메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 16, Issue 1, 2000, Pages 209-232

Promises, trust, and contracts

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0034421413     PISSN: 87566222     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/jleo/16.1.209     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (51)

References (44)
  • 1
    • 8344230535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, for instance, Dybvig and Spatt (1980), Shapiro (1983), Boot, Greenbaum, and Thakor (1993). Same as promises, reputations need not always be reliable. From time to time, people may run down their reputations, but that does not prevent the use of reputations to facilitate beneficial transactions [Gale and Rosenthal (1994)].
  • 2
    • 8344223504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We shall in Section 2 discuss in more detail several possible motivations for the behavior assumption here.
  • 3
    • 8344229079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Thus in our model an incomplete contract may be chosen, not because a complete contract is not available, but because the latter may not be optimal. Spier (1992) has also shown how incompleteness in contracts can arise endogenously, but it is due to signaling concerns: only bad types offer complete contingent contracts.
  • 4
    • 8344252564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is different from the residual right in incomplete contracts as is analyzed in Grossman and Hart (1986) and Hart and Moore (1990), where there are two sequential stages for investment and production and the residual right is associated with the ownership of assets. We also note that the notion of incomplete contract here captures a somewhat different aspect of contract incompleteness compared to the literature, where the incompleteness of contracts usually refers to a situation that the terms of contracts under some possible events are not specified. Here agreements can be made for all possible circumstances, and the incompleteness of contracts arises only if an agreement is not legally enforceable.
  • 5
    • 8344233993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If only complete contracts are used under either arrangement, then it becomes irrelevant how residual rights are assigned under incomplete contracts.
  • 6
    • 8344286294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In addition, real-world transactions may involve uncertainties that are not considered in our model, and the delivery can be nonconforming even if the seller has done the work in good faith. A price reduction allows the buyer to be properly compensated in such situations.
  • 7
    • 8344250759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A related practice is the use of subjective performance measures in incentive contracts. In many firms, an employee's compensation depends not only on objective performance measures, but also on subjective assessments of performance [Baker, Gibbons, and Murphy 1994)]. Rewards for good performance in these situations can also be viewed as promises by an employer to its employees, and a certain level of trust that the promises will be kept is crucial for such incomplete contracts to be successful.
  • 8
    • 8344254202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The nature of contract costs here differs from the verification (or monitoring) costs in Townsend (1979) and Dye (1986), where the outcomes can always be verified ex post and the costs occur only if there is verification. The cost of writing contingent contracts in Dye (1985) is more similar in nature to the contact costs here. Recently, Maskin and Tirole (1999) have noted that there can be a mechanism that turns an observable variable into verifiable when sufficiently high punishments can be imposed. Hart and Moore (1999), however, have instead argued that the usual "observable but not verifiable" assumption does lead to contractual incompleteness, provided that the panics cannot commit not to renegotiate.
  • 9
    • 8344276511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Alternatively, we can say that the player with the residual right moves last, and therefore can renege on any promise (s)he made earlier.
  • 10
    • 8344261223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • l. 11. In reputation models, such as in Tirole (1996), it is customary to assume that there are three types of agents: those who are always honest, those who are opportunistic, and those who always cheat. The individuals in our model may be viewed in some sense as the continuous version of the three types.
  • 11
    • 8344279382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To close a model like this, one would need to show that such behavior can be supported by some notion of equilibrium. Such an analysis is beyond the scope of this article.
  • 12
    • 8344241763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The reason for this assumption can be justified by showing that this order of moves is most efficient ex ante, but we prefer to state this order of moves as an assumption rather than a result, since a formal proof involves details that are not essential for the purpose of this article. Basically with this assumption we have a screening model and avoid signaling considerations, since the party making contract offers will have no use of his private information.
  • 13
    • 8344265849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note that since the seller has no residual right under BP, the equilibrium does not depend on the seller's type.
  • 14
    • 8344276510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • l). 16. In other words, there is an important asymmetry between the buyer and the seller in the effects on social surplus when they break a promise: one involves only a transfer payment and the other involves a distortion in resource allocation.
  • 15
    • 8344283342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This outcome is related to the "lemons problem" in models of adverse selection. See the seminal article on this issue by Akerlof (1970).
  • 16
    • 8344225085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While the contracting parties in our model are private individuals, our analysis also applies to contracting between companies. In fact, one may be willing to place a higher level of trust on a company than on an individual, for reasons including that a company may value reputation more than an individual; honest dealing with other parties may be necessary if a company wishes to establish a culture of trust and cooperation within the organization; and usually an agent making decisions for the company will not receive all the monetary gains if he acts dishonestly on behalf of his company.
  • 17
    • 8344240246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A limitation of our analysis is treating the (BP, SP) regime as exogenous. More generally, one could treat the regime as a contract provision and ask which regime will emerge in equilibrium (or prevail in the marketplace). This is an interesting issue that we hope will be addressed by future research.
  • 18
    • 8344219512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Notice that, by empirical or laboratory studies, one may actually be able to estimate F(·), the population distribution of willingness to keep promises in a society.
  • 19
    • 85005305538 scopus 로고
    • The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism
    • Akerlof, George. 1970. "The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism," 89 Quarterly Journal of Economics 488-500.
    • (1970) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.89 , pp. 488-500
    • Akerlof, G.1
  • 20
    • 84963036850 scopus 로고
    • Labor Contracts as a Partial Gift Exchange
    • _. 1982. "Labor Contracts as a Partial Gift Exchange," 97 Quarterly Journal of Economics 543-569.
    • (1982) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.97 , pp. 543-569
  • 21
    • 84936397875 scopus 로고
    • Giving with Impure Altruism: Applications to Charity and Ricardian Equivalence
    • Andreoni, James. 1989. "Giving with Impure Altruism: Applications to Charity and Ricardian Equivalence," 97 Journal of Political Economy 1447-1458.
    • (1989) Journal of Political Economy , vol.97 , pp. 1447-1458
    • Andreoni, J.1
  • 22
    • 0000362594 scopus 로고
    • Impure Altruism and Donations to Public Goods: A Theory of Warm-Glow Giving
    • _. 1990. "Impure Altruism and Donations to Public Goods: A Theory of Warm-Glow Giving," 100 Economic Journal 464-477.
    • (1990) Economic Journal , vol.100 , pp. 464-477
  • 24
    • 21844512599 scopus 로고
    • Subjective Performance Measures in Optimal Incentive Contracts
    • Baker, George, Robert Gibbons, and Kevin J. Murphy. 1994. "Subjective Performance Measures in Optimal Incentive Contracts," 104 Quarterly Journal of Economics 1125-1156.
    • (1994) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.104 , pp. 1125-1156
    • Baker, G.1    Gibbons, R.2    Murphy, K.J.3
  • 25
    • 0001146935 scopus 로고
    • Reputation and Discretion in Financial Contracting
    • Boot, Arnoud, Stuart Greenbaum, and Anjan Thakor. 1993. "Reputation and Discretion in Financial Contracting," 83 American Economic Review 1165-1183.
    • (1993) American Economic Review , vol.83 , pp. 1165-1183
    • Boot, A.1    Greenbaum, S.2    Thakor, A.3
  • 26
  • 28
    • 0009253283 scopus 로고
    • Costly Contract Contingencies
    • Dye, Ronald. 1985. "Costly Contract Contingencies," 26 International Economic Review 233-250.
    • (1985) International Economic Review , vol.26 , pp. 233-250
    • Dye, R.1
  • 29
    • 0000057794 scopus 로고
    • Optimal Monitoring Policies in Agencies
    • _. 1986. "Optimal Monitoring Policies in Agencies," 17 Rand Journal of Economics 339-350.
    • (1986) Rand Journal of Economics , vol.17 , pp. 339-350
  • 30
    • 0004178565 scopus 로고
    • New York: Free Press
    • Fukuyama, Francis. 1995. Trust New York: Free Press.
    • (1995) Trust
    • Fukuyama, F.1
  • 31
    • 21844512026 scopus 로고
    • Quality Cycles for Experience Goods
    • Gale, Douglas, and Robert Rosenthal. 1994. "Quality Cycles for Experience Goods," 25 Rand Journal of Economics 590-607.
    • (1994) Rand Journal of Economics , vol.25 , pp. 590-607
    • Gale, D.1    Rosenthal, R.2
  • 32
    • 84936194550 scopus 로고
    • The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration
    • Grossman, Sanford, and Oliver Hart. 1986. "The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration," 94 Journal of Political Economy 691-719.
    • (1986) Journal of Political Economy , vol.94 , pp. 691-719
    • Grossman, S.1    Hart, O.2
  • 33
    • 84934453985 scopus 로고
    • Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm
    • Hart, Oliver, and John Moore. 1990. "Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm," 98 Journal of Political Economy 1119-1158.
    • (1990) Journal of Political Economy , vol.98 , pp. 1119-1158
    • Hart, O.1    Moore, J.2
  • 34
    • 0040908085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Foundations of Incomplete Contracts
    • _. 1999. "Foundations of Incomplete Contracts," 66 Review of Economic Studies 115-138.
    • (1999) Review of Economic Studies , vol.66 , pp. 115-138
  • 36
    • 17944377188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unforeseen Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts
    • Maskin, Eric, and Jean Tirole. 1999. "Unforeseen Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts," 66 Review of Economic Studies 83-114.
    • (1999) Review of Economic Studies , vol.66 , pp. 83-114
    • Maskin, E.1    Tirole, J.2
  • 37
    • 0000832255 scopus 로고
    • Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory
    • Rabin, Matthew. 1993. "Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory," 83 American Economic Review 1281-1302.
    • (1993) American Economic Review , vol.83 , pp. 1281-1302
    • Rabin, M.1
  • 38
    • 8344282541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • mimeo, New York University
    • Radner, Roy. 1999. "Viscous Demand," mimeo, New York University.
    • (1999) Viscous Demand
    • Radner, R.1
  • 39
    • 0000952826 scopus 로고
    • Premiums for High Quality Products as Rents to Reputation
    • Shapiro, Carl. 1983. "Premiums for High Quality Products as Rents to Reputation," 98 Quarterly Journal of Economics 659-680.
    • (1983) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.98 , pp. 659-680
    • Shapiro, C.1
  • 40
    • 85076787280 scopus 로고
    • Incomplete Contracts and Signalling
    • Spier, E. Kathryn. 1992. "Incomplete Contracts and Signalling," 23 Rand Journal of Economics 432-443.
    • (1992) Rand Journal of Economics , vol.23 , pp. 432-443
    • Spier, E.K.1
  • 41
    • 0002237355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Collective Reputations (with applications to the persistence of corruption and to firm quality)
    • Tirole, Jean. 1996. "A Theory of Collective Reputations (with applications to the persistence of corruption and to firm quality)," 63 Review of Economic Studies 1-22.
    • (1996) Review of Economic Studies , vol.63 , pp. 1-22
    • Tirole, J.1
  • 42
    • 0009424011 scopus 로고
    • Optimal Contracts and Competitive Markets with Costly State Verification
    • Townsend, Robert. 1979. "Optimal Contracts and Competitive Markets with Costly State Verification," 21 Journal of Economic Theory 265-293.
    • (1979) Journal of Economic Theory , vol.21 , pp. 265-293
    • Townsend, R.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.