메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn , Issue , 2011, Pages 152-182

Trade secret law and information development incentives

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84874703849     PISSN: None     EISSN: None     Source Type: Book    
DOI: None     Document Type: Chapter
Times cited : (9)

References (55)
  • 1
    • 10944256273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property
    • noting that the 'incentive' versus 'access' paradigm is important in intellectual propert but that it should not be the only analysis to consider
    • Landes and Richard A. Posner, The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property 11, 115-23 (2003) (noting that the 'incentive' versus 'access' paradigm is important in intellectual property, but that it should not be the only analysis to consider)
    • (2003) , vol.11 , pp. 115-123
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 3
    • 84882045240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Eric von Hippel and Georg von Krogh, Chapter 9.
    • See generally Eric von Hippel and Georg von Krogh, Chapte
    • , vol.9
  • 5
    • 84882026313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss Dethroning Lear: Licensee Estoppel and the Incentive to Innovate, 72 Va. L. Rev. 677, 696-7 (1986); Luigi Franzoni and Vincenzo Denicolo, Innovation, Duplication, and the Contract Theory of Patents, in The Economics of Innovation: Incentives, Cooperation, and R&D Policy (R. Cellini and L. Lambertini eds., 2008)
  • 7
    • 61649109858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Promoting Innovation in the Software Industry: A First Principles Approach to Intellectual
    • Bruce Abramson, Promoting Innovation in the Software Industry: A First Principles Approach to Intellectual Property Reform, 8 B.U. Sci. & Tech. L. 75, 94-5 (2002).
    • (2002) Property Reform, 8 B.U. Sci. & Tech. L. , vol.75 , pp. 94-95
    • Abramson, B.1
  • 9
    • 84881995277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In theory, the price of the product would be the marginal cost of production because Intuit's development costs are sunk. However, return on development investment would be considered part of the marginal cost - an opportunity cost, but a cost nonetheless. This is obviously true in reality, because the cost of software is not zero, even in highly competitive markets (such as the tax market).
    • In theory, the price of the product would be the marginal cost of production because Intuit's development costs are sunk. However, return on development investment would be considered part of the marginal cost - an opportunity cost, but a cost nonetheless. This is obviously true in reality, because the cost of software is not zero, even in highly competitive markets (such as the tax market).
  • 10
    • 84882017795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is similar to copyright protection in the same code. The copyright gives the developer a private good to sell; without protection, the code could be copied, driving the price to zero. Software is often described as a potential natural monopoly due to the high ratio between development costs, which are substantial in some cases, and virtually zero reproduction costs.
    • This is similar to copyright protection in the same code. The copyright gives the developer a private good to sell; without protection, the code could be copied, driving the price to zero. Software is often described as a potential natural monopoly due to the high ratio between development costs, which are substantial in some cases, and virtually zero reproduction costs.
  • 11
    • 43049181882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perfectly Competitive Innovation
    • Stephen N.S. Cheung, Property Rights and Trade Secrets, 20 Econ. Inquiry 40 (1982).
    • Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine, Perfectly Competitive Innovation, 55 J. Monetary Econ. 435 (2008); Stephen N.S. Cheung, Property Rights and Trade Secrets, 20 Econ. Inquiry 40 (1982).
    • (2008) J. Monetary Econ. , vol.55 , Issue.435
    • Boldrin, M.1    Levine, D.K.2
  • 12
    • 0007138124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of Damages Rules in Intellectual Property Law
    • Roger D. Blair and Thomas F. Cotter, An Economic Analysis of Damages Rules in Intellectual Property Law, 39 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 1585, 1642 (1998).
    • (1998) Wm. & Mary L. Rev. , vol.39 , pp. 1585-1642
    • Blair, R.D.1    Cotter, T.F.2
  • 13
    • 84881978274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 431 F.2d 1012 (5th Cir. 1970).
    • 431 F.2d 1012 (5th Cir. 1970).
  • 14
    • 84882005478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Secrets: How Well Should We be Allowed to Hide Them? The Economic Espionage Act of 1996, 9 Fordham Intell.
    • Dreyfuss R.C.
    • Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss, Trade Secrets: How Well Should We be Allowed to Hide Them? The Economic Espionage Act of 1996, 9 Fordham Intell. Prop. Media & Ent. L.J. 1, 37 (1998).
    • (1998) Prop. Media & Ent. L.J. , vol.1 , pp. 37
  • 15
    • 84881979607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Goldilocks Hypothesis: Balancing Intellectual Property Rights at the Boundary of the Firm 2007
    • Burk and Brett H. McDonnell, The Goldilocks Hypothesis: Balancing Intellectual Property Rights at the Boundary of the Firm, 2007 U. Ill. L. Rev. 575, 601-2.
    • U. Ill. L. Rev. , vol.575 , pp. 601-602
    • Burk, D.L.1    McDonnell, B.H.2
  • 16
    • 1842764780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Intellectual Property and the Firm, 71
    • Dan L. Burk, Intellectual Property and the Firm, 71 U. Chi. L. Rev. 3, 8-9 (2004).
    • (2004) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.3 , pp. 8-9
    • Burk, D.L.1
  • 17
    • 84881984331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • California Labor Code § 2860 (West 2003); Nathan Newman, Trade Secrets and Collective Bargaining: A Solution to Resolving Tensions in the Economics of Innovation, 6 Emp. Rts. & Emp. Pol'y J. 1, 43 (2002).
  • 18
    • 29644436035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Petra Moser, How do Patent Laws Infl uence Innovation? Evidence from Nineteenth- Century World's Fairs, 95 Am. Econ. Rev. 1214, 1231 (2005) (in countries without patent laws, innovation shifted toward industries in which secrecy was available).
  • 19
    • 1642499810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lawrence Lessig, The Future of Ideas: The Fate of the Commons in a Connected World 70-1 (2001); Paul Almeida and Bruce Kogut, Localization of Knowledge and the Mobility of Engineers in Regional Networks, 45(7) Mgmt. Sci. 905 (1999); John Dubiansky, The Role of Patents in Fostering Open Innovation, 11 Va. J.L. & Tech. 7 (2006), 14; Ronald J. Gilson, The Legal Infrastructure of High Technology Industrial Districts: Silicon Valley, Route 128, and Covenants not to Compete, 74 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 575, 600-1 (1999).
    • Alan Hyde, Working in Silicon Valley: Economic and Legal Analysis of a High- Velocity Labor Market (2003); Lawrence Lessig, The Future of Ideas: The Fate of the Commons in a Connected World 70-1 (2001); Paul Almeida and Bruce Kogut, Localization of Knowledge and the Mobility of Engineers in Regional Networks, 45(7) Mgmt. Sci. 905 (1999); John Dubiansky, The Role of Patents in Fostering Open Innovation, 11 Va. J.L. & Tech. 7 (2006), 14; Ronald J. Gilson, The Legal Infrastructure of High Technology Industrial Districts: Silicon Valley, Route 128, and Covenants not to Compete, 74 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 575, 600-1 (1999).
    • Working in Silicon Valley: Economic and Legal Analysis of a High- Velocity Labor Market _rfpy1 2003
    • Hyde, A.1
  • 20
    • 10144233542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Top Ten Issues in Trade Secret Law,
    • James Pooley, The Top Ten Issues in Trade Secret Law, 70 Temp. L. Rev. 1181, 1182 (1997).
    • (1997) Temp. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 1181-1182
    • Pooley, J.1
  • 21
    • 11244330454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Yale University Press, New Haven, 2004).
    • Doron S. Ben- Atar, Trade Secrets 99-101 (Yale University Press, New Haven, 2004).
    • Trade Secrets , pp. 99-101
    • Ben-Atar, D.S.1
  • 22
    • 84881990521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Patents, Citations and Innovations 174-5 (2002).
    • Adam B. Jaffe and Manuel Trajtenberg, Patents, Citations and Innovations 174-5 (2002).
    • Jaffe, A.B.1    Trajtenberg, M.2
  • 24
    • 85040020717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Experimental Approach to the Study of Normative Failures: Divulging of Secrets by Silicon Valley Employees
    • Yuval Feldman, Experimental Approach to the Study of Normative Failures: Divulging of Secrets by Silicon Valley Employees, 2003 U. Ill. J.L. Tech. & Pol'y 105, 119.
    • (2003) U. Ill. J.L. Tech. & Pol'y , vol.105 , pp. 119
    • Feldman, Y.1
  • 27
    • 84882023788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Feist Publications, Inc. v. Rural Telephone Service Co., 499 U.S. 340, 349 (1991); ABBA Rubber Co. v. Seaquist, 286 Cal. Rptr. 518 (Cal. Ct. App. 1991).
    • Feist Publications, Inc. v. Rural Telephone Service Co., 499 U.S. 340, 349 (1991); ABBA Rubber Co. v. Seaquist, 286 Cal. Rptr. 518 (Cal. Ct. App. 1991).
  • 28
    • 84882002946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two parties can own the same trademark, so long as the mark protects different goods and services, or if they exclusively serve diff erent geographic regions. Such overlap is not really 'identical' information as that term is used here because they actually designate diff erent origination sources for diff erent types of goods.
  • 29
    • 84881990641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • California Civil Code § 3426.1(a) (West 1997) ('Reverse engineering or independent derivation alone shall not be considered improper means'). The Uniform Trade Secrets Act (UTSA) does not include this sentence, though reverse engineering is commonly accepted as an exception to improper means. Uniform Trade Secrets Act § 1 (amended 1985), 14 U.L.A. 437 (West Supp. 2006).
  • 30
    • 84882031378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 17 U.S.C. § 107 (2006).
    • 17 U.S.C. § 107 (2006).
  • 31
    • 84881994501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 35 U.S.C. § 101 (2006).
    • 35 U.S.C. § 101 (2006).
  • 32
    • 84882038585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1051(a) (2006).
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1051(a) (2006).
  • 33
    • 84882006048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inc. v. Metcalfe, 290 P.2d 646, 654 (Cal. Ct. App. 1955) (fi nding that peculiar 'likes and fancies' of customers are protectable).
    • Alex Foods, Inc. v. Metcalfe, 290 P.2d 646, 654 (Cal. Ct. App. 1955) (fi nding that peculiar 'likes and fancies' of customers are protectable).
    • Foods, A.1
  • 34
    • 84881996280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see 15 U.S.C. § 1051(b) (2006) (registration for intent to use).
    • But see 15 U.S.C. § 1051(b) (2006) (registration for intent to use).
  • 35
    • 84882036585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 17 U.S.C. § 411 (2006).
    • 17 U.S.C. § 411 (2006).
  • 36
    • 84882008567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 35 U.S.C. § 111 (2006); but see California Code of Civil Procedure § 2019.210 (West 2005) (requiring a plaintiff to identify the trade secrets at issue prior to discovery). Section 2019.210 is formerly and better known as § 2019(d).
    • 35 U.S.C. § 111 (2006); but see California Code of Civil Procedure § 2019.210 (West 2005) (requiring a plaintiff to identify the trade secrets at issue prior to discovery). Section 2019.210 is formerly and better known as § 2019(d).
  • 37
    • 84882011234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DVD Copy Control Ass'n v. Bunner, 10 Cal. Rptr. 3d 185, 192-3 (Cal. Ct. App. 2004) ('Publication on the Internet does not necessarily destroy the secret if the publication is suffi ciently obscure or transient or otherwise limited so that it does not become generally known to the relevant people, i.e., potential competitors or other persons to whom the information would have some economic value').
  • 38
    • 24644446871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Decision to Patent, Cumulative Innovation, and Optimal Policy
    • Sharon K. Sandeen, Kewanee Revisited: Returning to First Principles of Intellectual Property Law to Determine the Issue of Federal Preemption, 12 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 301, 344 (2008).
    • Nisvan Erkal, The Decision to Patent, Cumulative Innovation, and Optimal Policy, 23 Int'l J. Indus. Org. 535 (2005); Sharon K. Sandeen, Kewanee Revisited: Returning to First Principles of Intellectual Property Law to Determine the Issue of Federal Preemption, 12 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 301, 344 (2008).
    • (2005) Int'l J. Indus. Org. , vol.23 , pp. 535
    • Erkal, N.1
  • 39
    • 84882033037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 22 F.3d 290 (Fed. Cir. 1994). toward industries that provided eff ective secrecy).
    • 22 F.3d 290 (Fed. Cir. 1994). toward industries that provided eff ective secrecy).
  • 40
    • 84882028268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (arguing that market experimentation need not be (and often is not) secret in order to provide an incentive to experiment).
    • (arguing that market experimentation need not be (and often is not) secret in order to provide an incentive to experiment).
  • 41
    • 61349148630 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Users as Innovators: Implications for Patent Doctrine
    • Katherine J. Strandburg, Users as Innovators: Implications for Patent Doctrine, 79 U. Colo. L. Rev. 467, 476-7 (2008).
    • (2008) U. Colo. L. Rev. , vol.79 , Issue.467 , pp. 476-477
    • Strandburg, K.J.1
  • 43
    • 84882037542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chapter 18 for a further discussion of data exclusivity.
    • See Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Chapter 18 for a further discussion of data exclusivity.
    • Eisenberg, R.S.1
  • 44
    • 84882025195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Applications can cost from U.S.$2,500 to U.S.$250,000 or more depending on the nature of the application and any challenges to it on appeal or during patent interferences. Even U.S.$2,500 will be cost prohibitive for many individual or small company inventors.
  • 45
    • 84881686605 scopus 로고
    • Patenting in the Shadow of Competitors, 38
    • Josh Lerner, Patenting in the Shadow of Competitors, 38 J.L. & Econ. 463 (1995).
    • (1995) J.L. & Econ. , vol.463
    • Lerner, J.1
  • 46
    • 84882015901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is no requirement that a registration be fi led at all in order to secure a copyright, though in the United States one must fi le a registration in order to pursue an infringement claim.
  • 47
    • 84882014213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pseudo- code is a non- functional representation of computer code written in plain English rather than in a computer language. For example, the computer code c := a+b might be expressed in pseudo- code as 'add the values of variables a and b and assign the result to c'.
  • 48
    • 84882015597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The discussion above explains how trade secrets might provide an independent incentive to create source code where the law provides protection from disclosure by a regulatory agency (here, the Copyright Offi ce). Diane Zimmerman in Chapter 13 further discusses issues associated with copyright registration of trade secrets.
  • 49
    • 84881984231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, the Copyright Offi ce might allow 'secret' registrations without trade secret law, but in a world where trade secrets are not recognized by law, there is no reason to expect governmental agencies to protect information just because a company wants to keep it secret. In that sense, the existence of the law shifts the mindset toward protection.
  • 50
    • 84882040818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pseudo- code is a non- functional representation of computer code written in plain English rather than in a computer language. For example, the computer code c := a+b might be expressed in pseudo- code as 'add the values of variables a and b and assign the result to c'.
  • 51
    • 84882013601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The discussion above explains how trade secrets might provide an independent incentive to create source code where the law provides protection from disclosure by a regulatory agency (here, the Copyright Offi ce). Diane Zimmerman in Chapter 13 further discusses issues associated with copyright registration of trade secrets.
  • 52
    • 84882000528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, the Copyright Offi ce might allow 'secret' registrations without trade secret law, but in a world where trade secrets are not recognized by law, there is no reason to expect governmental agencies to protect information just because a company wants to keep it secret. In that sense, the existence of the law shifts the mindset toward protection.
  • 53
    • 84882012188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Software becomes less copyable if it is distributed with a 'dongle', a physical device that must be connected to the computer before the software will operate.
  • 54
    • 84882017284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Accessibility and Commercialization in Copyright Theory,
    • Robert A. Kreiss, Accessibility and Commercialization in Copyright Theory,
    • Kreiss, R.A.1
  • 55
    • 84881991665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • UCLA L. Rev. 1, 54-6 (1995). The DMCA is similar to trade secret law with respect to spending on protection; without the DMCA, more money would be spent on technology, such as better encryption or more fragmented data, which would better limit access to copyrighted work in the absence of a remedy for bypassing the control. The DMCA creates an incentive for information producers to limit overspending on access control technology. 101 Despite its fame, the 'special sauce' mark is not a registered trademark. The only registered mark associated with the 'special sauce' is Twoallbeefpattiesspecialsaucelettucecheesepicklesonionsonasesameseedbun® to McDonald's Corp. Even unregistered, however, the 'special sauce' mark has trademark value, as a diff erent company attempted to obtain 'special sauce' as a trademark covering a sandwich dressing and had the mark cancelled. 102 Quite often the secret sauce claimed by trade secrets plaintiff s ends up looking a lot like Thousand Island dressing. Indeed, the trade secret status of the 'special sauce' is dubious since it can be reverse engineered. One such attempt is available at www.topsecretrecipes.com/recipedetail.asp?id=65. Even so, the actual recipe is so closely guarded that McDonald's itself lost the recipe for a time. Wallet Pop, Closely- Guarded Trade Secrets, www.walletpop.com/specials/ closely- guarded- trade- secrets?photo=2. 103 Samuel D. Warren and Louis D. Brandeis, The Right to Privacy, 4 Harv. L. Rev. 193, 199-200 (1890) (emphasis in original). 109 Uniform Trade Secrets Act §7 ('except as provided in subsection (b), this [Act] displaces confl icting tort, restitutionary, and other law of this State providing civil remedies for misappropriation of a trade secret'). Of course, private information may be excluded from the pre- emption if the information does not fall under the defi nition of trade secret. Charles Tait Graves in Chapter 4 further discusses pre- emption. to the right of privacy).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.