메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 39, Issue 2, 1985, Pages 207-231

The mysterious case of vanishing hegemony; or, Is Mark Twain really dead?

(1)  Russett, Bruce a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84971189672     PISSN: 00208183     EISSN: 15315088     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0020818300026953     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (205)

References (45)
  • 1
    • 84972003239 scopus 로고
    • Cave! Hic Dragones: A Critique of Regime Analysis
    • For example Spring
    • For example, Susan Strange, “Cave! Hic Dragones: A Critique of Regime Analysis,” International Organization 36 (Spring 1982), pp. 299–324.
    • (1982) International Organization , vol.36 , pp. 299-324
    • Strange, S.1
  • 2
    • 84971103526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Introduction” to his edited volume, America as an Ordinary Country
    • (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1976), p. 1; Kenneth A. Oye, “The Domain of Choice,” in Oye, Donald Rothchild, and Robert J. Lieber, eds., Eagle Entangled: U.S. Foreign Policy in a Complex World (New York: Longman, 1979), pp. 4-5; and George Liska, Career of Empire (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1978), chap. 10.
    • See Richard Rosecrance's “Introduction” to his edited volume, America as an Ordinary Country (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1976), p. 1; Kenneth A. Oye, “The Domain of Choice,” in Oye, Donald Rothchild, and Robert J. Lieber, eds., Eagle Entangled: U.S. Foreign Policy in a Complex World (New York: Longman, 1979), pp. 4-5; and George Liska, Career of Empire (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1978), chap. 10.
    • Rosecrance's, R.1
  • 3
    • 26444551593 scopus 로고
    • The Erosion of U.S. Leadership Capabilities
    • For example Paul Johnson and William R. Thompson, eds. (New York: Praeger
    • For example, Mark E. Rupert and David P. Rapkin, “The Erosion of U.S. Leadership Capabilities,” in Paul Johnson and William R. Thompson, eds., Rhythms in International Politics and Economics (New York: Praeger, 1985).
    • (1985) Rhythms in International Politics and Economics
    • Rupert, M.E.1    Rapkin, D.P.2
  • 4
    • 84874353575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for instance (Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1979), esp. chap. 7, who regards the United States as more autonomous, and hence stronger, than more internationally involved states.
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1979), esp. chap. 7, who regards the United States as more autonomous, and hence stronger, than more internationally involved states.
    • Theory of International Politics
    • Waltz, K.1
  • 5
    • 84971157508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hegemon
    • at the time is underlined; there was no hegemon in 1938, but I have arbitrarily used the U.S. values as the base.
    • a. “Hegemon” at the time is underlined; there was no hegemon in 1938, but I have arbitrarily used the U.S. values as the base.
  • 6
    • 84971103508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.A. ranked fifth
    • b. U.S.A. ranked fifth.
  • 7
    • 0000480079 scopus 로고
    • Europe's Gross National Product
    • 1872 data used, as figures for French and German (Prussian) military spending were inflated in 1870 and 1871 by the Franco-Prussian War. Sources. GNP data 1983 from OECD, Main Economic Indicators (Paris, May 1984), p. 182; USSR total is estimated. Other GNP data from Paul Bairoch and U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, D.C., 1975). Military expenditures 1983 from World Armaments and Disarmament: SIPRI Yearbook, 1984 (London: Taylor & Francis, 1984), pp. 117–18. SIPRI lists USSR military expenses as 74% of the U.S. figure, but U.S. government sources (C.I.A. and D.I.A.) give USSR expenditures as exceeding those of U.S.A. I have set the two countries as equal. The estimate for China, given by SIPRI and used here, may be somewhat low. Military expenditure data for previous years are from the Correlates of War national capabilities data provided by Professor J. David Singer. Manufacturing production data from Paul Bairoch, “International Industrialization Levels from 1750 to 1980,” Journal of European Economic History 11, 2 (1982), pp. 269–333. Data for 1870 are interpolated between Bairoch's figures for 1860 and 1880
    • c. 1872 data used, as figures for French and German (Prussian) military spending were inflated in 1870 and 1871 by the Franco-Prussian War. Sources. GNP data 1983 from OECD, Main Economic Indicators (Paris, May 1984), p. 182; USSR total is estimated. Other GNP data from Paul Bairoch, “Europe's Gross National Product, 1800-1975,” Journal of European Economic History 5, 2 (1976), pp. 273–340, and U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, D.C., 1975). Military expenditures 1983 from World Armaments and Disarmament: SIPRI Yearbook, 1984 (London: Taylor & Francis, 1984), pp. 117–18. SIPRI lists USSR military expenses as 74% of the U.S. figure, but U.S. government sources (C.I.A. and D.I.A.) give USSR expenditures as exceeding those of U.S.A. I have set the two countries as equal. The estimate for China, given by SIPRI and used here, may be somewhat low. Military expenditure data for previous years are from the Correlates of War national capabilities data provided by Professor J. David Singer. Manufacturing production data from Paul Bairoch, “International Industrialization Levels from 1750 to 1980,” Journal of European Economic History 11, 2 (1982), pp. 269–333. Data for 1870 are interpolated between Bairoch's figures for 1860 and 1880.
    • (1976) Journal of European Economic History , vol.5 , Issue.2 , pp. 273-340
  • 8
    • 0004245427 scopus 로고
    • The Analysis of International Relations
    • 2d ed. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall
    • Karl W. Deutsch, The Analysis of International Relations, 2d ed. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1978).
    • (1978)
    • Deutsch, K.W.1
  • 9
    • 84970242850 scopus 로고
    • Power and Interdependence
    • Boston: Little, Brown and Stephen Krasner, “Structural Causes and Regime Consequences: Regimes as Intervening Variables,” International Organization 36 (Spring 1982), p. 199.
    • Robert O. Keohane and Joseph Nye, Power and Interdependence (Boston: Little, Brown, 1977), p. 44, and Stephen Krasner, “Structural Causes and Regime Consequences: Regimes as Intervening Variables,” International Organization 36 (Spring 1982), p. 199.
    • (1977) , pp. 44
    • Keohane, R.O.1    Nye, J.2
  • 10
    • 84868884288 scopus 로고
    • Tariffs and Hegemonic Stability Theory
    • Winter and Keohane, After Hegemony, p. 37
    • Timothy J. McKeown, “Tariffs and Hegemonic Stability Theory,” International Organization 37 (Winter 1983), pp. 73–93, and Keohane, After Hegemony, p. 37.
    • (1983) International Organization , vol.37 , pp. 73-93
    • McKeown, T.J.1
  • 11
    • 84938050073 scopus 로고
    • Public Goods, Property Rights, and Political Organization
    • December
    • Duncan Snidal, “Public Goods, Property Rights, and Political Organization,” International Studies Quarterly 23 (December 1979), pp. 532–66.
    • (1979) International Studies Quarterly , vol.23 , pp. 532-566
    • Snidal, D.1
  • 12
    • 84972091498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State Power and the Structure of International Trade
    • April 1975), pp. 314–47, and John Ruggie's review of Krasner’s book in American Political Science Review 74 (March 1980)
    • Stephen Krasner, “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics 27 (April 1975), pp. 314–47, and John Ruggie's review of Krasner’s book in American Political Science Review 74 (March 1980), pp. 296–99.
    • World Politics , vol.27 , pp. 296-299
    • Krasner, S.1
  • 13
    • 84965630262 scopus 로고
    • Collective Goods and Alliances: A Reassessment
    • September
    • Joe Oppenheimer, “Collective Goods and Alliances: A Reassessment,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 23 (September 1979), pp. 387–407.
    • (1979) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.23 , pp. 387-407
    • Oppenheimer, J.1
  • 14
    • 84972218390 scopus 로고
    • The Long Cycle of Global Politics and the Nation-State
    • April
    • George Modelski, “The Long Cycle of Global Politics and the Nation-State,” Comparative Studies in Society and History 20 (April 1978), pp. 214–35.
    • (1978) Comparative Studies in Society and History , vol.20 , pp. 214-235
    • Modelski, G.1
  • 15
    • 0003848502 scopus 로고
    • Political Community and the North Atlantic Area
    • (Princeton: Princeton University Press
    • Karl W. Deutsch et al., Political Community and the North Atlantic Area (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1957).
    • (1957)
    • Deutsch, K.W.1
  • 16
    • 0002144341 scopus 로고
    • A Crisis of Hegemony
    • Samir Amin (New York: Monthly Review Press
    • Giovanni Arrighi, “A Crisis of Hegemony,” in Samir Amin et al., Dynamics of Global Crisis (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1982), p. 77.
    • (1982) Dynamics of Global Crisis , pp. 77
    • Arrighi, G.1
  • 17
    • 84971157492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I am aware that much of the hegemonic stability literature (for example, a “founding father,” [Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973]) is concerned with very specific issue-areas and goods rather than with such broader achievements or “goods” as “peace and prosperity.” Focus on narrow issue-areas makes the thesis of a decline in American hegemony more plausible—at least for those selected issue-areas. Nevertheless, issue-areas are usually selected because they are assumed, implicitly or explicitly, to be symptomatic of a broad decline in U.S. ability to maintain the conditions of global prosperity. “Peace” among industrial capitalist powers (and containment of the Soviet Union) is one of those conditions. Thus, while some hegemonic stability writing can escape the strictures of my critique, a general evaluation of the state of American “hegemony” and its consequences—an evaluation that is both common and necessary—must carry the discussion beyond selected, rather narrow issue-areas. Gilpin, War and Change, and many of the contributors to the Spring 1982 special issue of International Organization would surely agree.
    • I am aware that much of the hegemonic stability literature (for example, a “founding father,” Charles Kindleberger, The World in Depression, 1929–1939 [Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973]) is concerned with very specific issue-areas and goods rather than with such broader achievements or “goods” as “peace and prosperity.” Focus on narrow issue-areas makes the thesis of a decline in American hegemony more plausible—at least for those selected issue-areas. Nevertheless, issue-areas are usually selected because they are assumed, implicitly or explicitly, to be symptomatic of a broad decline in U.S. ability to maintain the conditions of global prosperity. “Peace” among industrial capitalist powers (and containment of the Soviet Union) is one of those conditions. Thus, while some hegemonic stability writing can escape the strictures of my critique, a general evaluation of the state of American “hegemony” and its consequences—an evaluation that is both common and necessary—must carry the discussion beyond selected, rather narrow issue-areas. Gilpin, War and Change, and many of the contributors to the Spring 1982 special issue of International Organization would surely agree.
    • Charles Kindleberger, The World in Depression , pp. 1929-1939
  • 18
    • 0000248716 scopus 로고
    • World Politics: The Menu for Choice
    • See 2d ed. (New York: W. H. Freeman, 1985), chap. 15, and Michael Doyle, “Kant, Liberal Legacies, and Foreign Affairs,” (Summer
    • See Bruce Russett and Harvey Starr, World Politics: The Menu for Choice, 2d ed. (New York: W. H. Freeman, 1985), chap. 15, and Michael Doyle, “Kant, Liberal Legacies, and Foreign Affairs,” Philosophy and Public Affairs 12 (Summer 1983), pp. 205–35.
    • (1983) Philosophy and Public Affairs , vol.12 , pp. 205-235
    • Russett, B.1    Starr, H.2
  • 19
    • 84971179574 scopus 로고
    • The terms are, respectively, from Deutsch et al., Political Community, and Kenneth E. Boulding, Stable Peace (Austin: University of Texas Press
    • The terms are, respectively, from Deutsch et al., Political Community, and Kenneth E. Boulding, Stable Peace (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1978).
    • (1978)
  • 21
    • 84970226125 scopus 로고
    • Extended Deterrence by Superpower Alliance
    • Not to me the most persuasive explanation, though see June
    • Not to me the most persuasive explanation, though see Erich Weede, “Extended Deterrence by Superpower Alliance,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 27 (June 1983), pp. 231–53.
    • (1983) Journal of Conflict Resolution 27 , pp. 231-253
    • Weede, E.1
  • 22
    • 0038943379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Structural Causes
    • Krasner, “Structural Causes,” p. 185.
    • Krasner1
  • 23
    • 84972029004 scopus 로고
    • Security Regimes
    • Spring
    • Robert Jervis, “Security Regimes,” International Organization 36 (Spring 1982), p. 371.
    • (1982) International Organization , vol.36 , pp. 371
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 24
    • 84971177238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Trauma of Decolonization: The Dutch and West New Guinea
    • New Haven: Yale University Press, 1966), chap. 11; and Townsend Hoopes, The Devil and John Foster Dulles (Boston: Little, Brown, 1973)
    • See Arend Lijphart, The Trauma of Decolonization: The Dutch and West New Guinea (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1966), chap. 11; and Townsend Hoopes, The Devil and John Foster Dulles (Boston: Little, Brown, 1973), p. 384.
    • Lijphart, A.1
  • 25
    • 84927456255 scopus 로고
    • Islamic Iran: Soviet Dilemma
    • January-February
    • See Zalmay Khalilzad, “Islamic Iran: Soviet Dilemma,” Problems of Communism 33 (January-February 1984), pp. 1–20.
    • (1984) Problems of Communism , vol.33 , pp. 1-20
    • Khalilzad, Z.1
  • 26
    • 84971132230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • After Hegemony
    • Keohane, After Hegemony, p. 34.
    • Keohane1
  • 28
    • 84971151483 scopus 로고
    • Protectionism and World Politics
    • For the comparative data on trade I am indebted to Susan Strange Spring Helen Hughes and Jean Waelbroeck, “Foreign Trade and Structural Adjustment—Is There a New Protectionism?” in Hans-Gert Braun et al., eds., The European Economy in the 1980s (Aldershot: Gower, 1983), reply that the increase in protectionism during the 1970s was very small. There is some evidence that protectionism rises during periods of cyclical economic downturn, but those increases must not be mistaken for long-term trends. On the collapse of the Bretton Woods fixed-exchange-rate system see Hugh Patrick and Henry Rosovksy, “The End of Eras? Japan and the Western World in the 1970-1980s” (paper presented at the Japan Political Economy Research Conference, Honolulu, July 1983), p. 38: “In our view, despite excessively wide swings in real rates among currencies, the flexible exchange rate system was a way of maintaining the liberal international economic order rather than being a cause of its demise.” Also see Keohane, After Hegemony, p. 213: “Substantial erosion of the trade regime. has occurred, but. what is equally striking is the persistence of cooperation even if not always addressed to liberal ends. Trade wars have not taken place, despite economic distress. On the contrary, what we see are intensive efforts at cooperation, in response to discord in textiles, steel, electronics, and other areas.” On liberalization of the Japanese economy see Raymond Vernon, Two Hungry Giants: The United States and Japan in the Quest for Oil and Ores (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1983).
    • For the comparative data on trade I am indebted to Susan Strange, “Protectionism and World Politics,” International Organization 39 (Spring 1985). Helen Hughes and Jean Waelbroeck, “Foreign Trade and Structural Adjustment—Is There a New Protectionism?” in Hans-Gert Braun et al., eds., The European Economy in the 1980s (Aldershot: Gower, 1983), reply that the increase in protectionism during the 1970s was very small. There is some evidence that protectionism rises during periods of cyclical economic downturn, but those increases must not be mistaken for long-term trends. On the collapse of the Bretton Woods fixed-exchange-rate system see Hugh Patrick and Henry Rosovksy, “The End of Eras? Japan and the Western World in the 1970-1980s” (paper presented at the Japan Political Economy Research Conference, Honolulu, July 1983), p. 38: “In our view, despite excessively wide swings in real rates among currencies, the flexible exchange rate system was a way of maintaining the liberal international economic order rather than being a cause of its demise.” Also see Keohane, After Hegemony, p. 213: “Substantial erosion of the trade regime. has occurred, but. what is equally striking is the persistence of cooperation even if not always addressed to liberal ends. Trade wars have not taken place, despite economic distress. On the contrary, what we see are intensive efforts at cooperation, in response to discord in textiles, steel, electronics, and other areas.” On liberalization of the Japanese economy see Raymond Vernon, Two Hungry Giants: The United States and Japan in the Quest for Oil and Ores (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1983).
    • (1985) International Organization , vol.39
  • 29
    • 84971175338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Crisis of Hegemony
    • One could quarrel with the use of “national interest,” and qualify it by reference to the interests of the ruling classes, but on the whole I am not inclined to do so—major qualification would require some near-heroic assumptions about false consciousness.
    • Arrighi, “A Crisis of Hegemony,” p. 65. One could quarrel with the use of “national interest,” and qualify it by reference to the interests of the ruling classes, but on the whole I am not inclined to do so—major qualification would require some near-heroic assumptions about false consciousness.
    • Arrighi1
  • 30
    • 84971172312 scopus 로고
    • The Anarchical Society
    • (New York: Columbia University Press
    • Hedley Bull, The Anarchical Society (New York: Columbia University Press, 1977).
    • (1977)
    • Bull, H.1
  • 31
    • 84971881636 scopus 로고
    • The Demand for International Regimes
    • Spring Keohane’s discussion is reminiscent of Karl W. Deutsch, The Nerves of Government (New York: Free Press, 1963).
    • Robert O. Keohane, “The Demand for International Regimes,” International Organization 36 (Spring 1982), p. 348. Keohane’s discussion is reminiscent of Karl W. Deutsch, The Nerves of Government (New York: Free Press, 1963).
    • (1982) International Organization , vol.36 , pp. 348
    • Keohane, R.O.1
  • 32
    • 84936824515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Evolution of Cooperation
    • (New York: Basic Books, 1984).
    • Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984).
    • Axelrod, R.1
  • 33
    • 84971132230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • After Hegemony
    • “So the United States farsightedly made short-term sacrifices—in growing financial aid, and in permitting discrimination against American exports—in order to accomplish the longer-term objective of creating a stable and prosperous international economic order in which liberal capitalism would prevail and American influence would be predominant.” The proposition that the burdens of empire almost inevitably outweigh its benefits is of course a common one. Note Mark Elvin, The Pattern of the Chinese Past (London: Methuen, 1973): “The burdens of size consist mainly in the need to maintain a more extended bureaucracy with more intermediate layers, the growing difficulties of effective co-ordination as territorial area increases, and the heavier costs of maintaining troops on longer front lines further removed from the main sources of trustworthy manpower and supplies” (p. 19).
    • Keohane, After Hegemony, p. 270: “So the United States farsightedly made short-term sacrifices—in growing financial aid, and in permitting discrimination against American exports—in order to accomplish the longer-term objective of creating a stable and prosperous international economic order in which liberal capitalism would prevail and American influence would be predominant.” The proposition that the burdens of empire almost inevitably outweigh its benefits is of course a common one. Note Mark Elvin, The Pattern of the Chinese Past (London: Methuen, 1973): “The burdens of size consist mainly in the need to maintain a more extended bureaucracy with more intermediate layers, the growing difficulties of effective co-ordination as territorial area increases, and the heavier costs of maintaining troops on longer front lines further removed from the main sources of trustworthy manpower and supplies” (p. 19).
    • Keohane1
  • 34
    • 84971103577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Russett and Starr
    • See Russett and Starr, World Politics, chap. 18.
    • World Politics, chap. , pp. 18
  • 35
    • 0004035291 scopus 로고
    • What Price Vigilance? The Burdens of National Defense
    • New Haven: Yale University Press
    • Bruce Russett, What Price Vigilance? The Burdens of National Defense (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1970), chap. 4.
    • (1970) , pp. 4
    • Russett, B.1
  • 36
    • 84971814948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Global Wars, Public Debts, and the Long Cycle
    • October 1983), pp. 489–516, carefully recognize the particular private benefits, to the commercially extended hegemon, of providing defense and deterrence for others. This should be set against the more familiar argument that military expenditures become a private “bad” by inhibiting capital formation and growth in the hegemon. For evidence see Rasler and Thompson, “Longitudinal Change in Defense Burdens, Capital Formation, and Economic Growth,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, forthcoming.
    • Karen Rasler and William R. Thompson, “Global Wars, Public Debts, and the Long Cycle,” World Politics 36 (October 1983), pp. 489–516, carefully recognize the particular private benefits, to the commercially extended hegemon, of providing defense and deterrence for others. This should be set against the more familiar argument that military expenditures become a private “bad” by inhibiting capital formation and growth in the hegemon. For evidence see Rasler and Thompson, “Longitudinal Change in Defense Burdens, Capital Formation, and Economic Growth,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, forthcoming.
    • World Politics , vol.36
    • Rasler, K.1    Thompson, W.R.2
  • 37
    • 84974110696 scopus 로고
    • The Hegemon's Dilemma: Great Britain, the United States, and the International Economic Order
    • Spring For the argument that free trade is not necessarily a collective good see John Conybeare, “Public Goods, Prisoners' Dilemma, and the International Political Economy,” International Studies Quarterly 28 (March 1984), pp. 5–22
    • Arthur A. Stein, “The Hegemon's Dilemma: Great Britain, the United States, and the International Economic Order,” International Organization 38 (Spring 1984), pp. 355–86. For the argument that free trade is not necessarily a collective good see John Conybeare, “Public Goods, Prisoners' Dilemma, and the International Political Economy,” International Studies Quarterly 28 (March 1984), pp. 5–22.
    • (1984) International Organization , vol.38 , pp. 355-386
    • Stein, A.A.1
  • 38
    • 84971175338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Crisis of Hegemony
    • Arrighi, “A Crisis of Hegemony,” p. 57.
    • Arrighi1
  • 39
    • 0004219175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political Control of the Economy
    • (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1980); Daniel Ellsberg, Papers on the War (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1972); and Leslie Gelb and Richard Betts, The System Worked: The Irony of Vietnam (Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 1979).
    • Edward R. Tufte, Political Control of the Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1980); Daniel Ellsberg, Papers on the War (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1972); and Leslie Gelb and Richard Betts, The System Worked: The Irony of Vietnam (Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 1979).
    • Tufte, E.R.1
  • 40
    • 0007217241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hegemonic Stability Theory Revisited
    • his brilliant paper Duncan Snidal forthcoming, notes that both Krasner, “State Power,” and Gilpin, War and Change, fully recognize the degree to which the postwar regimes benefited the United States in particular, and that Gilpin particularly argues that the United States was significantly able to extract contributions as a quasi-government.
    • In his brilliant paper Duncan Snidal, “Hegemonic Stability Theory Revisited,” International Organization, forthcoming, notes that both Krasner, “State Power,” and Gilpin, War and Change, fully recognize the degree to which the postwar regimes benefited the United States in particular, and that Gilpin particularly argues that the United States was significantly able to extract contributions as a quasi-government.
    • International Organization
  • 41
    • 84889096526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • After Hegemony
    • See Keohane
    • See Keohane, After Hegemony.
  • 42
    • 84971155596 scopus 로고
    • That is, persuading someone to do something he or she would not otherwise do; see Robert A. Dahl, Modern Political Analysis, 4th ed. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall
    • That is, persuading someone to do something he or she would not otherwise do; see Robert A. Dahl, Modern Political Analysis, 4th ed. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1984).
    • (1984)
  • 43
    • 84971157531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The United States and World Order: On Structures of World Power and Structural Transformation
    • (paper presented at the Twelfth World Congress of the International Political Science Association, Rio de Janeiro, August 1982), p. 7: “World hegemony is founded through a process of cultural and ideological development. This process is rooted mainly in the civil society of the founding country, though it has the support of the state in that country, and it extends to include groups from other countries.” Also see Norbert Elias, The Civilizing Process, vol. 2: State Formation and Civilization (Oxford: Blackwell, 1982): “Just as it was not possible in the West itself, from a certain stage of interdependence onwards, to rule people solely by force and physical threats, so it also became necessary, in maintaining an empire that went beyond mere plantation-land and plantation-labour, to rule people in part through themselves, through the moulding of their superegos. The outsiders absorb the code of the established groups and thus undergo a process of assimilation. Their own affect-control, their own conduct, obeys the rules of the established groups. Partially they identify themselves with them, and even though the identification may show strong ambivalencies, still their own conscience, their whole superego apparatus, follows more or less the pattern of the established groups.” Neither of these statements is meant to deny some reciprocal role of elites in the periphery in helping to shape the dominant world culture.
    • Robert W. Cox and Harold K. Jacobson, “The United States and World Order: On Structures of World Power and Structural Transformation” (paper presented at the Twelfth World Congress of the International Political Science Association, Rio de Janeiro, August 1982), p. 7: “World hegemony is founded through a process of cultural and ideological development. This process is rooted mainly in the civil society of the founding country, though it has the support of the state in that country, and it extends to include groups from other countries.” Also see Norbert Elias, The Civilizing Process, vol. 2: State Formation and Civilization (Oxford: Blackwell, 1982): “Just as it was not possible in the West itself, from a certain stage of interdependence onwards, to rule people solely by force and physical threats, so it also became necessary, in maintaining an empire that went beyond mere plantation-land and plantation-labour, to rule people in part through themselves, through the moulding of their superegos. The outsiders absorb the code of the established groups and thus undergo a process of assimilation. Their own affect-control, their own conduct, obeys the rules of the established groups. Partially they identify themselves with them, and even though the identification may show strong ambivalencies, still their own conscience, their whole superego apparatus, follows more or less the pattern of the established groups.” Neither of these statements is meant to deny some reciprocal role of elites in the periphery in helping to shape the dominant world culture.
    • Cox, R.W.1    Jacobson, H.K.2
  • 44
    • 84971103547 scopus 로고
    • Power in a Schedule Sense
    • They form, for instance, a key element in conception of power Alker, eds (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass
    • They form, for instance, a key element in conception of power. Hayward R. Alker, “Power in a Schedule Sense,” in Alker et al., eds., Mathematical Approaches to Politics (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 1972).
    • (1972) Mathematical Approaches to Politics
    • Alker, H.R.1
  • 45
    • 84971922404 scopus 로고
    • Coordination and Collaboration: Regimes in an Anarchic World
    • Spring
    • Arthur A. Stein, “Coordination and Collaboration: Regimes in an Anarchic World,” International Organization 36 (Spring 1982), p. 324.
    • (1982) International Organization , vol.36 , pp. 324
    • Stein, A.A.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.