. eds., 1991). Each is largely a finance-centered description of trading mechanics. In this Article, in addition to adopting a different methodology, I rely on data and sources not examined by Schaede and sources not available at the time of that article's publication.
    • (1989) J. Bank. & Fin. , vol.13 , pp. 487
    • Schaede, U.1
  • 20
    • 38249007228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A search of U.S. scholarship reveals only one article: Ulrike Schaede, Forwards and Futures in Tokugawa-Period Japan: A New Perspective on the Dōjima Rice Market, 13 J. BANK. & FIN. 487 (1989) [hereinafter Schaede, Forwards and Futures]. A slightly different version appears as Ulrike Schaede, The Development of Organized Futures Trading: The Osaka Rice Bill Market of 1730, in JAPANESE FINANCIAL MARKET RESEARCH 339 (W.T. Ziemba et al. eds., 1991). Each is largely a finance-centered description of trading mechanics. In this Article, in addition to adopting a different methodology, I rely on data and sources not examined by Schaede and sources not available at the time of that article's publication.
    • Forwards and Futures.
    • Schaede1
  • 21
    • 38249007228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Development of Organized Futures Trading: The Osaka Rice Bill Market of 1730
    • W.T. Ziemba et al. eds., Each is largely a finance-centered description of trading mechanics. In this Article, in addition to adopting a different methodology, I rely on data and sources not examined by Schaede and sources not available at the time of that article's publication
    • A search of U.S. scholarship reveals only one article: Ulrike Schaede, Forwards and Futures in Tokugawa-Period Japan: A New Perspective on the Dōjima Rice Market, 13 J. BANK. & FIN. 487 (1989) [hereinafter Schaede, Forwards and Futures]. A slightly different version appears as Ulrike Schaede, The Development of Organized Futures Trading: The Osaka Rice Bill Market of 1730, in JAPANESE FINANCIAL MARKET RESEARCH 339 (W.T. Ziemba et al. eds., 1991). Each is largely a finance-centered description of trading mechanics. In this Article, in addition to adopting a different methodology, I rely on data and sources not examined by Schaede and sources not available at the time of that article's publication.
    • (1991) Japanese Financial Market Research , pp. 339
    • Schaede, U.1
  • 22
    • 0003678077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PETER L. BERNSTEIN, AGAINST THE GODS: THE REMARKABLE STORY OF RISK 306 (1996); BARBARA B. DIAMOND & MARK P. KOLLAR, 24-HOUR TRADING: THE GLOBAL NETWORK OF FUTURES AND OPTIONS MARKETS 6-9 (1989); JERRY W. MARKHAM, THE HISTORY OF COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING AND ITS REGULATION 3 (1987); RICHARD J. TEWELES & FRANK J. JONES, THE FUTURES GAME: WHO WINS? WHO LOSES? WHY? 8-9 (2d ed. 1987); Roberta Romano, A Thumbnail Sketch of Derivative Securities and Their Regulation, 55 MD. L. REV. 1, 10 (1996).
    • (1996) Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk , pp. 306
    • Bernstein, P.L.1
  • 23
    • 0343463494 scopus 로고
    • PETER L. BERNSTEIN, AGAINST THE GODS: THE REMARKABLE STORY OF RISK 306 (1996); BARBARA B. DIAMOND & MARK P. KOLLAR, 24-HOUR TRADING: THE GLOBAL NETWORK OF FUTURES AND OPTIONS MARKETS 6-9 (1989); JERRY W. MARKHAM, THE HISTORY OF COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING AND ITS REGULATION 3 (1987); RICHARD J. TEWELES & FRANK J. JONES, THE FUTURES GAME: WHO WINS? WHO LOSES? WHY? 8-9 (2d ed. 1987); Roberta Romano, A Thumbnail Sketch of Derivative Securities and Their Regulation, 55 MD. L. REV. 1, 10 (1996).
    • (1989) 24-Hour Trading: The Global Network of Futures and Options Markets , pp. 6-9
    • Diamond, B.B.1    Kollar, M.P.2
  • 24
    • 0008947024 scopus 로고
    • PETER L. BERNSTEIN, AGAINST THE GODS: THE REMARKABLE STORY OF RISK 306 (1996); BARBARA B. DIAMOND & MARK P. KOLLAR, 24-HOUR TRADING: THE GLOBAL NETWORK OF FUTURES AND OPTIONS MARKETS 6-9 (1989); JERRY W. MARKHAM, THE HISTORY OF COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING AND ITS REGULATION 3 (1987); RICHARD J. TEWELES & FRANK J. JONES, THE FUTURES GAME: WHO WINS? WHO LOSES? WHY? 8-9 (2d ed. 1987); Roberta Romano, A Thumbnail Sketch of Derivative Securities and Their Regulation, 55 MD. L. REV. 1, 10 (1996).
    • (1987) The History of Commodity Futures Trading and its Regulation , pp. 3
    • Markham, J.W.1
  • 25
    • 0005106920 scopus 로고
    • 2d ed.
    • PETER L. BERNSTEIN, AGAINST THE GODS: THE REMARKABLE STORY OF RISK 306 (1996); BARBARA B. DIAMOND & MARK P. KOLLAR, 24-HOUR TRADING: THE GLOBAL NETWORK OF FUTURES AND OPTIONS MARKETS 6-9 (1989); JERRY W. MARKHAM, THE HISTORY OF COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING AND ITS REGULATION 3 (1987); RICHARD J. TEWELES & FRANK J. JONES, THE FUTURES GAME: WHO WINS? WHO LOSES? WHY? 8-9 (2d ed. 1987); Roberta Romano, A Thumbnail Sketch of Derivative Securities and Their Regulation, 55 MD. L. REV. 1, 10 (1996).
    • (1987) The Futures Game: Who Wins? Who Loses? Why? , pp. 8-9
    • Teweles, R.J.1    Jones, F.J.2
  • 26
    • 0348162835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Thumbnail Sketch of Derivative Securities and Their Regulation
    • PETER L. BERNSTEIN, AGAINST THE GODS: THE REMARKABLE STORY OF RISK 306 (1996); BARBARA B. DIAMOND & MARK P. KOLLAR, 24-HOUR TRADING: THE GLOBAL NETWORK OF FUTURES AND OPTIONS MARKETS 6-9 (1989); JERRY W. MARKHAM, THE HISTORY OF COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING AND ITS REGULATION 3 (1987); RICHARD J. TEWELES & FRANK J. JONES, THE FUTURES GAME: WHO WINS? WHO LOSES? WHY? 8-9 (2d ed. 1987); Roberta Romano, A Thumbnail Sketch of Derivative Securities and Their Regulation, 55 MD. L. REV. 1, 10 (1996).
    • (1996) Md. L. Rev. , vol.55 , pp. 1
    • Romano, R.1
  • 27
    • 0039869768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See e.g., WALTER LEFEBER, THE CLASH: A HISTORY OF U.S.-JAPANESE RELATIONS 8 (1997); PATRICK SMITH, JAPANESE: A REINTERPRETATION 53 (1997); TETSURŌ WATSUJI, SAKOKU: NIHON NO HIGEKI [NATIONAL ISOLATION: THE TRAGEDY OF JAPAN] (1953).
    • (1997) The Clash: A History of U.S.-Japanese Relations , pp. 8
    • Lefeber, W.1
  • 28
    • 0347533195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See e.g., WALTER LEFEBER, THE CLASH: A HISTORY OF U.S.-JAPANESE RELATIONS 8 (1997); PATRICK SMITH, JAPANESE: A REINTERPRETATION 53 (1997); TETSURŌ WATSUJI, SAKOKU: NIHON NO HIGEKI [NATIONAL ISOLATION: THE TRAGEDY OF JAPAN] (1953).
    • (1997) Japanese: A Reinterpretation , pp. 53
    • Smith, P.1
  • 31
    • 0039044621 scopus 로고
    • Foreign Relations during the Edo Period: Sakoku Reexamined
    • Susan Downing Videen trans.
    • Kazui Tashiro, Foreign Relations During the Edo Period: Sakoku Reexamined, 8 J. JAPANESE STUD. 283 (Susan Downing Videen trans., 1982);
    • (1982) J. Japanese Stud. , vol.8 , pp. 283
    • Tashiro, K.1
  • 34
    • 0346902375 scopus 로고
    • Edo ni Okeru Shokō no Keihi Seikatsu ni Tsuite
    • See, e.g., YASUNARI MARUYAMA, NIHON KINSEI KŌTSŪSHI NO KENKYŪ [STUDY OF TRANSPORTATION HISTORY IN EARLY MODERN JAPAN] 585-600 (1989); Kenji Date, Edo ni Okeru Shokō no Keihi Seikatsu ni Tsuite [The Consumptive Life of Edo Period Feudal Lords], 4 REKISHIGAKU KENKYŪ 75 (1935).
    • (1935) Rekishigaku Kenkyū , vol.4 , pp. 75
    • Date, K.1
  • 36
    • 84909408088 scopus 로고
    • The Development of a Credit System in Seventeenth-Century Japan
    • See YŌTARŌ SAKUDŌ, NIHON KAHEI KIN'YŪSHI NO KENKYŪ: HŌREN SHAKAI NO SHIN'YŌ TSUKA NI KANSURU KISOTEKI KENKYŪ [A STUDY OF THE HISTORY OF JAPANESE CURRENCY IN FEUDAL SOCIETY] 33-58 (1961); Sydney Crawcour, The Development of a Credit System in Seventeenth-Century Japan, 21 J. ECON. HIST. 342 (1961).
    • (1961) J. Econ. Hist. , vol.21 , pp. 342
    • Crawcour, S.1
  • 39
    • 0348162832 scopus 로고
    • Tokugawa Jidai no Kahei Sūryō
    • Mataji Umemura et al. eds., Bills of exchange are said to have begun in Europe in the late twelfth century.
    • Masaru Iwahashi, Tokugawa Jidai no Kahei Sūryō [Currency Distribution in the Tokugawa Era] in NIHON KEIZAI NO HATTEN [THE DEVELOPMENT OF JAPANESE ECONOMICS] (Mataji Umemura et al. eds., 1976). Bills of exchange are said to have begun in Europe in the late twelfth century.
    • (1976) Nihon Keizai no Hatten [The Development of Japanese Economics]
    • Iwahashi, M.1
  • 41
    • 0346272066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Measures Taken
    • Carl R. Mueller et al. trans.
    • For an eloquent description of rice as pure commodity, see BERTOLT BRECHT, The Measures Taken, in THE MEASURES TAKEN, AND OTHER LEHRSTŪCKE 23-24 (Carl R. Mueller et al. trans., 1997) ("What is rice anyway?/Do I know what rice is?/How should I know who should know?/I don't know what rice is./All I know is its price.").
    • (1997) The Measures Taken, and other Lehrstūcke , pp. 23-24
    • Brecht, B.1
  • 47
    • 0346272065 scopus 로고
    • Yutaka Tezuka & Mitsuo Rikō eds.
    • See, e.g., MINJI KANREI RUISHŪ [COLLECTION OF CIVIL LAWS] (Yutaka Tezuka & Mitsuo Rikō eds., 1969); HARUO ŌKUBO, EDO NO KEIHŌ OSADAMEGAKI HYAKKAJŌ [CRIMINAL PROVISIONS OF TOKUGAWA ERA OSADAMEGAKI] (1978); CARL STEENSTRUP, A HISTORY OF LAW IN JAPAN UNTIL 1868, at 121 (1991).
    • (1969) Collection of Civil Laws
    • Ruishu, M.K.1
  • 48
    • 0346272067 scopus 로고
    • Edo no Keihō Osadamegaki Hyakkajō
    • See, e.g., MINJI KANREI RUISHŪ [COLLECTION OF CIVIL LAWS] (Yutaka Tezuka & Mitsuo Rikō eds., 1969); HARUO ŌKUBO, EDO NO KEIHŌ OSADAMEGAKI HYAKKAJŌ [CRIMINAL PROVISIONS OF TOKUGAWA ERA OSADAMEGAKI] (1978); CARL STEENSTRUP, A HISTORY OF LAW IN JAPAN UNTIL 1868, at 121 (1991).
    • (1978) Criminal Provisions of Tokugawa Era Osadamegaki
    • Okubo, H.1
  • 49
    • 0347533147 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., MINJI KANREI RUISHŪ [COLLECTION OF CIVIL LAWS] (Yutaka Tezuka & Mitsuo Rikō eds., 1969); HARUO ŌKUBO, EDO NO KEIHŌ OSADAMEGAKI HYAKKAJŌ [CRIMINAL PROVISIONS OF TOKUGAWA ERA OSADAMEGAKI] (1978); CARL STEENSTRUP, A HISTORY OF LAW IN JAPAN UNTIL 1868, at 121 (1991).
    • (1991) A History of Law in Japan Until , pp. 1868
    • Steenstrup, C.1
  • 53
    • 0347533143 scopus 로고
    • Some Aspects of Tokugawa Law
    • See Dan F. Henderson, Some Aspects of Tokugawa Law, 27 WASH. L. REV. 85, 92 (1952).
    • (1952) Wash. L. Rev. , vol.27 , pp. 85
    • Henderson, D.F.1
  • 54
    • 0347533149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., HENDERSON, supra note 23, at 101, 132-62 (noting that "criminal-civil distinction was not clearly observed and Tokugawa practice" and including transcript of civil suit in which local official routinely threatens death penalty).
  • 55
    • 0347533159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 32-33; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 8-9
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 32-33; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 8-9.
  • 56
    • 0346272060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • By the end of the Tokugawa period, 99% of payments between merchants were settled by bills. See SAKUDŌ, supra note 12, at7 249.
  • 57
    • 0348162826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 14-15
    • See, e.g., SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 14-15.
  • 58
    • 0346902369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SAKUDŌ, supra note 12, at 345
    • See SAKUDŌ, supra note 12, at 345.
  • 59
    • 0347533162 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although many sources cite Yodoya as the birthplace of futures trading, it is possible that Yodoya was one of several trading sites. See SUGIE, supra note 6, at 12.
  • 60
    • 0346902368 scopus 로고
    • Japan's Eternal Storehouse (1688)
    • YAMATANE GROUP KINEN SHUPPANKAI, NIHON SHIJŌSHI
    • IHARA SAIKAKU, NIPPON EITAIGURA [JAPAN'S ETERNAL STOREHOUSE] (1688), quoted in YAMATANE GROUP KINEN SHUPPANKAI, NIHON SHIJŌSHI [HISTORY OF JAPANESE MARKETS] 62 (1989).
    • (1989) History of Japanese Markets , pp. 62
    • Saikaku, I.1    Eitaigura, N.2
  • 61
    • 0348162829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 196
    • See, e.g., MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 196.
  • 62
    • 84958468289 scopus 로고
    • Changes in Japanese Commerce in the Tokugawa Period
    • Yodoya's wealth was astounding; if the commonly cited inventory of his wealth is accurate, he was a thousand times richer than other merchants, was owed 100 million ryō (several times the national income of Japan), and the amount confiscated by the government was equal to two hundred years of shogunate income. See, e.g., E.S. Crawcour, Changes in Japanese Commerce in the Tokugawa Period, 22 J. ASIAN STUD. 387, 392 (1962).
    • (1962) J. Asian Stud. , vol.22 , pp. 387
    • Crawcour, E.S.1
  • 63
    • 0346272064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SUGIE, supra note 6, at 177
    • See SUGIE, supra note 6, at 177; James L. McClain, Space, Power, Wealth and Status in Seventeenth-Century Osaka, in OSAKA: THE MERCHANT'S CAPITAL OF EARLY MODERN JAPAN (James L. McClain & Osamu Wakita eds., 1999) at 44, 58.
  • 64
    • 0013417228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Space, Power, Wealth and Status in Seventeenth-Century Osaka
    • James L. McClain & Osamu Wakita eds.
    • See SUGIE, supra note 6, at 177; James L. McClain, Space, Power, Wealth and Status in Seventeenth-Century Osaka, in OSAKA: THE MERCHANT'S CAPITAL OF EARLY MODERN JAPAN (James L. McClain & Osamu Wakita eds., 1999) at 44, 58.
    • (1999) Osaka: The Merchant's Capital of Early Modern Japan , pp. 44
    • McClain, J.L.1
  • 65
    • 0347533160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 176-79; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 17
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 176-79; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 17.
  • 66
    • 0346272058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 176-79; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 17
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 176-79; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 17.
  • 67
    • 0346272061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 196-97; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 17
    • See MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 196-97; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 17.
  • 68
    • 0346902370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., GEORGE SANSOM, A HISTORY OF JAPAN 1615-1867, at 164 (1963)
    • See, e.g., GEORGE SANSOM, A HISTORY OF JAPAN 1615-1867, at 164 (1963).
  • 69
    • 0346902374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ROBERTS, supra note 18, at 16
    • See ROBERTS, supra note 18, at 16.
  • 70
    • 0346272062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 89; MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 196
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 89; MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 196.
  • 71
    • 0348162824 scopus 로고
    • Mataji Miyamoto
    • (1616-1870) see also SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 9-10; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 31
    • BEISHŌ KYŪKI (1616-1870) (emphasis added) reprinted as MATAJI MIYAMOTO, 3 ŌSAKA KEIZAI SHIRYŌ SHŌSEI [COMPILATION OF OSAKA ECONOMY DOCUMENTS] 76-77 (1973); see also SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 9-10; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 31. The decree applied specifically to futures contracts. Spot transactions at Dojima apparently had separate legal treatment. At some point in the An'ei era (1772-1780), the shogunate systematically gave spot transaction suits precedence over other suits, rendering quick judgments and accepting filings on days other than the two-a-month "suing days" specified for such matters. See SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 20.
    • (1973) Ōsaka Keizai Shiryō Shōsei [Compilation of Osaka Economy Documents] , vol.3 , pp. 76-77
    • Kyuki, B.1
  • 72
    • 0346902371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 77
    • BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 77.
  • 73
    • 0346902372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Romano, supra note 8, at 10-20. Romano's list is similar to others
    • See Romano, supra note 8, at 10-20. Romano's list is similar to others, see, for example, A.W.B. Simpson, The Origins of Futures Trading in the Liverpool Cotton Market, in ESSAYS FOR PATRICK ATIYAH 179, 180-81 (Peter Cane & Jane Stapleton eds., 1991). Unless otherwise indicated, I draw here principally from BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, and more modern accounts reported in MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 195-232; SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 11-78; and SUGIE, supra note 6, at 31-83.
  • 74
    • 0346272056 scopus 로고
    • The Origins of Futures Trading in the Liverpool Cotton Market
    • Peter Cane & Jane Stapleton eds.
    • See Romano, supra note 8, at 10-20. Romano's list is similar to others, see, for example, A.W.B. Simpson, The Origins of Futures Trading in the Liverpool Cotton Market, in ESSAYS FOR PATRICK ATIYAH 179, 180-81 (Peter Cane & Jane Stapleton eds., 1991). Unless otherwise indicated, I draw here principally from BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, and more modern accounts reported in MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 195-232; SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 11-78; and SUGIE, supra note 6, at 31-83.
    • (1991) Essays for Patrick Atiyah , pp. 179
    • Simpson, A.W.B.1
  • 75
    • 0346272059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unless otherwise indicated, I draw here principally from BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, and more modern accounts reported in MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 195-232;
    • See Romano, supra note 8, at 10-20. Romano's list is similar to others, see, for example, A.W.B. Simpson, The Origins of Futures Trading in the Liverpool Cotton Market, in ESSAYS FOR PATRICK ATIYAH 179, 180-81 (Peter Cane & Jane Stapleton eds., 1991). Unless otherwise indicated, I draw here principally from BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, and more modern accounts reported in MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 195-232; SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 11-78; and SUGIE, supra note 6, at 31-83.
  • 76
    • 0348162827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 11-78
    • See Romano, supra note 8, at 10-20. Romano's list is similar to others, see, for example, A.W.B. Simpson, The Origins of Futures Trading in the Liverpool Cotton Market, in ESSAYS FOR PATRICK ATIYAH 179, 180-81 (Peter Cane & Jane Stapleton eds., 1991). Unless otherwise indicated, I draw here principally from BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, and more modern accounts reported in MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 195-232; SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 11-78; and SUGIE, supra note 6, at 31-83.
  • 77
    • 0347533157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SUGIE, supra note 6, at 31-83
    • See Romano, supra note 8, at 10-20. Romano's list is similar to others, see, for example, A.W.B. Simpson, The Origins of Futures Trading in the Liverpool Cotton Market, in ESSAYS FOR PATRICK ATIYAH 179, 180-81 (Peter Cane & Jane Stapleton eds., 1991). Unless otherwise indicated, I draw here principally from BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, and more modern accounts reported in MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 195-232; SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 11-78; and SUGIE, supra note 6, at 31-83.
  • 78
    • 0346272057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Risk Instruments in the Medieval and Early Modern Economy
    • supra note 13, at 10-12. id. at 12 & n.37
    • See Meir Kohn, Risk Instruments in the Medieval and Early Modern Economy, in KOHN, supra note 13, at 10-12. The mid-sixteenth-century wagers on exchange rates at Antwerp that Kohn says "seem like modern futures contracts," id. at 12 & n.37. appear merely to be forwards, with no evidence of standardized contracts, clearinghouses, and the like. See RICHARD EHRENBERG, CAPITAL & FINANCE IN THE AGE OF THE RENAISSANCE: A STUDY OF THE FUGGERS AND THEIR CONNECTIONS 243-44 (H.M. Lucas trans., 1928).
    • Kohn
    • Kohn, M.1
  • 79
    • 0348162823 scopus 로고
    • H.M. Lucas trans.
    • See Meir Kohn, Risk Instruments in the Medieval and Early Modern Economy, in KOHN, supra note 13, at 10-12. The mid-sixteenth-century wagers on exchange rates at Antwerp that Kohn says "seem like modern futures contracts," id. at 12 & n.37. appear merely to be forwards, with no evidence of standardized contracts, clearinghouses, and the like. See RICHARD EHRENBERG, CAPITAL & FINANCE IN THE AGE OF THE RENAISSANCE: A STUDY OF THE FUGGERS AND THEIR CONNECTIONS 243-44 (H.M. Lucas trans., 1928).
    • (1928) Capital & Finance in the Age of the Renaissance: A Study of the Fuggers and Their Connections , pp. 243-244
    • Ehrenberg, R.1
  • 80
    • 0348162818 scopus 로고
    • The Exchange also has special contract rules pertaining to such matters as quality and quotation unit for each commodity. See ROBERT GIBSON-JARVIE, THE LONDON METAL EXCHANGE: A COMMODITY MARKET 29-33 (1976); RUDOLF WOLFF & Co LTD., WOLFF'S GUIDE TO THE LONDON METALS EXCHANGE 199-221 (5th ed. 1995).
    • (1976) The London Metal Exchange: A Commodity Market , pp. 29-33
    • Gibson-Jarvie, R.1
  • 81
    • 0348162819 scopus 로고
    • The Exchange also has special contract rules pertaining to such matters as quality and quotation unit for each commodity. See ROBERT GIBSON-JARVIE, THE LONDON METAL EXCHANGE: A COMMODITY MARKET 29-33 (1976); RUDOLF WOLFF & Co LTD., WOLFF'S GUIDE TO THE LONDON METALS EXCHANGE 199-221 (5th ed. 1995).
    • (1995) Wolff's Guide to the London Metals Exchange 5th Ed. , pp. 199-221
    • Wolff, R.1
  • 82
    • 0347533155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the importance of grading, see Pirrong, supra note 1, at 234-35; Simpson, supra note 43, at 182
    • On the importance of grading, see Pirrong, supra note 1, at 234-35; Simpson, supra note 43, at 182.
  • 83
    • 0347533156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Dates may vary based on days of the week, and the winter and spring terms may technically have been one term split by the year-end holidays. See SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 38. Technically the months are lunar months and do not correspond exactly to the solar Gregorian calendar. The particular dates referred to herein are not important enough to merit revision of dates to the Gregorian system.
  • 85
    • 0347533142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SAKUDŌ, supra note 12, at 369
    • See SAKUDŌ, supra note 12, at 369.
  • 86
    • 0348162813 scopus 로고
    • But see MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 386-402 (noting the lack of united market until the mid-eighteenth century and finding less correlation among isolated markets)
    • See MATAHI MIYAMOTO, NIHON SHŌGYŌSHI [JAPANESE COMMERCIAL HISTORY] 120-21 (1949). But see MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 386-402 (noting the lack of united market until the mid-eighteenth century and finding less correlation among isolated markets).
    • (1949) Japanese Commercial History , pp. 120-121
    • Miyamoto, M.1    Shogyoshi, N.2
  • 87
    • 0011485003 scopus 로고
    • Frack Norris and Popular Perceptions of the Market
    • Morton Rothstein, Frack Norris and Popular Perceptions of the Market, 56 AGRIC. HIST. 58 (1982), cited in WILLIAM CRONON, NATURE'S METROPOLIS: CHICAGO AND THE GREAT WEST 125 (1992).
    • (1982) Agric. Hist. , vol.56 , pp. 58
    • Rothstein, M.1
  • 89
    • 0347533158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McClain, supra note 34, at 64-65
    • See McClain, supra note 34, at 64-65.
  • 90
    • 0347533152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Most modern exchanges rely on one central clearinghouse institution, while Dojima had multiple clearinghouses. Although competition among multiple clearinghouses operating as brokers might seem efficient, the duplication of basic clearinghouse services by multiple parties may have reduced potential gains.
  • 91
    • 0348162822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 205
    • See MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 205.
  • 93
    • 0347533154 scopus 로고
    • Kinsei Ōsaka no Keizai to Bunka
    • See OSAMU WAKITA, KINSEI ŌSAKA NO KEIZAI TO BUNKA [ECONOMICS AND CULTURE OF EARLY MODERN OSAKA] 44 (1994); JACK WEATHERFORD, THE HISTORY OF MONEY: FROM SANDSTONE TO CYBERSPACE 73-74 (1997) (noting that "if Christians lent money for interest, the Catholic church excommunicated them" and that "[t]he Koran specifically prohibited bills of exchange"). While usury prohibitions may have hampered the development of debt and financial intermediaries in Europe, they did encourage the early development of bills of exchange. See Kohn, supra note 13, at 9-10.
    • (1994) Economics and Culture of Early Modern Osaka , pp. 44
    • Wakita, O.1
  • 94
    • 0013495090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kohn, supra note 13, at 9-10
    • See OSAMU WAKITA, KINSEI ŌSAKA NO KEIZAI TO BUNKA [ECONOMICS AND CULTURE OF EARLY MODERN OSAKA] 44 (1994); JACK WEATHERFORD, THE HISTORY OF MONEY: FROM SANDSTONE TO CYBERSPACE 73-74 (1997) (noting that "if Christians lent money for interest, the Catholic church excommunicated them" and that "[t]he Koran specifically prohibited bills of exchange"). While usury prohibitions may have hampered the development of debt and financial intermediaries in Europe, they did encourage the early development of bills of exchange. See Kohn, supra note 13, at 9-10.
    • (1997) The History of Money: From Sandstone to Cyberspace , pp. 73-74
    • Weatherford, J.1
  • 95
    • 0346272052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 206
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 206.
  • 96
    • 15944392651 scopus 로고
    • Nihon Hōseishi Gaisetsu
    • See supra text accompanying note 33 hereinafter RYŌSUKE ISHII, NIHON HŌSEISHI GAISETSU;
    • See supra text accompanying note 33. Confiscation of assets (kessho) was connected with punishments for all types of crimes. The severity of the confiscation depended on the severity of the crime. See RYŌSUKE ISHII, NIHON HŌSEISHI GAISETSU [OUTLINE OF JAPANESE LEGAL HISTORY] 495, 498 n.13 (1948) [hereinafter RYŌSUKE ISHII, NIHON HŌSEISHI GAISETSU];
    • (1948) Outline of Japanese Legal History , Issue.13 , pp. 495
    • Ishii, R.1
  • 97
    • 0347533153 scopus 로고
    • Keibatsu no Rekishi
    • see also RYŌSUKE ISHII, KEIBATSU NO REKISHI [THE HISTORY OF PUNISHMENT] 132 (1992) (explaining how Yoshimune established graduated fine system to complement asset confiscation in 1718). Confiscation normally applied only to the offender and not to an offender's group.
    • (1992) The History of Punishment , pp. 132
    • Ishii, R.1
  • 99
    • 0346902366 scopus 로고
    • Chōnin
    • See YOSHIO SAKATA, CHŌNIN [MERCHANTS] 38 (1949).
    • (1949) Merchants , pp. 38
    • Sakata, Y.1
  • 100
    • 0348162807 scopus 로고
    • Hōreki, Tenmeiki no Bakusei [Shogunate Government in the Hōreki-Tenmei Era (1751-1789)]
    • See Shinzaburō Ōishi, Hōreki, Tenmeiki no Bakusei [Shogunate Government in the Hōreki-Tenmei Era (1751-1789)], in 11 IWANAMI KŌZA NIHON REKISHI [IWANAMI SERIES ON JAPANESE HISTORY] 139 (1976); E.S. Crawcour & Kozo Yamamura, The Tokugawa Monetary System: 1787-1868, 18 ECON. DEV. & CULTURAL CHANGE 489, 500 (1970); Shigeaki Yasuoka, Edo Chūki no Osaka Torhiki Soshiki [The Trade Structure of Osaka in the Middle Tokugawa Era], 16 DŌSHISHA SHŌGAKU 290 (1964). After 1830 and toward the end of the Tokugawa government, price control measures occurred with some regularity. See MASANORI HONJŌ, BAKUHANSEI SHAKAI NO TENKAI BEIKOKU SHIJŌ [DEVELOPMENT OF FEUDAL GOVERNMENT AND RICE MARKETS] 361 (1994).
    • (1976) Iwanami Kōza Nihon Rekishi [Iwanami Series on Japanese History] , vol.11 , pp. 139
    • Oishi, S.1
  • 101
    • 0348162812 scopus 로고
    • The Tokugawa Monetary System: 1787-1868
    • See Shinzaburō Ōishi, Hōreki, Tenmeiki no Bakusei [Shogunate Government in the Hōreki-Tenmei Era (1751-1789)], in 11 IWANAMI KŌZA NIHON REKISHI [IWANAMI SERIES ON JAPANESE HISTORY] 139 (1976); E.S. Crawcour & Kozo Yamamura, The Tokugawa Monetary System: 1787-1868, 18 ECON. DEV. & CULTURAL CHANGE 489, 500 (1970); Shigeaki Yasuoka, Edo Chūki no Osaka Torhiki Soshiki [The Trade Structure of Osaka in the Middle Tokugawa Era], 16 DŌSHISHA SHŌGAKU 290 (1964). After 1830 and toward the end of the Tokugawa government, price control measures occurred with some regularity. See MASANORI HONJŌ, BAKUHANSEI SHAKAI NO TENKAI BEIKOKU SHIJŌ [DEVELOPMENT OF FEUDAL GOVERNMENT AND RICE MARKETS] 361 (1994).
    • (1970) Econ. Dev. & Cultural Change , vol.18 , pp. 489
    • Crawcour, E.S.1    Yamamura, K.2
  • 102
    • 0348162820 scopus 로고
    • Edo Chūki no Osaka Torhiki Soshiki
    • See Shinzaburō Ōishi, Hōreki, Tenmeiki no Bakusei [Shogunate Government in the Hōreki-Tenmei Era (1751-1789)], in 11 IWANAMI KŌZA NIHON REKISHI [IWANAMI SERIES ON JAPANESE HISTORY] 139 (1976); E.S. Crawcour & Kozo Yamamura, The Tokugawa Monetary System: 1787-1868, 18 ECON. DEV. & CULTURAL CHANGE 489, 500 (1970); Shigeaki Yasuoka, Edo Chūki no Osaka Torhiki Soshiki [The Trade Structure of Osaka in the Middle Tokugawa Era], 16 DŌSHISHA SHŌGAKU 290 (1964). After 1830 and toward the end of the Tokugawa government, price control measures occurred with some regularity. See MASANORI HONJŌ, BAKUHANSEI SHAKAI NO TENKAI BEIKOKU SHIJŌ [DEVELOPMENT OF FEUDAL GOVERNMENT AND RICE MARKETS] 361 (1994).
    • (1964) Dōshisha Shōgaku , vol.16 , pp. 290
    • Yasuoka, S.1
  • 103
    • 0346272054 scopus 로고
    • Bakuhansei Shakai no Tenkai Beikoku Shijō
    • See Shinzaburō Ōishi, Hōreki, Tenmeiki no Bakusei [Shogunate Government in the Hōreki-Tenmei Era (1751-1789)], in 11 IWANAMI KŌZA NIHON REKISHI [IWANAMI SERIES ON JAPANESE HISTORY] 139 (1976); E.S. Crawcour & Kozo Yamamura, The Tokugawa Monetary System: 1787-1868, 18 ECON. DEV. & CULTURAL CHANGE 489, 500 (1970); Shigeaki Yasuoka, Edo Chūki no Osaka Torhiki Soshiki [The Trade Structure of Osaka in the Middle Tokugawa Era], 16 DŌSHISHA SHŌGAKU 290 (1964). After 1830 and toward the end of the Tokugawa government, price control measures occurred with some regularity. See MASANORI HONJŌ, BAKUHANSEI SHAKAI NO TENKAI BEIKOKU SHIJŌ [DEVELOPMENT OF FEUDAL GOVERNMENT AND RICE MARKETS] 361 (1994).
    • (1994) Development of Feudal Government and Rice Markets , pp. 361
    • Honjo, M.1
  • 104
    • 5644237202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commercial Change and Urban Growth in Early Modern Japan
    • SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 19; John Whitney Hall ed., 1991.
    • See SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 19; Nobuhiko Nakai & James L. McClain, Commercial Change and Urban Growth in Early Modern Japan, in 4 CAMBRIDGE HISTORY OF JAPAN 519, 587 (John Whitney Hall ed., 1991). After 1773, the shogunate still occasionally issued decrees regarding money claims, twice announcing that money clims must be settled out of court, and granting amnesty to old futures-related claims. See Heiichirō Kaneda, Tokugawa Jidai no Tokubetsu Minji Soshōhō: Kanekuji no Kenkyū [Special Procedural Law of the Tokugawa Era: Research on Money Suits], 43 KOKKA GAKKAI ZASSHI 362 (1928).
    • Cambridge History of Japan , vol.4 , pp. 519
    • Nakai, N.1    McClain, J.L.2
  • 105
    • 0348162821 scopus 로고
    • Tokugawa Jidai no Tokubetsu Minji Soshōhō: Kanekuji no Kenkyū
    • See SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 19; Nobuhiko Nakai & James L. McClain, Commercial Change and Urban Growth in Early Modern Japan, in 4 CAMBRIDGE HISTORY OF JAPAN 519, 587 (John Whitney Hall ed., 1991). After 1773, the shogunate still occasionally issued decrees regarding money claims, twice announcing that money clims must be settled out of court, and granting amnesty to old futures-related claims. See Heiichirō Kaneda, Tokugawa Jidai no Tokubetsu Minji Soshōhō: Kanekuji no Kenkyū [Special Procedural Law of the Tokugawa Era: Research on Money Suits], 43 KOKKA GAKKAI ZASSHI 362 (1928).
    • (1928) Kokka Gakkai Zasshi , vol.43 , pp. 362
    • Kaneda, H.1
  • 106
    • 0346902365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crawcour & Yamamura, supra note 60, at 500
    • Crawcour & Yamamura, supra note 60, at 500.
  • 109
    • 0348162825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 106
    • See id. at 106.
  • 110
    • 0003492426 scopus 로고
    • Id. at 173-74. A similar phenomenon occurred in Chicago futures markets
    • Id. at 173-74. A similar phenomenon occurred in Chicago futures markets. See JEFFREY WILLIAMS, THE ECONOMIC FUNCTION OF FUTURES MARKETS § 5.2, at 154-56 (1986).
    • (1986) The Economic Function of Futures Markets § 5.2 , pp. 154-156
    • Williams, J.1
  • 111
    • 0346902360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stout, supra note 2, at 717
    • See Stout, supra note 2, at 717.
  • 112
    • 77954754084 scopus 로고
    • The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise
    • See Henry Hansmann, The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise, 89 YALE L.J. 835, 841 (1980); Craig Pirrong, A Positive Theory of Financial Exchange Organization with Normative Implications for Financial Market Regulation, at 37 (Working Paper, Oct. 16, 1997), at http://www.olin.wustl.edu/faculty/pirrong.
    • (1980) Yale L.J. , vol.89 , pp. 835
    • Hansmann, H.1
  • 114
    • 0348162808 scopus 로고
    • Nihon Torihikijō Ron
    • See TASHICHIRŌ TANAKA, NIHON TORIHIKIJŌ RON [THEORY OF JAPANESE MARKETS] 29 (1910); see also Schaede, Forwards and Futures, supra note 7, at 496.
    • (1910) Theory of Japanese Markets , pp. 29
    • Tanaka, T.1
  • 115
    • 0347533198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • See TASHICHIRŌ TANAKA, NIHON TORIHIKIJŌ RON [THEORY OF JAPANESE MARKETS] 29 (1910); see also Schaede, Forwards and Futures, supra note 7, at 496.
    • Forwards and Futures , pp. 496
    • Schaede1
  • 116
    • 0041999257 scopus 로고
    • Dojima Kome Shijōshi
    • See MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 203
    • See MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 203: SHOHEI SUZUKI, DOJIMA KOME SHIJŌSHI [HISTORY OF THE DOJIMA RICE MARKET] 56-57 (1940).
    • (1940) History of the Dojima Rice Market , pp. 56-57
    • Suzuki, S.1
  • 117
    • 0346902352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kyōhō Kaikaku no Shōgyō Seisaku
    • Nakai & McClain, supra note 61, at 570-73
    • The Kyōho reforms of the 1710s and 1720s stressed the formation of protective associations and licensing requirements across a wide variety of industries. See SHINZABURŌ ŌISHI, KYŌHŌ KAIKAKU NO SHŌGYŌ SEISAKU [COMMERCIAL POLICY OF THE KYŌHŌ REFORMS] 201-03 (1998); Nakai & McClain, supra note 61, at 570-73.
    • (1998) Commercial Policy of the Kyōhō Reforms , pp. 201-203
    • Oishi, S.1
  • 118
    • 0346902358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 61 (stating that the shogunate issued 451 licenses in 1730, 538 in 1731, and 362 in 1734, for a total of 1,351, of which 451 were for spot transactions and 900 for futures)
    • See BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 61 (stating that the shogunate issued 451 licenses in 1730, 538 in 1731, and 362 in 1734, for a total of 1,351, of which 451 were for spot transactions and 900 for futures).
  • 119
    • 0346902356 scopus 로고
    • begun
    • See HAMAKATA KIROKU [HAMAKATA RECORDS] (begun 1716), reprinted as EIJIRŌ HONJŌ ET AL., 2 KINSEI SHAKAI KEIZAI SOSHO [EARLY MODERN SOCIETY ECONOMICS SERIES] 24 (1926) (stating that the shogunate issued a total of only 1,300, including 500 in 1731, 500 in 1732, and 300 in 1736).
    • (1716) Hamakata Records
    • Kiroku, H.1
  • 120
    • 0346272048 scopus 로고
    • See HAMAKATA KIROKU [HAMAKATA RECORDS] (begun 1716), reprinted as EIJIRŌ HONJŌ ET AL., 2 KINSEI SHAKAI KEIZAI SOSHO [EARLY MODERN SOCIETY ECONOMICS SERIES] 24 (1926) (stating that the shogunate issued a total of only 1,300, including 500 in 1731, 500 in 1732, and 300 in 1736).
    • (1926) Kinsei Shakai Keizai Sosho [Early Modern Society Economics Series] , vol.2 , pp. 24
    • Honjo, E.1
  • 121
    • 0347533144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 94-95: SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 58
    • See DOHI, supra note 6, at 94-95: SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 58.
  • 122
    • 0348162810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the Shōtoku Period (1711-1715), Osaka is said to have been home to 17,727 merchants, of which 483 were formal agents of feudal lords. See SANSOM, supra note 38, at 128
    • In the Shōtoku Period (1711-1715), Osaka is said to have been home to 17,727 merchants, of which 483 were formal agents of feudal lords. See SANSOM, supra note 38, at 128.
  • 124
    • 0346272051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare to the diamond trading industry, which allows participation by nonmembers. See Bernstein, supra note 1, at 152
    • Compare to the diamond trading industry, which allows participation by nonmembers. See Bernstein, supra note 1, at 152.
  • 125
    • 0347873755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Questionable Empirical Basis of Article 2's Incorporation Strategy: A Preliminary Study
    • See Lisa Bernstein, The Questionable Empirical Basis of Article 2's Incorporation Strategy: A Preliminary Study, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 710, 774-75 (1999) (noting that membership requirements can also aid in reputational constraints).
    • (1999) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.66 , pp. 710
    • Bernstein, L.1
  • 126
    • 0035628987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Manipulation of Cash-Settled Futures Contracts
    • forthcoming
    • See Stephen Craig Pirrong, Manipulation of Cash-Settled Futures Contracts, 74 J. BUS. (forthcoming 2001) (manuscript at 1 n.2. on file with author and available at http:// www.olin.wustl.edu/faculty/pirrong).
    • (2001) J. Bus. , vol.74
    • Pirrong, S.C.1
  • 127
    • 0346272049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying note 47
    • See supra text accompanying note 47.
  • 128
    • 84979344583 scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Futures and Options Contracts Based on Cash Settlement
    • Among other things, cash settlement does not allow the buyer to demand an excessive number of deliveries. See. e.g., Frank J. Jones. The Economics of Futures and Options Contracts Based on Cash Settlement, 2 J. FUTURES MARKETS 63 (1982); Steven Manaster, Economic Consequences of Delivery Options for Financial Futures Contracts: Analysts and Review, 11 REV. FUTURES MARKETS 142 (1992); cf. Praveen Kumar & Duane J. Seppi, Futures Manipulation with "Cash Settlement," 47 J. FIN. 1485 (1992) (noting that traders can manipulate cash-settled contracts through asymmetric information exploitation by "punching the settlement price"); Pirrong, supra note 79 (noting that traders can manipulate cash- settled contracts through market power manipulation by squeezing the commodity used to determine the value of the contract).
    • (1982) J. Futures Markets , vol.2 , pp. 63
    • Jones, F.J.1
  • 129
    • 84979344583 scopus 로고
    • Economic Consequences of Delivery Options for Financial Futures Contracts: Analysts and Review
    • Among other things, cash settlement does not allow the buyer to demand an excessive number of deliveries. See. e.g., Frank J. Jones. The Economics of Futures and Options Contracts Based on Cash Settlement, 2 J. FUTURES MARKETS 63 (1982); Steven Manaster, Economic Consequences of Delivery Options for Financial Futures Contracts: Analysts and Review, 11 REV. FUTURES MARKETS 142 (1992); cf. Praveen Kumar & Duane J. Seppi, Futures Manipulation with "Cash Settlement," 47 J. FIN. 1485 (1992) (noting that traders can manipulate cash-settled contracts through asymmetric information exploitation by "punching the settlement price"); Pirrong, supra note 79 (noting that traders can manipulate cash- settled contracts through market power manipulation by squeezing the commodity used to determine the value of the contract).
    • (1992) Rev. Futures Markets , vol.11 , pp. 142
    • Manaster, S.1
  • 130
    • 84977711560 scopus 로고
    • Futures Manipulation with "Cash Settlement,"
    • Pirrong, supra note 79
    • Among other things, cash settlement does not allow the buyer to demand an excessive number of deliveries. See. e.g., Frank J. Jones. The Economics of Futures and Options Contracts Based on Cash Settlement, 2 J. FUTURES MARKETS 63 (1982); Steven Manaster, Economic Consequences of Delivery Options for Financial Futures Contracts: Analysts and Review, 11 REV. FUTURES MARKETS 142 (1992); cf. Praveen Kumar & Duane J. Seppi, Futures Manipulation with "Cash Settlement," 47 J. FIN. 1485 (1992) (noting that traders can manipulate cash-settled contracts through asymmetric information exploitation by "punching the settlement price"); Pirrong, supra note 79 (noting that traders can manipulate cash- settled contracts through market power manipulation by squeezing the commodity used to determine the value of the contract).
    • (1992) J. Fin. , vol.47 , pp. 1485
    • Kumar, P.1    Seppi, D.J.2
  • 131
    • 84855684706 scopus 로고
    • The Self-Regulation of Commodity Exchanges: The Case of Market Manipulation
    • Craig Pirrong argues that control of manipulation by the state might be desirable in some circumstances. See Stephen Craig Pirrong, The Self-Regulation of Commodity Exchanges: The Case of Market Manipulation, 38 J.L. & ECON. 141 (1995). But see Frank H. Easterbrook, Monopoly, Manipulation, and the Regulation of Futures Markets, 59 J. BUS. S103 (1986); Daniel R. Fischel & David J. Ross, Should the Law Prohibit "Manipulation" in Financial Markets?, 105 HARV. L. REV. 503 (1991). Even if Pirrong is correct, Dojima differs from the markets that Pirrong examines. The Dojima rules discussed herein (but perhaps not the practice) appear to differ from those of the Chicago Board of Trade and other exchanges that Pirrong finds "took few, if any, actions to deter manipulation." Pirrong, supra, at 195. Pirrong also finds that effective self-regulation came about only after the advent of federal commodity laws. See Pirrong, supra, at 192-95. Dojima rules changed little after legal intervention. See infra text accompanying note 130. Determining why Dojima rules differ from other markets - why traders adopted the firebox system - is more difficult. Perhaps the answer lies in homogeneity. See Pirrong, supra, at 158. But the degree of homogeneity of financial interests that existed among merchants, which comprised a very broad status group, is unclear at best, and the size of the ex- change points toward heterogeneity. See Pirrong, supra, at 162 (noting that enforcement is lower when exchange membership is large). Perhaps the answer lies in the inability to cost- shift. Pirrong argues that consumers of exchange services may bear the bulk of costs of manipulation, not exchange members. See Pirrong. supra, at 164. But while Dojima may have had fewer external consumers than some modern markets, they did exist. See supra text accompanying note 75. Perhaps a better answer is that the firebox system was adopted simply to determine objectively a closing time, and its antimanipulation effects were an inadvertent bonus.
    • (1995) J.L. & Econ. , vol.38 , pp. 141
    • Pirrong, S.C.1
  • 132
    • 0000378670 scopus 로고
    • Monopoly, Manipulation, and the Regulation of Futures Markets
    • Craig Pirrong argues that control of manipulation by the state might be desirable in some circumstances. See Stephen Craig Pirrong, The Self-Regulation of Commodity Exchanges: The Case of Market Manipulation, 38 J.L. & ECON. 141 (1995). But see Frank H. Easterbrook, Monopoly, Manipulation, and the Regulation of Futures Markets, 59 J. BUS. S103 (1986); Daniel R. Fischel & David J. Ross, Should the Law Prohibit "Manipulation" in Financial Markets?, 105 HARV. L. REV. 503 (1991). Even if Pirrong is correct, Dojima differs from the markets that Pirrong examines. The Dojima rules discussed herein (but perhaps not the practice) appear to differ from those of the Chicago Board of Trade and other exchanges that Pirrong finds "took few, if any, actions to deter manipulation." Pirrong, supra, at 195. Pirrong also finds that effective self-regulation came about only after the advent of federal commodity laws. See Pirrong, supra, at 192-95. Dojima rules changed little after legal intervention. See infra text accompanying note 130. Determining why Dojima rules differ from other markets - why traders adopted the firebox system - is more difficult. Perhaps the answer lies in homogeneity. See Pirrong, supra, at 158. But the degree of homogeneity of financial interests that existed among merchants, which comprised a very broad status group, is unclear at best, and the size of the ex- change points toward heterogeneity. See Pirrong, supra, at 162 (noting that enforcement is lower when exchange membership is large). Perhaps the answer lies in the inability to cost- shift. Pirrong argues that consumers of exchange services may bear the bulk of costs of manipulation, not exchange members. See Pirrong. supra, at 164. But while Dojima may have had fewer external consumers than some modern markets, they did exist. See supra text accompanying note 75. Perhaps a better answer is that the firebox system was adopted simply to determine objectively a closing time, and its antimanipulation effects were an inadvertent bonus.
    • (1986) J. Bus. , vol.59
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 133
    • 0345820006 scopus 로고
    • Should the Law Prohibit "Manipulation" in Financial Markets?
    • Craig Pirrong argues that control of manipulation by the state might be desirable in some circumstances. See Stephen Craig Pirrong, The Self-Regulation of Commodity Exchanges: The Case of Market Manipulation, 38 J.L. & ECON. 141 (1995). But see Frank H. Easterbrook, Monopoly, Manipulation, and the Regulation of Futures Markets, 59 J. BUS. S103 (1986); Daniel R. Fischel & David J. Ross, Should the Law Prohibit "Manipulation" in Financial Markets?, 105 HARV. L. REV. 503 (1991). Even if Pirrong is correct, Dojima differs from the markets that Pirrong examines. The Dojima rules discussed herein (but perhaps not the practice) appear to differ from those of the Chicago Board of Trade and other exchanges that Pirrong finds "took few, if any, actions to deter manipulation." Pirrong, supra, at 195. Pirrong also finds that effective self-regulation came about only after the advent of federal commodity laws. See Pirrong, supra, at 192-95. Dojima rules changed little after legal intervention. See infra text accompanying note 130. Determining why Dojima rules differ from other markets - why traders adopted the firebox system - is more difficult. Perhaps the answer lies in homogeneity. See Pirrong, supra, at 158. But the degree of homogeneity of financial interests that existed among merchants, which comprised a very broad status group, is unclear at best, and the size of the ex-change points toward heterogeneity. See Pirrong, supra, at 162 (noting that enforcement is lower when exchange membership is large). Perhaps the answer lies in the inability to cost-shift. Pirrong argues that consumers of exchange services may bear the bulk of costs of manipulation, not exchange members. See Pirrong. supra, at 164. But while Dojima may have had fewer external consumers than some modern markets, they did exist. See supra text accompanying note 75. Perhaps a better answer is that the firebox system was adopted simply to determine objectively a closing time, and its antimanipulation effects were an inadvertent bonus.
    • (1991) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.105 , pp. 503
    • Fischel, D.R.1    Ross, D.J.2
  • 135
    • 0347533137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 82
    • See id. at 82.
  • 136
    • 0348162797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The following description relies on SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 45-46, 107; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 46; and SUZUKI, supra note 70, at 100-01
    • The following description relies on SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 45-46, 107; SUGIE, supra note 6, at 46; and SUZUKI, supra note 70, at 100-01.
  • 137
    • 0348162799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., FABOZZI ET AL., supra note 48, at 503
    • See, e.g., FABOZZI ET AL., supra note 48, at 503.
  • 138
    • 0346272037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 46
    • See SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 46.
  • 139
    • 0346272038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 43
    • See id. at 43.
  • 140
    • 0348162792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exchange directors were once forced to issue an order to control related violence. See BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 307
    • Exchange directors were once forced to issue an order to control related violence. See BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 307.
  • 141
    • 0347533134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying note 69
    • See supra text accompanying note 69.
  • 142
    • 0001103387 scopus 로고
    • Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders' Coalition
    • See Avner Grief, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders' Coalition, 83 A.M. ECON. REV. 525 (1993); Paul R. Milgrom et al., The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs, 2 ECON. & POL. 1 (1990).
    • (1993) A.M. Econ. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 525
    • Grief, A.1
  • 143
    • 0001786246 scopus 로고
    • The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant,
    • See Avner Grief, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders' Coalition, 83 A.M. ECON. REV. 525 (1993); Paul R. Milgrom et al., The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs, 2 ECON. & POL. 1 (1990).
    • (1990) Econ. & Pol. , vol.2 , pp. 1
    • Milgrom, P.R.1
  • 144
    • 0043193271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Commercial Law in the Cotton Industry: Value Creation Through Rules, Norms, and Institutions
    • forthcoming June
    • See Lisa Bernstein, Private Commercial Law in the Cotton Industry: Value Creation Through Rules, Norms, and Institutions, 99 MICH. L. REV. (forthcoming June 2001).
    • (2001) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • Bernstein, L.1
  • 145
    • 0346272044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying note 46
    • See supra text accompanying note 46.
  • 146
    • 0348162800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The force-out nature of the Exchange and the rules and organization that resulted may point to a difference among self-organized markets. Organizations that have the ability to rely on relational bonds among market participants as more precisely tailored substitutes for legal rules may be more likely than other organizations to opt out of the legal system. But in force-out cases, organizations might not opt out of the legal system because the binding propensity of relations is less significant. Relations might be less binding because the group is less homogenous, because costs are significant, or because the transactions involved are complex and rely more on an informed market than a relationally sound one. In these instances groups may be more likely to turn to rules, or organizational monitoring, to govern their affairs. The opt-out/force-out dichotomy may help explain why "it is primarily the fear of damage to reputation that maintains discipline in the diamond trade, not the bourse's board of arbitrators" that governs diamond traders who "opt out" of the legal system, Bernstein, supra note 1, at 152, just as close-knit groups like cattle ranchers and farmers in Shasta County animal trespass relv on social norms, see Ellickson, supra note 1, while early participants at the New York Stock Exchange relied on a "miniature legal system" that "filled the void created by the unenforceability of time bargains in New York courts," Banner supra note 1, at 132. Although Dojima traders were all members of the merchant status group, that designation alone may have been insufficient to establish the requisite bonds needed for inter-trader monitoring and a preemptive opt-out.
  • 147
    • 0347533131 scopus 로고
    • Otsu Kokurui Sonata Sōbahyō
    • attached to Kinsei Beikoku torhiki Shijō toshite no Ōtsu [Otsu as a Tokugawa Rice Market]
    • Mieko Tsuruoka, Otsu Kokurui Sonata Sōbahyō [Chart of Grain and Other Commodity Prices in Otsu], attached to Kinsei Beikoku torhiki Shijō toshite no Ōtsu [Otsu as a Tokugawa Rice Market], 5 SHIRYŌKAN KENKYŪ KIYŌ 19, 114-207 (1972). The Bulletin was at the time administered by the Ministry of Education but now by the National Institute of Japanese Literature.
    • (1972) Shiryōkan Kenkyū Kiyō , vol.5 , pp. 19
    • Tsuruoka, M.1
  • 148
    • 0348162798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 365; Ito, supra note 6, at 343; Wakita, supra note 6, at 241. To my knowledge, these three works, all in Japanese, are the only formal economic analyses of Dojima that exist. Each uses the Tsuruoka dataset. Miyamoto uses the entire dataset, but his examination focuses on the Exchange's efficiency relative to each shogun's reign and to currency valuation, and does not acknowledge the bias presented by the closed-trimester system, providing results that Ito bluntly calls "meaningless." Ito, supra note 6, at 345. Ito uses Tsuruoka data, but only for the period from 1763 to 1780, and only to fill in gaps between closing dates. Wakita uses a fuller set, from 1760 to 1811, but his focus is seasonal variation.
  • 149
    • 0346902347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kahei no Sanpomichi
    • ch. 16
    • Hachimoku is an early modern word for rice. See Kahei no Sanpomichi [Currency Walking Tour], INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES, BANK OF JAPAN, ch. 16, available at http://imes.boj.or.jp/cm/htmls/feature_16.htm. Some sources, both English and Japanese, occasionally mistransliterate the Japanese characters as "yagi," the surname that uses the same characters.
    • Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan
  • 150
    • 0346272041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Tsuruoka, supra note 95, at 113
    • See generally Tsuruoka, supra note 95, at 113.
  • 152
    • 0346272045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As noted infra notes 108 and 112, Japanese economists have attempted to address both questions, using smaller data sets and different tests, but obtaining similar results.
  • 154
    • 0041129268 scopus 로고
    • MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 365-85. see supra text accompanying note 47
    • See. e.g., WALTER C. LABYS & C.W.J. GRANGER, SPECULATION, HEDGING AND COMMODITY PRICE FORECASTS 25-32 (1970); MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 365-85. The trimester trading system, see supra text accompanying note 47, makes detailed empirical comparisons of this measure with other futures markets difficult, if not impossible.
    • (1970) Speculation, Hedging and Commodity Price Forecasts , pp. 25-32
    • Labys, W.C.1    Granger, C.W.J.2
  • 155
    • 84977703346 scopus 로고
    • Business Cycles and the Behavior of Metals Prices
    • See Eugene F. Fama & Kenneth R. French, Business Cycles and the Behavior of Metals Prices, 53 J. FIN. 1075 (1988); Holbrook Working, Theory of the Inverse Carrying Charge in Futures Markets, 30 J. FUTURE ECON. 9 (1949). On the efficiency of Dojima as a hedge institution, see Matao Miyamoto, Edo Jidai no Kome Shijō: Sono Kōzō to Kinō [The Structure and Function of Tokugawa Era Rice Markets], GENDAI KEIZAI, 48, 56-62 (Spring 1982).
    • (1988) J. Fin. , vol.53 , pp. 1075
    • Fama, E.F.1    French, K.R.2
  • 156
    • 84977703346 scopus 로고
    • Theory of the Inverse Carrying Charge in Futures Markets
    • See Eugene F. Fama & Kenneth R. French, Business Cycles and the Behavior of Metals Prices, 53 J. FIN. 1075 (1988); Holbrook Working, Theory of the Inverse Carrying Charge in Futures Markets, 30 J. FUTURE ECON. 9 (1949). On the efficiency of Dojima as a hedge institution, see Matao Miyamoto, Edo Jidai no Kome Shijō: Sono Kōzō to Kinō [The Structure and Function of Tokugawa Era Rice Markets], GENDAI KEIZAI, 48, 56-62 (Spring 1982).
    • (1949) J. Future Econ. , vol.30 , pp. 9
    • Working, H.1
  • 157
    • 84977703346 scopus 로고
    • Edo Jidai no Kome Shijō: Sono Kōzō to Kinō
    • Spring
    • See Eugene F. Fama & Kenneth R. French, Business Cycles and the Behavior of Metals Prices, 53 J. FIN. 1075 (1988); Holbrook Working, Theory of the Inverse Carrying Charge in Futures Markets, 30 J. FUTURE ECON. 9 (1949). On the efficiency of Dojima as a hedge institution, see Matao Miyamoto, Edo Jidai no Kome Shijō: Sono Kōzō to Kinō [The Structure and Function of Tokugawa Era Rice Markets], GENDAI KEIZAI, 48, 56-62 (Spring 1982).
    • (1982) Gendai Keizai , pp. 48
    • Miyamoto, M.1
  • 158
    • 0346902345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 190-91
    • See MIYAMOTO, supra note 6, at 190-91.
  • 159
    • 0004130519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • That the famine occurred at all may indicate the limited reach of the shogunate government. See AMARTYA SEN, DEVELOPMENT AS FREEDOM (1999).
    • (1999) Development as Freedom
    • Sen, A.1
  • 160
    • 0346902346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Other large movements are more difficult to explain. The early 1762 contango occurred at about the same time that the shogunate offered financial assistance to at least one rice brokerage suffering from low physical rice prices, perhaps due to excess supply. See DOHI, supra note 6, at 206. Spot prices rose in mid-1762 due to the Kyushu drought. See supra text accompanying note 87.
  • 161
    • 0346272039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying note 47
    • See supra text accompanying note 47.
  • 162
    • 0348162795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wakita, supra note 6, at 243 (showing seasonal efficiency with a smaller dataset by regressing the log of the spread against a seasonal dummy)
    • See Wakita, supra note 6, at 243 (showing seasonal efficiency with a smaller dataset by regressing the log of the spread against a seasonal dummy).
  • 163
    • 0346902344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PIRRONG ET AL., supra note 83, at 15-16
    • See PIRRONG ET AL., supra note 83, at 15-16.
  • 164
    • 0346272027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The data in Section III.A are biased toward higher correlation because of this phenomenon, but the monthly correlations show the same general trend even in the absence of term-ending months.
  • 165
    • 0346272033 scopus 로고
    • Yume no Shiro
    • Norihisa Mizuta et al. eds.
    • Banto Yamagata, Yume no Shiro [The Stuff of Dreams] (1802), in TOMINAGA NAKAMOTO, YAMAGATA BANTO 141, 398 (Norihisa Mizuta et al. eds., 1973).
    • (1973) Tominaga Nakamoto, Yamagata Banto , pp. 141
    • Yamagata, B.1
  • 166
    • 0346272035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ito conducts a similar test for different periods using a smaller dataset. See Ito, supra note 6, at 343
    • Ito conducts a similar test for different periods using a smaller dataset. See Ito, supra note 6, at 343.
  • 167
    • 0347533135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying note 41
    • See supra text accompanying note 41.
  • 168
    • 0346902339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RYŌSUKE ISHII, NIHON HŌSEISHI GAISETSU, supra note 58, at 471
    • See RYŌSUKE ISHII, NIHON HŌSEISHI GAISETSU, supra note 58, at 471.
  • 169
    • 0346902340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henderson, supra note 23, at 108
    • Henderson, supra note 23, at 108.
  • 170
    • 0346902342 scopus 로고
    • See RYŌSUKE ISHII, KINSEI TORIHIKIHŌSHI [HISTORY OF EARLY MODERN COMMERCIAL LAW] 52-58 (1982). On ten occasions in the Tokugawa period (about every twenty years, and four times after the Exchange's founding, in 1746, 1789, 1797, and 1843), the shogunate issued orders (aitaisumashirei) refusing to hear all credit-related suits. See id. at 15-49.
    • (1982) Kinsei Torihikihōshi [History of Early Modern Commercial Law] , pp. 52-58
    • Ishii, R.1
  • 171
    • 0347533127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RYŌSUKE ISHII, NIKON HŌSEISHI GAISETSU, supra note 58, at 527, 529-30
    • See RYŌSUKE ISHII, NIKON HŌSEISHI GAISETSU, supra note 58, at 527, 529-30.
  • 172
    • 0347533130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Edo no Shijō Keizai: Rekishi Seido Bunseki Kara Mita Kabunakama
    • See TETSUJI OKAZAKI, EDO NO SHIJŌ KEIZAI: REKISHI SEIDO BUNSEKI KARA MITA KABUNAKAMA [MARKET ECONOMICS OF EDO: COALITIONS THROUGH THE LENS OF HISTORICAL SYSTEM ANALYSIS] 76 (1999); see also MATAJI MIYAMOTO, KABUNAKAMA NO KENKYŪ [STUDY OF COMPANION SHARES] 21-33 (1938); ŌISHI, supra note 71.
    • (1999) Market Economics of Edo: Coalitions Through the Lens of Historical System Analysis , pp. 76
    • Okazaki, T.1
  • 173
    • 0348162791 scopus 로고
    • ŌISHI, supra note 71
    • See TETSUJI OKAZAKI, EDO NO SHIJŌ KEIZAI: REKISHI SEIDO BUNSEKI KARA MITA KABUNAKAMA [MARKET ECONOMICS OF EDO: COALITIONS THROUGH THE LENS OF HISTORICAL SYSTEM ANALYSIS] 76 (1999); see also MATAJI MIYAMOTO, KABUNAKAMA NO KENKYŪ [STUDY OF COMPANION SHARES] 21-33 (1938); ŌISHI, supra note 71.
    • (1938) Kabunakama no Kenkyū [Study of Companion Shares] , pp. 21-33
    • Miyamoto, M.1
  • 174
    • 0346902336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ISHII, supra note 116, at 52-58; OKAZAKI, supra note 118, at 76
    • See ISHII, supra note 116, at 52-58; OKAZAKI, supra note 118, at 76.
  • 175
    • 0346902335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 105 (discussing provisions for dealing with rule violators); ISHII, supra note 116, at 52-58; OKAZAKI, supra note 118, at 76; see also DIAMOND & KOLLAR, supra note 8, at 7-8
    • See BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 105 (discussing provisions for dealing with rule violators); ISHII, supra note 116, at 52-58; OKAZAKI, supra note 118, at 76; see also DIAMOND & KOLLAR, supra note 8, at 7-8.
  • 176
    • 85015094916 scopus 로고
    • Unlike the Edo commissioner, which apparently was largely a civil administration organ, the Osaka commissioner was charged with the administration of justice, including the powers to legislate and hear suits. See GENTARŌ HARUHARA, ŌSAKA NO MACHIBUGYŌSHO TO SAIBAN [LAWSUITS AND THE OSAKA TOWN COMMISSION] 11 (1962). The Osaka commissioner had criminal investigative powers as well, but often relied on private enforcement. See YOSHII FUJII, ŌSAKA MACHIBUGYŌ TO KEIBATSU [CRIMINAL PUNISHMENT AND THE OSAKA TOWN COMMISSIONER] 73, 83 (1990).
    • (1962) Ōsaka no Machibugyōsho to Saiban [Lawsuits and the Osaka Town Commission] , pp. 11
    • Haruhara, G.1
  • 177
    • 0346902334 scopus 로고
    • Unlike the Edo commissioner, which apparently was largely a civil administration organ, the Osaka commissioner was charged with the administration of justice, including the powers to legislate and hear suits. See GENTARŌ HARUHARA, ŌSAKA NO MACHIBUGYŌSHO TO SAIBAN [LAWSUITS AND THE OSAKA TOWN COMMISSION] 11 (1962). The Osaka commissioner had criminal investigative powers as well, but often relied on private enforcement. See YOSHII FUJII, ŌSAKA MACHIBUGYŌ TO KEIBATSU [CRIMINAL PUNISHMENT AND THE OSAKA TOWN COMMISSIONER] 73, 83 (1990).
    • (1990) Ōsaka Machibugyō to Keibatsu [Criminal Punishment and the Osaka Town Commissioner] , pp. 73
    • Fujii, Y.1
  • 178
    • 0346272029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying note 41
    • See supra text accompanying note 41.
  • 179
    • 0346272032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 177 (1971);
    • See BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 177 (1971); OFUREGAKI TENMEI SHŪSEI [COMPILATION OF TENMEI PERIOD ORDINANCES (1781-1789)] 835 (Shinzō Takayanagi & Ryōsuke Ishii eds., 1936);
  • 180
    • 0346272030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shinzō Takayanagi & Ryōsuke Ishii eds.
    • See BEISHŌ KYŪKI, supra note 41, at 177 (1971); OFUREGAKI TENMEI SHŪSEI [COMPILATION OF TENMEI PERIOD ORDINANCES (1781-1789)] 835 (Shinzō Takayanagi & Ryōsuke Ishii eds., 1936);
    • (1936) Ofuregaki Tenmei Shūsei Compilation of Tenmei Period Ordinances , pp. 1781-1789
  • 181
    • 0346272031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SAKUDŌ, supra note 12, at 370
    • SAKUDŌ, supra note 12, at 370.
  • 182
    • 0346819831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 19
    • See SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 19 . If a plaintiff had been forced to enforce the judgment against the defendant, the best way to enforce a debt claim was said to be the hiring of "[g]angs of ruffians to beat up non-paying debtors." STEENSTRUP, supra note 20, at 146; see also Curtis J. Milhaupt & Mark D. West, The Dark Side of Private Ordering: An Institutional and Empirical Analysis of Organized Crime, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 41 (2000).
  • 183
    • 0346819831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STEENSTRUP, supra note 20, at 146
    • See SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 19 . If a plaintiff had been forced to enforce the judgment against the defendant, the best way to enforce a debt claim was said to be the hiring of "[g]angs of ruffians to beat up non-paying debtors." STEENSTRUP, supra note 20, at 146; see also Curtis J. Milhaupt & Mark D. West, The Dark Side of Private Ordering: An Institutional and Empirical Analysis of Organized Crime, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 41 (2000).
  • 184
    • 0346819831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dark Side of Private Ordering: An Institutional and Empirical Analysis of Organized Crime
    • See SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 19 . If a plaintiff had been forced to enforce the judgment against the defendant, the best way to enforce a debt claim was said to be the hiring of "[g]angs of ruffians to beat up non-paying debtors." STEENSTRUP, supra note 20, at 146; see also Curtis J. Milhaupt & Mark D. West, The Dark Side of Private Ordering: An Institutional and Empirical Analysis of Organized Crime, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 41 (2000).
    • (2000) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 41
    • Milhaupt, C.J.1    West, M.D.2
  • 185
    • 0347533128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SAKUDŌ, supra note 12, at 370
    • See SAKUDŌ, supra note 12, at 370.
  • 188
    • 0346272030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See OFUREGAKI TENMEI SHŪSEI [COMPILATION OF TENMEI PERIOD ORDINANCES (1781-1789)]. supra note 123, at 837-38. After September 1782, rice bills were required to carry the seal of the commissioner's designated rice inspector, who settled disputes. See id.; see also SAKUDŌ, supra note 12, at 370; SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 20.
    • Ofuregaki Tenmei Shūsei Compilation of Tenmei Period Ordinances , pp. 1781-1789
  • 189
    • 0346272025 scopus 로고
    • Kinsei Ōsaka Chiiki no Toshi to Nōson
    • Osamu Wakita ed., See. e.g., DOHI, supra note 6, at 18
    • The impact of population on litigation rates in this case is ambiguous at best. The most precise estimates measure the population of Osaka at 268,760 in 1635, 389,866 in 1736, peaking at 419,863 in 1765, and gradually declining to 380,416 in 1785. See Osamu Wakita, Kinsei Ōsaka Chiiki no Toshi to Nōson [Farm Villages and Cities of the Early Modern Osaka Region], in KINSEI OSAKA CHIIKI NO SHITEKI BUNSEKI [HISTORICAL ANALYSIS OF THE EARLY MODERN OSAKA REGION] 295, 304 (Osamu Wakita ed., 1980). Other sources place the peak in the 1750s and at about 400,000. See. e.g., DOHI, supra note 6, at 18. If Wakita's figures are accurate, litigation rates in 18th-century Osaka (in 1785, about 43 suits per 1,000 population) were far higher than those in most contemporary United States jurisdictions. See Marc Galanter, Reading the Landscape of Disputes: What We Know and Don't Know (and Think We Know) About Our Allegedly Contentious and Litigious Society, 31 UCLA L. REV. 4 (1983).
    • (1980) Kinsei Osaka Chiiki no Shiteki Bunseki [Historical Analysis of the Early Modern Osaka Region] , pp. 295
    • Wakita, O.1
  • 190
    • 0001855739 scopus 로고
    • Reading the Landscape of Disputes: What We Know and Don't Know (and Think We Know) about Our Allegedly Contentious and Litigious Society
    • The impact of population on litigation rates in this case is ambiguous at best. The most precise estimates measure the population of Osaka at 268,760 in 1635, 389,866 in 1736, peaking at 419,863 in 1765, and gradually declining to 380,416 in 1785. See Osamu Wakita, Kinsei Ōsaka Chiiki no Toshi to Nōson [Farm Villages and Cities of the Early Modern Osaka Region], in KINSEI OSAKA CHIIKI NO SHITEKI BUNSEKI [HISTORICAL ANALYSIS OF THE EARLY MODERN OSAKA REGION] 295, 304 (Osamu Wakita ed., 1980). Other sources place the peak in the 1750s and at about 400,000. See. e.g., DOHI, supra note 6, at 18. If Wakita's figures are accurate, litigation rates in 18th-century Osaka (in 1785, about 43 suits per 1,000 population) were far higher than those in most contemporary United States jurisdictions. See Marc Galanter, Reading the Landscape of Disputes: What We Know and Don't Know (and Think We Know) About Our Allegedly Contentious and Litigious Society, 31 UCLA L. REV. 4 (1983).
    • (1983) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.31 , pp. 4
    • Galanter, M.1
  • 192
    • 0346902332 scopus 로고
    • The Development of Business Associations in Prewar Japan
    • Hiroaki Yamazaki & Matao Miyamoto eds., see also OKAZAKI, supra note 118
    • Matao Miyamoto, The Development of Business Associations in Prewar Japan, in TRADE ASSOCIATIONS IN BUSINESS HISTORY 7 (Hiroaki Yamazaki & Matao Miyamoto eds., 1988); see also OKAZAKI, supra note 118.
    • (1988) Trade Associations in Business History , pp. 7
    • Miyamoto, M.1
  • 193
    • 0346902333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dan Henderson finds that the general philosophy of Tokugawa courts was that "[r]eason is significantly superior to customary law." HENDERSON, supra note 23, at 58-59
    • Dan Henderson finds that the general philosophy of Tokugawa courts was that "[r]eason is significantly superior to customary law." HENDERSON, supra note 23, at 58-59.
  • 194
    • 0002254318 scopus 로고
    • The Selection of Disputes for Litigation
    • See George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984). In the Japanese context, see J. MARK RAMSEYER & MINORU NAKAZATO, JAPANESE LAW: AN ECONOMIC APPROACH 92-95 (1999).
    • (1984) J. Legal Stud. , vol.13 , pp. 1
    • Priest, G.L.1    Klein, B.2
  • 195
    • 0012410957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984). In the Japanese context, see J. MARK RAMSEYER & MINORU NAKAZATO, JAPANESE LAW: AN ECONOMIC APPROACH 92-95 (1999).
    • (1999) Japanese Law: An Economic Approach , pp. 92-95
    • Ramseyer, J.M.1    Nakazato, M.2
  • 196
    • 0348162788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See. e.g., OKAZAKI, supra note 118, at 71
    • See. e.g., OKAZAKI, supra note 118, at 71.
  • 197
    • 0347247727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taking Private Ordering Seriously
    • See Avery Katz, Taking Private Ordering Seriously, 144 U. PA. L. REV 1745, 1752 (1996).
    • (1996) U. Pa. L. Rev , vol.144 , pp. 1745
    • Katz, A.1
  • 198
    • 0346272021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The latter two variables I examine at the suggestion of Omri Yadlin. An event study to calculate abnormal returns based on the 1773 edict would be probative, but the data are too scarce for such a study.
  • 199
    • 0346902328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, because of Dojima's futures trading monopoly, the only legal alternative to futures trading at Dojima is not trading futures.
  • 200
    • 0346902329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Average = 3,797,840; standard deviation = 293,081.2
    • Average = 3,797,840; standard deviation = 293,081.2.
  • 201
    • 0348162784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standard deviation = 305,362.1
    • Standard deviation = 305,362.1.
  • 202
    • 0348162787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standard deviation = 254,788.7
    • Standard deviation = 254,788.7.
  • 203
    • 0346272019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For volume, the periods are pre-edict 1763-1772 and edict 1773-1780, as limited by the available data. For correlation, volatility, and price, I used equal eleven-year periods: pre-edict 1761-1772, edict 1773-1784, and post-edict 1785-1796. Using the full dataset for these periods results in pre-edict (1755-1772) correlation of .924 and post-edict (1785-1827) correlation of .807. Removing the Great Tenmei Famine period raises the edict period correlation to .898 and the post-edict correlation to .817. Using the full dataset for volatility results in pre-edict (1755-1772) log-volatility of spots .06286 and futures .06061. and post-edict log-volatility of spots .08404 and futures .07954. Using the full dataset for price results in a pre-edict (1755-1772) average spot price of 60.911 and average futures price of 61.367. and a post-edict (1785-1827) spot price of 61.364 and futures price of 61.034.
  • 204
    • 0041420020 scopus 로고
    • Time: The Second Dimension of Risk
    • Nov./Dec.
    • Standard deviation, which I mistakenly reported in an early draft of this Article, is an inappropriate and inaccurate measure of volatility because, among other things, it assumes a normal price distribution in which negative prices could exist. See Glyn A. Holton, Time: The Second Dimension of Risk, FIN. ANALYSTS J., Nov./Dec. 1992, at 38.
    • (1992) Fin. Analysts J. , pp. 38
    • Holton, G.A.1
  • 205
    • 0346272018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Because these figures may be affected by the Great Tenmei Famine (1783-1787), I also calculated log-volatilities designating the edict period as ending in 1782, and designating the post-edict period as beginning in 1788. The figures for the 1773-1782 period are spots, .06705: futures, .06178. The figures for the 1788-1827 period are spots, .07977; futures, .07484. I also calculated volatility at five-year intervals, with the following results: 1768-1772, spots, .06456: futures, .05903: 1773-1777, spots, .07015; futures, .06604-1778-1782, spots, .07377; futures, .07167.
  • 206
    • 0000186150 scopus 로고
    • The Use of Volatility Measures in Assessing Market Efficiency
    • See generally Robert J. Shiller, The Use of Volatility Measures in Assessing Market Efficiency, 36 J. FIN. 291 (1981).
    • (1981) J. Fin. , vol.36 , pp. 291
    • Shiller, R.J.1
  • 207
    • 0348162781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 38-42
    • See supra text accompanying notes 38-42.
  • 209
    • 0347533114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Crawcour & Yamamura, supra note 60, at 27-28
    • See Crawcour & Yamamura, supra note 60, at 27-28.
  • 210
    • 0000449743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Creating and Enforcing Norms, with Special Reference to Sanctions
    • See Charny, supra note 5, at 433-35; see also Ayres & Gertner, supra note 5
    • See Charny, supra note 5, at 433-35; see also Ayres & Gertner, supra note 5; Richard A. Posner & Eric B. Rasmusen, Creating and Enforcing Norms, with Special Reference to Sanctions, 19 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 369, 381 (1999).
    • (1999) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.19 , pp. 369
    • Posner, R.A.1    Rasmusen, E.B.2
  • 211
    • 0346272012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Perhaps state laws to address issues not addressed well by traders, such as nationwide trading or long-term contracting, might have been more successful.
  • 212
    • 0346902317 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 1
    • See, e.g., SHIMAMOTO, supra note 6, at 1.
  • 215
    • 0348162769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., YAMATANE GROUP KINEN SHUPPANKAI, supra note 31, at 130-31
    • See, e.g., YAMATANE GROUP KINEN SHUPPANKAI, supra note 31, at 130-31.
  • 216
    • 0346272006 scopus 로고
    • Kunimatsu Miyamoto ed., microformed on 4DM48902 (capitalized at 75,000 yen with 750 shares and formally established officers); Sano & Iura, supra note 152, at 225, 230
    • See ŌSAKA DŌJIMA SHŌKAIJO KISOKU [OSAKA DOJIMA RICE MARKET RULES] 2 (Kunimatsu Miyamoto ed., 1880), microformed on 4DM48902 (capitalized at 75,000 yen with 750 shares and formally established officers); Sano & Iura, supra note 152, at 225, 230.
    • (1880) Ōsaka Dōjima Shōkaijo Kisoku [Osaka Dojima Rice Market Rules] , pp. 2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.