메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 160, Issue 7, 2012, Pages 2061-2095

The property strategy

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84864058037     PISSN: 00419907     EISSN: 19428537     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (40)

References (88)
  • 1
    • 0004252521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These descriptions of alternatives are skeletal and are not meant to be exhaustive. With respect to bureaucratic governance, for example, what I principally have in mind are government bureaucracies, such as the Bureau of Land Management, state highway commissions, and municipal public housing authorities. Obviously, there are many other types of hierarchical organizations that manage resources, including business corporations and nonprofit organizations like universities. See generally HENRY HANSMANN, THE OWNERSHIP OF ENTERPRISE (1996). I do not explore the many distinctions among different hierarchical organizations here, nor do I deny that from the perspective of an organization, its assets are typically held as a form of private property. Group consensus also covers a variety of subtypes, ranging from preliterate hunting clans to Israeli kibbutzim to cooperative apartment houses.
    • (1996) The Ownership of Enterprise
    • Hansmann, H.1
  • 3
    • 84861370985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property as the law of things
    • 1700-16
    • See Henry E. Smith, Property as the Law of Things, 125 HARV. L. REV. 1691, 1700-16 (2012) (discussing "the modularity of things and by extension the legal relations defined in terms of them").
    • (2012) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.125 , pp. 1691
    • Smith, H.E.1
  • 4
    • 77950127937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Both ideas and cultural knowledge are excluded from intellectual property regimes. See, e.g., 17 U. S. C. § 102 (b) (2006) ("In no case does copyright protection⋯ extend to any idea,⋯ concept, principle, or discovery⋯.");
    • (2006) U. S. C. , vol.17 , pp. 102
  • 5
    • 0004755432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grounded visions: Native American conceptions of landscapes and ceremony
    • Russel L. Barsh, Grounded Visions: Native American Conceptions of Landscapes and Ceremony, 13 ST. THOMAS L. REV. 127, 141 (2000) ("[C]opyright only applies to new works by individual authors, not to old collective traditions, or 'folklore.'").
    • (2000) St. Thomas L. Rev. , vol.13 , pp. 127
    • Barsh, R.L.1
  • 6
    • 33745696180 scopus 로고
    • Bd. of Regents v. Roth
    • 573-74
    • See Bd. of Regents v. Roth, 408 U. S. 564, 573-74 (1972) (discussing reputation as a liberty interest, not a property interest).
    • (1972) U. S. , vol.408 , pp. 564
  • 7
    • 33847234641 scopus 로고
    • Moore v. Regents of the Univ. of Cal
    • 489
    • See Moore v. Regents of the Univ. of Cal., 793 P.2d 479, 489 (Cal. 1990) (holding that spleen cells were not the property of the patient from whom they were extracted).
    • (1990) P.2d , vol.793 , pp. 479
  • 8
    • 0347684363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The landscape of constitutional property
    • 900-07, 974-78
    • Thomas W. Merrill, The Landscape of Constitutional Property, 86 VA. L. REV. 885, 900-07, 974-78 (2000).
    • (2000) Va. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 885
    • Merrill, T.W.1
  • 9
    • 0003712986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See J. W. HARRIS, PROPERTY AND JUSTICE 50-51 (1996) (discussing how "cashable rights" "are treated as property");
    • (1996) Property and Justice , pp. 50-51
    • Harris, J.W.1
  • 10
    • 0004132521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J. E. PENNER, THE IDEA OF PROPERTY IN LAW 129-32 (1997) (discussing choses in action, a category of property encompassing company shares, bank balances, debts, and other negotiable instruments).
    • (1997) The Idea of Property in Law , pp. 129-132
    • Penner, J.E.1
  • 11
    • 0041669221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Introduction: The demsetz thesis and the evolution of property rights
    • S331
    • See Thomas W. Merrill, Introduction: The Demsetz Thesis and the Evolution of Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S331, S331 (2002) ("[P]roperty regimes are not static but change over time.");
    • (2002) J. Legal Stud. , vol.31
    • Merrill, T.W.1
  • 12
    • 84917275342 scopus 로고
    • The evolution of property rights: A study of the American west
    • 164-68
    • see also Terry L. Anderson & P. J. Hill, The Evolution of Property Rights: A Study of the American West, 18 J. L. & ECON. 163, 164-68 (1975) (presenting "a theory of property rights evolution" expressed in terms of marginal benefits and costs).
    • (1975) J. L. & Econ. , vol.18 , pp. 163
    • Anderson, T.L.1    Hill, P.J.2
  • 13
    • 84904656914 scopus 로고
    • The comedy of the commons: Custom, commerce, and inherently public property
    • 723-30
    • See Carol Rose, The Comedy of the Commons: Custom, Commerce, and Inherently Public Property, 53 U. CHI. L. REV. 711, 723-30 (1986) (offering examples of and considering various rationales for open-access resources).
    • (1986) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.53 , pp. 711
    • Rose, C.1
  • 14
    • 18344388926 scopus 로고
    • Missouri v. Holland
    • 431, 434
    • See, e.g., Missouri v. Holland, 252 U. S. 416, 431, 434 (1920) ("[Missouri] alleges a pecuniary interest, as owner of the wild birds within its borders⋯. Wild birds are not in the possession of anyone; and possession is the beginning of ownership⋯. [T]omorrow [they] may be in another State and in a week a thousand miles away.");
    • (1920) U. S. , vol.252 , pp. 416
  • 15
    • 77951952671 scopus 로고
    • Pierson v. Post
    • 178
    • Pierson v. Post, 3 Cai. 175, 178 (N. Y. Sup. Ct. 1805) ("The⋯ authorities are decisive to shew, that mere pursuit, gave Post no legal right to the fox, but that he became the property of Pierson, who intercepted and killed him."). A number of commentators have suggested that an open-access resource like a fishery can be regarded as a form of community property.
    • (1805) Cai. , vol.3 , pp. 175
  • 16
    • 0001394870 scopus 로고
    • Toward a theory of property rights
    • 354
    • See, e.g., Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 AM. ECON. REV. 347, 354 (1967)
    • (1967) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.57 , pp. 347
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 17
    • 85194342840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Open access versus common property
    • ("Communal ownership means that the community denies to the state or to individual citizens the right to interfere with any person's exercise of communally-owned rights."). Community property presents an interesting borderline case because, insofar as the community excludes outsiders and is governed by a welldefined and enforced set of norms, it is not inappropriate to describe the community as a manager and, therefore, to regard the arrangement as falling within the property strategy. As exclusion of outsiders weakens and norms become contested, such communities tend to look more like open-access regimes. The further a communityregulated resource falls toward the open-access end of the spectrum, the less plausible it is to regard it as being managed in any meaningful sense, and hence to regard it as following the property strategy. See generally Thráinn Eggertsson, Open Access Versus Common Property, in PROPERTY RIGHTS: COOPERATION, CONFLICT, AND LAW 73, 86 (Terry L. Anderson & Fred S. McChesney eds., 2003).
    • (2003) Property Rights: Cooperation, Conflict, and Law , pp. 73
    • Eggertsson, T.1
  • 18
    • 4444277517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The origins of the American public trust doctrine: What really happened in Illinois Central
    • 801-03
    • See Joseph D. Kearney & Thomas W. Merrill, The Origins of the American Public Trust Doctrine: What Really Happened in Illinois Central, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 799, 801-03 (2004).
    • (2004) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 799
    • Kearney, J.D.1    Merrill, T.W.2
  • 19
    • 84864056504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Golan v. Holder
    • 882
    • See, e.g., Golan v. Holder, 132 S. Ct. 873, 882 (2012).
    • (2012) S. Ct. , vol.132 , pp. 873
  • 20
    • 84864034622 scopus 로고
    • 87 &, 112
    • See, e.g., A. S. DIAMOND, PRIMITIVE LAW PAST AND PRESENT 82-83, 87 & n. 3, 112 (1971) (noting that in ancient Babylonian law "the father of the family⋯ [became] the legal owner of all its property", in ancient Chinese law "the wife owned no⋯ property", and in ancient Indian law the wife also had no property (citations omitted)).
    • (1971) A. S. Diamond, Primitive Law Past and Present , Issue.3 , pp. 82-83
  • 21
    • 0011536887 scopus 로고
    • Married women's property law: 1800-1850
    • 1384-412
    • See generally Richard H. Chused, Married Women's Property Law: 1800-1850, 71 GEO. L. J. 1359, 1384-412 (1983) (tracing the development of married women's property acts in both England and the United States);
    • (1983) Geo. L. J. , vol.71 , pp. 1359
    • Chused, R.H.1
  • 22
    • 30444460236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Class, gender, and liberalism in parliament, 1868-1882: The case of the married women's property acts
    • 62-83
    • Ben Griffin, Class, Gender, and Liberalism in Parliament, 1868-1882: The Case of the Married Women's Property Acts, 46 HIST. J. 59, 62-83 (2003) (chronicling the reform in British law brought about by the Married Women's Property Acts).
    • (2003) Hist. J. , vol.46 , pp. 59
    • Griffin, B.1
  • 23
    • 0037678339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property and the right to exclude
    • 731
    • Thomas W. Merrill, Property and the Right to Exclude, 77 NEB. L. REV. 730, 731 (1998).
    • (1998) Neb. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 730
    • Merrill, T.W.1
  • 24
    • 0004191128 scopus 로고
    • JEREMY WALDRON, THE RIGHT TO PRIVATE PROPERTY 39 (1988) ("The owner of a resource is simply the individual whose determination as to the use of the resource is taken as final⋯.").
    • (1988) The Right to Private Property , pp. 39
    • Waldron, J.1
  • 25
    • 84919642169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HANOCH DAGAN, PROPERTY: VALUES AND INSTITUTIONS 37 (2011) (conceding that "every property right involves some power to exclude others from doing something").
    • (2011) Property: Values and Institutions , pp. 37
    • Dagan, H.1
  • 26
    • 80051879506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • *2 ("[P]roperty [is] that sole and despotic dominion which one man claims and exercises over the external things of the world, in total exclusion of the right of any other individual in the universe.");
    • William Blackstone, Commentaries , vol.2 , pp. 2
  • 27
    • 0003370480 scopus 로고
    • Property and sovereignty
    • cf. Morris R. Cohen, Property and Sovereignty, 13 CORNELL L. Q. 8 (1927) (developing the analogy between ownership and sovereignty).
    • (1927) Cornell L. Q. , vol.13 , pp. 8
    • Cohen, M.R.1
  • 28
    • 77249161152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusion and exclusivity in property law
    • 278
    • See, e.g., Larissa Katz, Exclusion and Exclusivity in Property Law, 58 U. TORONTO L. J. 275, 278 (2008).
    • (2008) U. Toronto L. J. , vol.58 , pp. 275
    • Katz, L.1
  • 29
    • 0003740491 scopus 로고
    • Something similar to my two prerogatives has been recognized by what is sometimes called the "property rights" theory of the business firm. According to this account, the owners of a business firm (the shareholders) have two key entitlements: the power to make residual control decisions and the right to receive residual financial flows. See PAUL MILGROM & JOHN ROBERTS, ECONOMICS, ORGANIZATION AND MANAGEMENT 288-93 (1992) (introducing the concepts of residual control and residual returns);
    • (1992) Economics, Organization and Management , pp. 288-293
    • Milgrom, P.1    Roberts, J.2
  • 30
    • 84934453985 scopus 로고
    • Property rights and the nature of the firm
    • 1120-21
    • Oliver Hart & John Moore, Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm, 98 J. POL. ECON. 1119, 1120-21 (1990) (same);
    • (1990) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.98 , pp. 1119
    • Hart, O.1    Moore, J.2
  • 31
    • 84936194550 scopus 로고
    • The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration
    • 716
    • see also Sanford J. Grossman & Oliver D. Hart, The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration, 94 J. POL. ECON. 691, 716 (1986) ("Ownership is the purchase of⋯ residual rights of control."). Bob Ellickson has extended this analysis from the business firm to the household.
    • (1986) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.94 , pp. 691
    • Grossman, S.J.1    Hart, O.D.2
  • 33
    • 0003994492 scopus 로고
    • Armen Alchian may have been the first to perceive this feature of the property strategy. He described property rights as "a method of assigning to particular individuals the 'authority' to select, for specific goods, any use from a nonprohibited class of uses." ARMEN A. ALCHIAN, ECONOMIC FORCES AT WORK 130 (1977) (emphasis added).
    • (1977) Economic Forces at Work , pp. 130
    • Alchian, A.A.1
  • 34
    • 0041669218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusion versus governance: Two strategies for delineating property rights
    • What I am characterizing as "subtractions" from owner managerial authority can also be regarded as alternative methods of delineating property rights. See Henry E. Smith, Exclusion Versus Governance: Two Strategies for Delineating Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S453, S454-55 (2002) (arguing that property "rights fall on a spectrum between the poles of exclusion and governance", and that in addition to the issue of who can exclude whom, we must attend to "a wide range of rules, from contractual provisions, to norms of proper use, to nuisance law and public environmental regulation" that limit the property right in question).
    • (2002) J. Legal Stud. , vol.31
    • Smith, H.E.1
  • 35
    • 0005303148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What happened to property in law and economics?
    • 375-84
    • See Thomas W. Merrill & Henry E. Smith, What Happened to Property in Law and Economics?, 111 YALE L. J. 357, 375-84 (2001) (criticizing the list-of-uses conception of property adopted in post-Coasean law and economics as "lead[ing] to an incomplete picture of property").
    • (2001) Yale L. J. , vol.111 , pp. 357
    • Merrill, T.W.1    Smith, H.E.2
  • 36
    • 84864051271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • China reins in entertainment and blogging
    • Oct. 27
    • See, e.g., Sharon LaFraniere et al., China Reins In Entertainment and Blogging, N. Y. TIMES, Oct. 27, 2011, at A1 (discussing examples of Internet and media censorship in China);
    • (2011) N. Y. Times
    • Lafraniere, S.1
  • 37
    • 84864073728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beijing imposes new rules on social networking sites
    • Dec. 17
    • Edward Wong, Beijing Imposes New Rules on Social Networking Sites, N. Y. TIMES, Dec. 17, 2011, at A9 (same).
    • (2011) N. Y. Times
    • Wong, E.1
  • 38
    • 80052612791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Accession and original ownership
    • 462-74
    • For a discussion of the wide range and ubiquity of accessionary rights, see Thomas W. Merrill, Accession and Original Ownership, 1 J. LEGAL ANALYSIS 459, 462-74 (2009).
    • (2009) J. Legal Analysis , vol.1 , pp. 459
    • Merrill, T.W.1
  • 40
    • 0010463099 scopus 로고
    • 91-94, 327-29, 528
    • See TRIMBLE R. HEDGES, FARM MANAGEMENT DECISIONS 17-20, 91-94, 327-29, 528 (1963) (recognizing that farmers are subject to government regulation of pesticide use, the common law of property and contract, controls that accompany government subsidies, employment rules promulgated by regulatory agencies, and social customs);
    • (1963) Farm Management Decisions , pp. 17-20
    • Hedges, T.R.1
  • 42
    • 0001789397 scopus 로고
    • G. F. WARREN, FARM MANAGEMENT 525 (1914) ("One's success is very largely controlled by the community.").
    • (1914) Farm Management , pp. 525
    • Warren, G.F.1
  • 43
    • 0003691257 scopus 로고
    • Peter Laslett ed., Cambridge Univ. Press
    • See, e.g., JOHN LOCKE, TWO TREATISES OF GOVERNMENT 305 (Peter Laslett ed., Cambridge Univ. Press 1960) (1690) ("[T]he wild Indian⋯ knows no Inclosure, and is still a Tenant in common⋯.");
    • (1690) Two Treatises of Government , pp. 305
    • Locke, J.1
  • 44
    • 0004312118 scopus 로고
    • Peter Smith ed.
    • HENRY SUMNER MAINE, ANCIENT LAW 124-32 (Peter Smith ed., 1970) (1861) (conjecturing that private property evolved out of common or communal property).
    • (1861) Ancient Law , pp. 124-132
    • Maine, H.S.1
  • 45
    • 0003942014 scopus 로고
    • Extremely primitive hunter-gatherer clans may have had little sense of individual possession, in part because they put a premium on being able to travel light. See MARSHALL SAHLINS, STONE AGE ECONOMICS 9-14 (1972). Others have surveyed the anthropological understanding of property among more advanced preliterate societies.
    • (1972) Stone Age Economics , pp. 9-14
    • Sahlins, M.1
  • 46
    • 84934453528 scopus 로고
    • Approximate optimality of aboriginal property rights
    • See, e.g., Martin J. Bailey, Approximate Optimality of Aboriginal Property Rights, 35 J. L. & ECON. 183 (1992);
    • (1992) J. L. & Econ. , vol.35 , pp. 183
    • Bailey, M.J.1
  • 47
    • 0003533912 scopus 로고
    • see also MELVILLE J. HERSKOVITS, ECONOMIC ANTHROPOLOGY 350-70 (1952) (describing land tenure in various agricultural societies);
    • (1952) Economic Anthropology , pp. 350-370
    • Herskovits, M.J.1
  • 48
    • 0040760128 scopus 로고
    • E. ADAMSON HOEBEL, THE LAW OF PRIMITIVE MAN 46-63 (1954) (applying "fundamental legal concepts" to the study of the "law" of primitive societies).
    • (1954) The Law of Primitive Man , pp. 46-63
    • Hoebel, E.A.1
  • 50
    • 0001791014 scopus 로고
    • A theory of primitive society, with special reference to law
    • 16-19, 24-25
    • Richard A. Posner, A Theory of Primitive Society, with Special Reference to Law, 23 J. L. & ECON. 1, 16-19, 24-25 (1980) (same).
    • (1980) J. L. & Econ. , vol.23 , pp. 1
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 52
    • 33947542912 scopus 로고
    • Property in land
    • 1399
    • see also Robert C. Ellickson, Property in Land, 102 Yale L. J. 1315, 1399 (1993) (reporting a "'universally applicable' cultural rule that a crop is the private property of the individual, household, or narrow kinship line that has cultivated it" (citation omitted)).
    • (1993) Yale L. J. , vol.102 , pp. 1315
    • Ellickson, R.C.1
  • 53
    • 84864065618 scopus 로고
    • See 1 JEREMY BENTHAM, THEORY OF LEGISLATION 146-47 (Étienne Dumont ed., Charles Milner Atkinson trans., 1914) (1802) ("Property and law were born together, and would die together. Before the laws property did not exist; take away the laws, and property will be no more.").
    • (1802) Theory of Legislation , vol.1 , pp. 146-147
    • Bentham, J.1
  • 54
    • 0004258026 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JAMES M. ACHESON, THE LOBSTER GANGS OF MAINE 71-83 (1988) (documenting informal allocations of rights among lobster fishermen);
    • (1988) The Lobster Gangs of Maine , pp. 71-83
    • Acheson, J.M.1
  • 58
    • 0003410706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 3d ed
    • See MAURICE J. MEISNER, MAO'S CHINA AND AFTER 420 (3d ed. 1999) ("[I]t was precisely the absence of private ownership of the means of production that came to crucially define Chinese society only a few years after the Communist victory of 1949.");
    • (1999) Mao'S China and After , pp. 420
    • Meisner, M.J.1
  • 59
    • 0003885373 scopus 로고
    • RICHARD PIPES, RUSSIA UNDER THE BOLSHEVIK REGIME 386-403 (1993) ("[L]ocal officials⋯ felt at liberty to appropriate food, cattle, even clothing for their personal use⋯. The system operated on the absurd principle that the more the peasant produced the more would be taken from him⋯." (footnotes omitted)).
    • (1993) Russia Under the Bolshevik Regime , pp. 386-403
    • Pipes, R.1
  • 60
    • 84864073304 scopus 로고
    • Potter v. Couch
    • 315
    • Potter v. Couch, 141 U. S. 296, 315 (1891);
    • (1891) U. S. , vol.141 , pp. 296
  • 62
    • 77955493093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Government takings of private property (describing public attitudes toward economic development takings)
    • These sorts of compulsory exchanges of property typically go by the name "economic development" and are controversial. See generally Janice Nadler et al., Government Takings of Private Property (describing public attitudes toward economic development takings), in PUBLIC OPINION AND CONSTITUTIONAL CONTROVERSY 286 (Nathaniel Persily et al. eds., 2008).
    • (2008) Public Opinion and Constitutional Controversy , pp. 286
    • Nadler, J.1
  • 63
    • 0001073135 scopus 로고
    • The use of information in society
    • 526
    • See F. A. Hayek, The Use of Information in Society, 35 AM. ECON. REV. 519, 526 (1945) (arguing that when knowledge of relevant facts is dispersed among many people, the pricing system will effectively coordinate economic activity);
    • (1945) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.35 , pp. 519
    • Hayek, F.A.1
  • 64
    • 0004069543 scopus 로고
    • see also LUDWIG VON MISES, HUMAN ACTION: A TREATISE ON ECONOMICS 694-711 (Ludwig von Mises Inst. 1998) (1949) (arguing that human planning and cooperation are best optimized by a system that relies on the efforts of individual actors without centralized management).
    • (1949) Human Action: A Treatise on Economics , pp. 694-711
    • Von Mises, L.1
  • 65
    • 84864061010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The world factbook: Country comparison: GDP - Per Capita (PPP)
    • last visited Apr. 15, 2012
    • See The World Factbook: Country Comparison: GDP - Per Capita (PPP), CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY, https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world- factbook/rankorder/2004rank.html (last visited Apr. 15, 2012) (estimating that as of 2011, the GDP per capita of South Korea was $31, 700, whereas the GDP per capita of North Korea was $1800).
    • Cent. Intelligence Agency
  • 66
    • 84864045843 scopus 로고
    • The case against natural law reassessed
    • 41-42
    • See Edgar Bodenheimer, The Case Against Natural Law Reassessed, 17 STAN. L. REV. 39, 41-42 (1964) (chronicling the history of various natural and common law doctrines and noting that "private property in some articles of personal consumption, such as tools and clothing, is almost universally recognized").
    • (1964) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.17 , pp. 39
    • Bodenheimer, E.1
  • 68
    • 84864066009 scopus 로고
    • Int'l News Serv. v. Associated Press
    • 239-40
    • Int'l News Serv. v. Associated Press, 248 U. S. 215, 239-40 (1918).
    • (1918) U. S. , vol.248 , pp. 215
  • 69
    • 0002380185 scopus 로고
    • Profit sharing and productivity: Microeconomic evidence from the United States
    • 29-36
    • See, e.g., Douglas L. Kruse, Profit Sharing and Productivity: Microeconomic Evidence from the United States, 102 ECON. J. 24, 29-36 (1992) (concluding that profit-sharing plans generally increase managerial effort).
    • (1992) Econ. J. , vol.102 , pp. 24
    • Kruse, D.L.1
  • 70
    • 0014413249 scopus 로고
    • The tragedy of the commons
    • See generally Garrett Hardin, The Tragedy of the Commons, 162 SCIENCE 1243 (1968) (addressing the inherent problems in common-rights resource management in an increasingly overpopulated world).
    • (1968) Science , vol.162 , pp. 1243
    • Hardin, G.1
  • 73
    • 0010417299 scopus 로고
    • Condominium and cooperative housing: Transactional efficiency, tax subsidies, and tenure choice
    • 34-37
    • See Henry Hansmann, Condominium and Cooperative Housing: Transactional Efficiency, Tax Subsidies, and Tenure Choice, 20 J. LEGAL STUD. 25, 34-37 (1991) (discussing the high costs of collective decisionmaking in common interest communities).
    • (1991) J. Legal Stud. , vol.20 , pp. 25
    • Hansmann, H.1
  • 75
    • 0003772810 scopus 로고
    • See MILTON FRIEDMAN, CAPITALISM AND FREEDOM 15 (1962) ("The preservation of freedom requires the elimination of [the] concentration of power to the fullest possible extent and the dispersal and distribution of whatever power cannot be eliminated-a system of checks and balances.").
    • (1962) Capitalism and Freedom , pp. 15
    • Friedman, M.1
  • 76
    • 0000861359 scopus 로고
    • The new property
    • 772
    • See Charles A. Reich, The New Property, 73 YALE L. J. 733, 772 (1964) ("Like the Bill of Rights, property represents a general, long range protection of individual and private interests⋯.").
    • (1964) Yale L. J. , vol.73 , pp. 733
    • Reich, C.A.1
  • 77
    • 0000542896 scopus 로고
    • Property and personhood
    • Margaret Jane Radin, Property and Personhood, 34 STAN. L. REV. 957 (1982).
    • (1982) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.34 , pp. 957
    • Radin, M.J.1
  • 78
    • 0004032597 scopus 로고
    • 28, 48-49
    • ERVING GOFFMAN, ASYLUMS 18-21, 28, 48-49 (1961).
    • (1961) Asylums , pp. 18-21
    • Goffman, E.1
  • 79
    • 80052609869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strategic spillovers
    • 1642-44, 1649-51
    • See Daniel B. Kelly, Strategic Spillovers, 111 COLUM. L. REV. 1641, 1642-44, 1649-51 (2011) (defining and analyzing negative externalities).
    • (2011) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.111 , pp. 1641
    • Kelly, D.B.1
  • 80
    • 0002455414 scopus 로고
    • The fable of the bees: An economic investigation
    • Of course, social norms or Coasean bargains may sometimes internalize these and other externalities. See Steven N. S. Cheung, The Fable of the Bees: An Economic Investigation, 16 J. L. & ECON. 11, 12-13 (1973) (explaining that beekeepers often contract with neighboring apple farmers).
    • (1973) J. L. & Econ. , vol.16 , pp. 11
    • Cheung, S.N.S.1
  • 83
    • 80052633322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private property and public rights (Surveying Legal Doctrines Relating to Public Domain, Public Streets, Highways, Airspace, and Public Use Takings)
    • 77-80, Kenneth Ayotte & Henry E. Smith eds.
    • SEE THOMAS W. MERRILL, Private Property And Public Rights (Surveying Legal Doctrines Relating To Public Domain, Public Streets, Highways, Airspace, And Public Use Takings), In Research Handbook On The Economics Of Property Law 75, 77-80 (Kenneth Ayotte & Henry E. Smith eds., 2011).
    • (2011) Research Handbook on the Economics of Property Law , pp. 75
    • Merrill, T.W.1
  • 84
    • 33746076618 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Causby
    • 260-61
    • See, e.g., United States v. Causby, 328 U. S. 256, 260-61 (1946) ("The air is a public highway, as Congress has declared⋯. Common sense revolts at the idea [of] private claims to the airspace⋯.").
    • (1946) U. S. , vol.328 , pp. 256
  • 85
    • 84864037781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 47 U. S. C. § 301 (2006) (declaring "the control of the United States over all channels of radio transmission").
    • (2006) U. S. C. , vol.47 , pp. 301
  • 87
    • 84864073306 scopus 로고
    • Donald R. Kelly & Bonnie G. Smith eds. & trans.
    • PIERRE-JOSEPH PROUDHON, WHAT IS PROPERTY? 13 (Donald R. Kelly & Bonnie G. Smith eds. & trans., 1994) (1840).
    • (1840) What Is Property? , pp. 13
    • Proudhon, P.-J.1
  • 88
    • 0003516433 scopus 로고
    • John E. Toews ed., Bedford/St. Martin's
    • KARL MARX & FREDERICK ENGELS, THE COMMUNIST MANIFESTO 84 (John E. Toews ed., Bedford/St. Martin's 1999) (1848) (predicting that advanced countries would begin to see the abolition of property).
    • (1848) The Communist Manifesto , pp. 84
    • Marx, K.1    Engels, F.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.