메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 94, Issue 3, 2000, Pages 749-774

A theory of contract law under conditions of radical judicial error

(1)  Posner, Eric A a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0013371177     PISSN: 00293571     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (42)

References (76)
  • 1
    • 0000073663 scopus 로고
    • Contracts: Adjustment of long-term economic relations under classical, neoclassical, and relational contract law
    • Ian R. Macneil, Contracts: Adjustment of Long-Term Economic Relations Under Classical, Neoclassical, and Relational Contract Law, 72 Nw. U. L. REV. 854 (1978).
    • (1978) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 854
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 2
    • 0002692296 scopus 로고
    • Filling gaps in incomplete contracts: An economic theory of default rules
    • hereinafter Filling Gaps
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1989) Yale L.J. , vol.94 , pp. 97
    • Ayres, I.1    Gertner, R.2
  • 3
    • 84924201687 scopus 로고
    • Strategic contractual inefficiency and the optimal choice of legal rules
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1992) Yale L.J. , vol.101 , pp. 729
    • Ayres, I.1    Gertner, R.2
  • 4
    • 0000949337 scopus 로고
    • Information and the scope of liability for breach of contract: The rule of Hadley v. Baxendale
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1991) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.7 , pp. 284
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 5
    • 84930561365 scopus 로고
    • Strategic bargaining and the economic theory of contract default rules
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1990) Yale L.J. , vol.100 , pp. 615
    • Johnston, J.S.1
  • 6
    • 0042579165 scopus 로고
    • Contract remedies and options pricing
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1995) J. Legal Stud. , vol.24 , pp. 139
    • Mahoney, P.G.1
  • 7
    • 0005922414 scopus 로고
    • Contract modification when litigating for damages is costly
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1995) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.15 , pp. 87
    • Miceli, T.J.1
  • 8
    • 0001475698 scopus 로고
    • Contract law in the welfare state: A defense of the unconscionability doctrine, usury laws, and related limitations on the freedom of contract
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1995) J. Legal Stud. , vol.24 , pp. 283
    • Posner, E.A.1
  • 9
    • 0011679357 scopus 로고
    • The default rule paradigm and the limits of contract law
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1994) S. Cal. Interdisc. L.J. , vol.3 , pp. 389
    • Schwartz, A.1
  • 10
    • 21144473629 scopus 로고
    • The economics of liquidated damage clauses in contractual environments with private information
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1992) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.8 , pp. 582
    • Stole, L.A.1
  • 11
    • 84937312878 scopus 로고
    • Contract renegotiation, mechanism design, and the liquidated damages rule
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1994) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 1195
    • Talley, E.1
  • 12
    • 11544375813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Timing problems in contract breach decisions
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1998) J.L. & Econ. , vol.41 , pp. 163
    • Triantis, A.J.1    Triantis, G.G.2
  • 13
    • 0347651353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An economic analysis of the guaranty contract
    • In particular, it is hard to believe that the neoclassical model, to the extent that it overlaps with the standard economic approach, has been exhausted. A sample of recent work along these lines includes Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules, 94 YALE L.J. 97 (1989) [hereinafter Filling Gaps]; Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules, 101 YALE L.J. 729 (1992); Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284 (1991); Jason Scott Johnston, Strategic Bargaining and the Economic Theory of Contract Default Rules, 100 YALE L.J. 615 (1990); Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 139 (1995); Thomas J. Miceli, Contract Modification when Litigating for Damages Is Costly, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 87 (1995); Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom of Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283 (1995) (restrictions on contractual freedom); Alan Schwartz, The Default Rule Paradigm and the Limits of Contract Law, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 389 (1994); Lars A. Stole, The Economics of Liquidated Damage Clauses in Contractual Environments with Private Information, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 582 (1992) (penalty doctrine); Eric Talley, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195 (1994); Alexander J. Triantis & George G. Triantis, Timing Problems in Contract Breach Decisions, 41 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1998) (options approach to contract damages); Avery Wiener Katz, An Economic Analysis of the Guaranty Contract, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 47 (1999) (guaranty contracts). Some other examples are cited below.
    • (1999) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.66 , pp. 47
    • Katz, A.W.1
  • 14
    • 0001573251 scopus 로고
    • The many futures of contract
    • For Macneil's acknowledgment, see Ian R. Macneil, The Many Futures of Contract, 47 S. CAL. L. REV. 691, 734 n.131 (1974).
    • (1974) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.47 , pp. 691
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 15
    • 0000134195 scopus 로고
    • What price contract? - An essay in perspective
    • Karl Llewellyn, What Price Contract? - An Essay in Perspective, 40 YALE L.J. 704 (1931); Stewart Macaulay, Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study, 28 AM. SOC. REV. 55 (1963).
    • (1931) Yale L.j. , vol.40 , pp. 704
    • Llewellyn, K.1
  • 16
    • 0001875669 scopus 로고
    • Non-contractual relations in business: A preliminary study
    • Karl Llewellyn, What Price Contract? - An Essay in Perspective, 40 YALE L.J. 704 (1931); Stewart Macaulay, Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study, 28 AM. SOC. REV. 55 (1963).
    • (1963) Am. Soc. Rev. , vol.28 , pp. 55
    • Macaulay, S.1
  • 18
    • 0000597389 scopus 로고
    • Damage measures for breach of contract
    • See, e.g., Steven Shavell, Damage Measures for Breach of Contract, 11 BELL J. ECON. 466 (1980).
    • (1980) Bell J. Econ. , vol.11 , pp. 466
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 19
    • 0042579164 scopus 로고
    • Specific performance
    • See, e.g., Anthony Kronman, Specific Performance, 45 U. CHI. L. REV. 351 (1978); Alan Schwartz, The Case for Specific Performance, 89 YALE L.J. 271 (1979). In fact, all of these ideas appeared in articles by economists going back into the early 1970s, work from which much of the law-and-economics literature derives. The economic literature on "incomplete contracts," which parallels the legal work on relational contracts, has its roots in this earlier work See Oliver Hart & Bengt Holmstrom, The Theory of Contracts, in ADVANCES IN ECONOMIC THEORY 71-155 (Truman Bewley ed., 1987). See also OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, MARKETS AND HIERARCHIES: ANALYSIS AND ANTITRUST IMPLICATIONS (1975). For Macneil's views, see Ian R. Macneil, Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for a "Rich Classiflcatory Apparatus," 75 Nw. U. L. REV. 1018, 1039 (1981) [hereinafter Economic Analysis].
    • (1978) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.45 , pp. 351
    • Kronman, A.1
  • 20
    • 0040746598 scopus 로고
    • The case for specific performance
    • See, e.g., Anthony Kronman, Specific Performance, 45 U. CHI. L. REV. 351 (1978); Alan Schwartz, The Case for Specific Performance, 89 YALE L.J. 271 (1979). In fact, all of these ideas appeared in articles by economists going back into the early 1970s, work from which much of the law-and-economics literature derives. The economic literature on "incomplete contracts," which parallels the legal work on relational contracts, has its roots in this earlier work See Oliver Hart & Bengt Holmstrom, The Theory of Contracts, in ADVANCES IN ECONOMIC THEORY 71-155 (Truman Bewley ed., 1987). See also OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, MARKETS AND HIERARCHIES: ANALYSIS AND ANTITRUST IMPLICATIONS (1975). For Macneil's views, see Ian R. Macneil, Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for a "Rich Classiflcatory Apparatus," 75 Nw. U. L. REV. 1018, 1039 (1981) [hereinafter Economic Analysis].
    • (1979) Yale L.J. , vol.89 , pp. 271
    • Schwartz, A.1
  • 21
    • 0000585411 scopus 로고
    • The theory of contracts
    • Truman Bewley ed.
    • See, e.g., Anthony Kronman, Specific Performance, 45 U. CHI. L. REV. 351 (1978); Alan Schwartz, The Case for Specific Performance, 89 YALE L.J. 271 (1979). In fact, all of these ideas appeared in articles by economists going back into the early 1970s, work from which much of the law-and-economics literature derives. The economic literature on "incomplete contracts," which parallels the legal work on relational contracts, has its roots in this earlier work See Oliver Hart & Bengt Holmstrom, The Theory of Contracts, in ADVANCES IN ECONOMIC THEORY 71-155 (Truman Bewley ed., 1987). See also OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, MARKETS AND HIERARCHIES: ANALYSIS AND ANTITRUST IMPLICATIONS (1975). For Macneil's views, see Ian R. Macneil, Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for a "Rich Classiflcatory Apparatus," 75 Nw. U. L. REV. 1018, 1039 (1981) [hereinafter Economic Analysis].
    • (1987) Advances in Economic Theory , pp. 71-155
    • Hart, O.1    Holmstrom, B.2
  • 22
    • 0003965377 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Anthony Kronman, Specific Performance, 45 U. CHI. L. REV. 351 (1978); Alan Schwartz, The Case for Specific Performance, 89 YALE L.J. 271 (1979). In fact, all of these ideas appeared in articles by economists going back into the early 1970s, work from which much of the law-and-economics literature derives. The economic literature on "incomplete contracts," which parallels the legal work on relational contracts, has its roots in this earlier work See Oliver Hart & Bengt Holmstrom, The Theory of Contracts, in ADVANCES IN ECONOMIC THEORY 71-155 (Truman Bewley ed., 1987). See also OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, MARKETS AND HIERARCHIES: ANALYSIS AND ANTITRUST IMPLICATIONS (1975). For Macneil's views, see Ian R. Macneil, Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for a "Rich Classiflcatory Apparatus," 75 Nw. U. L. REV. 1018, 1039 (1981) [hereinafter Economic Analysis].
    • (1975) Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 23
    • 0000073664 scopus 로고
    • Economic analysis of contractual relations: Its shortfalls and the need for a "rich classiflcatory apparatus,"
    • hereinafter Economic Analysis
    • See, e.g., Anthony Kronman, Specific Performance, 45 U. CHI. L. REV. 351 (1978); Alan Schwartz, The Case for Specific Performance, 89 YALE L.J. 271 (1979). In fact, all of these ideas appeared in articles by economists going back into the early 1970s, work from which much of the law-and-economics literature derives. The economic literature on "incomplete contracts," which parallels the legal work on relational contracts, has its roots in this earlier work See Oliver Hart & Bengt Holmstrom, The Theory of Contracts, in ADVANCES IN ECONOMIC THEORY 71-155 (Truman Bewley ed., 1987). See also OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, MARKETS AND HIERARCHIES: ANALYSIS AND ANTITRUST IMPLICATIONS (1975). For Macneil's views, see Ian R. Macneil, Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for a "Rich Classiflcatory Apparatus," 75 Nw. U. L. REV. 1018, 1039 (1981) [hereinafter Economic Analysis].
    • (1981) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 1018
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 24
    • 0003643930 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT (1980); Macneil, Economic Analysis, supra note 8; Ian R. Macneil, Values in Contract: Internal and External, 78 Nw. U. L. REV. 340, 383-89 (1983). An interesting application is Richard E. Speidel, Court-Imposed Price Adjustments Under Long-Term Supply Contracts, 76 Nw. U. L. REV. 369, 370-81 (1981). There is also a flavor of this approach in Gillian Hadfield, Problematic Relations: Franchising and the Law of Incomplete Contracts, 42 STAN. L. REV. 927 (1990).
    • (1980) The New Social Contract
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 25
    • 0004312275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 8
    • See, e.g., IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT (1980); Macneil, Economic Analysis, supra note 8; Ian R. Macneil, Values in Contract: Internal and External, 78 Nw. U. L. REV. 340, 383-89 (1983). An interesting application is Richard E. Speidel, Court-Imposed Price Adjustments Under Long-Term Supply Contracts, 76 Nw. U. L. REV. 369, 370-81 (1981). There is also a flavor of this approach in Gillian Hadfield, Problematic Relations: Franchising and the Law of Incomplete Contracts, 42 STAN. L. REV. 927 (1990).
    • Economic Analysis
    • Macneil1
  • 26
    • 68149167283 scopus 로고
    • Values in contract: Internal and external
    • See, e.g., IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT (1980); Macneil, Economic Analysis, supra note 8; Ian R. Macneil, Values in Contract: Internal and External, 78 Nw. U. L. REV. 340, 383-89 (1983). An interesting application is Richard E. Speidel, Court-Imposed Price Adjustments Under Long-Term Supply Contracts, 76 Nw. U. L. REV. 369, 370-81 (1981). There is also a flavor of this approach in Gillian Hadfield, Problematic Relations: Franchising and the Law of Incomplete Contracts, 42 STAN. L. REV. 927 (1990).
    • (1983) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.78 , pp. 340
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 27
    • 0040310900 scopus 로고
    • Court-imposed price adjustments under long-term supply contracts
    • See, e.g., IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT (1980); Macneil, Economic Analysis, supra note 8; Ian R. Macneil, Values in Contract: Internal and External, 78 Nw. U. L. REV. 340, 383-89 (1983). An interesting application is Richard E. Speidel, Court-Imposed Price Adjustments Under Long-Term Supply Contracts, 76 Nw. U. L. REV. 369, 370-81 (1981). There is also a flavor of this approach in Gillian Hadfield, Problematic Relations: Franchising and the Law of Incomplete Contracts, 42 STAN. L. REV. 927 (1990).
    • (1981) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 369
    • Speidel, R.E.1
  • 28
    • 84881962199 scopus 로고
    • Problematic relations: Franchising and the law of incomplete contracts
    • See, e.g., IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT (1980); Macneil, Economic Analysis, supra note 8; Ian R. Macneil, Values in Contract: Internal and External, 78 Nw. U. L. REV. 340, 383-89 (1983). An interesting application is Richard E. Speidel, Court-Imposed Price Adjustments Under Long-Term Supply Contracts, 76 Nw. U. L. REV. 369, 370-81 (1981). There is also a flavor of this approach in Gillian Hadfield, Problematic Relations: Franchising and the Law of Incomplete Contracts, 42 STAN. L. REV. 927 (1990).
    • (1990) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.42 , pp. 927
    • Hadfield, G.1
  • 29
    • 0000450443 scopus 로고
    • Principles of relational contracts
    • See Charles Goetz and Robert Scott, Principles of Relational Contracts, 67 VA. L. REV. 1089 (1981); Robert E. Scott, A Relational Theory of Default Rules for Commercial Contracts, 19 J. LEGAL STUD. 597 (1990). Robert Cooter takes a position midway between Goetz and Scott, on one hand, and Macneil, on the other, arguing that courts should, under certain conditions, identify and apply prevailing commercial customs in order to resolve contractual disputes, and that these customs will generally be efficient. Robert Cooter, Structural Adjudication and the New Law Merchant: A Model of Decentralized Law, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 215 (1994).
    • (1981) Va. L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 1089
    • Goetz, C.1    Scott, R.2
  • 30
    • 0042579162 scopus 로고
    • A relational theory of default rules for commercial contracts
    • See Charles Goetz and Robert Scott, Principles of Relational Contracts, 67 VA. L. REV. 1089 (1981); Robert E. Scott, A Relational Theory of Default Rules for Commercial Contracts, 19 J. LEGAL STUD. 597 (1990). Robert Cooter takes a position midway between Goetz and Scott, on one hand, and Macneil, on the other, arguing that courts should, under certain conditions, identify and apply prevailing commercial customs in order to resolve contractual disputes, and that these customs will generally be efficient. Robert Cooter, Structural Adjudication and the New Law Merchant: A Model of Decentralized Law, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 215 (1994).
    • (1990) J. Legal Stud. , vol.19 , pp. 597
    • Scott, R.E.1
  • 31
    • 0000934115 scopus 로고
    • Structural adjudication and the new law merchant: A model of decentralized law
    • See Charles Goetz and Robert Scott, Principles of Relational Contracts, 67 VA. L. REV. 1089 (1981); Robert E. Scott, A Relational Theory of Default Rules for Commercial Contracts, 19 J. LEGAL STUD. 597 (1990). Robert Cooter takes a position midway between Goetz and Scott, on one hand, and Macneil, on the other, arguing that courts should, under certain conditions, identify and apply prevailing commercial customs in order to resolve contractual disputes, and that these customs will generally be efficient. Robert Cooter, Structural Adjudication and the New Law Merchant: A Model of Decentralized Law, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 215 (1994).
    • (1994) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.14 , pp. 215
    • Cooter, R.1
  • 32
    • 0000472772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Incomplete contracts
    • Peter Newman ed.
    • See Alan Schwanz, Incomplete Contracts, in THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW (Peter Newman ed.,1998); Alan Schwartz, Relational Contracts in the Courts: An Analysis of Incomplete Agreements and Judicial Strategies, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 271 (1992).
    • (1998) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law
    • Schwanz, A.1
  • 33
    • 0000218023 scopus 로고
    • Relational contracts in the courts: An analysis of incomplete agreements and judicial strategies
    • See Alan Schwanz, Incomplete Contracts, in THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW (Peter Newman ed.,1998); Alan Schwartz, Relational Contracts in the Courts: An Analysis of Incomplete Agreements and Judicial Strategies, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 271 (1992).
    • (1992) J. Legal Stud. , vol.21 , pp. 271
    • Schwartz, A.1
  • 34
    • 0001202406 scopus 로고
    • Incomplete contracts and renegotiation
    • See. e.g., Oliver Hart and John Moore, Incomplete Contracts and Renegotiation, 56 ECONOMETRICA 755 (1988); Philippe Aghion, Mathias Dewatripont, and Patrick Rey, Renegotiation Design with Unverifiable Information, 62 ECONOMETRlCA 257 (1994); Aaron S. Edlin and Stefan Reichelstein, Holdups, Standard Breach Remedies, and Optimal Investment, 86 AM. ECON. REV. 478 (1996).
    • (1988) Econometrica , vol.56 , pp. 755
    • Hart, O.1    Moore, J.2
  • 35
    • 0001668625 scopus 로고
    • Renegotiation design with unverifiable information
    • See. e.g., Oliver Hart and John Moore, Incomplete Contracts and Renegotiation, 56 ECONOMETRICA 755 (1988); Philippe Aghion, Mathias Dewatripont, and Patrick Rey, Renegotiation Design with Unverifiable Information, 62 ECONOMETRlCA 257 (1994); Aaron S. Edlin and Stefan Reichelstein, Holdups, Standard Breach Remedies, and Optimal Investment, 86 AM. ECON. REV. 478 (1996).
    • (1994) Econometrlca , vol.62 , pp. 257
    • Aghion, P.1    Dewatripont, M.2    Rey, P.3
  • 36
    • 0000270253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Holdups, standard breach remedies, and optimal investment
    • See. e.g., Oliver Hart and John Moore, Incomplete Contracts and Renegotiation, 56 ECONOMETRICA 755 (1988); Philippe Aghion, Mathias Dewatripont, and Patrick Rey, Renegotiation Design with Unverifiable Information, 62 ECONOMETRlCA 257 (1994); Aaron S. Edlin and Stefan Reichelstein, Holdups, Standard Breach Remedies, and Optimal Investment, 86 AM. ECON. REV. 478 (1996).
    • (1996) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 478
    • Edlin, A.S.1    Reichelstein, S.2
  • 37
    • 0038564041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The design and interpretation of contracts: Why complexity matters
    • forthcoming
    • See Karen Eggleston, Eric A. Posner, and Richard Zeckhauser, The Design and Interpretation of Contracts: Why Complexity Matters, 95 NW. U. L. REV. (forthcoming 2000).
    • (2000) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.95
    • Eggleston, K.1    Posner, E.A.2    Zeckhauser, R.3
  • 38
    • 0003722090 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JANET T. LANDA, TRUST, ETHNICITY AND IDENTITY: BEYOND THE NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS OF ETHNIC TRADING NETWORKS, CONTRACT LAW, AND GIFT EXCHANGE (1994); ELINOR OSTROM, GOVERNING THE COMMONS: THE EVOLUTION OF INSTITUTIONS FOR COLLECTIVE ACTION (1990); Avner Greif, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders Coalition, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 525 (1993); Avner Greif et al., Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild, 102 J. POL. ECON. 745 (1994); Eric A. Posner, The Regulation of Groups: The Influence of Legal and Nonlegal Sanctions on Collective Action, 63 U. CHI. L. REV. 133 (1996) [hereinafter Posner, Regulation of Groups].
    • (1994) Trust, Ethnicity and Identity: Beyond the New Institutional Economics of Ethnic Trading Networks, Contract Law, and Gift Exchange
    • Landa, J.T.1
  • 39
    • 85040890266 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JANET T. LANDA, TRUST, ETHNICITY AND IDENTITY: BEYOND THE NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS OF ETHNIC TRADING NETWORKS, CONTRACT LAW, AND GIFT EXCHANGE (1994); ELINOR OSTROM, GOVERNING THE COMMONS: THE EVOLUTION OF INSTITUTIONS FOR COLLECTIVE ACTION (1990); Avner Greif, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders Coalition, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 525 (1993); Avner Greif et al., Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild, 102 J. POL. ECON. 745 (1994); Eric A. Posner, The Regulation of Groups: The Influence of Legal and Nonlegal Sanctions on Collective Action, 63 U. CHI. L. REV. 133 (1996) [hereinafter Posner, Regulation of Groups].
    • (1990) Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action
    • Ostrom, E.1
  • 40
    • 0001103387 scopus 로고
    • Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: The maghribi traders coalition
    • See, e.g., JANET T. LANDA, TRUST, ETHNICITY AND IDENTITY: BEYOND THE NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS OF ETHNIC TRADING NETWORKS, CONTRACT LAW, AND GIFT EXCHANGE (1994); ELINOR OSTROM, GOVERNING THE COMMONS: THE EVOLUTION OF INSTITUTIONS FOR COLLECTIVE ACTION (1990); Avner Greif, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders Coalition, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 525 (1993); Avner Greif et al., Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild, 102 J. POL. ECON. 745 (1994); Eric A. Posner, The Regulation of Groups: The Influence of Legal and Nonlegal Sanctions on Collective Action, 63 U. CHI. L. REV. 133 (1996) [hereinafter Posner, Regulation of Groups].
    • (1993) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 525
    • Greif, A.1
  • 41
    • 84924196668 scopus 로고
    • Coordination, commitment, and enforcement: The case of the merchant guild
    • See, e.g., JANET T. LANDA, TRUST, ETHNICITY AND IDENTITY: BEYOND THE NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS OF ETHNIC TRADING NETWORKS, CONTRACT LAW, AND GIFT EXCHANGE (1994); ELINOR OSTROM, GOVERNING THE COMMONS: THE EVOLUTION OF INSTITUTIONS FOR COLLECTIVE ACTION (1990); Avner Greif, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders Coalition, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 525 (1993); Avner Greif et al., Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild, 102 J. POL. ECON. 745 (1994); Eric A. Posner, The Regulation of Groups: The Influence of Legal and Nonlegal Sanctions on Collective Action, 63 U. CHI. L. REV. 133 (1996) [hereinafter Posner, Regulation of Groups].
    • (1994) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.102 , pp. 745
    • Greif, A.1
  • 42
    • 0346353782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The regulation of groups: The influence of legal and nonlegal sanctions on collective action
    • hereinafter Posner, Regulation of Groups
    • See, e.g., JANET T. LANDA, TRUST, ETHNICITY AND IDENTITY: BEYOND THE NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS OF ETHNIC TRADING NETWORKS, CONTRACT LAW, AND GIFT EXCHANGE (1994); ELINOR OSTROM, GOVERNING THE COMMONS: THE EVOLUTION OF INSTITUTIONS FOR COLLECTIVE ACTION (1990); Avner Greif, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders Coalition, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 525 (1993); Avner Greif et al., Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild, 102 J. POL. ECON. 745 (1994); Eric A. Posner, The Regulation of Groups: The Influence of Legal and Nonlegal Sanctions on Collective Action, 63 U. CHI. L. REV. 133 (1996) [hereinafter Posner, Regulation of Groups].
    • (1996) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.63 , pp. 133
    • Posner, E.A.1
  • 43
    • 0001457802 scopus 로고
    • The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance
    • See Benjamin Klein & Keith B. Leffler, The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance, 89 J. POL. ECON. 615 (1981).
    • (1981) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.89 , pp. 615
    • Klein, B.1    Leffler, K.B.2
  • 44
    • 84926271010 scopus 로고
    • Reliance, reputation, and breach of contract
    • But see Louis A. Komhauser, Reliance, Reputation, and Breach of Contract, 26 J.L. & ECON. 691 (1983).
    • (1983) J.L. & Econ. , vol.26 , pp. 691
    • Komhauser, L.A.1
  • 45
    • 0042078095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strip clubs under siege as salesman's havens
    • Sept 20, at Al
    • Robyn Meredith, Strip Clubs Under Siege as Salesman's Havens, N.Y. TIMES, Sept 20, 1997, at Al.
    • (1997) N.Y. Times
    • Meredith, R.1
  • 47
    • 0042579152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 20-21
    • Id. at 20-21.
  • 49
    • 0042579148 scopus 로고
    • The nexus between usury, "time price," and unconscionability in installment sales
    • Jeffrey E. Allen & Robert J. Staaf, The Nexus Between Usury, "Time Price," and Unconscionability in Installment Sales, 14 UCC L.J. 219 (1982).
    • (1982) UCC L.J. , vol.14 , pp. 219
    • Allen, J.E.1    Staaf, R.J.2
  • 51
    • 0043079905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Discount rate" refers to the extent to which a person values future payoffs relative to current payoffs. A person with a high discount rate values future payoffs much less than current payoffs; a person with a low discount rate values future payoffs only a little less than current payoffs.
  • 53
    • 0347873842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • forthcoming
    • See ERIC A. POSNER, LAW AND SOCIAL NORMS (forthcoming 2000); Eric A. Posner, Symbols, Signals, and Social Norms in Politics and the Law, 27 J. LEGAL STUD. 765 (1998).
    • (2000) Law and Social Norms
    • Posner, E.A.1
  • 54
    • 0347873842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Symbols, signals, and social norms in politics and the law
    • See ERIC A. POSNER, LAW AND SOCIAL NORMS (forthcoming 2000); Eric A. Posner, Symbols, Signals, and Social Norms in Politics and the Law, 27 J. LEGAL STUD. 765 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Legal Stud. , vol.27 , pp. 765
    • Posner, E.A.1
  • 55
    • 0003531998 scopus 로고
    • The argument is in the spirit of Williamson, who also assumes that contracts are not enforceable. See Oliver E. Williamson, THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM 168-69 (1985). But Williamson focuses on private ordering, and does not have any specific ideas about the role of courts. Id. at 400-01.
    • (1985) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism , pp. 168-169
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 56
    • 0000525496 scopus 로고
    • Deterrence and uncertain legal standards
    • Existing work on judicial error does not make such an extreme assumption. See, e.g., Richard Craswell & John E. Calfee, Deterrence and Uncertain Legal Standards, 2 J.L. ECON. AND ORG. 279 (1986); Gillian Hadfield, Judicial Competence and the Interpretation of Incomplete Contracts, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 159 (1994).
    • (1986) J.L. Econ. and Org. , vol.2 , pp. 279
    • Craswell, R.1    Calfee, O.E.2
  • 57
    • 0000525496 scopus 로고
    • Judicial competence and the interpretation of incomplete contracts
    • Existing work on judicial error does not make such an extreme assumption. See, e.g., Richard Craswell & John E. Calfee, Deterrence and Uncertain Legal Standards, 2 J.L. ECON. AND ORG. 279 (1986); Gillian Hadfield, Judicial Competence and the Interpretation of Incomplete Contracts, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 159 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Legal Stud. , vol.23 , pp. 159
    • Hadfield, G.1
  • 58
    • 0009037768 scopus 로고
    • Contract remedies, renegotiation, and the theory of efficient breach
    • I assume away a number of complications that are well rehearsed in the literature. The most lucid discussion remains Richard Craswell, Contract Remedies, Renegotiation, and the Theory of Efficient Breach, 61 S. CAL. L. REV. 630 (1988).
    • (1988) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 630
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 59
    • 0043079922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One might make different assumptions about how much information the third parties have. In the simplest case, the third parties know who cheated. By hypothesis, this knowledge does not deter Buyer from cheating because Buyer has a high-value opportunity. But it is enough to give Seller an incentive to sue, and the suit is what deters Buyer. (Imagine that Seller deals with these third parties more than Buyer does, or that Buyer's gain from cheating is high compared to Seller's loss.) In the other extreme, third parties do not know whether Buyer cheated. If that is the case, in the current model Seller may have no incentive to sue, because third parties do not know whether Seller is suing because Buyer cheated her or in order to persuade them that she is tough. But real cases no doubt fall between the two extremes. In such cases, third parties have more information about Buyer's actions than courts do but less than Buyer and Seller do. The consequence of such partial information is to blunt the reputation effect on which the model relies but not to eliminate it.
  • 60
    • 0041577051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Seller will enter the contract, and Buyer will not cheat, when R > C, P > D - C, and P > 0. It follows that contracts will occur when D < P + R. When D > P + R, Seller does not enter the contract in round 0 because she knows that the threat to sue will not deter Buyer from cheating in round 2. To sum up, there are three possibilities. (1) D < P, in which case contracting is possible because Buyer either gains little from defecting or because nonlegal sanctions are effective ("low-value opportunism"); (2) P < D < P + R, in which case contracting is possible because of incompetent courts; and (3) D > P + R, in which case contracts are not possible.
  • 61
    • 0042078109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The contrast is a bit overstated. Courts do state that certain promises will be interpreted in certain ways. For example, they often say that if an employment contract does not provide expressly for tenure or termination for cause, it will be interpreted as employment at will.
  • 62
    • 0042579147 scopus 로고
    • The duel: Can these gentlemen be acting efficiently?
    • See Warren F. Schwartz et al., The Duel: Can These Gentlemen Be Acting Efficiently?, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 321 (1984).
    • (1984) J. Legal Stud. , vol.13 , pp. 321
    • Schwartz, W.F.1
  • 65
    • 0042579160 scopus 로고
    • The bargain principle and its limits
    • See generally Melvin A. Eisenberg, The Bargain Principle and Its Limits, 95 HARV. L. REV. 741 (1982).
    • (1982) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.95 , pp. 741
    • Eisenberg, M.A.1
  • 66
    • 0042078097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2
    • See, e.g., Ayres & Gertner, Filling Gaps, supra note 2; Louis Kaplow, Rules Versus Standards: An Economic Analysis, 42 DUKE L.J. 557 (1992).
    • Filling Gaps
    • Ayres1    Gertner2
  • 67
    • 21144468370 scopus 로고
    • Rules versus standards: An economic analysis
    • See, e.g., Ayres & Gertner, Filling Gaps, supra note 2; Louis Kaplow, Rules Versus Standards: An Economic Analysis, 42 DUKE L.J. 557 (1992).
    • (1992) Duke L.J. , vol.42 , pp. 557
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 68
    • 0042078108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See OLIVER WENDELL HOLMES, THE COMMON LAW (M. Howe ed., 1963). Hand's most famous remark on this subject can be found in Hotchkiss v. National City Bank of New York, 200 F. 287, 293 (S.D.N.Y. 1911): A contract has, strictly speaking, nothing to do with the personal, or individual, intent of the parties. A contract is an obligation attached by the mere force of law to certain acts of the parties, usually words, which ordinarily accompany and represent a known intent. If, however, it were proved by twenty bishops that either party, when he used the words, intended something else than the usual meaning which the law imposes upon them, he would still be held, unless there were some mutual mistake, or something else of the sort. Of course, if it appear by other words, or acts, of the parties, that they attribute a peculiar meaning to such words as they use in the contract, that meaning will prevail, but only by virtue of the other words, and not because of their unexpressed intent.
  • 69
    • 0008644053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The decline of formality in contract law
    • F. H. Buckley ed.
    • See Eric A. Posner, The Decline of Formality in Contract Law, in THE FALL AND RISE OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT 61 (F. H. Buckley ed. 1999).
    • (1999) The Fall And Rise Of Freedom Of Contract , pp. 61
    • Posner, E.A.1
  • 71
    • 0042078092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is an implication of the literature on this topic, cited above. See supra note 36.
  • 72
    • 0042078094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 133 N.W.2d 267 (Wis. 1965)
    • 133 N.W.2d 267 (Wis. 1965).
  • 73
    • 0042078093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As noted above, technically this behavior is off the equilibrium path, but would occur in a model in which the parties (more realistically) have imperfect information and make mistakes.
  • 74
    • 0000626130 scopus 로고
    • The myth that promisees prefer supracompensatory remedies: An analysis of contracting for damage measures
    • Alan Schwartz, The Myth that Promisees Prefer Supracompensatory Remedies: An Analysis of Contracting for Damage Measures, 100 YALE L.J. 369 (1990).
    • (1990) Yale L.J. , vol.100 , pp. 369
    • Schwartz, A.1
  • 75
    • 0043079910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The argument assumes that Seller obtains R simply if she sues Buyer after Buyer cheats. One might alternatively assume that R is an increasing function of C, because future parties are more likely to be impressed by Seller's toughness when Seller spends a lot on litigation rather than a little.
  • 76
    • 0347873668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Saints and sinners: How does Delaware corporate law work?
    • See Edward B. Rock, Saints and Sinners: How Does Delaware Corporate Law Work?, 44 UCLA L. REV. 1009 (1997).
    • (1997) UCLA L. Rev. , vol.44 , pp. 1009
    • Rock, E.B.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.