메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 94, Issue 3, 2000, Pages 823-845

The characteristics and challenges of relational contracts

(1)  Speidel, Richard E a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0041525054     PISSN: 00293571     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (33)

References (124)
  • 1
    • 0003643930 scopus 로고
    • See IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT: AN INQUIRY INTO MODERN CONTRACTUAL RELATIONS (1980). In addition, in the last forty years there have been several notable books discussing the policy and theory of contract. At the core of all has been concern about promises and the permissible scope of freedom of contract. Interesting contrasts include CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE: A THEORY OF CONTRACTUAL OBLIGATION (1981) , GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (2d ed. 1995), and HAROLD C. HAVIGHURST, THE NATURE OF PRIVATE CONTRACT (1961). Since 1990 there have been five additions to the contracts academic library: E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CHANGING YOUR MIND: THE LAW OF REGRETTED DECISIONS (1998); JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991); ROBERT A. HILLMAN, THE RICHNESS OF CONTRACT LAW: AN ANALYSIS AND CRITIQUE OF CONTEMPORARY THEORIES OF CONTRACT LAW (1997); W. DAVID SLAWSON, BINDING PROMISES: THE LATE 20TH CENTURY REFORMATION OF CONTRACT LAW (1996); MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, THE LIMITS OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT (1993).
    • (1980) The New Social Contract: An Inquiry into Modern Contractual Relations
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 2
    • 0004111838 scopus 로고
    • See IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT: AN INQUIRY INTO MODERN CONTRACTUAL RELATIONS (1980). In addition, in the last forty years there have been several notable books discussing the policy and theory of contract. At the core of all has been concern about promises and the permissible scope of freedom of contract. Interesting contrasts include CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE: A THEORY OF CONTRACTUAL OBLIGATION (1981) , GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (2d ed. 1995), and HAROLD C. HAVIGHURST, THE NATURE OF PRIVATE CONTRACT (1961). Since 1990 there have been five additions to the contracts academic library: E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CHANGING YOUR MIND: THE LAW OF REGRETTED DECISIONS (1998); JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991); ROBERT A. HILLMAN, THE RICHNESS OF CONTRACT LAW: AN ANALYSIS AND CRITIQUE OF CONTEMPORARY THEORIES OF CONTRACT LAW (1997); W. DAVID SLAWSON, BINDING PROMISES: THE LATE 20TH CENTURY REFORMATION OF CONTRACT LAW (1996); MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, THE LIMITS OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT (1993).
    • (1981) Contract as Promise: A Theory of Contractual Obligation
    • Fried, C.1
  • 3
    • 0003726851 scopus 로고
    • See IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT: AN INQUIRY INTO MODERN CONTRACTUAL RELATIONS (1980). In addition, in the last forty years there have been several notable books discussing the policy and theory of contract. At the core of all has been concern about promises and the permissible scope of freedom of contract. Interesting contrasts include CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE: A THEORY OF CONTRACTUAL OBLIGATION (1981) , GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (2d ed. 1995), and HAROLD C. HAVIGHURST, THE NATURE OF PRIVATE CONTRACT (1961). Since 1990 there have been five additions to the contracts academic library: E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CHANGING YOUR MIND: THE LAW OF REGRETTED DECISIONS (1998); JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991); ROBERT A. HILLMAN, THE RICHNESS OF CONTRACT LAW: AN ANALYSIS AND CRITIQUE OF CONTEMPORARY THEORIES OF CONTRACT LAW (1997); W. DAVID SLAWSON, BINDING PROMISES: THE LATE 20TH CENTURY REFORMATION OF CONTRACT LAW (1996); MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, THE LIMITS OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT (1993).
    • (1995) The Death of Contract 2d Ed.
    • Gilmore, G.1
  • 4
    • 0041576961 scopus 로고
    • See IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT: AN INQUIRY INTO MODERN CONTRACTUAL RELATIONS (1980). In addition, in the last forty years there have been several notable books discussing the policy and theory of contract. At the core of all has been concern about promises and the permissible scope of freedom of contract. Interesting contrasts include CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE: A THEORY OF CONTRACTUAL OBLIGATION (1981) , GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (2d ed. 1995), and HAROLD C. HAVIGHURST, THE NATURE OF PRIVATE CONTRACT (1961). Since 1990 there have been five additions to the contracts academic library: E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CHANGING YOUR MIND: THE LAW OF REGRETTED DECISIONS (1998); JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991); ROBERT A. HILLMAN, THE RICHNESS OF CONTRACT LAW: AN ANALYSIS AND CRITIQUE OF CONTEMPORARY THEORIES OF CONTRACT LAW (1997); W. DAVID SLAWSON, BINDING PROMISES: THE LATE 20TH CENTURY REFORMATION OF CONTRACT LAW (1996); MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, THE LIMITS OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT (1993).
    • (1961) The Nature of Private Contract
    • Havighurst, H.C.1
  • 5
    • 0009196298 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT: AN INQUIRY INTO MODERN CONTRACTUAL RELATIONS (1980). In addition, in the last forty years there have been several notable books discussing the policy and theory of contract. At the core of all has been concern about promises and the permissible scope of freedom of contract. Interesting contrasts include CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE: A THEORY OF CONTRACTUAL OBLIGATION (1981) , GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (2d ed. 1995), and HAROLD C. HAVIGHURST, THE NATURE OF PRIVATE CONTRACT (1961). Since 1990 there have been five additions to the contracts academic library: E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CHANGING YOUR MIND: THE LAW OF REGRETTED DECISIONS (1998); JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991); ROBERT A. HILLMAN, THE RICHNESS OF CONTRACT LAW: AN ANALYSIS AND CRITIQUE OF CONTEMPORARY THEORIES OF CONTRACT LAW (1997); W. DAVID SLAWSON, BINDING PROMISES: THE LATE 20TH CENTURY REFORMATION OF CONTRACT LAW (1996); MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, THE LIMITS OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT (1993).
    • (1998) Changing Your Mind: the Law of Regretted Decisions
    • Farnsworth, E.A.1
  • 6
    • 0003672634 scopus 로고
    • See IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT: AN INQUIRY INTO MODERN CONTRACTUAL RELATIONS (1980). In addition, in the last forty years there have been several notable books discussing the policy and theory of contract. At the core of all has been concern about promises and the permissible scope of freedom of contract. Interesting contrasts include CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE: A THEORY OF CONTRACTUAL OBLIGATION (1981) , GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (2d ed. 1995), and HAROLD C. HAVIGHURST, THE NATURE OF PRIVATE CONTRACT (1961). Since 1990 there have been five additions to the contracts academic library: E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CHANGING YOUR MIND: THE LAW OF REGRETTED DECISIONS (1998); JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991); ROBERT A. HILLMAN, THE RICHNESS OF CONTRACT LAW: AN ANALYSIS AND CRITIQUE OF CONTEMPORARY THEORIES OF CONTRACT LAW (1997); W. DAVID SLAWSON, BINDING PROMISES: THE LATE 20TH CENTURY REFORMATION OF CONTRACT LAW (1996); MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, THE LIMITS OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT (1993).
    • (1991) The Philosophical Origins of Modern Contract Doctrine
    • Gordley, J.1
  • 7
    • 0013325610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT: AN INQUIRY INTO MODERN CONTRACTUAL RELATIONS (1980). In addition, in the last forty years there have been several notable books discussing the policy and theory of contract. At the core of all has been concern about promises and the permissible scope of freedom of contract. Interesting contrasts include CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE: A THEORY OF CONTRACTUAL OBLIGATION (1981) , GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (2d ed. 1995), and HAROLD C. HAVIGHURST, THE NATURE OF PRIVATE CONTRACT (1961). Since 1990 there have been five additions to the contracts academic library: E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CHANGING YOUR MIND: THE LAW OF REGRETTED DECISIONS (1998); JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991); ROBERT A. HILLMAN, THE RICHNESS OF CONTRACT LAW: AN ANALYSIS AND CRITIQUE OF CONTEMPORARY THEORIES OF CONTRACT LAW (1997); W. DAVID SLAWSON, BINDING PROMISES: THE LATE 20TH CENTURY REFORMATION OF CONTRACT LAW (1996); MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, THE LIMITS OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT (1993).
    • (1997) The Richness of Contract Law: An Analysis and Critique of Contemporary Theories of Contract Law
    • Hillman, R.A.1
  • 8
    • 0003607871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT: AN INQUIRY INTO MODERN CONTRACTUAL RELATIONS (1980). In addition, in the last forty years there have been several notable books discussing the policy and theory of contract. At the core of all has been concern about promises and the permissible scope of freedom of contract. Interesting contrasts include CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE: A THEORY OF CONTRACTUAL OBLIGATION (1981) , GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (2d ed. 1995), and HAROLD C. HAVIGHURST, THE NATURE OF PRIVATE CONTRACT (1961). Since 1990 there have been five additions to the contracts academic library: E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CHANGING YOUR MIND: THE LAW OF REGRETTED DECISIONS (1998); JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991); ROBERT A. HILLMAN, THE RICHNESS OF CONTRACT LAW: AN ANALYSIS AND CRITIQUE OF CONTEMPORARY THEORIES OF CONTRACT LAW (1997); W. DAVID SLAWSON, BINDING PROMISES: THE LATE 20TH CENTURY REFORMATION OF CONTRACT LAW (1996); MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, THE LIMITS OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT (1993).
    • (1996) Binding Promises: The Late 20th Century Reformation of Contract Law
    • Slawson, W.D.1
  • 9
    • 0004140491 scopus 로고
    • See IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT: AN INQUIRY INTO MODERN CONTRACTUAL RELATIONS (1980). In addition, in the last forty years there have been several notable books discussing the policy and theory of contract. At the core of all has been concern about promises and the permissible scope of freedom of contract. Interesting contrasts include CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE: A THEORY OF CONTRACTUAL OBLIGATION (1981) , GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (2d ed. 1995), and HAROLD C. HAVIGHURST, THE NATURE OF PRIVATE CONTRACT (1961). Since 1990 there have been five additions to the contracts academic library: E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CHANGING YOUR MIND: THE LAW OF REGRETTED DECISIONS (1998); JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991); ROBERT A. HILLMAN, THE RICHNESS OF CONTRACT LAW: AN ANALYSIS AND CRITIQUE OF CONTEMPORARY THEORIES OF CONTRACT LAW (1997); W. DAVID SLAWSON, BINDING PROMISES: THE LATE 20TH CENTURY REFORMATION OF CONTRACT LAW (1996); MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK, THE LIMITS OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT (1993).
    • (1993) The Limits of Freedom of Contract
    • Trebilcock, M.J.1
  • 10
    • 0000073663 scopus 로고
    • Contracts: Adjustment of long-term economic relations under classical, neoclassical, and relational contract law
    • See Ian R. Macneil, Contracts: Adjustment of Long-Term Economic Relations Under Classical, Neoclassical, and Relational Contract Law, 72 NW. U. L. REV. 854 (1978).
    • (1978) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 854
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 11
    • 84881962199 scopus 로고
    • Problematic relations: Franchising and the law of incomplete contracts
    • See Gillian K. Hadfield, Problematic Relations: Franchising and the Law of Incomplete Contracts, 42 STAN. L. REV. 927 (1990).
    • (1990) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.42 , pp. 927
    • Hadfield, G.K.1
  • 12
    • 0347669716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Marriage as relational contract
    • See Elizabeth S. Scott & Robert E. Scott, Marriage as Relational Contract, 84 VA. L. REV. 1225 (1998).
    • (1998) Va. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 1225
    • Scott, E.S.1    Scott, R.E.2
  • 13
    • 0007116619 scopus 로고
    • A primer of contract planning
    • See Ian R. Macneil, A Primer of Contract Planning, 48 S. CAL. L. REV. 627 (1975).
    • (1975) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 627
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 14
    • 0041577019 scopus 로고
    • Restatement (second) of contracts and presentiation
    • Ian R. Macneil, RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS and Presentiation, 60 VA. L. REV. 589 (1974).
    • (1974) Va. L. Rev. , vol.60 , pp. 589
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 15
    • 84919438892 scopus 로고
    • Book review: The resurrection of contract
    • Lewis Kornhauser, Book Review: The Resurrection of Contract, 82 COLUM. L. REV. 184, 188 (1990).
    • (1990) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 184
    • Kornhauser, L.1
  • 16
    • 0041576958 scopus 로고
    • Conflicting visions: A critique of ian macneil's relational theory of contract
    • Professor Barnett, a "rights" theorist, criticizes Macneil for downplaying the importance of consent in relational contracts and by neglecting the relationship between contracts and property. Randy E. Barnett, Conflicting Visions: A Critique of Ian Macneil's Relational Theory of Contract, 78 VA. L. REV. 1175 (1992).
    • (1992) Va. L. Rev. , vol.78 , pp. 1175
    • Barnett, R.E.1
  • 17
    • 0042078007 scopus 로고
    • Article 2 and relational sales contracts
    • Richard E. Speidel, Article 2 and Relational Sales Contracts, 26 LOY. L.A. L. REV. 789 (1993). See also Symposium, Law, Private Governance and Continuing Relationships, 1985 WIS. L. REV. 483-579 (selected bibliography in app. A). The existence and importance of relational contracts in the real world has also been verified in an interesting empirical study. See Russell J. Weintraub, A Survey of Contract Practice and Policy, 1992 WIS. L. REV. 1, 16-24.
    • (1993) Loy. L.a. L. Rev. , vol.26 , pp. 789
    • Speidel, R.E.1
  • 18
    • 0041576959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Symposium, Law, private governance and continuing relationships
    • selected bibliography in app. A
    • Richard E. Speidel, Article 2 and Relational Sales Contracts, 26 LOY. L.A. L. REV. 789 (1993). See also Symposium, Law, Private Governance and Continuing Relationships, 1985 WIS. L. REV. 483-579 (selected bibliography in app. A). The existence and importance of relational contracts in the real world has also been verified in an interesting empirical study. See Russell J. Weintraub, A Survey of Contract Practice and Policy, 1992 WIS. L. REV. 1, 16-24.
    • Wis. L. Rev. , vol.1985 , pp. 483-579
  • 19
    • 0042237540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A survey of contract practice and policy
    • Richard E. Speidel, Article 2 and Relational Sales Contracts, 26 LOY. L.A. L. REV. 789 (1993). See also Symposium, Law, Private Governance and Continuing Relationships, 1985 WIS. L. REV. 483-579 (selected bibliography in app. A). The existence and importance of relational contracts in the real world has also been verified in an interesting empirical study. See Russell J. Weintraub, A Survey of Contract Practice and Policy, 1992 WIS. L. REV. 1, 16-24.
    • Wis. L. Rev. , vol.1992 , pp. 1
    • Weintraub, R.J.1
  • 20
    • 0042078010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McGinnis v. Cayton, 312 S.E.2d 765 (W. Va. 1984)
    • A Westlaw search of the ALLSTATES and ALLFEDS databases uncovered only one case of significance where the work of Ian R. Macneil was cited or relational contract scholarship was explicitly discussed. See McGinnis v. Cayton, 312 S.E.2d 765 (W. Va. 1984). See also Nathan M. Crystal, An Empirical View of Relational Contracts Under Article Two of the Uniform Commercial Code, 1988 ANN. SURV. AM. L. 293, 303 (1988) (concluding that reported decisions under Article 2 of the U.C.C. from its inception to 1987 show a "predominance of discrete over relational contracts in litigated cases").
  • 21
    • 0041576956 scopus 로고
    • An empirical view of relational contracts under article two of the uniform commercial code
    • A Westlaw search of the ALLSTATES and ALLFEDS databases uncovered only one case of significance where the work of Ian R. Macneil was cited or relational contract scholarship was explicitly discussed. See McGinnis v. Cayton, 312 S.E.2d 765 (W. Va. 1984). See also Nathan M. Crystal, An Empirical View of Relational Contracts Under Article Two of the Uniform Commercial Code, 1988 ANN. SURV. AM. L. 293, 303 (1988) (concluding that reported decisions under Article 2 of the U.C.C. from its inception to 1987 show a "predominance of discrete over relational contracts in litigated cases").
    • (1988) Ann. Surv. Am. L. , vol.1988 , pp. 293
    • Crystal, N.M.1
  • 22
    • 0041576960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 1, at 241-66
    • By "modern" (or neo-classical) contract law, I mean the rules and standards found in Article 2 of the Uniform Commercial Code and the Restatement, Second, of Contracts. See HILLMAN, supra note 1, at 241-66 (comparing relational contract theory with neo-classical doctrine).
    • Hillman1
  • 23
    • 0043079812 scopus 로고
    • Restatement second: Omitted terms and contract method
    • Praise (or blame) for establishing the significance of this vital link goes to the realists. See Richard E. Speidel, Restatement Second: Omitted Terms and Contract Method, 67 CORNELL L. REV. 785, 786-92 (1982). See also James J. White, Legal Realism: Promise Fulfilled and Principle Betrayed, 1988 ANN. SURV. AM. L. 7 (1989).
    • (1982) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 785
    • Speidel, R.E.1
  • 24
    • 0041576945 scopus 로고
    • Legal realism: Promise fulfilled and principle betrayed
    • Praise (or blame) for establishing the significance of this vital link goes to the realists. See Richard E. Speidel, Restatement Second: Omitted Terms and Contract Method, 67 CORNELL L. REV. 785, 786-92 (1982). See also James J. White, Legal Realism: Promise Fulfilled and Principle Betrayed, 1988 ANN. SURV. AM. L. 7 (1989).
    • (1989) Ann. Surv. Am. L. , vol.1988 , pp. 7
    • White, J.J.1
  • 25
    • 0043079797 scopus 로고
    • This starting point is dictated by the promise-based theory of the RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS. Under the Restatement approach, the core questions to be considered in establishing liability are whether there was a promise, whether the promise was part of an offer and acceptance, and whether the promise was supported by consideration or induced reliance. See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS §§ 1-5, 71, 90 (1981).
    • (1981) Restatement (Second) of Contracts §§ , pp. 1-5
  • 26
    • 0041576944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 12
    • See Speidel, supra note 12.
    • Speidel1
  • 27
    • 0042579064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., U.C.C. §§ 2-201(3), 1-205, 2-202, 2-208 (1998)
    • See, e.g., U.C.C. §§ 2-201(3), 1-205, 2-202, 2-208 (1998).
  • 28
    • 0041576939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reflections upon commercial context and the judicial process
    • See Richard E. Speidel, Contract Law: Some Reflections Upon Commercial Context and the Judicial Process, 1967 WIS. L. REV. 822, 829-832. The realist approach, attributable to Karl N. Llewellyn, has been criticized as resting on a "triad of dubious assumptions that self-evident ideal resolutions or situational problems exists, that they can be discovered by careful scrutiny of actual situations, and that once articulated they will be widely accepted." Richard Danzig, A Comment on the Jurisprudence of the Uniform Commercial Code, 27 STAN. L. REV. 621, 635 (1975). More recently, Dean Robert E. Scott has argued that, by and large, the courts under Article 2 have rejected the invitation to travel back along the vital link into the commercial context. Robert E. Scott, The Case for Formalism in Relational Contract, 94 NW. U. L. REV. 847 (2000).
    • Wis. L. Rev. , vol.1967 , pp. 822
    • Some, C.L.1
  • 29
    • 0043079851 scopus 로고
    • A comment on the jurisprudence of the uniform commercial code
    • See Richard E. Speidel, Contract Law: Some Reflections Upon Commercial Context and the Judicial Process, 1967 WIS. L. REV. 822, 829-832. The realist approach, attributable to Karl N. Llewellyn, has been criticized as resting on a "triad of dubious assumptions that self-evident ideal resolutions or situational problems exists, that they can be discovered by careful scrutiny of actual situations, and that once articulated they will be widely accepted." Richard Danzig, A Comment on the Jurisprudence of the Uniform Commercial Code, 27 STAN. L. REV. 621, 635 (1975). More recently, Dean Robert E. Scott has argued that, by and large, the courts under Article 2 have rejected the invitation to travel back along the vital link into the commercial context. Robert E. Scott, The Case for Formalism in Relational Contract, 94 NW. U. L. REV. 847 (2000).
    • (1975) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.27 , pp. 621
    • Danzig, R.1
  • 30
    • 0038016314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The case for formalism in relational contract
    • See Richard E. Speidel, Contract Law: Some Reflections Upon Commercial Context and the Judicial Process, 1967 WIS. L. REV. 822, 829-832. The realist approach, attributable to Karl N. Llewellyn, has been criticized as resting on a "triad of dubious assumptions that self-evident ideal resolutions or situational problems exists, that they can be discovered by careful scrutiny of actual situations, and that once articulated they will be widely accepted." Richard Danzig, A Comment on the Jurisprudence of the Uniform Commercial Code, 27 STAN. L. REV. 621, 635 (1975). More recently, Dean Robert E. Scott has argued that, by and large, the courts under Article 2 have rejected the invitation to travel back along the vital link into the commercial context. Robert E. Scott, The Case for Formalism in Relational Contract, 94 NW. U. L. REV. 847 (2000).
    • (2000) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 847
    • Scott, R.E.1
  • 31
    • 0007058536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An empirical view of contracts
    • See Stewart Macaulay, An Empirical View of Contracts, 1985 WIS. L. REV. 463.
    • Wis. L. Rev. , vol.1985 , pp. 463
    • Macaulay, S.1
  • 33
    • 0000900683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relational contract theory: Challenges and queries
    • Ian R. Macneil, Relational Contract Theory: Challenges and Queries, 94 NW. U. L. REV. 877 (2000).
    • (2000) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 877
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 34
    • 22444453012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relational contract theory and the concept of exchange
    • See Paul J. Gudel, Relational Contract Theory and the Concept of Exchange, 46 BUFF. L. REV. 763, 771-72 (1998) (describing the relationships in an employment contract terminated at will).
    • (1998) Buff. L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 763
    • Gudel, P.J.1
  • 35
    • 0011077160 scopus 로고
    • Relational contract theory as sociology: A reply to professors lindenberg and de vos
    • See Ian R. Macneil, Relational Contract Theory as Sociology: A Reply to Professors Lindenberg and de Vos, 143 J. INSTITUTIONAL & THEORETICAL ECON. 272 (1987).
    • (1987) J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. , vol.143 , pp. 272
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 36
    • 0041576937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 273-76
    • See id. at 273-76.
  • 37
    • 0042077738 scopus 로고
    • Relational contract and default rules
    • In essence, "default" rules operate in the absence of enforceable agreements to the contrary and perform two basic functions. First, they supply terms to fill gaps in the agreement. Second, they supply the legal principles of contract formation, interpretation, performance, and remedy. The question is whether the default rules for relational contracts should be different from those for discrete contracts. See Jay M. Feinman, Relational Contract and Default Rules, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 91 (1993).
    • (1993) S. Cal. Interdisc. L.J. , vol.3 , pp. 91
    • Feinman, J.M.1
  • 38
    • 0042077998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This course of dealing may be the source of norms and expectations that carry from one short term deal to the next. See U.C.C. § 1-205 (1998)
    • This course of dealing may be the source of norms and expectations that carry from one short term deal to the next. See U.C.C. § 1-205 (1998).
  • 39
    • 0000450443 scopus 로고
    • Principles of relational contracts
    • The consequences of extended duration are well discussed in Charles Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Principles of Relational Contracts, 67 VA. L. REV. 1089 (1981). See also Robert A. Hillman, An Analysis of the Cessation of Contractual Relations, 68 CORNELL L. REV. 617 (1983) (discussing termination clauses).
    • (1981) Va. L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 1089
    • Goetz, C.1    Scott, R.E.2
  • 40
    • 84926272438 scopus 로고
    • An analysis of the cessation of contractual relations
    • The consequences of extended duration are well discussed in Charles Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Principles of Relational Contracts, 67 VA. L. REV. 1089 (1981). See also Robert A. Hillman, An Analysis of the Cessation of Contractual Relations, 68 CORNELL L. REV. 617 (1983) (discussing termination clauses).
    • (1983) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.68 , pp. 617
    • Hillman, R.A.1
  • 41
    • 0043079780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An excellent example is Northern Indiana Public Service Co. v. Carbon County Coal Co., 799 F.2d 265 (7th Cir. 1986), where the parties entered into a twenty-year contract without a termination clause for the sale of a fixed quantity of coal each year at a fixed price with upward escalation. When the market price of coal (and other energy sources) dropped well below the contract price, the court held that the buyer, NIPSCO, was not excused from the contract because the risk had been allocated to it by the contract. The court awarded Carbon County damages rather than specific performance, noting that the workers and merchants at Carbon County's mine who had relied on the long-term contract assumed the risk that the mine would close down if it became uneconomical. See id. 27 See Victor Goldberg, Price Adjustment in Long-Term Contracts, 1985 WIS. L. REV. 527 (arguing that incentive to engaged in opportunistic behavior increases as divergence between contract price and market alternatives increases).
  • 42
    • 0042579057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5th ed.
    • Such a clause is reprinted in EDWARD J. MURPHY ET AL., STUDIES IN CONTRACT LAW 746-47 (5th ed. 1997). See Robert E. Scott, Conflict and Cooperation in Long-Term Contracts, 75 CAL. L. REV. 2005 (1987).
    • (1997) Studies In Contract Law , pp. 746-747
    • Murphy, E.J.1
  • 43
    • 84934349166 scopus 로고
    • Conflict and cooperation in long-term contracts
    • Such a clause is reprinted in EDWARD J. MURPHY ET AL., STUDIES IN CONTRACT LAW 746-47 (5th ed. 1997). See Robert E. Scott, Conflict and Cooperation in Long-Term Contracts, 75 CAL. L. REV. 2005 (1987).
    • (1987) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 2005
    • Scott, R.E.1
  • 44
    • 0043079778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Oglebay Norton Co. v. Armco, Inc., 556 N.E.2d 515 (Ohio 1990) (discussed infra note 37)
    • See Oglebay Norton Co. v. Armco, Inc., 556 N.E.2d 515 (Ohio 1990) (discussed infra note 37).
  • 45
    • 0042579055 scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS §§ 272(1), 240, 377 (1981). If a contract is discharged for impracticability, however, justice may require protection of the parties' reliance interests. Id. § 272(2).
    • (1981) Restatement (Second) Of Contracts §§ , vol.272 , Issue.1 , pp. 240
  • 46
    • 0041576934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 21, at 275-76
    • Macneil identifies two other characteristics of relational contracts that will not be discussed here: (1) trouble is expected as a matter of course, and (2) the relationship apart from the exchange has independent value. The former encourages the parties to plan for dispute resolution and the latter helps to explain why parties to an extended relationship are willing to share risks and engage in cooperative behavior. See Macneil, supra note 21, at 275-76.
    • Macneil1
  • 47
    • 84933490573 scopus 로고
    • Third-party beneficiaries
    • See generally Melvin A. Eisenberg, Third-Party Beneficiaries, 92 COLUM. L. REV. 1358 (1992).
    • (1992) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 1358
    • Eisenberg, M.A.1
  • 48
    • 21344448861 scopus 로고
    • Take the money and stay: Industrial location incentives and relational contracting
    • Note
    • Joshua P. Rubin, Note, Take the Money and Stay: Industrial Location Incentives and Relational Contracting, 70 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1277 (1995).
    • (1995) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 1277
    • Rubin, J.P.1
  • 49
    • 0043079772 scopus 로고
    • Warranty theory, economic loss, and the privity requirement: Once more into the void
    • See Richard E. Speidel, Warranty Theory, Economic Loss, and the Privity Requirement: Once More into the Void, 67 B.U. L. REV. 9 (1987).
    • (1987) B.U. L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 9
    • Speidel, R.E.1
  • 50
    • 0003531998 scopus 로고
    • There is an extensive literature on the relational dimensions of business organizations. See, e.g., OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM: FIRMS, MARKETS, RELATIONAL CONTRACTING (1985); Victor Brudney, Corporate Governance, Agency Costs, and the Rhetoric of Contract, 85 COLUM. L. REV.1403 (1985); John P. Esser, Institutionalizing Industry: The Changing Forms of Contract, 21 L. & SOC. INQUIRY 593 (1996); Robert W. Hillman, Private Ordering Within Partnerships, 41 U. MIAMI L. REV. 425 (1987); Steven R. Salbu, The Decline of Contract as a Relationship Management Form, 47 RUTGERS L. REV. 1271 (1995); Steven R. Salbu, Joint Venture Contracts as Strategic Tools, 25 IND. L. REV. 397 (1991).
    • (1985) The Economic Institutions Of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 51
    • 84928216925 scopus 로고
    • Corporate governance, agency costs, and the rhetoric of contract
    • There is an extensive literature on the relational dimensions of business organizations. See, e.g., OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM: FIRMS, MARKETS, RELATIONAL CONTRACTING (1985); Victor Brudney, Corporate Governance, Agency Costs, and the Rhetoric of Contract, 85 COLUM. L. REV.1403 (1985); John P. Esser, Institutionalizing Industry: The Changing Forms of Contract, 21 L. & SOC. INQUIRY 593 (1996); Robert W. Hillman, Private Ordering Within Partnerships, 41 U. MIAMI L. REV. 425 (1987); Steven R. Salbu, The Decline of Contract as a Relationship Management Form, 47 RUTGERS L. REV. 1271 (1995); Steven R. Salbu, Joint Venture Contracts as Strategic Tools, 25 IND. L. REV. 397 (1991).
    • (1985) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.85 , pp. 1403
    • Brudney, V.1
  • 52
    • 9944251066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutionalizing industry: The changing forms of contract
    • There is an extensive literature on the relational dimensions of business organizations. See, e.g., OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM: FIRMS, MARKETS, RELATIONAL CONTRACTING (1985); Victor Brudney, Corporate Governance, Agency Costs, and the Rhetoric of Contract, 85 COLUM. L. REV.1403 (1985); John P. Esser, Institutionalizing Industry: The Changing Forms of Contract, 21 L. & SOC. INQUIRY 593 (1996); Robert W. Hillman, Private Ordering Within Partnerships, 41 U. MIAMI L. REV. 425 (1987); Steven R. Salbu, The Decline of Contract as a Relationship Management Form, 47 RUTGERS L. REV. 1271 (1995); Steven R. Salbu, Joint Venture Contracts as Strategic Tools, 25 IND. L. REV. 397 (1991).
    • (1996) L. & Soc. Inquiry , vol.21 , pp. 593
    • Esser, J.P.1
  • 53
    • 0043079769 scopus 로고
    • Private ordering within partnerships
    • There is an extensive literature on the relational dimensions of business organizations. See, e.g., OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM: FIRMS, MARKETS, RELATIONAL CONTRACTING (1985); Victor Brudney, Corporate Governance, Agency Costs, and the Rhetoric of Contract, 85 COLUM. L. REV.1403 (1985); John P. Esser, Institutionalizing Industry: The Changing Forms of Contract, 21 L. & SOC. INQUIRY 593 (1996); Robert W. Hillman, Private Ordering Within Partnerships, 41 U. MIAMI L. REV. 425 (1987); Steven R. Salbu, The Decline of Contract as a Relationship Management Form, 47 RUTGERS L. REV. 1271 (1995); Steven R. Salbu, Joint Venture Contracts as Strategic Tools, 25 IND. L. REV. 397 (1991).
    • (1987) U. Miami L. Rev. , vol.41 , pp. 425
    • Hillman, R.W.1
  • 54
    • 0039561123 scopus 로고
    • The decline of contract as a relationship management form
    • There is an extensive literature on the relational dimensions of business organizations. See, e.g., OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM: FIRMS, MARKETS, RELATIONAL CONTRACTING (1985); Victor Brudney, Corporate Governance, Agency Costs, and the Rhetoric of Contract, 85 COLUM. L. REV.1403 (1985); John P. Esser, Institutionalizing Industry: The Changing Forms of Contract, 21 L. & SOC. INQUIRY 593 (1996); Robert W. Hillman, Private Ordering Within Partnerships, 41 U. MIAMI L. REV. 425 (1987); Steven R. Salbu, The Decline of Contract as a Relationship Management Form, 47 RUTGERS L. REV. 1271 (1995); Steven R. Salbu, Joint Venture Contracts as Strategic Tools, 25 IND. L. REV. 397 (1991).
    • (1995) Rutgers L. Rev. , vol.47 , pp. 1271
    • Salbu, S.R.1
  • 55
    • 0042579044 scopus 로고
    • Joint venture contracts as strategic tools
    • There is an extensive literature on the relational dimensions of business organizations. See, e.g., OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM: FIRMS, MARKETS, RELATIONAL CONTRACTING (1985); Victor Brudney, Corporate Governance, Agency Costs, and the Rhetoric of Contract, 85 COLUM. L. REV.1403 (1985); John P. Esser, Institutionalizing Industry: The Changing Forms of Contract, 21 L. & SOC. INQUIRY 593 (1996); Robert W. Hillman, Private Ordering Within Partnerships, 41 U. MIAMI L. REV. 425 (1987); Steven R. Salbu, The Decline of Contract as a Relationship Management Form, 47 RUTGERS L. REV. 1271 (1995); Steven R. Salbu, Joint Venture Contracts as Strategic Tools, 25 IND. L. REV. 397 (1991).
    • (1991) Ind. L. Rev. , vol.25 , pp. 397
    • Salbu, S.R.1
  • 56
    • 0042579056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If the parties have failed adequately to plan for the relational contract or have failed to resolve a dispute by agreement, the ultimate policy question is whether contract law should impose further duties to preserve the relationship and facilitate further agreement. If the answer is no, the parties are left to their own devices. In short, the failure to plan or to agree in the relational contract leaves the parties with the nonrelational default rules of modern contract law.
  • 57
    • 0043079779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 556 N.E.2d 515 (Ohio 1990). Virtually no attention has been paid to this case in either the state or federal courts or the law reviews.
  • 58
    • 0041576932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The court noted that the "parties recognized that Oglebay could be required to ship up to 7.1 million gross tons of Armco iron ore per year." 556 N.E.2d at 519.
  • 59
    • 0041576933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 516
    • Id. at 516.
  • 60
    • 0042077983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is a perfect example of a transaction-specific investment. Whether the improvements would have aided Oglebay in contracts with other shippers is not clear from the opinion.
  • 61
    • 0043079773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 556 N.E.2d at 517
    • 556 N.E.2d at 517.
  • 62
    • 0042077995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The court does not elaborate. Presumably, the demand for steel dropped sharply. In addition, the court does not discuss whether Armco could have reduced its output of iron ore in good faith or whether the price of shipping iron ore on the Great Lakes was affected by the steel industry decline.
  • 63
    • 0041576935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Oglebay apparently accepted that substituted rate even though it was not satisfactory. It is not stated in the opinion how much ore was shipped that year.
  • 64
    • 0042077994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The parties continued performance during 1986, but at rates fixed by Armco.
  • 65
    • 0042077990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 556 N.E.2d at 519. U.C.C. section 2-305(1), which the court applied by analogy, provides that the parties, if they so intend, can "conclude a contract for sale even though the price is not settled." U.C.C. § 2-305(4) (1998). Further, if the "price is left to be agreed by the parties and they fail to agree," then the "price is a reasonable price at the time for delivery." Id. On the other hand, if the parties "intend not to be bound unless the price be fixed or agreed and it is not fixed or agreed, there is no contract." Id. See also U.C.C. § 2-204 (1998). Section 33(1) of the Restatement states that an offer cannot be accepted "unless the terms of the contract are reasonably certain." RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 33(1) (1981). Even so, a purported acceptance may not create a contract if open or uncertain terms "show that a manifestation of intention is not intended to be understood as an offer or as an acceptance." Id. § 33(2) (1981). Section 34(2) states that part performance may "establish that a contract enforceable as a bargain has been formed." Id. § 34(2) (1981). Despite the intention of the parties, the "reasonably certain" requirement in Section 33(1) must be satisfied, either by proof that there is a basis for "determining the existence of a breach and for giving an appropriate remedy," in Section 33(2), or from part performance. Id. § 34(2) (1981). Section 34(3) provides that "action in reliance on an agreement may make a contractual remedy appropriate even though uncertainty is not removed." Id. § 34(3) (1981).
  • 66
    • 0043027985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why there is no law of relational contracts
    • Professor Melvin Eisenberg has asserted that courts should not preserve contracts, whether or not they are relational. Melvin A. Eisenberg, Why There is No Law of Relational Contracts, 94 NW. U. L. REV. 805 (2000). This is clearly so if both parties agree before or after the judicial decision to terminate the contract. Where there is no agreement, however, relational characteristics such as transaction-specific investments and third-person involvement support an action to preserve the contract and intervene in some way to facilitate further agreement. That action may be followed by either an agreed termination or an agreed adjustment and continued performance.
    • (2000) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 805
    • Eisenberg, M.A.1
  • 67
    • 0042077991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.C.C. § 2-305(4) (1998)
    • See U.C.C. § 2-305(4) (1998).
  • 68
    • 0041576931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If Armco had breached the long-term contract, the remedy of specific performance would probably have been available to Oglebay. See Laclede Gas Co. v. Amoco Oil Co., 522 F.2d 33 (8th Cir. 1975). The court apparently declared that the contract still existed and ordered performance without determining whether either party was in breach. See Oglebay, 556 N.E.2d 515.
  • 69
    • 0043079774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 556 N.E.2d at 520
    • 556 N.E.2d at 520.
  • 70
    • 0041576925 scopus 로고
    • Enforcing the contract to bargain
    • See Charles L. Knapp, Enforcing the Contract to Bargain, 44 N.Y.U. L. REV. 673 (1969). Knapp argues that where the parties have agreed to agree and there is no agreement, the court ought not to fill the gap with a reasonable term unless the party has failed to agree in bad faith. The court must first know and evaluate the reasons why the agreement failed. Id. 51 Suppose that there was no agreement to agree if the external price mechanism failed. Should a duty be imposed anyway? Could it emerge as an internal norm over time?
    • (1969) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.44 , pp. 673
    • Knapp, C.L.1
  • 71
    • 0043079762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oglebay Norton Co. v. Armco Inc., 556 N.E.2d 515, 521 (Ohio 1990)
    • Oglebay Norton Co. v. Armco Inc., 556 N.E.2d 515, 521 (Ohio 1990).
  • 72
    • 0042077970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Equity's modification of contract: An analysis of the twentieth century's equitable reformation of contract law
    • See generally Larry A. Dimatteo, Equity's Modification of Contract: An Analysis of the Twentieth Century's Equitable Reformation of Contract Law, 33 NEW ENG. L. REV. 265 (1999) (reviewing exercising of equitable powers to modify contracts).
    • (1999) New Eng. L. Rev. , vol.33 , pp. 265
    • Dimatteo, L.A.1
  • 73
    • 0000218023 scopus 로고
    • Relational contracts in the courts: An analysis of incomplete agreements and judicial strategies
    • See Alan Schwartz, Relational Contracts in the Courts: An Analysis of Incomplete Agreements and Judicial Strategies, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 271 (1992) (concluding that courts, lacking sufficient information about party intent and market alternatives, are reluctant to intervene if the parties have failed to agree).
    • (1992) J. Legal Stud. , vol.21 , pp. 271
    • Schwartz, A.1
  • 74
    • 0042579162 scopus 로고
    • A relational theory of default rules for commercial contracts
    • See Robert E. Scott, A Relational Theory of Default Rules for Commercial Contracts, 19 J. LEGAL STUD. 597 (1990) (arguing for clear, categorical default rules that facilitate agreement but rely primarily on social rather than legal norms to promote risk sharing and adjustment).
    • (1990) J. Legal Stud. , vol.19 , pp. 597
    • Scott, R.E.1
  • 75
    • 0000073664 scopus 로고
    • Economic analysis of contractual relations: Its shortfalls and the need for a rich classificatory apparatus
    • n.20
    • Ian R. Macneil, Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for a Rich Classificatory Apparatus, 75 NW. U. L. REV. 1018, 1023, n.20 (1981). See also Steven Burton, Good Faith Performance of a Contract Within Article 2 of the Uniform Commercial Code, 67 IOWA L. REV. 1, 24 (1981) (opportunism recaptures gains "foregone at the time of contracting"); Timothy Muris, Opportunistic Behavior and the Law of Contracts, 65 MINN. L. REV. 521 (1981) (opportunism is behavior by party A which is contrary to party B's understanding but not necessarily contrary to the explicit terms of the agreement and which results in a transfer of resources).
    • (1981) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 1018
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 76
    • 0042579040 scopus 로고
    • Good faith performance of a contract within article 2 of the uniform commercial code
    • Ian R. Macneil, Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for a Rich Classificatory Apparatus, 75 NW. U. L. REV. 1018, 1023, n.20 (1981). See also Steven Burton, Good Faith Performance of a Contract Within Article 2 of the Uniform Commercial Code, 67 IOWA L. REV. 1, 24 (1981) (opportunism recaptures gains "foregone at the time of contracting"); Timothy Muris, Opportunistic Behavior and the Law of Contracts, 65 MINN. L. REV. 521 (1981) (opportunism is behavior by party A which is contrary to party B's understanding but not necessarily contrary to the explicit terms of the agreement and which results in a transfer of resources).
    • (1981) Iowa L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 1
    • Burton, S.1
  • 77
    • 0000036639 scopus 로고
    • Opportunistic behavior and the law of contracts
    • Ian R. Macneil, Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for a Rich Classificatory Apparatus, 75 NW. U. L. REV. 1018, 1023, n.20 (1981). See also Steven Burton, Good Faith Performance of a Contract Within Article 2 of the Uniform Commercial Code, 67 IOWA L. REV. 1, 24 (1981) (opportunism recaptures gains "foregone at the time of contracting"); Timothy Muris, Opportunistic Behavior and the Law of Contracts, 65 MINN. L. REV. 521 (1981) (opportunism is behavior by party A which is contrary to party B's understanding but not necessarily contrary to the explicit terms of the agreement and which results in a transfer of resources).
    • (1981) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.65 , pp. 521
    • Muris, T.1
  • 78
    • 0040310900 scopus 로고
    • Court-imposed price adjustments under long-term supply contracts
    • In Aluminum Co. of America v. Essex Group, Inc., 499 F. Supp. 53 (W.D. Pa. 1980), a highly relational contract was disrupted when unexpected events (e.g., the Arab oil embargo, inflation) dramatically increased the cost of energy and caused a negotiated price escalation clause to fail the purpose for which it was intended. The result was that Alcoa incurred substantial financial losses and Essex, because of a dramatic increase in the market price over the contract price for the services supplied, received a windfall. Alcoa claimed that it was excused from performance and that the contract should be discharged. Essex disagreed and filed a declaratory judgment action. The court held that the changed circumstances entitled Alcoa to "some relief" but refused to discharge the balance of the contract. Rather, the court, in effect, preserved the contract and supplied a new price term to supplant the failed escalation clause. This was done in the interest of avoiding hardship and preserving expectations, as part of what the court called a "new spirit" of contract. 499 F. Supp. at 91-92. I have argued elsewhere that this "new spirit of contract" is, in essence, relational contract theory, and that the result in this case was justified on the facts. See Richard E. Speidel, Court-Imposed Price Adjustments Under Long-Term Supply Contracts, 76 NW. U. L. REV. 369 (1981); Richard E. Speidel, The New Spirit of Contract, 2 J.L. & COM. 193 (1982). See also Mark P. Gergen, A Defense of Judicial Reconstruction of Contracts, 71 IND. L.J. 45 (1995).
    • (1981) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 369
    • Speidel, R.E.1
  • 79
    • 0043079749 scopus 로고
    • The new spirit of contract
    • In Aluminum Co. of America v. Essex Group, Inc., 499 F. Supp. 53 (W.D. Pa. 1980), a highly relational contract was disrupted when unexpected events (e.g., the Arab oil embargo, inflation) dramatically increased the cost of energy and caused a negotiated price escalation clause to fail the purpose for which it was intended. The result was that Alcoa incurred substantial financial losses and Essex, because of a dramatic increase in the market price over the contract price for the services supplied, received a windfall. Alcoa claimed that it was excused from performance and that the contract should be discharged. Essex disagreed and filed a declaratory judgment action. The court held that the changed circumstances entitled Alcoa to "some relief" but refused to discharge the balance of the contract. Rather, the court, in effect, preserved the contract and supplied a new price term to supplant the failed escalation clause. This was done in the interest of avoiding hardship and preserving expectations, as part of what the court called a "new spirit" of contract. 499 F. Supp. at 91-92. I have argued elsewhere that this "new spirit of contract" is, in essence, relational contract theory, and that the result in this case was justified on the facts. See Richard E. Speidel, Court-Imposed Price Adjustments Under Long-Term Supply Contracts, 76 NW. U. L. REV. 369 (1981); Richard E. Speidel, The New Spirit of Contract, 2 J.L. & COM. 193 (1982). See also Mark P. Gergen, A Defense of Judicial Reconstruction of Contracts, 71 IND. L.J. 45 (1995).
    • (1982) J.l. & Com. , vol.2 , pp. 193
    • Speidel, R.E.1
  • 80
    • 21844510405 scopus 로고
    • A defense of judicial reconstruction of contracts
    • In Aluminum Co. of America v. Essex Group, Inc., 499 F. Supp. 53 (W.D. Pa. 1980), a highly relational contract was disrupted when unexpected events (e.g., the Arab oil embargo, inflation) dramatically increased the cost of energy and caused a negotiated price escalation clause to fail the purpose for which it was intended. The result was that Alcoa incurred substantial financial losses and Essex, because of a dramatic increase in the market price over the contract price for the services supplied, received a windfall. Alcoa claimed that it was excused from performance and that the contract should be discharged. Essex disagreed and filed a declaratory judgment action. The court held that the changed circumstances entitled Alcoa to "some relief" but refused to discharge the balance of the contract. Rather, the court, in effect, preserved the contract and supplied a new price term to supplant the failed escalation clause. This was done in the interest of avoiding hardship and preserving expectations, as part of what the court called a "new spirit" of contract. 499 F. Supp. at 91-92. I have argued elsewhere that this "new spirit of contract" is, in essence, relational contract theory, and that the result in this case was justified on the facts. See Richard E. Speidel, Court-Imposed Price Adjustments Under Long-Term Supply Contracts, 76 NW. U. L. REV. 369 (1981); Richard E. Speidel, The New Spirit of Contract, 2 J.L. & COM. 193 (1982). See also Mark P. Gergen, A Defense of Judicial Reconstruction of Contracts, 71 IND. L.J. 45 (1995).
    • (1995) Ind. L.J. , vol.71 , pp. 45
    • Gergen, M.P.1
  • 82
    • 0042077986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.C.C. § 1-203 (1998)
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 205 (1981); U.C.C. § 1-203 (1998).
  • 83
    • 0042077934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A comparative study of good faith, fair dealing, and precontractual liability
    • For an excellent study, see Nadia E. Nedzel, A Comparative Study of Good Faith, Fair Dealing, and Precontractual Liability, 12 TUL. EUR. & CIV. L. F. 97 (1997). The study discusses United States law. Id. at 102-09, 118-25, 149-50.
    • (1997) Tul. Eur. & Civ. L. F. , vol.12 , pp. 97
    • Nedzel, N.E.1
  • 84
    • 0043079767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 102-09, 118-25, 149-50
    • For an excellent study, see Nadia E. Nedzel, A Comparative Study of Good Faith, Fair Dealing, and Precontractual Liability, 12 TUL. EUR. & CIV. L. F. 97 (1997). The study discusses United States law. Id. at 102-09, 118-25, 149-50.
  • 85
    • 0041576920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United Airlines, Inc. v. Good Taste, Inc., 982 P.2d 1259 (Alaska 1999); cf. Sons of Thunder, Inc. v. Borden, Inc., 690 A.2d 575 (N.J. 1997) (holding that while termination was in good faith, there was bad faith in performance before the termination)
    • See United Airlines, Inc. v. Good Taste, Inc., 982 P.2d 1259 (Alaska 1999); cf. Sons of Thunder, Inc. v. Borden, Inc., 690 A.2d 575 (N.J. 1997) (holding that while termination was in good faith, there was bad faith in performance before the termination).
  • 86
    • 0041576922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Missouri Pub. Serv. Co. v. Peabody Coal Co., 583 S.W.2d 721 (Mo. App. 1979). The court stated: "Where an enforceable, untainted contract exists, refusing modification of price and seeking performance of valid covenants does not constitute bad faith or breach of contract." Id. at 725
    • See Missouri Pub. Serv. Co. v. Peabody Coal Co., 583 S.W.2d 721 (Mo. App. 1979). The court stated: "Where an enforceable, untainted contract exists, refusing modification of price and seeking performance of valid covenants does not constitute bad faith or breach of contract." Id. at 725.
  • 87
    • 21744444507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The "duty" of good faith in contract performance and enforcement
    • For a concise summary of the authorities and arguments, see Richard E. Speidel, The "Duty" of Good Faith in Contract Performance and Enforcement, 46 J. LEGAL ED. 537 (1996). See also STEVEN J. BURTON & ERIC G. ANDERSEN, CONTRACTUAL GOOD FAITH: FORMATION, PERFORMANCE, BREACH (1995).
    • (1996) J. Legal Ed. , vol.46 , pp. 537
    • Speidel, R.E.1
  • 89
    • 84882201231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The american provenance of the unidroit principles
    • The Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts were published in Rome by the International Institute for the Unification of Private Law in 1994. They are, on one level, an international restatement of contracts. They may also be adopted by the parties as the law of the transaction. See E. Allan Farnsworth, The American Provenance of the Unidroit Principles, 72 TUL. L. REV. 1985 (1998); Boris Kozolchyk, The Unidroit Principles as a Model for the Unification of the Best Contractual Practices in the Americas, 46 AM. J. COMP. L. 151 (1998); Joseph M. Perillo, Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts: The Black Letter Text and a Review, 63 FORDHAM L. REV. 281 (1994). The UNIDROIT Principles are reprinted in STEVEN J. BURTON & MELVIN A. EISENBERG, CONTRACT LAW: SELECTED SOURCE MATERIALS 333 (1999).
    • (1998) Tul. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 1985
    • Farnsworth, E.A.1
  • 90
    • 0346208568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The unidroit principles as a model for the unification of the best contractual practices in the Americas
    • The Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts were published in Rome by the International Institute for the Unification of Private Law in 1994. They are, on one level, an international restatement of contracts. They may also be adopted by the parties as the law of the transaction. See E. Allan Farnsworth, The American Provenance of the Unidroit Principles, 72 TUL. L. REV. 1985 (1998); Boris Kozolchyk, The Unidroit Principles as a Model for the Unification of the Best Contractual Practices in the Americas, 46 AM. J. COMP. L. 151 (1998); Joseph M. Perillo, Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts: The Black Letter Text and a Review, 63 FORDHAM L. REV. 281 (1994). The UNIDROIT Principles are reprinted in STEVEN J. BURTON & MELVIN A. EISENBERG, CONTRACT LAW: SELECTED SOURCE MATERIALS 333 (1999).
    • (1998) Am. J. Comp. L. , vol.46 , pp. 151
    • Kozolchyk, B.1
  • 91
    • 0042077966 scopus 로고
    • Unidroit principles of international commercial contracts: The black letter text and a review
    • The Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts were published in Rome by the International Institute for the Unification of Private Law in 1994. They are, on one level, an international restatement of contracts. They may also be adopted by the parties as the law of the transaction. See E. Allan Farnsworth, The American Provenance of the Unidroit Principles, 72 TUL. L. REV. 1985 (1998); Boris Kozolchyk, The Unidroit Principles as a Model for the Unification of the Best Contractual Practices in the Americas, 46 AM. J. COMP. L. 151 (1998); Joseph M. Perillo, Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts: The Black Letter Text and a Review, 63 FORDHAM L. REV. 281 (1994). The UNIDROIT Principles are reprinted in STEVEN J. BURTON & MELVIN A. EISENBERG, CONTRACT LAW: SELECTED SOURCE MATERIALS 333 (1999).
    • (1994) Fordham L. Rev. , vol.63 , pp. 281
    • Perillo, J.M.1
  • 92
    • 0041576918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The UNIDROIT Principles are reprinted
    • The Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts were published in Rome by the International Institute for the Unification of Private Law in 1994. They are, on one level, an international restatement of contracts. They may also be adopted by the parties as the law of the transaction. See E. Allan Farnsworth, The American Provenance of the Unidroit Principles, 72 TUL. L. REV. 1985 (1998); Boris Kozolchyk, The Unidroit Principles as a Model for the Unification of the Best Contractual Practices in the Americas, 46 AM. J. COMP. L. 151 (1998); Joseph M. Perillo, Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts: The Black Letter Text and a Review, 63 FORDHAM L. REV. 281 (1994). The UNIDROIT Principles are reprinted in STEVEN J. BURTON & MELVIN A. EISENBERG, CONTRACT LAW: SELECTED SOURCE MATERIALS 333 (1999).
    • (1999) Contract Law: Selected Source Materials , pp. 333
    • Burton, S.J.1    Eisenberg, M.A.2
  • 93
    • 0042579035 scopus 로고
    • Duties of good faith and fair dealing under the unidroit principles, relevant international conventions, and national laws
    • See E. Allan Farnsworth, Duties of Good Faith and Fair Dealing Under the Unidroit Principles, Relevant International Conventions, and National Laws, 3 TUL. J. INT'L & COMP. L. 47 (1995);
    • (1995) Tul. J. Int'l & Comp. L. , vol.3 , pp. 47
    • Farnsworth, E.A.1
  • 94
    • 0042077971 scopus 로고
    • The concept of good faith in the unidroit principles for international commercial contracts
    • Arthur Hartkamp, The Concept of Good Faith in the Unidroit Principles for International Commercial Contracts, 3 TUL. J. INT'L & COMP. L. 65 (1995);
    • (1995) Tul. J. Int'l & Comp. L. , vol.3 , pp. 65
    • Hartkamp, A.1
  • 95
    • 0043079752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The keeper of the flame: Good faith and fair dealing in international trade
    • Mary E. Hiscock, The Keeper of the Flame: Good Faith and Fair Dealing in International Trade, 29 LOY. L.A. L. REV. 1059 (1996);
    • (1996) Loy. L.a. L. Rev. , vol.29 , pp. 1059
    • Hiscock, M.E.1
  • 96
    • 0041576912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Remarks on goods faith: The united nations convention on contracts for the international sale of goods and the international institute for the unification of private law, principles of international commercial contracts
    • Ulrich Magnus, Remarks on Goods Faith: The United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods and the International Institute for the Unification of Private Law, Principles of International Commercial Contracts, 10 PACE INT'L. L. REV. 89 (1998).
    • (1998) Pace Int'l. L. Rev. , vol.10 , pp. 89
    • Magnus, U.1
  • 97
    • 0346375373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 63, Art. 1.7(2)
    • The parties "may not exclude or limit this duty." UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES, supra note 63, Art. 1.7(2).
    • Unidroit Principles
  • 98
    • 0346375373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 63, Art. 4.8(2)
    • See Art. 4.8(1) on the power of a court or arbitrator to supply an appropriate term "where the parties to a contract have not agreed with respect to a term which is important for a determination of their rights and duties." Factors the court or arbitrator should consider are the intention of the parties, the nature and purpose of the contract, good faith and fair dealing, and reasonableness. UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES, supra note 63, Art. 4.8(2).
    • Unidroit Principles
  • 99
    • 0042077974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This, of course, was the situation in Oglebay. See supra text accompanying notes 37-53. The court, however, did not ask whether Armco's failure to agree was in bad faith.
  • 100
    • 0043079753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 62, at 543-45
    • See Speidel, supra note 62, at 543-45.
    • Speidel1
  • 101
    • 0346375373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 63, Art. 6.2.1
    • UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES, supra note 63, Art. 6.2.1. In Oglebay, the performance arguably was more onerous for Armco.
    • Unidroit Principles
  • 102
    • 0346375373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 63, Art. 6.2.3(1)
    • UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES, supra note 63, Art. 6.2.3(1). The grounds upon which the claim of hardship is based must be stated.
    • Unidroit Principles
  • 103
    • 0041576914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Force majeure and hardship under the unidroit principles of international commercial contracts
    • The options are to "terminate the contract at a date and on terms to be fixed" or "adapt the contract with a view to restoring its equilibrium." UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES, supra note 63, Art. 6.2.3(4). This response is similar to that invoked in the much-criticized Alcoa case, supra note 57, where the court, after finding that Alcoa was entitled to "some relief" after changed circumstances not foreseen as likely to occur, supplied a price-adjustment term to fill the gap left when the agreed term failed of its essential purpose. Like the Oglebay court, the Alcoa court declared that the contract should continue but under the supplied term. This general problem is discussed in Joseph M. Perillo, Force Majeure and Hardship Under the Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts, 5 TUL. J. INT'L & COMP. L. 5 (1997).
    • (1997) Tul. J. Int'l & Comp. L. , vol.5 , pp. 5
    • Perillo, J.M.1
  • 104
    • 0041576915 scopus 로고
    • Art. 6.2.3, comment 5
    • International Institute for the Unification of Private Law, UNDROIT PRINCIPLES Art. 6.2.3, comment 5 (1994).
    • (1994) Undroit Principles
  • 105
    • 0041576916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This caution is illustrated by Norcon Power Partners, L.P. v. Niagara Mohawk Power Corp., 705 N.E.2d 656 (N.Y. 1998), where the United States Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit certified the following question to the New York Court of Appeals: Does a party have a right to demand adequate assurance of future performance when reasonable grounds arise to believe that the other party will commit a breach by non-performance of a contract governed by New York law, where the other party is solvent and the contract is not governed by the U.C.C.? Id. at 658. In giving an affirmative answer on the facts of the particular case (a long-term contract for the sale of electricity), the court rejected a wholesale adoption of the broad principle of adequate assurance in RESTATEMENT (SECOND) CONTRACTS § 251: We conclude . . . that it is unnecessary . . . to promulgate so sweeping a change and proposition in contract law, as has been sought, in one dramatic promulgation. This approach might clash with our customary incremental common-law development process, rooted in particular fact patterns and keener wisdom acquired through observations of empirical application of a proportioned, less than absolute, rule in future cases. 705 N.E.2d at 669.
  • 106
    • 0042579041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 62, at 21-40
    • See BURTON & ANDERSEN, supra note 62, at 21-40.
    • Burton1    Andersen2
  • 107
    • 0042077973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A force majeure event, such as a fire, flood, strike, act of government, or war, actually impedes the agreed performance of the exchange. See Article 79; United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods, Apr. 11, 1980, art. 9, UN. Doc. A/Conf.97/18 (1981);UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES, supra note 63, Art. 7.1.7.
  • 108
    • 0042077970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Equity's modification of contract: An analysis of the twentieth century's equitable reformation of contract law
    • See Larry A. Dimatteo, Equity's Modification of Contract: An Analysis of the Twentieth Century's Equitable Reformation of Contract Law , 33 NEW. ENG. L. REV. 265 (1999).
    • (1999) New. Eng. L. Rev. , vol.33 , pp. 265
    • Dimatteo, L.A.1
  • 109
    • 0043079754 scopus 로고
    • Delicatessen, Inc. v. Schumacher, 417 N.E.2d 541 (N.Y.)
    • See Joseph Martin, Jr., Delicatessen, Inc. v. Schumacher, 417 N.E.2d 541 (N.Y.1981), in which the court commented as follows: We begin our analysis with the basic observation that, unless otherwise mandated by law . . . , a contract is a private "ordering" in which a party binds himself to do, or not to do, a particular thing . . . . This liberty is no right at all if it is not accompanied by freedom not to contract. The corollary is that, before one may secure redress in our courts because another has failed to honor a promise, it must appear that the promisee assented to the obligation in question.
    • (1981)
    • Martin J., Jr.1
  • 110
    • 0042077981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15 (describing this tension)
    • See Scott, supra note 15 (describing this tension).
    • Scott1
  • 111
    • 0347416182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Must formalism be defended empirically?
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Must Formalism be Defended Empirically?, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 636, 644 (1999).
    • (1999) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.66 , pp. 636
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 112
    • 0013371177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16
    • See Scott, supra note 16; Eric A. Posner, A Theory of Contract Law Under Conditions of Radical Judicial Error, 94 NW. U. L. REV. 749 (2000).
    • Scott1
  • 113
    • 0013371177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A theory of contract law under conditions of radical judicial error
    • See Scott, supra note 16; Eric A. Posner, A Theory of Contract Law Under Conditions of Radical Judicial Error, 94 NW. U. L. REV. 749 (2000).
    • (2000) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 749
    • Posner, E.A.1
  • 114
    • 0011655815 scopus 로고
    • The nonjudicial life of contract: Beyond the shadow of the law
    • Advocates of this approach rarely confront the dilemmas of bargaining beyond the shadow of the law. See Edward L. Rubin, The Nonjudicial Life of Contract: Beyond the Shadow of the Law, 90 NW. U. L. REV. 107 (1995).
    • (1995) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.90 , pp. 107
    • Rubin, E.L.1
  • 115
    • 0042077976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at 866
    • See Scott, supra note 16, at 866; Posner, supra note 80, at 752.
    • Scott1
  • 116
    • 0043079748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 80, at 752
    • See Scott, supra note 16, at 866; Posner, supra note 80, at 752.
    • Posner1
  • 117
    • 0345759567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Symposium, Formalism revisited
    • See, e.g., Symposium, Formalism Revisited, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 527 (1999); Symposia, Law, Economics, and Norms, 144 U. PA. L. REV. 1765 (1996).
    • (1999) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.66 , pp. 527
  • 118
    • 0042077972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Symposia, Law, economics, and norms
    • See, e.g., Symposium, Formalism Revisited, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 527 (1999); Symposia, Law, Economics, and Norms, 144 U. PA. L. REV. 1765 (1996).
    • (1996) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.144 , pp. 1765
  • 119
    • 0013241513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For more of the gospel, see CLAYTON P. GILLETTE & STEVEN D. WALT, SALES LAW: DOMESTIC AND INTERNATIONAL 222-29 (1999), favoring ex ante risk allocation and supporting a rule of "no adjustment" without even consideration the relational alternatives.
    • (1999) Sales Law: Domestic and International , pp. 222-229
    • Gillette, C.P.1    Walt, S.D.2
  • 120
    • 0042077969 scopus 로고
    • Judicial revision of frustrated contracts
    • I have taken my lumps. See, e.g., John P. Dawson, Judicial Revision of Frustrated Contracts, 64 B.U. L. REV. 1 (1984).
    • (1984) B.u. L. Rev. , vol.64 , pp. 1
    • Dawson, J.P.1
  • 121
    • 0013149919 scopus 로고
    • In an oft quoted phrase, William Twining said "realism is dead; we are all realists." WILLIAM TWINING, KARL LLEWELLYN AND THE REALIST MOVEMENT 382 (1973). Dean Scott now states that "[w]e are all relationalists." Scott, supra note 16, at 852. Nonsense. Those advocating the virulent strain of the new formalists are neither realists nor relationalists and the sooner we say so the better.
    • (1973) William Twining, Karl Llewellyn and the Realist Movement , pp. 382
  • 122
    • 0041576917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at 852
    • In an oft quoted phrase, William Twining said "realism is dead; we are all realists." WILLIAM TWINING, KARL LLEWELLYN AND THE REALIST MOVEMENT 382 (1973). Dean Scott now states that "[w]e are all relationalists." Scott, supra note 16, at 852. Nonsense. Those advocating the virulent strain of the new formalists are neither realists nor relationalists and the sooner we say so the better.
    • Scott1
  • 123
    • 0042077968 scopus 로고
    • The new conceptualism in contract law
    • For evidence of that "return" in the courts, see Ralph J. Mooney, The New Conceptualism in Contract Law, 74 OR. L. REV. 1131 (1995).
    • (1995) Or. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 1131
    • Mooney, R.J.1
  • 124
    • 0042579038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The parties intend to contract even though material terms are indefinite. In most cases, the parties still intend to contract even though an open term or deferred agreement runs into difficulty during performance.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.