메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 60, Issue 2, 2008, Pages 323-370

The FTC and new paternalism

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 79551574209     PISSN: 00018368     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (12)

References (514)
  • 1
    • 79551558079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • infra Part I
    • See infra Part I.
  • 3
    • 0033724976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond homo economicus: Evidence from experimental economics
    • 312
    • See Herbert Gintis, Beyond Homo Economicus: Evidence from Experimental Economics, 35 ECOLOGICAL EcoN. 311, 312 (2000) (discussing the characteristics of Homo economicus). Homo economicus is also referred to as "Chicago man" in academic literature.
    • (2000) Ecological Econ. , vol.35 , pp. 311
    • Gintis, H.1
  • 4
    • 0042214272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rationality for economists?
    • 76
    • See Daniel McFadden, Rationality for Economists?, 19 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 73, 76 (1999);
    • (1999) J. Risk & Uncertainty , vol.19 , pp. 73
    • McFadden, D.1
  • 5
    • 2442603585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chicago man, k-t man, and the future of behavioral law and economics
    • 1670
    • Robert A. Prentice, Chicago Man, K-T Man, and the Future of Behavioral Law and Economics, 56 VAND. L. REV. 1663, 1670 (2003).
    • (2003) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.56 , pp. 1663
    • Prentice, R.A.1
  • 6
    • 77951883986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Against the new paternalism: Internalities and the economics of self-control
    • Cato Inst., Wash., D.C. Feb. 22
    • Glen Whitman, Against the New Paternalism: Internalities and the Economics of Self-Control, POL'Y ANALYSIS 563 (Cato Inst., Wash., D.C.) Feb. 22, 2006, at 2.
    • (2006) Pol'y Analysis , vol.563 , pp. 2
    • Whitman, G.1
  • 7
    • 23944511168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paternalism and cognitive bias
    • 394
    • See, e.g., J.D. Trout, Paternalism and Cognitive Bias, 24 LAW & PHIL. 393, 394 (2005) (making "the case for the legitimacy of governmental regulation on behalf of a person's good for selected classes of cognitive bias").
    • (2005) Law & Phil. , vol.24 , pp. 393
    • Trout, J.D.1
  • 10
    • 0042409519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and behavioral science: Removing the rationality assumption from law and economics
    • For an extraordinarily helpful treatment of this subject, see Russell B. Korobkin & Thomas S. Ulen, Law and Behavioral Science: Removing the Rationality Assumption from Law and Economics, 88 CAL. L. REV. 1051 (2000) [hereinafter Korobkin & Ulen, Rationality Assumption];
    • (2000) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 1051
    • Korobkin, R.B.1    Ulen, T.S.2
  • 11
    • 79551563995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rational choice theory in law and economics
    • Boudewijn Bouckaert & Geerit De Geest eds.
    • see also Thomas S. Ulen, Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics, in ENCYCLOPEDIA OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 790 (Boudewijn Bouckaert & Geerit De Geest eds., 2000) [hereinafter Ulen, Rational Choice].
    • (2000) Encyclopedia of Law and Economics , pp. 790
    • Ulen, T.S.1
  • 13
    • 3142743508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A multi-disciplinary approach to legal scholarship: Economics, behavioral economics, and evolutionary psychology
    • 331
    • See Russell Korobkin, A Multi-Disciplinary Approach to Legal Scholarship: Economics, Behavioral Economics, and Evolutionary Psychology, 41 JURIMETRICS319, 331 (2001) ("The thinnest version of rational choice theory provides that individuals will act to maximize their expected utility, a completely nonfalsifiable proposition standing alone.");
    • (2001) Jurimetrics , vol.41 , pp. 319
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 15
    • 0001990652 scopus 로고
    • Probabilistic models of consumer choice behavior
    • 88 Thomas S. Robertson & Harold H. Kassarjian eds.
    • see also Robert J. Meyer & Barbara E. Kahn, Probabilistic Models of Consumer Choice Behavior, in HANDBOOK OF CONSUMER BEHAVIOR 85, 88 (Thomas S. Robertson & Harold H. Kassarjian eds., 1991) (observing the tautological nature of utility maximization claims);
    • (1991) Handbook of Consumer Behavior , pp. 85
    • Meyer, R.J.1    Kahn, B.E.2
  • 16
    • 0034346736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Educating homo economicus: Cautionary notes on the new behavioral law and economics movement
    • 977
    • Tanina Rostain, Educating Homo Economicus: Cautionary Notes on the New Behavioral Law and Economics Movement, 34 LAW & SOC'Y REV. 973, 977 (2000) ("When the content of a rational actor's preferences is left open, however, the theory is too indeterminate to yield many empirically falsifiable predictions.").
    • (2000) Law & Soc'y Rev. , vol.34 , pp. 973
    • Rostain, T.1
  • 17
    • 67651033086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Departures from rational choice: With and without regret
    • 19 Francesco Parisi & Vernon L. Smith eds.
    • Robert H. Frank, Departures from Rational Choice: With and Without Regret, in THE LAW AND ECONOMICS OF IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR 17, 19 (Francesco Parisi & Vernon L. Smith eds., 2005).
    • (2005) The Law and Economics of Irrational Behavior , pp. 17
    • Frank, R.H.1
  • 18
    • 0348246071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A behavioral approach to law and economics
    • 1488
    • Christine Jolis, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1471, 1488 (1998);
    • (1998) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.50 , pp. 1471
    • Jolis, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Thaler, R.3
  • 19
    • 33645786491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wanting, liking, and learning: Neuroscience and paternalism
    • 91
    • see also Colin F. Camerer, Wanting, Liking, and Learning: Neuroscience and Paternalism, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 87, 91 (2006) [hereinafter Camerer, Wanting, Liking, and Learning] ("If my neighbor thumps his head repeatedly with a ball-peen hammer, do I have no alternative but to infer that hammering his head with a ball-peen hammer is the most fun he can have?").
    • (2006) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.73 , pp. 87
    • Camerer, C.F.1
  • 20
    • 79551537886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7, n.34
    • This theory is sometimes referred to as "subjective expected utility." See Korobkin & Ulen. Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1062 n.34 ("The addition of the word 'subjective' merely allows for the probabilities by which the decisionmaker weighs the utilities of uncertain outcomes to be subjective, rather than objective.").
    • Rationality Assumption , pp. 1062
    • Korobkin1    Ulen2
  • 21
    • 79551541263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1063
    • Id. at 1063;
  • 22
    • 0003774434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §1.3, 7th ed.
    • RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW §1.3, at 15 (7th ed. 2007) ("Rationality means little more to an economist than a disposition to choose, consciously or unconsciously, an apt means to whatever ends the chooser happens to have selected, consciously or unconsciously.").
    • (2007) Economic Analysis of Law , pp. 15
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 23
    • 84889322145 scopus 로고
    • Some implications of cognitive psychology for risk regulation
    • 751-53
    • For those readers interested in representative utility equations, see Roger G. Noll & James E. Krier, Some Implications of Cognitive Psychology for Risk Regulation, 19 J. LEGAL STUD. 747,751-53 (1990).
    • (1990) J. Legal Stud. , vol.19 , pp. 747
    • Noll, R.G.1    Krier, J.E.2
  • 24
    • 84881941671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 4th ed.
    • See ROBERT COOTER & THOMAS ULEN, LAW & ECONOMICS 18 (4th ed. 2004). Cooter and Ulen note that: [T]he preferences of the consumer are subjective. Different people have different tastes.... Economists leave to other disciplines, such as psychology and sociology, the study of the source of these preferences. We take consumer tastes or preferences as given, or, as economists say, as exogenous, which means that they are determined outside the economic system.
    • (2004) Law & Economics , pp. 18
    • Cooter, R.1    Ulen, T.2
  • 25
    • 79551505460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 22.
    • Id. at 22.
  • 26
    • 79551537886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • Although the actor's self-interest need not be defined solely in terms of wealth maximization, the implication is that the well-being of others is not a concern in the decisionmaking process. See Korobkin & Ulen, Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1064-66.
    • Rationality Assumption , pp. 1064-1066
    • Korobkin1    Ulen2
  • 27
    • 79551554531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 1060-61
    • See id. at 1060-61 (explaining differences between thin and thick versions of rational choice theory)
  • 29
    • 79551522225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1066
    • Id. at 1066.
  • 30
    • 22644448880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taking behavioralism seriously: The problem of market manipulation
    • 641-42
    • For a slightly different list, see Jon D. Hanson & Douglas A. Kysar, Taking Behavioralism Seriously: The Problem of Market Manipulation, 74 N.Y.U. L. REV. 630, 641-42 (1999)
    • (1999) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 630
    • Hanson, J.D.1    Kysar, D.A.2
  • 31
    • 0002340332 scopus 로고
    • Individual decision making
    • 618 John H. Kagel & Alvin E. Roth eds.
    • (derived from Colin Camerer, Individual Decision Making, in THE HANDBOOK OF EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS 587, 618 (John H. Kagel & Alvin E. Roth eds., 1995) [hereinafter Camerer, Individual Decision Making]);
    • (1995) The Handbook of Experimental Economics , pp. 587
    • Camerer, C.1
  • 32
    • 0038548458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulation for conservatives: Behavioral economics and the case for asymmetric paternalism
    • 1217
    • see also Colin Camerer et al., Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for "Asymmetric Paternalism", 151 U. PA. L. REV. 1211,1217 (2003) [hereinafter Camerer et al., Regulation for Conservatives] (describing the basic components of rationality).
    • (2003) U. PA. L. Rev. , vol.151 , pp. 1211
    • Camerer, C.1
  • 33
    • 79551537886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • Korobkin & Ulen Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1064 ("Commensurability: actors should be able to compare the utility consequences of all alternatives to each other.").
    • Rationality Assumption , pp. 1064
    • Korobkin1    Ulen2
  • 34
    • 79551571744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id. ("Transitivity: if an actor prefers choice A to choice B and choice B to choice C, he should then prefer choice A to choice C.");
  • 35
    • 79551518872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • Ulen, Rational Choice, supra note 7, at 792 ("Transitive preferences are those for which, if some good or bundle of goods denoted A is preferred to another good or bundle of goods denoted B and B is preferred to a third good or bundle of goods denoted C, then it must be the case that A is preferred to C").
    • Rational Choice , pp. 792
    • Ulen1
  • 36
    • 79551537886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • Korobkin & Ulea Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1064 ("Invariance: the preference between two or more choices should not depend on how the choice is presented or structured, so long as the outcome possibilities are constant.");
    • Rationality Assumption , pp. 1064
    • Korobkin1    Ulea2
  • 37
    • 1542582705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 18
    • see also Camerer, Individual Decision Making, supra note 18, at 652 (noting that "different representations of the same choice problem, and different elicitation procedures, should yield the same preference");
    • Individual Decision Making , pp. 652
    • Camerer1
  • 38
    • 79551556463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hanson &Kysar, supra note 18, at 642 ("[W]here alternative descriptions of the same outcome are formulated, players should express the same preferences regardless of which description is presented.").
    • Hanson & Kysar, supra note 18, at 642 ("[W]here alternative descriptions of the same outcome are formulated, players should express the same preferences regardless of which description is presented.").
  • 39
    • 79551537886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • See Korobkin & Ulea Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1064 ("Cancellation: a choice between options should not depend on features of the options that are identical.");
    • Rationality Assumption , pp. 1064
    • Korobkin1    Ulea2
  • 40
    • 0001371984 scopus 로고
    • Rational choice and the framing of decisions
    • S252
    • see also Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions, 59 J. Bus. S251, S252 (1986) (elaborating further on cancellation).
    • (1986) J. Bus. , vol.59
    • Tversky, A.1    Kahneman, D.2
  • 41
    • 79551537886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • Korobkin & Ulen. Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1064 ("Dominance: an actor should never choose an option in which every feature is only as good as the features of a competing option, and at least one feature is not as good.").
    • Rationality Assumption , pp. 1064
    • Korobkin1    Ulen2
  • 43
    • 79551530680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also
    • supra note 18
    • see also Camerer, Individual Decision Making, supra note 18, at 596 (illustrating Bayes's law as a formula).
    • Individual Decision Making , pp. 596
    • Camerer1
  • 44
    • 79551537886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • See Korobkin & Ulen, Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1064 ("If an actor fails to follow one or more of these principles, he cannot be making decisions consistent with the expected utility model. Consequently, the predictions of the model are testable, at least at some minimum level.");
    • Rationality Assumption , pp. 1064
    • Korobkin1    Ulen2
  • 45
    • 0036874075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why law and economics' perfect rationality should not be traded for behavioral law and economics ' equal incompetence
    • 81
    • see also Gregory Mitchell, Why Law and Economics' Perfect Rationality Should Not Be Traded for Behavioral Law and Economics ' Equal Incompetence, 91 GEO. LJ. 67, 81 (2002) [hereinafter Mitchell, Equal Incompetence] ("[W]hen the legal decision theorists say that some legally relevant behavior is supposedly 'nonrational,' 'quasi-rational,' or 'irrational,' they simply mean that a legal actor failed to apply the proper rules or norms for arriving at a judgment or decision, not that the action taken has an irrational purpose or unwise goal.").
    • (2002) Geo. LJ. , vol.91 , pp. 67
    • Mitchell, G.1
  • 46
    • 17044376351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and behavioral biology
    • 443
    • Owen D. Jones & Timothy H. Goldsmith, Law and Behavioral Biology, 105 COLUM. L. REV. 405,443 (2005).
    • (2005) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.105 , pp. 405
    • Jones, O.D.1    Goldsmith, T.H.2
  • 47
    • 20444484184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and the emotions: The problems of affective forecasting
    • 158
    • See Jeremy A. Blumenthal, Law and the Emotions: The Problems of Affective Forecasting, 80 IND. L.J. 155, 158 (2005) [hereinafter Blumenthal, Law and Emotions] (noting that the central tenet of the rational decisionmaker and its underlying assumptions are "flawed");
    • (2005) Ind. L.J. , vol.80 , pp. 155
    • Blumenthal, J.A.1
  • 48
    • 79551508263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Small business and the false dichotomies of contract law
    • 314
    • Larry T. Garvin, Small Business and the False Dichotomies of Contract Law, 40 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 295, 314 (2005) ("The experimental literature has shown many departures from conventional expected utility theory-enough to warrant the comment that if expected utility theory 'is an empirical, testable theory, then it is, in any conventional sense, untrue.'")
    • (2005) Wake Forest L. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 295
    • Garvin, L.T.1
  • 50
    • 78649380711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rational choice and rat choice: Some thoughts on the relationship among rationality, markets, and human beings
    • 1098
    • Edward L. Rubin, Rational Choice and Rat Choice: Some Thoughts on the Relationship Among Rationality, Markets, and Human Beings, 80 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1091, 1098 (2005).
    • (2005) Chi.-Kent L. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 1091
    • Rubin, E.L.1
  • 51
    • 84890743754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral economics: Past, present, future
    • Colin Camerer et al. eds.
    • For an overview of behavioral economics, see Colin Camerer & George Loewenstein, Behavioral Economics: Past, Present, Future, in ADVANCES IN BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 3 (Colin Camerer et al. eds., 2004) [hereinafter ADVANCES IN BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS].
    • (2004) Advances in Behavioral Economics , pp. 3
    • Camerer, C.1    Loewenstein, G.2
  • 52
    • 0004264559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cass R. Sunstein ed.
    • The extraordinary volume of recent behavioral law and economics (BLE) scholarship makes it difficult to provide a comprehensive list of valuable contributions to the field, but the following sources are good starting points: BEHAVIORAL LAW AND ECONOMICS (Cass R. Sunstein ed., 2000);
    • (2000) BEHAVIORAL LAW and ECONOMICS
  • 53
    • 33645285759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Francesco Parisi & Vernon L. Smith eds.
    • THE LAW AND ECONOMICS OF IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR (Francesco Parisi & Vernon L. Smith eds., 2005) [hereinafter LAW AND ECONOMICS OF IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR];
    • (2005) The Law and Economics of Irrational Behavior
  • 54
    • 0242534459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empirical legal realism: A new social scientific assessment of law and human behavior
    • Symposium
    • Symposium, Empirical Legal Realism: A New Social Scientific Assessment of Law and Human Behavior, 97 Nw. U. L. REV. 1075 (2003);
    • (2003) Nw. U. L. REV. , vol.97 , pp. 1075
  • 55
    • 0347776265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The legal implications of psychology: Human behavior, behavioral economics, and the law
    • Symposium
    • Symposium, The Legal Implications of Psychology: Human Behavior, Behavioral Economics, and the Law, 51 VAND. L. REV. 1495 ( 1998).
    • (1998) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 1495
  • 56
    • 0008784761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral law and economics: A progress report
    • 115
    • See Cass R. Sunstein, Behavioral Law and Economics: A Progress Report, 1 AM. L. & ECON. REV. 115, 115 (1999) ("The last decade has seen an outpouring of work in 'behavioral law and economics;' in the last few years, the outpouring has become a flood.").
    • (1999) Am. L. & Econ. Rev. , vol.1 , pp. 115
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 57
    • 79551513588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 27
    • Scholars have debated the proper term to describe this movement in legal academia. See Blumenthal, Law and Emotions, supra note 27, at 159 (listing names for this movement);
    • Law and Emotions , pp. 159
    • Blumenthal1
  • 58
    • 3142698048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Time-shifted rationality and the law of law's leverage: Behavioral economics meets behavioral biology
    • 1142 n.2
    • Owen D. Jones, Time-Shifted Rationality and the Law of Law's Leverage: Behavioral Economics Meets Behavioral Biology, 95 Nw. U. L. REV. 1141, 1142 n.2 (2001) ("This outpouring of scholarship appears under various names. These include 'behavioral law and economics,' 'law and behavioral science,' 'behavioral analysis of law,' 'behavioral economic analysis of law,' 'the behavioral approach to law and economics,' 'behavioral economics analysis,' and 'law and the "new" psychology.'");
    • (2001) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.95 , pp. 1141
    • Jones, O.D.1
  • 59
    • 79551508920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 25
    • Mitchell, Equal Incompetence, supra note 25, at 78-79 (discussing the debate over the terminology and choosing to use the term "legal decision theory").
    • Equal Incompetence , pp. 78-79
    • Mitchell1
  • 60
    • 33644684566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Duty to Be a Rational Shareholder
    • 546
    • See David A. Hoffman, The "Duty " to Be a Rational Shareholder, 90 MINN. L. REV. 537, 546 (2006) ("Behavioral law and economics undermines the rationality assumption by using data from psychological experiments to radically alter our view of how humans make choices. BLE documents how individuals' choice-making behavior systematically diverges from the predictions of the rational-actor model of human behavior.") (citations omitted);
    • (2006) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.90 , pp. 537
    • Hoffman, D.A.1
  • 61
    • 33846595327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Framing effects and regulatory choice
    • 316
    • Jonathan Remy Nash, Framing Effects and Regulatory Choice, 82 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 313, 316 (2006) ("Behavioral law and economics seeks to improve the predictive power of traditional law and economics by incorporating behavioral considerations into the model.");
    • (2006) Notre Dame L. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 313
    • Nash, J.R.1
  • 62
    • 33645289278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The fable of entry: Bounded rationality, market discipline, and legal policy
    • 484
    • Avishalom Tor, The Fable of Entry: Bounded Rationality, Market Discipline, and Legal Policy, 101 MICH. L. REV. 482, 484 (2002) (noting that hallmark of the BLE approach "is the replacement of the perfectly rational actor with a 'boundedly rational' decisionmaker who, apart from being affected by emotion and motivation, has only limited cognitive resources");
    • (2002) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.101 , pp. 482
    • Tor, A.1
  • 63
    • 79551505459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rostain, supra note 9, at980
    • see also Rostain, supra note 9, at 980 ("The point of this new movement, these writers insist, is not to displace the law and economics model, but to enhance its descriptive and predictive powers by importing insights from cognitive and social psychology and behavioral economics.") (citations omitted). Rostain is skeptical, however, of this goal.
  • 64
    • 79551550403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 984
    • See id. at 984 ("Incorporating behavioral insights into legal analysis provides a richer and 'truer' account of human decisionmaking and behavior, but not necessarily one with significant predictive power.").
  • 65
    • 79551545309 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For ease of exposition, this framework is taken from Jolis et al., supra note 11
    • For ease of exposition, this framework is taken from Jolis et al., supra note 11.
  • 66
    • 79551518871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1479
    • Id. at 1479;
  • 67
    • 0040516017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In search of homo economicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies
    • see also Joseph Henrich et al., In Search of Homo Economicus: Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies, 91 AM. ECON. REV. 73 (2001) ("[I]n addition to their own material payoffs, many experimental subjects appear to care about fairness and reciprocity, are willing to change the distribution of material outcomes at personal cost, and are willing to reward those who act in a cooperative manner while punishing those who do not even when these actions are costly to the individual.");
    • (2001) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.91 , pp. 73
    • Henrich, J.1
  • 68
    • 79551510795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rostain, supra note 9, at 979
    • Rostain, supra note 9, at 979 ("People are not consistently self-interested, as such theories would hold, but have been shown to have other regarding preferences that are seemingly not reducible to material, or even reputational, interests. Such non-self-interested preferences are reflected in conduct governed by social norms, such as norms of fairness.").
  • 69
    • 79551570290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 18
    • See Camerer et al., Regulation for Conservatives, supra note 18, at 1217 (observing that "a substantial body of literature examines how people with self-control problems may fail to carry out their desired course of action")
    • Regulation for Conservatives , pp. 1217
    • Camerer1
  • 70
    • 0038969032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting
    • 444-45
    • (citing David Laibson, Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting, 112 Q.J. ECON. 443, 444-45 (1997);
    • (1997) Q.J. Econ. , vol.112 , pp. 443
    • Laibson, D.1
  • 71
    • 0030100132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior
    • 272-73
    • George Loewenstein, Out of Control: Visceral Influences on Behavior, 65 ORG'L BEHAV. & HUM. DECISION PROCESSES 272, 272-73 (1996);
    • (1996) Org'l Behav. & Hum. Decision Processes , vol.65 , pp. 272
    • Loewenstein, G.1
  • 72
    • 0038957677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Doing it now or later
    • 118-20
    • Ted O'Donoghue & Matthew Rabin, Doing It Now or Later, 89 AM. ECON. REV. 103, 118-20 (1999));
    • (1999) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 103
    • O'Donoghue, T.1    Rabin, M.2
  • 73
    • 79551551127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jolis et al., supra note 11, at 1479
    • Jolis et al., supra note 11, at 1479 ("[P]eople often display bounded willpower. This term refers to the fact that human beings often take actions that they know to be in conflict with their own long-term interests.").
  • 74
    • 79551531371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Addiction, choice, and irrationality
    • supra note 30
    • See Ole-Jergen Skog, Addiction, Choice, and Irrationality, in LAW AND ECONOMICS OF IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR, supra note 30, at 135 (arguing that the "central features of addiction cannot be adequately dealt with by theories embedded within the framework of standard rational choice theory"). Herbert Gintis has a slightly different take on addiction: Drug addiction may seem a perfect example of people making choices that are not in their self-interest. However, a much larger fraction of those who try drugs either give them up or maintain their use at recreational levels than become addicted. Therefore drug taking may be a risky behavior the net benefit of which is positive, even though it has a negative payoff for some.
    • Law and Economics of Irrational Behavior , pp. 135
    • Skog, O.-J.1
  • 75
    • 79551539460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gintis, supra note 3, at 312
    • Gintis, supra note 3, at 312.
  • 76
    • 79551573496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 11.
    • Of course, any discussion about poor impulse control can lead to difficult questions over the very nature of happiness and the differences between what we want, need, like, and find pleasurable over the course of our lives. For an excellent discussion of these issues, see Camerer, Wanting, Liking, and Learning, supra note 11. An additional layer of complex issues emerges if we consider these matters over time and question whether people are capable of predicting accurately what will give them future happiness.
    • Wanting, Liking, and Learning
    • Camerer1
  • 78
    • 79551540202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jolis et al., supra note 11, at 1477
    • See Jolis et al., supra note 11, at 1477 ("Bounded rationality, an idea first introduced by Herbert Simon, refers to the obvious fact that human cognitive abilities are not infinite. We have limited computational skills and seriously flawed memories.") (citation omitted);
  • 79
    • 79551511719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jones & Goldsmith, supra note 26, at 445
    • Jones & Goldsmith, supra note 26, at 445 (noting "constraints on the brain's information capacities, wiring, and computing speed");
  • 80
    • 41149170536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blinded by the light: Information overload and its consequences for securities regulation
    • 435
    • Troy A. Paredes, Blinded by the Light: Information Overload and Its Consequences for Securities Regulation, 81 WASH. U. L.Q. 417, 435 (2003) ("Cognitive capabilities are scarce resources that have to be allocated; because of limited cognitive capabilities, people cannot attend to all the information made available to them and cannot evaluate all their choices perfectly.").
    • (2003) Wash. U. L.Q. , vol.81 , pp. 417
    • Paredes, T.A.1
  • 81
    • 35649005857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is the mind irrational or ecologically rational?
    • supra note 30
    • But see Gerd Gigerenzer, Is the Mind Irrational or Ecologically Rational?, in LAW AND ECONOMICS OF IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR, supra note 30, at 39 (2005) (criticizing Jolis, Sunstein, and Thaler for misrepresenting Simon's views).
    • (2005) Law and Economics of Irrational Behavior , pp. 39
    • Gigerenzer, G.1
  • 82
    • 0032285185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constructive consumer choice processes
    • 187
    • James R. Bettman et al., Constructive Consumer Choice Processes, 25 J. CONSUMER RES. 187,187 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Consumer Res. , vol.25 , pp. 187
    • Bettman, J.R.1
  • 83
    • 79551512837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jones, supra note 32, at 1150
    • See Jones, supra note 32, at 1150 ("Bounded rationality essentially captures the idea that there are very real, very important constraints on the actual human capacity to gather and process information.");
  • 84
    • 79551536800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jones & Goldsmith, supra note 26, at 445
    • Jones & Goldsmith, supra note 26, at 445 (noting "constraints on time and energy for gathering perfect information").
  • 85
    • 33645279705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The uncertain psychological case for paternalism
    • 1170-75
    • See Jeffrey J. Rachlinski, The Uncertain Psychological Case for Paternalism, 97 Nw. U. L. REV. 1165, 1170-75 (2003) (reviewing the availability heuristic, the representativeness heuristic, anchoring and adjustment, hindsight bias, and self-serving biases, such as overoptimism, overconfidence, and egocentrism).
    • (2003) Nw. U. L. REV. , vol.97 , pp. 1165
    • Rachlinski, J.J.1
  • 86
    • 58149433367 scopus 로고
    • Rational choice and the structure of the environment
    • One example is what Herbert Simon referred to as "satisficing." See Herbert A. Simon, Rational Choice and the Structure of the Environment, 63 PSYCHOL. REV. 129 (1956);
    • (1956) Psychol. Rev. , vol.63 , pp. 129
    • Simon, H.A.1
  • 87
    • 84959810873 scopus 로고
    • A behavioral model of rational choice
    • Herbert A. Simon, A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice, 69 Q.J. ECON. 99 (1955);
    • (1955) Q.J. Econ. , vol.69 , pp. 99
    • Simon, H.A.1
  • 88
    • 79551547395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Garvin, supra note 27, at 308-09
    • see also Garvin, supra note 27, at 308-09 (discussing "satisficing");
  • 89
    • 79551509334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paredes, supra note 39, at 435-36
    • Paredes, supra note 39, at 435-36 (discussing Herbert Simon's work).
  • 90
    • 79551518870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Simon's work on satisficing led to work that explores a variety of non-compensatory decisionmaking strategies
    • Simon's work on "satisficing" led to work that explores a variety of non-compensatory decisionmaking strategies.
  • 92
    • 79551571403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paredes, supra note 39, at 437-40
    • Paredes, supra note 39, at 437-40 (surveying decisionmaking strategies including the lexicographic strategy and elimination by aspects).
  • 93
    • 79551508920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 25
    • See Mitchell, Equal Incompetence, supra note 25, at 82 ("[W]e must rely on often unconscious mental shortcuts or rules of thumb to assess evidence, draw inferences, and make predictions, because deliberate, careful computations pursuant to rules of procedural rationality simply would be too mentally taxing or time consuming.").
    • Equal Incompetence , pp. 82
    • Mitchell1
  • 94
    • 79551537886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • For an in-depth discussion of various decisionmaking heuristics and biases, see Korobkin & Ulen, Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1084-1102;
    • Rationality Assumption , pp. 1084-1102
    • Korobkin1    Ulen2
  • 95
    • 79551536242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PLOUS, supra note 43, at 109-88
    • see also PLOUS, supra note 43, at 109-88.
  • 96
    • 79551537886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7
    • Korobkin and Ulen point out: The widespread use of heuristics, at least in many cases, is no doubt a quite useful evolutionary adaptation; without such mental shortcuts, the task of making even relatively simple decisions would become so complex that daily life would almost certainly grind to a halt. But the use of heuristics surely results in the widespread failure of decision makers to maximize their expected utility in particular decision situations. Korobkin & Ulen, Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1076 (citation omitted);
    • Rationality Assumption , pp. 1076
    • Korobkin1    Ulen2
  • 97
    • 52749096859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Predatory lending practices: Definition and behavioral implications
    • 93 (Gregory D. Squires ed., 2004)
    • see also Patricia A. McCoy, Predatory Lending Practices: Definition and Behavioral Implications, in WHY THE POOR PAY MORE: HOW TO STOP PREDATORY LENDING 81, 93 (Gregory D. Squires ed., 2004) ("All consumers... use heuristic principles of one sort or another to simplify their financial decisions. When these principles are sound, they can provide a useful shortcut to financial decision-making. Other choice heuristics, however, can lead to grave and systematic errors in weighing risks and benefits.")
    • Why the Poor Pay More: How to Stop Predatory Lending , pp. 81
    • McCoy, P.A.1
  • 98
    • 0016264378 scopus 로고
    • Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases
    • (citing Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, 185 SCIENCE 1124 (1974));
    • (1974) Science , vol.185 , pp. 1124
    • Tversky, A.1    Kahneman, D.2
  • 99
    • 79551508920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 25
    • Mitchell, Equal Incompetence, supra note 25, at 83 (observing that "over-reliance on, or unthinking use of heuristics can bias judgment and cause errors in decisions").
    • Equal Incompetence , pp. 83
    • Mitchell1
  • 100
    • 0141852355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Automated choice heuristics
    • 549 Thomas Gilovich et al. eds.
    • A contrast can be drawn between "'deliberate' choice heuristics," which are simplifying decision strategies that may be adaptive, and "'automatic' judgmental heuristics." See Shane Frederick, Automated Choice Heuristics, in HEURISTICS AND BIASES: THE PSYCHOLOGY OF INTUITIVE JUDGMENT 548, 549 (Thomas Gilovich et al. eds., 2002) [hereinafter HEURISTICS AND BIASES];
    • (2002) Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment , pp. 548
    • Frederick, S.1
  • 101
  • 102
    • 33747825301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How good are fast and frugal heuristics?
    • supra note 30
    • Gerd Gigerenzer et al., How Good Are Fast and Frugal Heuristics?, in HEURISTICS AND BIASES, supra note 30, at 559.
    • Heuristics and Biases , pp. 559
    • Gigerenzer, G.1
  • 103
    • 79551553065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 21 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 21 and accompanying text.
  • 105
    • 10044298804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The endowment effect and legal analysis
    • 1228-29
    • See Russell Korobkin, The Endowment Effect and Legal Analysis, 97 Nw. U. L. REV. 1227, 1228-29 (2003) [hereinafter Korobkin, Endowment Effect] ("[Individuals tend to prefer the present state of the world to alternative states, all other things being equal.");
    • (2003) Nw. U. L. REV. , vol.97 , pp. 1227
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 106
    • 84890742870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prospect theory in the wild: Evidence from the field
    • supra note 29, 154
    • see also Colin Camerer, Prospect Theory in the Wild: Evidence from the Field, in ADVANCES IN BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS, supra note 29, at 148, 154 ("Samuelson and Zeckhauser ... coined the term status quo bias to refer to an exaggerated preference for the status quo . . . .").
    • Advances in Behavioral Economics , pp. 148
    • Camerer, C.1
  • 107
    • 77950140638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 49
    • Korobkin, Endowment Effect, supra note 49, at 1228 & n.3 ("[P]eople tend to value goods more when they own them than when they do not.") (crediting Richard Thaler for coining the term "endowment effect" in
    • Endowment Effect , pp. 1228
    • Korobkin1
  • 108
    • 0041906953 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice
    • 44
    • Richard Thaler, Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice, 1 J. ECON. BEHAV. & ORG. 39, 44 (1980));
    • (1980) J. Econ. Behav. & Org. , vol.1 , pp. 39
    • Thaler, R.1
  • 110
    • 79551508262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Colin Camerer et al. eds., 2004
    • (Colin Camerer et al. eds., 2004).
  • 111
    • 3042718957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prospect theory, risk preference, and the law
    • 1119
    • Chris Guthrie, Prospect Theory, Risk Preference, and the Law, 97 Nw. U. L. REV. 1115, 1119 (2003) ("[Individuals tend to value losses more heavily than gains of the same magnitude.")
    • (2003) Nw. U. L. REV. , vol.97 , pp. 1115
    • Guthrie, C.1
  • 112
    • 0000125532 scopus 로고
    • Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk
    • (citing Daniel Kahneman & Amos Tversky, Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk, 47 ECONOMÉTRICA 263 (1979));
    • (1979) ECONOMÉTRICA , vol.47 , pp. 263
    • Kahneman, D.1    Tversky, A.2
  • 113
    • 79551567056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jolis et al., supra note 11, at 1535 & n.182
    • Jolis et al., supra note 11, at 1535 & n.182 ("[O]ne of the central features of Kahneman and Tversky's prospect theory is that people evaluate outcomes based on the change they represent from an initial reference point, rather than based on the nature of the outcome itself; also, losses from the initial reference point are weighted much more heavily than gains.")
  • 114
    • 79551517831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kahneman & Tversky, supra, at 277-79. Russell Korobkin breaks loss aversion down further based upon various second-order explanations for loss aversion.
    • (citing Kahneman & Tversky, supra, at 277-79). Russell Korobkin breaks loss aversion down further based upon various second-order explanations for loss aversion.
  • 115
    • 77950140638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 49
    • See Korobkin, Endowment Effect, supra note 49, at 1250-55.
    • Endowment Effect , pp. 1250-1255
    • Korobkin1
  • 117
    • 79551536799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PLOUS, supra note 43, at 64-76
    • PLOUS, supra note 43, at 64-76 (providing an overview of framing with an emphasis on Tversky and Kahneman's work);
  • 118
    • 79551535551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rostain, supra note 9, at 978 ("Contrary to the requirement of description and process invariance, experimental evidence establishes that preferences depend importantly on how choices are described.").
    • Rostain, supra note 9, at 978 ("Contrary to the requirement of description and process invariance, experimental evidence establishes that preferences depend importantly on how choices are described.").
  • 119
    • 11044221426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political preference formation: Competition, deliberation, and the (ir)relevance of framing effects
    • 683
    • But see James N. Druckman, Political Preference Formation: Competition, Deliberation, and the (Ir)relevance of Framing Effects, 98 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 671,683 (2004) ("[F]raming effects depend in critical ways on context. As a result, framing effects appear to be neither robust nor particularly pervasive.");
    • (2004) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 671
    • Druckman, J.N.1
  • 120
    • 0242619237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taking behavioralism too seriously? The unwarranted pessimism of the new behavioral analysis of law
    • 1961-63, 2005-11
    • Gregory Mitchell, Taking Behavioralism Too Seriously? The Unwarranted Pessimism of the New Behavioral Analysis of Law, 43 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1907, 1961-63, 2005-11 (2002) [hereinafter Mitchell, Unwarranted Pessimism] (providing a skeptical discussion of framing effects literature).
    • (2002) WM. & MARY L. REV. , vol.43 , pp. 1907
    • Mitchell, G.1
  • 121
    • 79551523957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Guthrie, supra note 51
    • See generally Guthrie, supra note 51 ;
  • 123
    • 77957364613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Emotional paternalism
    • See, e.g., Jeremy A. Blumenthal, Emotional Paternalism, 35 FLA. ST. U. L. REV. 1 (2007) [hereinafter Blumenthal, Emotional Paternalism];
    • (2007) Fla. St. U. L. Rev. , vol.35 , pp. 1
    • Blumenthal, J.A.1
  • 127
    • 79551536798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumer Contracts: Behavioral Economics vs. Neoclassical Economics
    • See, e.g., Richard A. Epstein & Oren Bar-Gill, Consumer Contracts: Behavioral Economics vs. Neoclassical Economics (NYU Sch. of Law, Working Paper No. 07-17, 2007), available at http://lsr.neUco.org/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article- 1095&context=nyu/lewp;
    • (2007) NYU Sch. of Law, Working Paper No. 07-17
    • Epstein, R.A.1    Bar-Gill, O.2
  • 128
    • 79551535881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 30 (listing recent symposia dedicated to the implications of behavioral law and economics on public policymaking and legal decisionmaking).
    • see also supra note 30 (listing recent symposia dedicated to the implications of behavioral law and economics on public policymaking and legal decisionmaking).
  • 129
    • 0001592419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Back to bentham? Explorations of experienced utility
    • 397
    • See Daniel Kahneman et al., Back to Bentham? Explorations of Experienced Utility, 112 Q.J. ECON. 375, 397 (1997) ("The point of these observations is not to support paternalism, but to reject one of the arguments commonly raised against it. The claim that agents should be left alone because they generally know what is good for them is less secure than is generally assumed in economic discourse.").
    • (1997) Q.J. Econ. , vol.112 , pp. 375
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 130
    • 79551519593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trout, supra note 5, at 394
    • See Trout, supra note 5, at 394 ("Regulation can be permissible even when it runs counter to that person's spontaneous wishes, particularly when the regulation advances the agent's considered judgments or implicit long-term goals.").
  • 131
    • 79551551481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rachlinski, supra note 42, at 1166
    • Rachlinski, supra note 42, at 1166.
  • 132
    • 33745949507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Government regulation of irrationality: Moral and cognitive hazards
    • 1621
    • Jonathan Klick & Gregory Mitchell, Government Regulation of Irrationality: Moral and Cognitive Hazards, 90 MINN. L. REV. 1620, 1621 (2006) (explaining that under "hard forms of paternalism, . . . the government determines what is best for citizens and accordingly restricts the freedom of citizens to act otherwise");
    • (2006) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.90 , pp. 1620
    • Klick, J.1    Mitchell, G.2
  • 133
    • 33645794938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Boundedly rational borrowing
    • 254
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Boundedly Rational Borrowing, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 249, 254 (2006) ("[S]trong paternalism forecloses choice, typically on the ground that all or most people will choose unwisely.");
    • (2006) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.73 , pp. 249
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 134
    • 79551516891 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paternalism
    • last visited Jan. 25
    • see also Gerald Dworkin, Paternalism, in STANFORD ENCYCLOPEDIA OF PHILOSOPHY, available at http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/paternalism (last visited Jan. 25, 2008) (comparing hard and soft paternalism).
    • (2008) Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy
    • Dworkin, G.1
  • 135
    • 79551563627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 54
    • For discussions of the many definitions of paternalism, see Blumenthal, Emotional Paternalism, supra note 54, at 5-6;
    • Emotional Paternalism , pp. 5-6
    • Blumenthal1
  • 136
    • 79551542823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trout, supra note 5, at 408-13
    • Trout, supra note 5, at 408-13.
  • 137
    • 79551565958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Whitman, supra note 4, at 2
    • Whitman, supra note 4, at 2.
  • 138
    • 0742306363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Libertarian Paternalism Is Not an Oxymoron
    • 1159
    • See Cass R. Sunstein & Richard H. Thaler, Libertarian Paternalism Is Not an Oxymoron, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 1159,1159 (2003).
    • (2003) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 1159
    • Sunstein, C.R.1    Thaler, R.H.2
  • 140
    • 23844457021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Libertarian Paternalism Is an Oxymoron
    • 1248 n.10
    • see also Gregory Mitchell, Libertarian Paternalism Is an Oxymoron, 99 Nw. U. L. REV. 1245, 1248 n.10 (2005) [hereinafter Mitchell, Libertarian Paternalism] (contrasting both forms of regulation);
    • (2005) Nw. U. L. REV. , vol.99 , pp. 1245
    • Mitchell, G.1
  • 141
    • 79551520288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sunstein, supra note 60, at 257 (discussing similarities and differences between asymmetrical paternalism and libertarian paternalism).
    • Sunstein, supra note 60, at 257 (discussing similarities and differences between asymmetrical paternalism and libertarian paternalism).
  • 142
    • 79551538242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Klick & Mitchell, supra note 60, at 1621 (noting that under "softer forms of paternalism . . . the government regulates the form in which information and options are presented to citizens and restricts the role of laypersons in the market, legal, and political systems without completely controlling choices");
    • See Klick & Mitchell, supra note 60, at 1621 (noting that under "softer forms of paternalism . . . the government regulates the form in which information and options are presented to citizens and restricts the role of laypersons in the market, legal, and political systems without completely controlling choices");
  • 143
    • 33645781946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paternalism and psychology
    • 149
    • Edward L. Glaeser, Paternalism and Psychology, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 133, 149 (2006) ("Typical examples of soft or libertarian paternalism include 'debiasing' campaigns, default rules, and other interventions that change beliefs and attitude without impacting formal prices faced by consumers.").
    • (2006) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.73 , pp. 133
    • Glaeser, E.L.1
  • 144
    • 79551570290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 18
    • See Camerer et al., Regulation for Conservatives, supra note 18, at 1224-30 (discussing use of default rules in insurance contracts and retirement savings accounts).
    • Regulation for Conservatives , pp. 1224-1230
    • Camerer1
  • 145
    • 79551549696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 1238-47
    • See id. at 1238-47 (discussing the use of cooling-off periods in various contexts, including certain consumer purchases and loans, marriage licensure, and mediated settlements).
  • 146
    • 79551533358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. §§ 1601-1667(f) (2000)
    • 15 U.S.C. §§ 1601-1667(f) (2000);
  • 147
    • 79551570290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 18
    • see also Camerer et al., Regulation for Conservatives, supra note 18, at 1237-48 (discussing the Truth in Lending Act's purposes).
    • Regulation for Conservatives , pp. 1237-1248
    • Camerer1
  • 148
    • 79551525380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Informing consumers about themselves
    • discussing costs and limits of disclosure
    • See Oren Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers About Themselves 63-67 (NYU School of Law, Working Paper No. 111, 2007), available at http://lsr.nellco.org/nyu/ lewp/papers/111/ (discussing costs and limits of disclosure);
    • NYU School of Law, Working Paper No. 111, 2007 , vol.63-67
    • Bar-Gill, O.1
  • 149
    • 79251571384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empirical and behavioral critiques of mandatory disclosure: Socio-economics and the quest for truth in lending
    • 217 n.101
    • see also Matthew A. Edwards, Empirical and Behavioral Critiques of Mandatory Disclosure: Socio-Economics and the Quest for Truth in Lending, 14 CORNELL J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 199, 217 n.101 (2005) (noting costs incurred by those who must provide mandatory disclosures).
    • (2005) CORNELL J.L. & PUB. POL'Y , vol.14 , pp. 199
    • Edwards, M.A.1
  • 150
    • 79551551126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bar-Gill, supra note 69, at 63
    • Bar-Gill, supra note 69, at 63.
  • 151
    • 79551552369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jolis et al., supra note 11, at 1541 ("[B]ounded rationality pushes toward a sort of anti-antipaternalism-a skepticism about antipatemalism, but not an affirmative defense of paternalism.");
    • Supra Note 11, at 1541
    • Jolis1
  • 152
    • 0344497355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral economics and the SEC
    • 4
    • see also Stephen J. Choi & A.C. Pritchard, Behavioral Economics and the SEC, 56 STAN. L. REV. 1, 4 (2003) ("[T]he behavioral economics school generally subscribes to an 'anti-antipaternalism.' As any high school English teacher no doubt could translate, this means a belief in the benefit of 'paternalism.'") (citation omitted).
    • (2003) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.56 , pp. 1
    • Choi, S.J.1    Pritchard, A.C.2
  • 153
    • 79551523721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Garvin, supra note 27, at 315 n.80 (2005) (collecting sources critical of BLE)
    • See Garvin, supra note 27, at 315 n.80 (2005) (collecting sources critical of BLE);
  • 154
    • 79551547757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jones, supra note 32, at 1156-61
    • Jones, supra note 32, at 1156-61 (surveying criticisms of BLE).
  • 155
    • 79551542353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an argument that BLE scholars have not gone far enough to discredit the rational actor model
    • For an argument that BLE scholars have not gone far enough to discredit the rational actor model,
  • 156
    • 17544376308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The situational character: A critical realist perspective on the human animal
    • see Jon Hanson & David Yosifon, The Situational Character: A Critical Realist Perspective on the Human Animal, 93 GEO. L.J. 1 (2004).
    • (2004) Geo. L.J. , vol.93 , pp. 1
    • Hanson, J.1    Yosifon, D.2
  • 157
    • 79551567055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 52
    • Gregory Mitchell has been a leader on this issue. See Mitchell, Unwarranted Pessimism, supra note 52;
    • Unwarranted Pessimism
    • Mitchell1
  • 158
    • 2442616162 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tendencies versus boundaries: Levels of generality in behavioral law and economics
    • Gregory Mitchell, Tendencies Versus Boundaries: Levels of Generality in Behavioral Law and Economics, 56 VAND. L. REV. 1781 (2003);
    • (2003) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.56 , pp. 1781
    • Mitchell, G.1
  • 160
    • 79551523720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hoffman, supra note 33, at 547 n.41
    • see also Hoffman, supra note 33, at 547 n.41 ("Some argue that BLE experiments are flawed in design or execution.");
  • 161
    • 0142169485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How relevant is jury rationality?
    • 517
    • David A. Hoffman, How Relevant is Jury Rationality?, 2003 U. ILL. L. REV. 507, 517 ("Critics of behavioralism's empirical findings argue that isolating decision making in this way is an especially poor way to test human rationality. In laboratories, subjects lack context from which to make decisions-they are given no feedback or opportunity to learn from their mistakes."). For vigorous counterarguments to Mitchell's work,
    • (2003) U. Ill. L. Rev. , pp. 507
    • Hoffman, D.A.1
  • 162
    • 79551520287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prentice, supra note 3.
    • see Prentice, supra note 3.
  • 163
    • 79551510454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Choi, supra note 71 (applying behavioral law and economics theory to the SEC and other regulators)
    • See Choi, supra note 71 (applying behavioral law and economics theory to the SEC and other regulators);
  • 164
    • 79551534838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Glaeser, supra note 65, at 134 (contending that "there are good reasons why we might think that public decisionmaking is likely to be more flawed than private decisionmaking")
    • Glaeser, supra note 65, at 134 (contending that "there are good reasons why we might think that public decisionmaking is likely to be more flawed than private decisionmaking")
  • 165
    • 79551521841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Klick & Mitchell, supra note 60, at 1622-23. For example, the provision of certain types of information to de-bias consumers may lead consumers to overestimate whatever risks they face in a particular market transaction.
    • See Klick & Mitchell, supra note 60, at 1622-23. For example, the provision of certain types of information to "de-bias" consumers may lead consumers to overestimate whatever risks they face in a particular market transaction.
  • 166
    • 33645788995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral economics: Human errors and market corrections
    • See Richard A. Epstein, Behavioral Economics: Human Errors and Market Corrections, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 111, 131 (2006) (discussing credit cards).
    • (2006) U. Chi. L. Rev. 111 , vol.73 , pp. 131
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 167
    • 79551563627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 54
    • See Blumenthal, Emotional Paternalism, supra note 54, at 61-62 (noting the "classic objection" that "people know their tastes and preferences, and act rationally to achieve them, certainly better than any third party might know or do");
    • Emotional Paternalism , pp. 61-62
    • Blumenthal1
  • 168
    • 79551544956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 64
    • Mitchell, Libertarian Paternalism, supra note 64, at 1267-70 (explaining the difficulty for a third party to make judgments about another individual's utility);
    • Libertarian Paternalism , pp. 1267-1270
    • Mitchell1
  • 169
    • 0345777613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The efficiency of paternalism
    • 237-39
    • Eyal Zamir, The Efficiency of Paternalism, 84 VA. L. REV. 229, 237-39 (1998) (discussing and rejecting anti-paternalism arguments based upon the inability of policymakers to assess the well-being of different people).
    • (1998) Va. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 229
    • Zamir, E.1
  • 170
    • 0346029508 scopus 로고
    • The meaning of unfair acts or practices in section 5 of the federal trade commission act
    • Much of this territory has been covered quite ably elsewhere. See, e.g., Neil W. Averitt, The Meaning of "Unfair Acts or Practices" in Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 70 GEO. L.J. 225 (1981);
    • (1981) Geo. L.J. , vol.70 , pp. 225
    • Averitt, N.W.1
  • 171
    • 0348173832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The federal trade commission's use of unfairness authority: Its rise, fall, and resurrection
    • J. Howard Beales III, The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection, 22 J. PUB. POL'Y& MARKETING 192 (2003);
    • (2003) J. Pub. Pol'y& Marketing , vol.22 , pp. 192
    • Howard Beales III, J.1
  • 172
    • 79551528394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The standard for determining unfair acts or practices under state unfair trade practices acts
    • David L. Belt, The Standard for Determining "Unfair Acts or Practices" Under State Unfair Trade Practices Acts, 80 CONN. BAR J. 247 (2006);
    • (2006) Conn. Bar J. , vol.80 , pp. 247
    • Belt, D.L.1
  • 173
    • 79551570648 scopus 로고
    • Defining unfairness: Empathy and economic analysis at the federal trade commission
    • Jean Braucher, Defining Unfairness: Empathy and Economic Analysis at the Federal Trade Commission, 68 B.U. L. REV. 349 (1988) [hereinafter Braucher, Defining Unfairness];
    • (1988) B.U. L. Rev. , vol.68 , pp. 349
    • Braucher, J.1
  • 174
    • 77952874562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC unfairness: An essay
    • Stephen Calkins, FTC Unfairness: An Essay, 46 WAYNE L. REV. 1935 (2000);
    • (2000) Wayne L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 1935
    • Calkins, S.1
  • 175
    • 79551523719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The re-emergence of the unfairness doctrine in federal trade commission and state consumer protection cases
    • Dara J. Diomande, The Re-Emergence of the Unfairness Doctrine in Federal Trade Commission and State Consumer Protection Cases, 18 ANTITRUST 53 (2004);
    • (2004) Antitrust , vol.18 , pp. 53
    • Diomande, D.J.1
  • 176
    • 0346767352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trading Stamps, S & H, and the FTC's Unfairness Doctrine
    • Ernest Gellhorn, Trading Stamps, S & H, and the FTC's Unfairness Doctrine, 1983 DUKE L.J. 903;
    • Duke L.J. , vol.1983 , pp. 903
    • Gellhorn, E.1
  • 178
    • 0347290927 scopus 로고
    • Consumer unfairness at the FTC: Misadventures in law and economics
    • David A. Rice, Consumer Unfairness at the FTC: Misadventures in Law and Economics, 52 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 1 (1983);
    • (1983) Geo. Wash. L. Rev. , vol.52 , pp. 1
    • Rice, D.A.1
  • 179
    • 33847358210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The unfairness of click-on software licenses
    • Roger E. Schechter, The Unfairness of Click-On Software Licenses, 46 WAYNE L. REV. 1735 (2000).
    • (2000) Wayne L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 1735
    • Schechter, R.E.1
  • 180
    • 79551571065 scopus 로고
    • An excellent judicial review of the FTC's unfairness authority can be found
    • 767 F.2d 957,965-72 D.C. Cir.
    • An excellent judicial review of the FTC's unfairness authority can be found in American Financial Services Ass'n v. FTC, 767 F.2d 957,965-72 (D.C. Cir. 1985).
    • (1985) American Financial Services Ass'n V. FTC
  • 181
    • 13844259700 scopus 로고
    • ch. 311, §5, 38 Stat. 717, 719
    • Federal Trade Commission Act, ch. 311, §5, 38 Stat. 717, 719 (1914) (codified at 15 U.S.C. §45 (2000)).
    • (1914) Federal Trade Commission Act
  • 182
    • 79551555382 scopus 로고
    • 631142, at 19
    • A House Report explained the purpose of this open-ended language as follows: "There is no limit to human inventiveness in this field. Even if all known unfair practices were specifically defined and prohibited, it would be at once necessary to begin over again. If Congress were to adopt the method of definition, it would undertake an endless task." H.R. REP. No. 63-1142, at 19(1914).
    • (1914) H.R. Rep.
  • 183
    • 24144440074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How BC and BCP Can strengthen their respective policy missions through new uses of each other's authority
    • 1168
    • See Robert A. Skitol, How BC and BCP Can Strengthen Their Respective Policy Missions Through New Uses of Each Other's Authority, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 1167, 1168 (2005) (noting that between 1914 and 1936, "deception and other practices deemed to be 'oppressive' to consumers were common targets of Commission activity even as the Supreme Court flip-flopped over the central issue of whether the agency had authority to reach these practices without a showing of adverse effect on competition or competitors")
    • (2005) Antitrust L.J. , vol.72 , pp. 1167
    • Skitol, R.A.1
  • 184
    • 79551562905 scopus 로고
    • 253 U.S. 421
    • (comparing FTC v. Gratz, 253 U.S. 421 (1920),
    • (1920) FTC V. Gratz
  • 185
    • 79551569566 scopus 로고
    • 283 U.S. 643
    • and FTC v. Raladam Co., 283 U.S. 643 (1931),
    • (1931) FTC V. Raladam Co.
  • 186
    • 79551523179 scopus 로고
    • 291 U.S. 304
    • with FTC v. R.F. Keppel & Bros., 291 U.S. 304 (1934)). Neil Averitt points out that in most cases, harm to competition accompanied harm to consumers, a fact that case law from this period recognized.
    • (1934) FTC V. R.F. Keppel & Bros.
  • 187
    • 79551507590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Averitt, supra note 77, at 231-32
    • See Averitt, supra note 77, at 231-32.
  • 188
    • 79551533143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 283 U.S. 643 (1931)
    • 283 U.S. 643 (1931).
  • 189
    • 79551556462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Calkins, supra note 77, at 1949
    • Calkins, supra note 77, at 1949.
  • 190
    • 79551548460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Raladam, 283 U.S. at 654
    • Raladam, 283 U.S. at 654.
  • 191
    • 79551574196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 649
    • Id. at 649.
  • 192
    • 79551548459 scopus 로고
    • Calkins, supra note 77, at 1936 "Unhappy with a cramped Supreme Court interpretation of this prohibition in Congress in supplemented this language by declaring that unfair or deceptive acts or practices are also 'unlawful.'" (citations omitted)
    • See Calkins, supra note 77, at 1936 ("Unhappy with a cramped Supreme Court interpretation of this prohibition in FTC v. Raladam Co., Congress in 1938 supplemented this language by declaring that 'unfair or deceptive acts or practices' are also 'unlawful.'") (citations omitted);
    • (1938) FTC V. Raladam Co.
  • 193
    • 75449115451 scopus 로고
    • New Applications of Consumer Protection Law: Judicial activism or legislative directive?
    • 363
    • J.R. Franke & D. A. Bailam, New Applications of Consumer Protection Law: Judicial Activism or Legislative Directive?, 32 SANTA CLARA L. REV. 347, 363 (1992) (viewing the Wheeler-Lea Amendment as a response to the Supreme Court's decision in Raladam);
    • (1992) Santa Clara L. Rev. , vol.32 , pp. 347
    • Franke, J.R.1    Bailam, D.A.2
  • 194
    • 79551563993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MURIS & BEALES, supra note 77, at 10
    • MURIS & BEALES, supra note 77, at 10.
  • 195
    • 79551518869 scopus 로고
    • ch. 49, § 3, 52 Stat. 111
    • Wheeler-Lea Act, ch. 49, § 3, 52 Stat. 111 (1938). As amended, section 5(a)(1) of the Federal Trade Commission Act now provides: "Unfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce, and unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce, are hereby declared unlawful." 15 U.S.C. §45(a)(1) (2000).
    • (1938) Wheeler-Lea Act
  • 197
    • 79551524333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beales, supra note 77, at 192 ("Prior to 1964, the commission largely ignored the word or in the amendment and described acts it found offensive as 'unfair and deceptive' without making any attempt to distinguish between 'unfair' on the one hand and 'deceptive' on the other hand.")
    • See Beales, supra note 77, at 192 ("Prior to 1964, the commission largely ignored the word 'or' in the amendment and described acts it found offensive as 'unfair and deceptive' without making any attempt to distinguish between 'unfair' on the one hand and 'deceptive' on the other hand.");
  • 198
    • 79551556461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schechter, supra note 77, at 1761 ("From the mid-thirties through the early sixties the FTC... did not attempt to distinguish between 'deceptive' practices and those that were 'unfair.' Instead, it would allege an 'unfair-and-deceptive-practice' as if the term constituted a single compound word, defining a unitary phenomenon.")
    • Schechter, supra note 77, at 1761 ("From the mid-thirties through the early sixties the FTC... did not attempt to distinguish between 'deceptive' practices and those that were 'unfair.' Instead, it would allege an 'unfair-and-deceptive-practice' as if the term constituted a single compound word, defining a unitary phenomenon.")
  • 200
    • 79551556848 scopus 로고
    • Regulating Unfair Practices under the FTC Act: The Need for a Legal Standard of Unfairness
    • 4-6
    • See Teresa M. Schwartz, Regulating Unfair Practices Under the FTC Act: The Need for a Legal Standard of Unfairness, 11 AKRON L. REV. 1, 4-6 (1977) (describing the FTC's first articulation of the unfairness theory in a rulemaking procedure).
    • (1977) Akron L. Rev. , vol.11 , pp. 1
    • Schwartz, T.M.1
  • 201
    • 15844381654 scopus 로고
    • Unfair or deceptive advertising and labeling of cigarettes in relation to the health hazards of smoking
    • Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking, 29 Fed. Reg. 8324 (1964) [hereinafter Cigarette Rule].
    • (1964) Fed. Reg. , vol.29 , pp. 8324
  • 202
    • 79551569565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ironically, even though he later was the intellectual leader of the law and economics movement that contributed to the demise of the Cigarette Rule, FTC lore holds that the principal author of this document was Richard Posner, then a 25-year-old attorney adviser to Commissioner Philip Elman. Beales, supra note 77, at 193 n.4
    • Ironically, even though he later was the intellectual leader of the law and economics movement that contributed to the demise of the Cigarette Rule, "FTC lore holds that the principal author of this document was Richard Posner, then a 25-year-old attorney adviser to Commissioner Philip Elman." Beales, supra note 77, at 193 n.4
  • 203
    • 79551524332 scopus 로고
    • Oral History Research Office, Columbia University
    • (citing The Reminiscences of Philip Elman, Oral History Research Office, Columbia University, at 372-73 (1986)).
    • (1986) The Reminiscences of Philip Elman , pp. 372-373
  • 204
    • 79551551124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Judge Posner confirmed this fact wim the author via e-mail. E-mail from Richard Posner, Judge, United States Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit, to author (May 30, 2007, 02:52:00 EST).
    • Judge Posner confirmed this fact wim the author via e-mail. E-mail from Richard Posner, Judge, United States Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit, to author (May 30, 2007, 02:52:00 EST).
  • 205
    • 79551531055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cigarette Rule, supra note 90, at 8355. The Cigarette Rule begins with this guidance: No enumeration of examples can define the outer limits of the Commission's authority to proscribe unfair acts or practices, but the examples should help to indicate the breadth and flexibility of the concept of unfair acts or practices and to suggest the factors that determine whether a particular act or practice should be forbidden on this ground
    • Cigarette Rule, supra note 90, at 8355. The Cigarette Rule begins with this guidance: No enumeration of examples can define the outer limits of the Commission's authority to proscribe unfair acts or practices, but the examples should help to indicate the breadth and flexibility of the concept of unfair acts or practices and to suggest the factors that determine whether a particular act or practice should be forbidden on this ground.
  • 206
    • 79551540201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 207
    • 24144475529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Three Rules and a Constitution: Consumer Protection Finds Its Limits in Competition Policy
    • 946-48
    • See William MacLeod et al., Three Rules and a Constitution: Consumer Protection Finds Its Limits in Competition Policy, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 943, 946-48 (2005) (reviewing the congressional response to the Cigarette Rule, culminating in the passage of the Federal Cigarette Labeling and Advertising Act in 1969);
    • (2005) Antitrust L.J. , vol.72 , pp. 943
    • MacLeod, W.1
  • 208
    • 79551529460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schechter, supra note 77, at 1762
    • Schechter, supra note 77, at 1762 ("The FTC's effort to promulgate a final cigarette rule eventually foundered in the face of the complicated politics of tobacco, and Congress took direct legislative action to deal with the problem, rather than leaving it to administrative resolution."
  • 210
    • 79551543184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwartz, supra note 89, at 6 (noting that the Act "effectively overruled the Commission's trade regulation rule").
    • Schwartz, supra note 89, at 6 (noting that the Act "effectively overruled the Commission's trade regulation rule").
  • 211
    • 79551565957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schechter, supra note 77, at 1762
    • Schechter, supra note 77, at 1762.
  • 214
    • 33645344644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Consumer Fraud Class Action: Reining in Abuse by Requiring Plaintiffs to A liege Reliance as an Essential Element
    • 12
    • Sheila B. Scheuerman, The Consumer Fraud Class Action: Reining in Abuse by Requiring Plaintiffs to A liege Reliance as an Essential Element, 43 HARV. J. ON LEGIS. 1, 12 (2006).
    • (2006) Harv. J. On Legis. , vol.43 , pp. 1
    • Scheuerman, S.B.1
  • 215
    • 79551520634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 943
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 943.
  • 218
    • 79551512836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 405 U.S. 233,244 (1972)
    • 405 U.S. 233,244 (1972).
  • 219
    • 79551506535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 244 n.5
    • Id. at 244 n.5.
  • 220
    • 79551524669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Averitt, supra note 77, at 245 n.130
    • See Averitt, supra note 77, at 245 n.130 ("Although the Court merely quoted the Commission's statement without expressly assenting to it, the overall context implied approval.");
  • 221
    • 79551514322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 77
    • Braucher, Defining Unfairness, supra note 77, at 408 (noting "protracted debate about whether the Supreme Court really approved of the criteria");
    • Defining Unfairness , pp. 408
    • Braucher1
  • 222
    • 79551561444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Calkins, supra note 77, at 1952
    • Calkins, supra note 77, at 1952
  • 223
    • 79551540894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Cigarette Rule Statement's factors acquired talismanic status when the Supreme Court cited them with apparent approval
    • ("The Cigarette Rule Statement's factors acquired talismanic status when the Supreme Court cited them with apparent approval in FTC v. Sperry & Hutchinson Co.");
    • FTC V. Sperry & Hutchinson Co.
  • 224
    • 79551507926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rice, supra note 77, at 24-25 (Close consideration of the [Sperry & Hutchinson] opinion, and the petition and brief in the case, demonstrates that the Commission did not seek the Supreme Court's approbation of the Cigarette Rule test and that the Court's quotation of the test in a footnote to its broad dictum expressed neither approval nor disapproval.") (citation omitted);
    • Rice, supra note 77, at 24-25 ("Close consideration of the [Sperry & Hutchinson] opinion, and the petition and brief in the case, demonstrates that the Commission did not seek the Supreme Court's approbation of the Cigarette Rule test and that the Court's quotation of the test in a footnote to its broad dictum expressed neither approval nor disapproval.") (citation omitted);
  • 225
    • 79551564489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schechter, supra note 77, at 1763
    • Schechter, supra note 77, at 1763 ("While not strictly germane to the issue before it, the Court made favorable reference to the FTC unfairness definition in a footnote.").
  • 226
    • 79551535879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MURIS & BEALES, supra note 77, at 12
    • MURIS & BEALES, supra note 77, at 12.
  • 227
    • 79551572422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prior to enactment of the Magnuson-Moss Act, the FTC claimed that it had substantive rulemaking authority under section 6(g) of the FTC Act, which gives the Commission authority "to make rules and regulations for the purpose of carrying out the provisions of the FTC Act. 15 U.S.C. §46(g)
    • Prior to enactment of the Magnuson-Moss Act, the FTC claimed that it had substantive rulemaking authority under section 6(g) of the FTC Act, which gives the Commission authority "to make rules and regulations for the purpose of carrying out the provisions of the FTC Act. 15 U.S.C. §46(g) (2000)
    • (2000)
  • 228
    • 79551526818 scopus 로고
    • The D.C. Circuit endorsed the FTC's view 482 F.2d 672, 697-98 D.C. Cir.
    • . The D.C. Circuit endorsed the FTC's view in National Petroleum Refiners Ass 'n v. FTC, 482 F.2d 672, 697-98 (D.C. Cir. 1973). Nonetheless, the passage of the Magnuson-Moss Act removed all doubt.
    • (1973) National Petroleum Refiners Ass 'N V. FTC
  • 229
    • 0347397651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The FTC's consumer protection program during the miller years: Lessons for administrative agency structure and operation
    • 414-16
    • See Mark E. Budnitz, The FTC's Consumer Protection Program During the Miller Years: Lessons for Administrative Agency Structure and Operation, 46 CATH. U. L. REV. 371, 414-16 (1997) (discussing the history of FTC rulemaking authority);
    • (1997) Cath. U. L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 371
    • Budnitz, M.E.1
  • 230
    • 79551552367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WARD, supra note 88, §13.01, at 13-2 to 13-6 (elaborating on rulemaking authority under FTC Act §6(g))
    • WARD, supra note 88, §13.01, at 13-2 to 13-6 (elaborating on rulemaking authority under FTC Act §6(g)).
  • 231
    • 79551516890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WARD, supra note 88, § 13.01, at 13-4 (discussing the more
    • See WARD, supra note 88, § 13.01, at 13-4 (discussing the more "elaborate procedures" under the Magnuson-Moss/FTC Improvement Act).
  • 232
    • 79551505458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 93637, 88 Stat. 2183 (1975) (codified at 15 U.S.C. § 57a(a)(1)(B) (2000)) (providing authority to promulgate "rules which define with specificity acts or practices which are unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce")
    • See Pub. L. No. 93-637, 88 Stat. 2183 (1975) (codified at 15 U.S.C. § 57a(a)(1)(B) (2000)) (providing authority to promulgate "rules which define with specificity acts or practices which are unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce").
  • 233
    • 79551514758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Budnitz, supra note 104, at 376 (noting the support of the Nixon administration and Congress for increased FTC activism)
    • See Budnitz, supra note 104, at 376 (noting the support of the Nixon administration and Congress for increased FTC activism).
  • 234
    • 73049104434 scopus 로고
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 953-54 (listing twenty-eight major rulemakings in the 1970s). Actually, some of the successful FTC rulemaking efforts in the 1970s began prior to publication of the Supreme Court's opinion in decided Mar. 1, and enactment of the Magnuson-Moss Act (signed into law by President Ford on Jan. 4, 1975). For these rules, it would be erroneous to suggest that they were inspired by those events
    • See MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 953-54 (listing twenty-eight major rulemakings in the 1970s). Actually, some of the successful FTC rulemaking efforts in the 1970s began prior to publication of the Supreme Court's opinion in FTC v. Sperry & Hutchinson Co. (decided Mar. 1, 1972) and enactment of the Magnuson-Moss Act (signed into law by President Ford on Jan. 4, 1975). For these rules, it would be erroneous to suggest that they were inspired by those events.
    • (1972) FTC V. Sperry & Hutchinson Co.
  • 235
    • 79551557932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posting of Minimum Octane Numbers on Gasoline Dispensing Pumps, 36 Fed. Reg. 23,871 (Dec. 16, 1971) (codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 422)
    • See, e.g., Posting of Minimum Octane Numbers on Gasoline Dispensing Pumps, 36 Fed. Reg. 23,871 (Dec. 16, 1971) (codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 422);
  • 236
    • 79551506871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Care Labeling of Textile Wearing Apparel, 36 Fed. Reg. 23,883 (Dec. 16, 1971) (codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 423)
    • Care Labeling of Textile Wearing Apparel, 36 Fed. Reg. 23,883 (Dec. 16, 1971) (codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 423);
  • 237
    • 79551507589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cooling-Off Period for Door-to-Door Sales, 37 Fed. Reg. 22,934 (Oct. 26,1972) (codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 429)
    • Cooling-Off Period for Door-to-Door Sales, 37 Fed. Reg. 22,934 (Oct. 26,1972) (codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 429).
  • 238
    • 79551563267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 952-54
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 952-54.
  • 239
    • 79551563990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 944 (using the term "Kid Vid" to describe the Children's Advertising rulemaking). Other sources use the term kidvid or "Kidvid
    • See id. at 944 (using the term "Kid Vid" to describe the Children's Advertising rulemaking). Other sources use the term "kidvid" or "Kidvid."
  • 240
    • 77951147820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Advertising to kids and the FTC: A regulatory retrospective that advises the present
    • 878 [hereinafter Beales, Advertising to Kids]
    • See, e.g., J. Howard Beales III, Advertising to Kids and the FTC: A Regulatory Retrospective that Advises the Present, 12 GEO. MASON L. REV. 873, 878 (2004) [hereinafter Beales, Advertising to Kids];
    • (2004) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.12 , pp. 873
    • Howard Beales III, J.1
  • 241
    • 79551549334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merchants of discontent: An exploration of the psychology of advertising, addiction, and the implications for commercial speech
    • 442
    • Tamara R. Piety, "Merchants of Discontent": An Exploration of the Psychology of Advertising, Addiction, and the Implications for Commercial Speech, 25 SEATTLE U. L. REV. 377, 442 (2001).
    • (2001) Seattle U. L. Rev. , vol.25 , pp. 377
    • Piety, T.R.1
  • 242
    • 79551530275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Children's Advertising, 43 Fed. Reg. 17,967 (Apr. 27, 1978)
    • Children's Advertising, 43 Fed. Reg. 17,967 (Apr. 27, 1978).
  • 243
    • 24144470828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brightening the lines: The use of policy statements at the federal trade commission
    • 1065 [hereinafter Beales, Brightening the Lines]
    • J. Howard Beales III, Brightening the Lines: The Use of Policy Statements at the Federal Trade Commission, 72 ANTITRUST LJ. 1057, 1065 (2005) [hereinafter Beales, Brightening the Lines];
    • (2005) Antitrust L.J. , vol.72 , pp. 1057
    • Howard Beales III, J.1
  • 244
    • 79551569929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 955 (referring to the Washington Post as a typically friendly observer)
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 955 (referring to the Washington Post as "a typically friendly observer").
  • 245
    • 79551551992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Editorial, The FTC as National Nanny, WASH. POST, Mar. 1, 1978, at A22 (asserting that flat bans on advertising to children are "a preposterous intervention that would turn the agency into a great national nanny")
    • See Editorial, The FTC as National Nanny, WASH. POST, Mar. 1, 1978, at A22 (asserting that flat bans on advertising to children are "a preposterous intervention that would turn the agency into a great national nanny").
  • 247
    • 79551568733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Mark Budnitz questions this account: The conventional wisdom, which views Pertschuk as the chairman who defied Congress by taking the FTC down the path of increased activism against Congress's wishes, clearly is wrong. Pertschuk was chided for his wide-ranging effort to promulgate trade regulation rules, but most of that activity began when Nixon was President, and it was Congress that had enacted the Magnuson-Moss ... Act, which conferred broad rulemaking authority upon the FTC. Although Pertschuk was vilified by Congress and others for his "kid vid" initiative, Congress itself had recommended FTC action to protect children from television advertisements. The conflicting messages may be more a reflection of the election of a more conservative Congress than a principled objection to the Pertschuk agenda. Budnitz, supra note 104, at 376 (internal citations omitted).
  • 248
    • 79551554530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Children's Advertising, 46 Fed. Reg. 48,710 (Oct. 2, 1981) (terminating the Children's Advertising rulemaking process). For a helpful review of the process by which the FTC decided not to pursue the Kid Vid rulemaking
    • See Children's Advertising, 46 Fed. Reg. 48,710 (Oct. 2, 1981) (terminating the Children's Advertising rulemaking process). For a helpful review of the process by which the FTC decided not to pursue the Kid Vid rulemaking,
  • 249
    • 79551529810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 956-58 (discussing an FTC Staff Report on Television Advertising to Children (Mar. 14, 1978) and an FTC Final Staff Report and Recommendation (Mar. 31,1981))
    • see MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 956-58 (discussing an FTC Staff Report on Television Advertising to Children (Mar. 14, 1978) and an FTC Final Staff Report and Recommendation (Mar. 31,1981)).
  • 250
    • 79551563266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Budnitz, supra note 104, at 371 ("The conventional wisdom is that the Federal Trade Commission... under President Carter's Chairman, Michael Pertschuk, turned the FTC into a renegade agency which engaged in runaway consumer protection, hamstringing business with excessive regulation to such an extent it became known as the 'national nanny.'")
    • See Budnitz, supra note 104, at 371 ("The conventional wisdom is that the Federal Trade Commission... under President Carter's Chairman, Michael Pertschuk, turned the FTC into a renegade agency which engaged in runaway consumer protection, hamstringing business with excessive regulation to such an extent it became known as the 'national nanny.'");
  • 251
    • 79551538593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Calkins, supra note 77, at 195354 (discussing FTC overreaching and congressional backlash); MURIS & BEALES, supra note 77, at 14-15 (noting legislative, press, and business responses to "unfocused unfairness theories")
    • Calkins, supra note 77, at 1953-54 (discussing FTC overreaching and congressional backlash); MURIS & BEALES, supra note 77, at 14-15 (noting legislative, press, and business responses to "unfocused unfairness theories").
  • 252
    • 79551535877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beales, Advertising to Kids, supra note 110, at 879-80 (internal citations omitted)
    • Beales, Advertising to Kids, supra note 110, at 879-80 (internal citations omitted);
  • 253
    • 79551515464 scopus 로고
    • F.2d 969-70 D.C. Cir. (citing Federal Trade Commission Improvements Act of 1980, Pub. L. No. 96252, 94 Stat. 374 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 15 U.S.C.)) (noting that the congressional response to Kid Vid included enactment of a federal law that "suspended the Commission's controversial rulemaking on children's advertising and placed a moratorium on the initiation of any new rulemakings aimed at regulating commercial advertising as an unfair practice pending congressional oversight hearings")
    • see also Am. Fin. Servs. Ass'n v. FTC, 767 F.2d 957, 969-70 (D.C. Cir. 1985) (citing Federal Trade Commission Improvements Act of 1980, Pub. L. No. 96-252, 94 Stat. 374 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 15 U.S.C.)) (noting that the congressional response to Kid Vid included enactment of a federal law that "suspended the Commission's controversial rulemaking on children's advertising and placed a moratorium on the initiation of any new rulemakings aimed at regulating commercial advertising as an unfair practice pending congressional oversight hearings");
    • (1985) Am. Fin. Servs. Ass'n V. FTC , vol.767 , pp. 957
  • 254
    • 79551550044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 961 ("The FTC Improvements Act of 1980 ... revoked the Commission's authority to promulgate any rule invoking a theory of unfairness to govern advertising and terminated other proceedings.")
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 961 ("The FTC Improvements Act of 1980 ... revoked the Commission's authority to promulgate any rule invoking a theory of unfairness to govern advertising and terminated other proceedings.");
  • 255
    • 24144470829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The federal trade commission and consumer protection: Regulatory change and administrative pragmatism
    • 925 ("The controversy surrounding 'Kid Vid' proved to be a lightning rod, which led eventually to efforts by Congress and the Reagan administration that halted, at least for a decade, consumer activism in the Commission.")
    • Sidney M. Milkis, The Federal Trade Commission and Consumer Protection: Regulatory Change and Administrative Pragmatism, 72 ANTITRUST LJ. 911, 925 (2005) ("The controversy surrounding 'Kid Vid' proved to be a lightning rod, which led eventually to efforts by Congress and the Reagan administration that halted, at least for a decade, consumer activism in the Commission.").
    • (2005) Antitrust L.J. , vol.72 , pp. 911
    • Milkis, S.M.1
  • 256
    • 79551509332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Piety, supra note 110, at 443 ("The FTC that emerged from these disputes was a distinctly chastened one for many years thereafter.")
    • See Piety, supra note 110, at 443 ("The FTC that emerged from these disputes was a distinctly chastened one for many years thereafter.").
  • 257
    • 79551567327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 953-54 (chart indicating that fourteen of twenty-one rulemakings from 1974 to 1980 were terminated by the FTC)
    • See MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 953-54 (chart indicating that fourteen of twenty-one rulemakings from 1974 to 1980 were terminated by the FTC);
  • 258
    • 21144470858 scopus 로고
    • Some thoughts on deossifying the rulemaking process
    • 1389-90 (observing that "[o]f the nineteen major rules and amendments proposed ... during the latter part of the 1970s... only seven were completed") (internal citations omitted)
    • Thomas O. McGarity, Some Thoughts on "Deossifying" the Rulemaking Process, 41 DUKE LJ. 1385, 1389-90 (1992) (observing that "[o]f the nineteen major rules and amendments proposed ... during the latter part of the 1970s... only seven were completed") (internal citations omitted).
    • (1992) Duke L.J. , vol.41 , pp. 1385
    • McGarity, T.O.1
  • 260
    • 79551554186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beales, Brightening the Lines, supra note 112, at 1063 ("The Unfairness Policy Statement emerged as the Commission's response to mounting external political pressure. As concerns grew about the breadth of the Commission's authority to declare a practice unfair, the agency faced serious threats to important parts of its consumer protection jurisdiction.")
    • See Beales, Brightening the Lines, supra note 112, at 1063 ("The Unfairness Policy Statement emerged as the Commission's response to mounting external political pressure. As concerns grew about the breadth of the Commission's authority to declare a practice unfair, the agency faced serious threats to important parts of its consumer protection jurisdiction.");
  • 261
    • 79551542352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Braucher, Defining Unfairness, supra note 77, at 409 (discussing the Unfairness Policy Statement's political purposes)
    • Braucher, Defining Unfairness, supra note 77, at 409 (discussing the Unfairness Policy Statement's political purposes).
  • 262
    • 79551508916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Letter from the FTC to Hon. Wendell Ford and Hon. John Danforth, S. Comm. on Commerce, Sei., and Transp., Comm. Statement of Policy on the Scope of Consumer Unfairness Jurisdiction (Dec. 17, 1980), reprinted in Int'l Harvester Co., 104 F.T.C. 949, 1070-76 (1984) [hereinafter FTC Unfairness Policy Statement]. In 1982, the FTC reaffirmed the 1980 Unfairness Policy Statement in a letter from Chairman Miller to Senators Packwood and Kasten (Mar. 5, 1982), reprinted in H.R. REP. NO. 99162, at 28 (1985)
    • See Letter from the FTC to Hon. Wendell Ford and Hon. John Danforth, S. Comm. on Commerce, Sei., and Transp., Comm. Statement of Policy on the Scope of Consumer Unfairness Jurisdiction (Dec. 17, 1980), reprinted in Int'l Harvester Co., 104 F.T.C. 949, 1070-76 (1984) [hereinafter FTC Unfairness Policy Statement]. In 1982, the FTC reaffirmed the 1980 Unfairness Policy Statement in a letter from Chairman Miller to Senators Packwood and Kasten (Mar. 5, 1982), reprinted in H.R. REP. NO. 99-162, at 28 (1985).
  • 263
    • 79551557930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some sources refer to the three part test as the Cigarette Test, due to its original administrative pedigree, see Cigarette Rule, supra note 90, whereas other sources refer to it as the S&H standard because of the Supreme Court's purported endorsement of the Cigarette Test in
    • Some sources refer to the three part test as the Cigarette Test, due to its original administrative pedigree, see Cigarette Rule, supra note 90, whereas other sources refer to it as the S&H standard because of the Supreme Court's purported endorsement of the Cigarette Test in FTC v. Sperry & Hutchinson.
    • FTC V. Sperry & Hutchinson.
  • 264
    • 79551550043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 100-02 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 100-02 and accompanying text.
  • 265
    • 79551564870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC Unfairness Policy Statement, supra note 123, at 1073 ("Unjustified consumer injury is the primary focus of the FTC Act, and the most important of the three S&H criteria. By itself it can be sufficient to warrant a finding of unfairness.)
    • See FTC Unfairness Policy Statement, supra note 123, at 1073 ("Unjustified consumer injury is the primary focus of the FTC Act, and the most important of the three S&H criteria. By itself it can be sufficient to warrant a finding of unfairness.");
  • 266
    • 79551519234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MURIS & BEALES, supra note 77, at 15
    • MURIS & BEALES, supra note 77, at 15;
  • 267
    • 79551563986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unfairness under section 5 of the FTC act and its impact on state law
    • 1874 (quoting Int 7 Harvester Co., 104 F.T.C. at 1071). The Unfairness Policy Statement also retained the public policy prong" of the Cigarette/S&H Test, noting that "[i]t may be used to test the validity and strength of the evidence of consumer injury, or, less often, it may be cited for a dispositive legislative or judicial determination that such injury is present." FTC Unfairness Policy Statement, supra note 123, at 1074-75. The FTC made clear, however, that "[t]o the extent that the Commission relies heavily on public policy to support a finding of unfairness, the policy should be clear and well-established
    • Michael M. Greenfield, Unfairness Under Section 5 of the FTC Act and Its Impact on State Law, 46 WAYNE L. REV. 1869, 1874 (2000) (quoting Int 7 Harvester Co., 104 F.T.C. at 1071). The Unfairness Policy Statement also retained the "public policy prong" of the Cigarette/S&H Test, noting that "[i]t may be used to test the validity and strength of the evidence of consumer injury, or, less often, it may be cited for a dispositive legislative or judicial determination that such injury is present." FTC Unfairness Policy Statement, supra note 123, at 1074-75. The FTC made clear, however, that "[t]o the extent that the Commission relies heavily on public policy to support a finding of unfairness, the policy should be clear and well-established."
    • (2000) Wayne L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 1869
    • Greenfield, M.M.1
  • 268
    • 79551523715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1076. The FTC subsequently backed off from this view, when "in 1982 a unanimous Commission . . . clarified that the use of public policy is not an independent basis for finding unfairness." MURIS & BEALES, supra note 77, at 18 (citing Letter from FTC to Hon. Robert Packwood and Hon. Robert Kasten at 8 (Mar. 5, 1982), reprinted in H.R. REP. NO. 98-156, pt. 1, at 27, 32-33 (1983))
    • Id. at 1076. The FTC subsequently backed off from this view, when "in 1982 a unanimous Commission . . . clarified that the use of public policy is not an independent basis for finding unfairness." MURIS & BEALES, supra note 77, at 18 (citing Letter from FTC to Hon. Robert Packwood and Hon. Robert Kasten at 8 (Mar. 5, 1982), reprinted in H.R. REP. NO. 98-156, pt. 1, at 27, 32-33 (1983));
  • 269
    • 79551505454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unfair acts or practices under CUTPA-The case for abandoning the obsolete cigarette rule and following modern FTC unfairness policy
    • 118 (discussing the FTC's shifting treatment of public policy). Congress later codified the FTC's stated limitation on the use of public policy
    • see also Paul Sobel, Unfair Acts or Practices Under CUTPA-The Case for Abandoning the Obsolete Cigarette Rule and Following Modern FTC Unfairness Policy, 11 CONN. BJ. 105, 118 (2003) (discussing the FTC's shifting treatment of public policy). Congress later codified the FTC's stated limitation on the use of public policy.
    • (2003) Conn. Bj. , vol.11 , pp. 105
    • Sobel, P.1
  • 270
    • 79551532408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra note 163
    • See infra note 163.
  • 271
    • 79551515134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Int 7 Harvester Co., 104 F.T.C. at 1070-76
    • Int 7 Harvester Co., 104 F.T.C. at 1070-76.
  • 272
    • 79551535550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 1073 ("First of all, the injury must be substantial. The Commission is not concerned with trivial or merely speculative harms.")
    • See id. at 1073 ("First of all, the injury must be substantial. The Commission is not concerned with trivial or merely speculative harms.").
  • 273
    • 79551544221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. ("[T]he injury must not be outweighed by any offsetting consumer or competitive benefits that the sales practice also produces.")
    • See id. ("[T]he injury must not be outweighed by any offsetting consumer or competitive benefits that the sales practice also produces.").
  • 274
    • 79551568394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 1074 ("[T]he injury must be one which consumers could not reasonably have avoided.")
    • See id. at 1074 ("[T]he injury must be one which consumers could not reasonably have avoided.").
  • 275
    • 79551522223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHELDON & CARTER, supra note 6, § 4.3.2.2, at 193-94 ("Substantial injury must not be trivial or merely speculative harm, but will usually involve monetary harm or unwarranted health and safety risks. Emotional or other subjective harm alone will not ordinarily make a practice unfair, although invasion of privacy may be a substantial injury.") (internal citations omitted)
    • See SHELDON & CARTER, supra note 6, § 4.3.2.2, at 193-94 ("Substantial injury must not be trivial or merely speculative harm, but will usually involve monetary harm or unwarranted health and safety risks. Emotional or other subjective harm alone will not ordinarily make a practice unfair, although invasion of privacy may be a substantial injury.") (internal citations omitted);
  • 276
    • 70349499311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Delayed disclosure in consumer e-commerce as an unfair and deceptive practice
    • 1858 ("The essence of 'substantialness' is monetary harm.")
    • Jean Braucher, Delayed Disclosure in Consumer E-Commerce As an Unfair and Deceptive Practice, 46 WAYNE L. REV. 1805, 1858 (2000) ("The essence of 'substantialness' is monetary harm.");
    • (2000) Wayne L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 1805
    • Braucher, J.1
  • 277
    • 79551506177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schechter, supra note 77, at 1770 (discussing injury requirement and noting that "the concept of 'injury' in the law of unfairness is surprisingly underdeveloped")
    • Schechter, supra note 77, at 1770 (discussing injury requirement and noting that "the concept of 'injury' in the law of unfairness is surprisingly underdeveloped").
  • 278
    • 79551552710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC Unfairness Policy Statement, supra note 123, at 1076
    • FTC Unfairness Policy Statement, supra note 123, at 1076.
  • 279
    • 79551569198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. The Commission made clear that it has therefore never relied on the third element of S&H as an independent basis for a finding of unfairness, and it will act in the future only on the basis of the first two
    • Id. The Commission made clear that it "has therefore never relied on the third element of S&H as an independent basis for a finding of unfairness, and it will act in the future only on the basis of the first two."
  • 280
    • 79551516154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 281
    • 79551523716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PRIDGEN, supra note 6, § 9:5, at 569 ("The notion of immorality or lack of ethics (a more intuitive understanding of unfairness) plays no role in this legal construct. Instead, the discipline of economics looms large as the guiding light of the FTC's new unfairness doctrine.)
    • See PRIDGEN, supra note 6, § 9:5, at 569 ("The notion of immorality or lack of ethics (a more intuitive understanding of unfairness) plays no role in this legal construct. Instead, the discipline of economics looms large as the guiding light of the FTC's new unfairness doctrine.");
  • 282
    • 79551509733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unfairness and the internet
    • 1713 (noting that the Cigarette Rule gave primacy to moral and ethical concepts, and to precedent" whereas the newer standard "gives primacy to economic factors, and introduces the notion of consumer responsibility")
    • Thomas B. Leary, Unfairness and the Internet, 46 WAYNE L. REV. 1711, 1713 (2000) (noting that the Cigarette Rule gave "primacy to moral and ethical concepts, and to precedent" whereas the newer standard "gives primacy to economic factors, and introduces the notion of consumer responsibility") .
    • (2000) Wayne L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 1711
    • Leary, T.B.1
  • 283
    • 79551548113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Int'l Harvester Co., 104 F.T.C. at 1061 ("The Commission does not ordinarily seek to mandate specific conduct or specific social outcomes, but rather seeks to ensure simply that markets operate freely, so that consumers can make their own decisions."); PRIDGEN, supra note 6, § 9:5, at 568-69 ("Indeed, the entire consumer unfairness doctrine now appears to be based solely on the idea of consumer sovereignty, i.e., that consumers must be able to make their own decisions in the marketplace, free of unfair impediments.")
    • See Int'l Harvester Co., 104 F.T.C. at 1061 ("The Commission does not ordinarily seek to mandate specific conduct or specific social outcomes, but rather seeks to ensure simply that markets operate freely, so that consumers can make their own decisions."); PRIDGEN, supra note 6, § 9:5, at 568-69 ("Indeed, the entire consumer unfairness doctrine now appears to be based solely on the idea of consumer sovereignty, i.e., that consumers must be able to make their own decisions in the marketplace, free of unfair impediments.").
  • 284
    • 21744435535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumer sovereignty: A unified theory of antitrust and consumer protection law
    • 715 (internal citation omitted). According to Averitt and Lande, consumers are sovereign when they have the power to define their own wants and the opportunity to satisfy those wants at prices not greatly in excess of the costs borne by the providers of the relevant goods and services
    • Neil W. Averitt & Robert H. Lande, Consumer Sovereignty: A Unified Theory of Antitrust and Consumer Protection Law, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 713, 715 (1997) (internal citation omitted). According to Averitt and Lande, consumers are sovereign when they have "the power to define their own wants and the opportunity to satisfy those wants at prices not greatly in excess of the costs borne by the providers of the relevant goods and services."
    • (1997) Antitrust L.J. , vol.65 , pp. 713
    • Averitt, N.W.1    Lande, R.H.2
  • 285
    • 79551526465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 716. For more on the concept of consumer sovereignty
    • Id. at 716. For more on the concept of consumer sovereignty,
  • 286
    • 0003511427 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge Univ. Press (discussing alternative definitions of "consumer sovereignty")
    • see G. PETER PENZ, CONSUMER SOVEREIGNTY AND HUMAN INTERESTS 13-14 (Cambridge Univ. Press 1986) (discussing alternative definitions of "consumer sovereignty");
    • (1986) Consumer Sovereignty and Human Interests , pp. 13-14
    • Penz, G.P.1
  • 287
    • 0008111966 scopus 로고
    • The concept of consumers sovereignty
    • 66 (defining "consumer sovereignty" as "the controlling power exercised by free individuals, in choosing between ends, over the custodians of the community's resources, when the resources by which those ends can be served are scarce")
    • W.H. Hutt, The Concept of Consumers' Sovereignty, 50 ECON. J. 66,66 (1940) (defining "consumer sovereignty" as "the controlling power exercised by free individuals, in choosing between ends, over the custodians of the community's resources, when the resources by which those ends can be served are scarce");
    • (1940) Econ. J. , vol.50 , pp. 66
    • Hutt, W.H.1
  • 288
    • 0008019507 scopus 로고
    • Consumer sovereignty
    • 184
    • Joseph Persky, Consumer Sovereignty, 7 J. ECON. PERSP. 183, 184 (1993).
    • (1993) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.7 , pp. 183
    • Persky, J.1
  • 289
    • 79551521126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Averitt & Lande, supra note 135, at 716 ("The concept of consumer sovereignty goes so far as to embody at least some implicit notions about the proper relationship between the individual and the state. It is part of the Western world's answers to the prescriptions of Marxism.")
    • Averitt & Lande, supra note 135, at 716 ("The concept of consumer sovereignty goes so far as to embody at least some implicit notions about the proper relationship between the individual and the state. It is part of the Western world's answers to the prescriptions of Marxism.").
  • 290
    • 33745313973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The dark side of choice: When choice impairs social welfare
    • 25-26 (discussing theoretical connections between the benefits of choice and rational choice theory)
    • See Simona Borti & Sheena S. Iyenger, The Dark Side of Choice: When Choice Impairs Social Welfare, 25 J. PUB. POL'Y & MARKETING 24, 25-26 (2006) (discussing theoretical connections between the benefits of choice and rational choice theory).
    • (2006) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.25 , pp. 24
    • Borti, S.1    Iyenger, S.S.2
  • 291
    • 31544453873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does consumer irrationality trump consumer sovereignty?
    • 691
    • Joel Waldfogel, Does Consumer Irrationality Trump Consumer Sovereignty?, 87 REV. ECON. & STAT. 691,691 (2005).
    • (2005) Rev. Econ. & Stat. , vol.87 , pp. 691
    • Waldfogel, J.1
  • 292
    • 79551524331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The early years of the Reagan presidency were heady times for those sympathetic to the Chicago school law and economics movement. The academic leader of the movement, Richard Posner, was appointed to the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit, along with another prominent law and economics scholar, Frank Easterbrook
    • The early years of the Reagan presidency were heady times for those sympathetic to the Chicago school law and economics movement. The academic leader of the movement, Richard Posner, was appointed to the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit, along with another prominent law and economics scholar, Frank Easterbrook.
  • 293
    • 0004257004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clarendon Press 1995. In addition, Reagan issued Exec. Order No. 12,291, which mandated cost-benefit analysis in administrative rulemaking. Exec. Order No. 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193 (Feb. 19, 1981) ("Regulatory action shall not be undertaken unless the potential benefits to society for the regulation outweigh the potential costs to society."). Exec. Order No. 12,291 did not technically apply to the FTC, since the FTC is an independent agency
    • See NEIL DUXBURY, PATTERNS OF AMERICAN JURISPRUDENCE 358 (Clarendon Press 1995). In addition, Reagan issued Exec. Order No. 12,291, which mandated cost-benefit analysis in administrative rulemaking. Exec. Order No. 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193 (Feb. 19, 1981) ("Regulatory action shall not be undertaken unless the potential benefits to society for the regulation outweigh the potential costs to society."). Exec. Order No. 12,291 did not technically apply to the FTC, since the FTC is an independent agency.
    • Patterns of American Jurisprudence , pp. 358
    • Duxbury, N.1
  • 294
    • 0347664773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential administration
    • 2277-78
    • See Elena Kagan, Presidential Administration, 114 HARV. L. REV. 2245, 2277-78 (2001);
    • (2001) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.114 , pp. 2245
    • Kagan, E.1
  • 295
    • 26444488260 scopus 로고
    • Presidential coordination of the independent regulatory process
    • 494-97
    • Angel Manuel Moreno, Presidential Coordination of the Independent Regulatory Process, 8 ADMIN. L.J. AM. U. 461, 494-97 (1994).
    • (1994) Admin. L.J. Am. U. , vol.8 , pp. 461
    • Moreno, A.M.1
  • 296
    • 0012072114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The language of law and the language of business
    • 303 noting that Miller, who was "an economist sympathetic to Chicago school economics . . . was the first economist to serve on the Commission itself and the first non-lawyer in thirty years
    • See Spencer Weber Waller, The Language of Law and the Language of Business, 52 CASE W. RES. L. REV. 283, 303 n.86 (2001) (noting that Miller, who was "an economist sympathetic to Chicago school economics . . . was the first economist to serve on the Commission itself and the first non-lawyer in thirty years"
    • (2001) Case W. Res. L. Rev. , vol.52 , Issue.86 , pp. 283
    • Waller, S.W.1
  • 298
    • 79551564871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CLARKSON & MURIS, supra note 99
    • See CLARKSON & MURIS, supra note 99.
  • 299
    • 79551534094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MEIER & GARMAN, supra note 99, at 118 ("Miller recruited numerous economists to the FTC so that he could rely on others with similar views to implement policy. Included among the personnel was Timothy J. Muris, a longtime FTC critic, to head the Bureau of Consumer Protection.") (internal citation omitted); Budnitz, supra note 104, at 383
    • See MEIER & GARMAN, supra note 99, at 118 ("Miller recruited numerous economists to the FTC so that he could rely on others with similar views to implement policy. Included among the personnel was Timothy J. Muris, a longtime FTC critic, to head the Bureau of Consumer Protection.") (internal citation omitted); Budnitz, supra note 104, at 383;
  • 300
    • 79551539830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Looking back on the muris years in consumer protection: An interview with Timothy J. Muris
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 962 (observing that two of Miller's top policy appointees had doctorates in economics and that Timothy Muris, his Director of the Bureau of Consumer Protection, was a lawyer whose work drew on economic theory). Muris later became Chairman of the Federal Trade Commission under President [hereinafter Muris Interview]
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93, at 962 (observing that two of Miller's top policy appointees had doctorates in economics and that Timothy Muris, his Director of the Bureau of Consumer Protection, was a lawyer whose work drew on economic theory). Muris later became Chairman of the Federal Trade Commission under President George W. Bush. See Looking Back on the Muris Years in Consumer Protection: An Interview with Timothy J. Muris, 18 ANTITRUST 9 (2004) [hereinafter Muris Interview].
    • (2004) Antitrust , vol.18 , pp. 9
    • Bush, G.W.1
  • 301
    • 9344236751 scopus 로고
    • Budnitz, supra note 104, at 377-81 (discussing Miller's approach and his confirmation testimony). Miller discusses his tenure at the FTC and the Reagan administration's regulatory philosophy in
    • See Budnitz, supra note 104, at 377-81 (discussing Miller's approach and his confirmation testimony). Miller discusses his tenure at the FTC and the Reagan administration's regulatory philosophy in JAMES C. MILLER III, THE ECONOMIST AS REFORMER: REVAMPING THE FTC, 1981-1985 (1989).
    • (1989) The Economist as Reformer: Revamping the Ftc , pp. 1981-1985
    • Miller III, J.C.1
  • 302
    • 79551545919 scopus 로고
    • HI to Hon. John D. Dingell (Sept. 21, 1984), Comm. Print [hereinafter FTC Review] (asserting that it was "very difficult . . . to make headway when someone in authority sees his role as resident saboteur"). For a scholarly treatment of the Miller years at the FTC
    • Letter from James C. Miller HI to Hon. John D. Dingell (Sept. 21, 1984), in FTC REVIEW (1977-84): A REPORT PREPARED FOR THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON OVERSIGHT AND INVESTIGATIONS OF THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON ENERGY AND COMMERCE 273 (Comm. Print 1984) [hereinafter FTC Review] (asserting that it was "very difficult . . . to make headway when someone in authority sees his role as resident saboteur"). For a scholarly treatment of the Miller years at the FTC,
    • (1984) FTC Review (1977-84): A Report Prepared for the Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations of the House Committee on Energy and Commerce , pp. 273
    • Miller, J.C.1
  • 303
    • 79551518177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Budnitz, supra note 104
    • see Budnitz, supra note 104.
  • 304
    • 79551535201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC REVIEW, supra note 144, at 242
    • See FTC REVIEW, supra note 144, at 242.
  • 305
    • 79551546681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 275394, 280 (criticizing Pertschuk's report as consisting of "errors, mischaracterizations, and outright lies")
    • See id. at 275-394, 280 (criticizing Pertschuk's report as consisting of "errors, mischaracterizations, and outright lies").
  • 306
    • 79551521464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 280
    • Id. at 280.
  • 307
    • 79551534096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rule was initially proposed in 1975. See Credit Practices Rule, 40 Fed. Reg. 16,347-50 (Apr. 11, 1975) (codified at 16 C.F.R. pt 444)
    • The rule was initially proposed in 1975. See Credit Practices Rule, 40 Fed. Reg. 16,347-50 (Apr. 11, 1975) (codified at 16 C.F.R. pt 444);
  • 308
    • 79551524668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93
    • MacLeod et al., supra note 93;
  • 309
    • 79551515464 scopus 로고
    • F.2d 962-63 D.C. Cir. (reviewing the history of Credit Practices rulemaking)
    • see also Am. Fin. Servs. Ass'n v. FTC, 767 F.2d 957, 962-63 (D.C. Cir. 1985) (reviewing the history of Credit Practices rulemaking);
    • (1985) Am. Fin. Servs. Ass'n V. FTC , vol.767 , pp. 957
  • 310
    • 79551523717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Braucher, Defining Unfairness, supra note 77, at 412-13 (describing the history and content of the Credit Practices Rule)
    • Braucher, Defining Unfairness, supra note 77, at 412-13 (describing the history and content of the Credit Practices Rule).
  • 311
    • 79551527637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Am. Fin. Servs. Ass'n, 767 F.2d at 963 ("On July 20, 1983, the Commission tentatively adopted, by unanimous vote, the revised proposed rule. The final rule was published on March 1, 1984, to become effective March 1, 1985." (citing Credit Practices Rule, 49 Fed. Reg. 7740 (Mar. 1,1984) (codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 444))). Although the vote was unanimous, Commissioner Pertschuk suggested that the two conservative members of the Commission, Chairman Miller and Commissioner Carol Crawford, vote in favor of the proposed rule despite their opposition because they faced defeat. See Pertschuk Report, in FTC Review, supra note 144, at 160-61 (describing the initial opposition to the rule that ultimately led to the unanimous vote of the commissioners)
    • See Am. Fin. Servs. Ass'n, 767 F.2d at 963 ("On July 20, 1983, the Commission tentatively adopted, by unanimous vote, the revised proposed rule. The final rule was published on March 1, 1984, to become effective March 1, 1985." (citing Credit Practices Rule, 49 Fed. Reg. 7740 (Mar. 1,1984) (codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 444))). Although the vote was unanimous, Commissioner Pertschuk suggested that the two conservative members of the Commission, Chairman Miller and Commissioner Carol Crawford, vote in favor of the proposed rule despite their opposition because they faced defeat. See Pertschuk Report, in FTC Review, supra note 144, at 160-61 (describing the initial opposition to the rule that ultimately led to the unanimous vote of the commissioners).
  • 312
    • 79551517263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 16 C.F.R. § 444.1-444.4 (2007) (banning certain practices in connection with consumer credit contracts); see also 16 C.F.R. §444.5 (state exemptions to Credit Practices Rule). For background of the Credit Practices Rule
    • See 16 C.F.R. § 444.1-444.4 (2007) (banning certain practices in connection with consumer credit contracts); see also 16 C.F.R. §444.5 (state exemptions to Credit Practices Rule). For background of the Credit Practices Rule,
  • 313
    • 79551517830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see PRIDGEN, supra note 6, §9:20, at 710-13
    • see PRIDGEN, supra note 6, §9:20, at 710-13;
  • 314
    • 79551513587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHELDON & CARTER, supra note 6, §5.1.3.1, at 278-79
    • SHELDON & CARTER, supra note 6, §5.1.3.1, at 278-79.
  • 315
    • 79551534095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 16 C.F.R. § 444.2(a), (a)(1) (deeming it an unfair act or practice for a lender or retail installment seller "to take or receive from a consumer an obligation that . . . constitutes or contains a cognovit or confession of judgment . . . or other waiver of the right to notice and the opportunity to be heard in the event of suit")
    • See 16 C.F.R. § 444.2(a), (a)(1) (deeming it an unfair act or practice for a lender or retail installment seller "to take or receive from a consumer an obligation that . . . [constitutes or contains a cognovit or confession of judgment . . . or other waiver of the right to notice and the opportunity to be heard in the event of suit").
  • 316
    • 79551508917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 444.2(a), (a)(2) (deeming it an unfair act or practice for a lender or retail installment seller "to take or receive from a consumer an obligation that . . . constitutes or contains an executory waiver or a limitation of exemption from attachment, execution, or other process on real or personal property held, owned by, or due to the consumer" with the exception of "a security interest executed in connection with the obligation")
    • See id. § 444.2(a), (a)(2) (deeming it an unfair act or practice for a lender or retail installment seller "to take or receive from a consumer an obligation that . . . [constitutes or contains an executory waiver or a limitation of exemption from attachment, execution, or other process on real or personal property held, owned by, or due to the consumer" with the exception of "a security interest executed in connection with the obligation").
  • 317
    • 79551569197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 444.2(a), (a)(3) (deeming it an unfair act or practice for a lender or retail installment seller "to take or receive from a consumer an obligation that . . . constitutes or contains an assignment of wages or other earnings," with certain exceptions)
    • See id. § 444.2(a), (a)(3) (deeming it an unfair act or practice for a lender or retail installment seller "to take or receive from a consumer an obligation that . . . [constitutes or contains an assignment of wages or other earnings," with certain exceptions);
  • 318
    • 79551515809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 444.2(a)(3)(i)-(iii) (listing exceptions to the prohibition on wage assignments)
    • see also id. § 444.2(a)(3)(i)-(iii) (listing exceptions to the prohibition on wage assignments).
  • 319
    • 79551508918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 444.2(a), (a)(4) (deeming it an unfair act or practice "to take or receive from a consumer an obligation that . . . constitutes or contains a nonpossessory security interest in household goods other than a purchase money security interest")
    • See id. § 444.2(a), (a)(4) (deeming it an unfair act or practice "to take or receive from a consumer an obligation that . . . [constitutes or contains a nonpossessory security interest in household goods other than a purchase money security interest").
  • 320
    • 79551560946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 444.4(a) (deeming it an unfair act or practice for a creditor to levy "any delinquency charge on a payment, which payment is otherwise a full payment for the applicable period and is paid on its due date or within an applicable grace period, when the only delinquency is attributable to late fee(s) or delinquency charge(s) assessed on earlier installment(s))
    • Id. § 444.4(a) (deeming it an unfair act or practice for a creditor to levy "any delinquency charge on a payment, which payment is otherwise a full payment for the applicable period and is paid on its due date or within an applicable grace period, when the only delinquency is attributable to late fee(s) or delinquency charge(s) assessed on earlier installment(s)").
  • 321
    • 79551527270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Braucher, Defining Unfairness, supra note 77, at 414 n.311 (explaining pyramiding); PRIDGEN, supra note 6, § 9:20, at 712 (defining pyramiding" as "any method of accounting that results in the assessment of multiple late charges based on a single late payment")
    • See Braucher, Defining Unfairness, supra note 77, at 414 n.311 (explaining pyramiding); PRIDGEN, supra note 6, § 9:20, at 712 (defining "pyramiding" as "any method of accounting that results in the assessment of multiple late charges based on a single late payment");
  • 322
    • 79551549694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHELDON & CARTER, supra note 6, §5.1.3.1, at 278-79
    • SHELDON & CARTER, supra note 6, §5.1.3.1, at 278-79.
  • 323
    • 79551558078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 16 C.F.R. § 444.3(a)(2) (deeming it an unfair act or practice for a "lender or retail installment seller . . . to obligate a cosigner unless the cosigner is informed prior to becoming obligated . . . of the nature of his or her liability as cosigner")
    • See 16 C.F.R. § 444.3(a)(2) (deeming it an unfair act or practice for a "lender or retail installment seller . . . to obligate a cosigner unless the cosigner is informed prior to becoming obligated . . . of the nature of his or her liability as cosigner");
  • 324
    • 79551540199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 444.3(c) (mandating the form of notice disclosing the obligation of liability to a cosigner)
    • id. § 444.3(c) (mandating the form of notice disclosing the obligation of liability to a cosigner);
  • 325
    • 79551528011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 444.3(a)(1) (deeming it a deceptive act or practice "for a lender or retail installment seller . . . to misrepresent the nature or extent of cosigner liability to any person")
    • see also id. § 444.3(a)(1) (deeming it a deceptive act or practice "for a lender or retail installment seller . . . to misrepresent the nature or extent of cosigner liability to any person").
  • 326
    • 79551547394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Credit Practices Rule: Statement of Basis and Purpose and Regulatory Analysis, 49 Fed. Reg. 7740 (Mar. 1, 1984) (describing the purpose and legal basis of the rule)
    • See Credit Practices Rule: Statement of Basis and Purpose and Regulatory Analysis, 49 Fed. Reg. 7740 (Mar. 1, 1984) (describing the purpose and legal basis of the rule);
  • 327
    • 79551573842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beales, supra note 77, at 194-95 (indicating that market imperfections led to consumer injuries)
    • see also Beales, supra note 77, at 194-95 (indicating that market imperfections led to consumer injuries);
  • 328
    • 79551562576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Braucher, Defining Unfairness, supra note 77, at 418-21 (reviewing evidence of market failure for consumer credit remedies)
    • Braucher, Defining Unfairness, supra note 77, at 418-21 (reviewing evidence of market failure for consumer credit remedies);
  • 329
    • 79551513958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 418 ("The FTC's two fundamental questions can be summed up as follows: (1) does use of a practice result from market failure; and (2) would prohibiting the practice result in a net benefit?")
    • id. at 418 ("The FTC's two fundamental questions can be summed up as follows: (1) does use of a practice result from market failure; and (2) would prohibiting the practice result in a net benefit?").
  • 330
    • 79551557195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PRIDGEN, supra note 6, § 9:20, at 713
    • PRIDGEN, supra note 6, § 9:20, at 713.
  • 331
    • 79551515464 scopus 로고
    • F.2d D.C. Cir.
    • Am. Fin. Servs. Ass'n v. FTC, 767 F.2d 957 (D.C. Cir. 1985).
    • (1985) Am. Fin. Servs. Ass'n V. FTC , vol.767 , pp. 957
  • 332
    • 79551573494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 962 (finding that the rule was justified)
    • See id. at 962 (finding that the rule was justified).
  • 333
    • 79551549693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 991 (Tamm, J., dissenting) (arguing that the FTC's decision exceeded its statutory authority and that the rule was not justified)
    • See id. at 991 (Tamm, J., dissenting) (arguing that the FTC's decision exceeded its statutory authority and that the rule was not justified).
  • 334
    • 79551553807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of the economic and empirical research
    • For an overview of the economic and empirical research,
  • 335
    • 0041418502 scopus 로고
    • The political economy of consumer credit regulation
    • see Peter V. Letsou, The Political Economy of Consumer Credit Regulation, 44 EMORY L.J. 587 (1995);
    • (1995) Emory L.J. , vol.44 , pp. 587
    • Letsou, P.V.1
  • 336
    • 84934452638 scopus 로고
    • Benefits and costs of legal restrictions on personal loan markets
    • see also James R. Barth et al., Benefits and Costs of Legal Restrictions on Personal Loan Markets, 29 J.L. & ECON. 357 (1986);
    • (1986) J.L. & Econ. , vol.29 , pp. 357
    • Barth, J.R.1
  • 337
    • 79551522609 scopus 로고
    • Mr. Micawber Revisited: A critique of the credit practices rule
    • Peter M. Juzwiak, Mr. Micawber Revisited: A Critique of the Credit Practices Rule, 64 S. CAL. L. REV. 417 (1991);
    • (1991) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.64 , pp. 417
    • Juzwiak, P.M.1
  • 338
    • 84929063825 scopus 로고
    • Rethinking the regulation of coercive creditor remedies
    • Robert E. Scott, Rethinking the Regulation of Coercive Creditor Remedies, 89 COLUM. L. REV. 730 (1989);
    • (1989) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 730
    • Scott, R.E.1
  • 339
    • 38249021232 scopus 로고
    • Regulation of creditor practices: An evaluation of the FTC's credit practice rule
    • Daniel J. Villegas, Regulation of Creditor Practices: An Evaluation of the FTC's Credit Practice Rule, 42 J. ECON. & Bus. 51(1990);
    • (1990) J. Econ. & Bus. , vol.42 , pp. 51
    • Villegas, D.J.1
  • 340
    • 53249148764 scopus 로고
    • The appropriate role of security interests in consumer transactions
    • William C. Whitford, The Appropriate Role of Security Interests in Consumer Transactions, 7 CARDOZO L. REV. 959 (1986).
    • (1986) Cardozo L. Rev. , vol.7 , pp. 959
    • Whitford, W.C.1
  • 341
    • 79551506533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 45(n) (2000) (providing that the Commission has no authority to declare unlawful acts or practices on the basis of unfairness "unless the act or practice causes or is likely to cause substantial injury to consumers which is not reasonably avoidable by consumers themselves and not outweighed by countervailing benefits to consumers or to competition")
    • See 15 U.S.C. § 45(n) (2000) (providing that the Commission has no authority to declare unlawful acts or practices on the basis of unfairness "unless the act or practice causes or is likely to cause substantial injury to consumers which is not reasonably avoidable by consumers themselves and not outweighed by countervailing benefits to consumers or to competition").
  • 342
    • 79551520633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. (permitting considerations of public policy along with other evidence, but not allowing them to serve as a primary basis in determining whether an act or practice is unfair)
    • See id. (permitting considerations of public policy along with other evidence, but not allowing them to serve as a primary basis in determining whether an act or practice is unfair).
  • 343
    • 79551544570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State consumer laws that protect against unfair practices are beyond the scope of this Article. I would note, however, that the FTC Act serves both formally and informally as a model for state consumer protection laws
    • State consumer laws that protect against unfair practices are beyond the scope of this Article. I would note, however, that the FTC Act serves both formally and informally as a model for state consumer protection laws.
  • 344
    • 79551539330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • generally Greenfield, supra note 125 (describing the impact of the FTC's rules on states). At the same time, many states have not adopted the newer approach to unfairness embodied in the Unfairness Policy Statement and the revision of the FTC Act, but instead have continued to use the arguably more liberal Cigarette Rule
    • See generally Greenfield, supra note 125 (describing the impact of the FTC's rules on states). At the same time, many states have not adopted the newer approach to unfairness embodied in the Unfairness Policy Statement and the revision of the FTC Act, but instead have continued to use the arguably more liberal Cigarette Rule.
  • 345
    • 79551521125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The law, marketing and behavioral economics of consumer rebates
    • 404 [hereinafter Edwards, Consumer Rebates] (indicating that "most states" have not adopted the FTC's definition of unfairness)
    • See Matthew A. Edwards, The Law, Marketing and Behavioral Economics of Consumer Rebates, 12 STAN. J.L. Bus. & FIN. 362, 404 n.223 (2007) [hereinafter Edwards, Consumer Rebates] (indicating that "most states" have not adopted the FTC's definition of unfairness).
    • (2007) Stan. J.L. Bus. & Fin. , vol.12 , Issue.223 , pp. 362
    • Edwards, M.A.1
  • 346
    • 79551565576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beales, supra note 77, at 195
    • See Beales, supra note 77, at 195.
  • 347
    • 79551526094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 197-200 (citing instances in which the FTC utilized its unfairness authority)
    • See id. at 197-200 (citing instances in which the FTC utilized its unfairness authority);
  • 348
    • 79551519590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Diomande, supra note 77, at 54 (discussing the expanded use of the FTC's unfairness authority in the 1990s)
    • Diomande, supra note 77, at 54 (discussing the expanded use of the FTC's unfairness authority in the 1990s);
  • 349
    • 79551521463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Panel probes revival of unfairness doctrine in FTC or states' consumer protection cases
    • 352-53 Apr. 9, [hereinafter Revival of Unfairness] (summarizing the Consumer Protection Committee program at the 52nd Annual Spring Meeting of the American Bar Association's Section of Antitrust Law in Washington, D.C.)
    • Panel Probes Revival of Unfairness Doctrine in FTC or States' Consumer Protection Cases, 86 ANTITRUST & TRADE REG. REP. (BNA) 352, 352-53 (Apr. 9, 2004) [hereinafter Revival of Unfairness] (summarizing the Consumer Protection Committee program at the 52nd Annual Spring Meeting of the American Bar Association's Section of Antitrust Law in Washington, D.C.).
    • (2004) Antitrust & Trade Reg. Rep. (Bna) , vol.86 , pp. 352
  • 350
    • 79551563989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • No. 1:96-CV-615F, WL 33642380, at *2 (N.D. Ga. Sept. 30, 1997) (unpublished) (enjoining a company from marketing based on findings of its participation in false, deceptive, misleading, and unfair marketing and banking practices)
    • See FTC v. Winward Mktg, Ltd., No. 1:96-CV-615F, 1997 WL 33642380, at *2 (N.D. Ga. Sept. 30, 1997) (unpublished) (enjoining a company from marketing based on findings of its participation in false, deceptive, misleading, and unfair marketing and banking practices).
    • (1997) FTC V. Winward Mktg, Ltd.
  • 351
    • 79551530274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • F. Supp. 2d 498-99 S.D.N.Y. (holding that the "defendants' practice of billing line subscribers for Internet services that they neither used, nor authorized use of, constituted an unfair trade practice in violation of Section 5(a) of the FTC Act"), aff'd in part and vacated in part, 443 F.3d 48 (2d Cir. 2006)
    • See FTC v. Verity Infi, Ltd., 335 F. Supp. 2d 479, 498-99 (S.D.N.Y. 2004) (holding that the "defendants' practice of billing line subscribers for Internet services that they neither used, nor authorized use of, constituted an unfair trade practice in violation of Section 5(a) of the FTC Act"), aff'd in part and vacated in part, 443 F.3d 48 (2d Cir. 2006).
    • (2004) FTC V. Verity Infi, Ltd. , vol.335 , pp. 479
  • 352
    • 79551556460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • No. 03-C-2540, WL 1175047, at *2 (N.D. Ill. Mar. 4, 2004) (unpublished) (defining spoofing as the practice of disguising an e-mail to make the e-mail appear to come from an address from which it did not originate)
    • See FTC v. Westby, No. 03-C-2540, 2004 WL 1175047, at *2 (N.D. Ill. Mar. 4, 2004) (unpublished) (defining spoofing as the practice of disguising an e-mail to make the e-mail appear to come from an address from which it did not originate);
    • (2004) FTC V. Westby
  • 353
    • 79551556460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Amended Complaint for Injunctive and Other Equitable Relief, No. 03-C-2540, WL 1175047, at *3 (N.D. Ill. Mar. 4, 2004), (defining spoofing)
    • see also Amended Complaint for Injunctive and Other Equitable Relief, FTC v. Westby, No. 03-C-2540, 2004 WL 1175047, at *3 (N.D. Ill. Mar. 4, 2004), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/09/marriedcomp.pdf (defining spoofing).
    • (2004) FTC V. Westby
  • 354
    • 39049105064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • First do no harm: The problem of spyware
    • 1465-66 (discussing the FT'Cs response to spyware)
    • See generally Susan P. Crawford, First Do No Harm: The Problem of Spyware, 20 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 1433, 1465-66 (2005) (discussing the FT'Cs response to spyware);
    • (2005) Berkeley Tech. L.J. , vol.20 , pp. 1433
    • Crawford, S.P.1
  • 355
    • 79551522836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • No. 04-377-JD, U.S. Dist. LEXIS 22788, at *15-16 (D.N.H. Oct. 21, 2004) (finding that the public's interest in preventing unauthorized access to consumers' computers by an internet marketing company to be of grave concern)
    • see also FTC v. Seismic Entm't Prods., Inc., No. 04-377-JD, 2004 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 22788, at *15-16 (D.N.H. Oct. 21, 2004) (finding that the public's interest in preventing unauthorized access to consumers' computers by an internet marketing company to be of grave concern).
    • (2004) FTC V. Seismic Entm't Prods., Inc.
  • 356
    • 79551529100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Diomande, supra note 77, at 54 (referring to "mousetrapping" as "the misuse of pop-up windows to post advertisements on the Internet")
    • See Diomande, supra note 77, at 54 (referring to " mousetrapping" as "the misuse of pop-up windows to post advertisements on the Internet");
  • 357
    • 79551567053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Complaint for Permanent Injunction and Other Equitable Relief ¶ No. 01-CV-4854, WL 34131412 (E.D. Pa. Apr. 9, 2002) (explaining that when consumers attempted to close a browser window, they found "themselves in yet another new window and viewing yet another of Defendant's advertisements-a practice commonly referred to as 'mousetrapping'"). Although the final court order did not use the term mousetrapping, it did describe the underlying conduct
    • Complaint for Permanent Injunction and Other Equitable Relief ¶ 26, FTC v. Zuccarini, No. 01-CV-4854, 2001 WL 34131412 (E.D. Pa. Apr. 9, 2002) (explaining that when consumers attempted to close a browser window, they found "themselves in yet another new window and viewing yet another of Defendant's advertisements-a practice commonly referred to as 'mousetrapping'"). Although the final court order did not use the term "mousetrapping," it did describe the underlying conduct.
    • (2001) FTC V. Zuccarini , vol.26
  • 358
    • 79551518176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • No. 01-CV-4854, 2002 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 13324, at *3 E.D. Pa. Apr. 9
    • See FTC v. Zuccarini, No. 01-CV-4854, 2002 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 13324, at *3 (E.D. Pa. Apr. 9, 2002).
    • (2002) FTC V. Zuccarini
  • 359
    • 0842334737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Literacy and contract
    • 259 ("The FTC has not issued a substantive consumer-contract regulation since the 1984 Credit Practices Rule. Recent rules tend to emphasize disclosures or the avoidance of misrepresentations and to regulate abusive conduct, rather than regulating substantive terms.")
    • See Alan M. White & Cathy Lesser Mansfield, Literacy and Contract, 13 STAN. L. & POL'Y REV. 233, 259 (2002) ("The FTC has not issued a substantive consumer-contract regulation since the 1984 Credit Practices Rule. Recent rules tend to emphasize disclosures or the avoidance of misrepresentations and to regulate abusive conduct, rather than regulating substantive terms.").
    • (2002) Stan. L. & Pol'y Rev. , vol.13 , pp. 233
    • White, A.M.1    Mansfield, C.L.2
  • 360
    • 79551570288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PRIDGEN, supra note 6, § 12:13, at 1004-05 (citing the rulemaking in response to the Telephone and Dispute Resolution Act of 1992, the Telemarketing Act in 1994, the Comprehensive National Energy Policy Act of 1992, and amendments to the Fair Packaging and Labeling Act)
    • See PRIDGEN, supra note 6, § 12:13, at 1004-05 (citing the rulemaking in response to the Telephone and Dispute Resolution Act of 1992, the Telemarketing Act in 1994, the Comprehensive National Energy Policy Act of 1992, and amendments to the Fair Packaging and Labeling Act).
  • 361
    • 79551555380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The FTC Funeral Industry Practices Rule, which became effective in 1984, is one exception. See PRIDGEN, supra note 6, §9:14, at 590-91 (discussing 16 C.F.R. §453.2 (1985)). For an economic analysis of die FTC Funeral Rule
    • The FTC Funeral Industry Practices Rule, which became effective in 1984, is one exception. See PRIDGEN, supra note 6, §9:14, at 590-91 (discussing 16 C.F.R. §453.2 (1985)). For an economic analysis of die FTC Funeral Rule,
  • 362
    • 84929229941 scopus 로고
    • Consumer ignorance and consumer protection law: Empirical evidence from the FTC funeral rule
    • see Fred S. McChesney, Consumer Ignorance and Consumer Protection Law: Empirical Evidence from the FTC Funeral Rule, 7 J. L. & POL. 1 (1990).
    • (1990) J. L. & Pol. , vol.7 , pp. 1
    • McChesney, F.S.1
  • 363
    • 79551525377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The do-not-call registry and its overwhelming support: This time congress really means it
    • 16 C.F.R. § 310 (2007). For discussions of the administrative and legislative history of the Do Not Call Registry, see
    • See 16 C.F.R. § 310 (2007). For discussions of the administrative and legislative history of the Do Not Call Registry, see Joseph Dean Findley, The Do-Not-Call Registry and Its Overwhelming Support: This Time Congress Really Means It, 5 WYO. L. REV. 605 (2005);
    • (2005) Wyo. L. Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 605
    • Findley, J.D.1
  • 364
    • 85055307710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Telemarketing regulation and the commercial speech doctrine
    • R. Michael Hoefges, Telemarketing Regulation and the Commercial Speech Doctrine, 32 J. LEGIS. 50 (2005);
    • (2005) J. Legis. , vol.32 , pp. 50
    • Hoefges, R.M.1
  • 365
    • 39649120697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The do-not-call implementation act: Legislating the sound of silence
    • Douglas C. Nelson, The Do-Not-Call Implementation Act: Legislating the Sound of Silence, 16 LOY. CONSUMER L. REV. 63 (2003).
    • (2003) Loy. Consumer L. Rev. , vol.16 , pp. 63
    • Nelson, D.C.1
  • 366
    • 79551506532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. §6101(2000)
    • 15 U.S.C. §6101(2000).
  • 367
    • 79551534473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • F. Supp. 2d 1294 W.D. Okla. (holding that the FTC lacked authority to create the Do-Not-Call Registry)
    • See U.S. Security v. FTC, 282 F. Supp. 2d 1285, 1294 (W.D. Okla. 2003) (holding that the FTC lacked authority to create the Do-Not-Call Registry),
    • (2003) U.S. Security V. FTC , vol.282 , pp. 1285
  • 368
    • 84922674569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • F.3d 1251 10th Cir. cert. denied, 543 U.S. 812 (2004)
    • rev'd sub nom. Mainstream Mktg. Servs., Inc. v. FTC, 358 F.3d 1228, 1251 (10th Cir. 2004), cert. denied, 543 U.S. 812 (2004).
    • (2004) Mainstream Mktg. Servs., Inc. V. FTC , vol.358 , pp. 1228
  • 369
    • 79551530677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Act to Ratify the Authority of the Federal Trade Commission to Establish a DoNot-Call Registry, Pub. L. No. 10882, 117 Stat. 1006 (2003) (codified at 15 U.S.C. § 6102 (Supp. V 2005))
    • See Act to Ratify the Authority of the Federal Trade Commission to Establish a DoNot-Call Registry, Pub. L. No. 108-82, 117 Stat. 1006 (2003) (codified at 15 U.S.C. § 6102 (Supp. V 2005)).
  • 370
    • 79551559150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Regulation Rule Pursuant to the Telephone Disclosure and Dispute Resolution Act of 1992,16 C.F.R. pt. 308 (2004)
    • Trade Regulation Rule Pursuant to the Telephone Disclosure and Dispute Resolution Act of 1992,16 C.F.R. pt. 308 (2004).
  • 371
    • 79551517262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Children's Online Privacy Protection Rule, 16 C.F.R. pt. 312 (2004)
    • Children's Online Privacy Protection Rule, 16 C.F.R. pt. 312 (2004).
  • 372
    • 79551525735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Telephone Disclosure and Dispute Resolution Act, Pub. L. No. 102-556, 106 Stat. 4181 (1992) (codified in pertinent part at 15 U.S.C. §§ 5711-5724 (2000)); Children's Online Privacy Protection Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 6501-6506 (2000)
    • Telephone Disclosure and Dispute Resolution Act, Pub. L. No. 102-556, 106 Stat. 4181 (1992) (codified in pertinent part at 15 U.S.C. §§ 5711-5724 (2000)); Children's Online Privacy Protection Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 6501-6506 (2000).
  • 373
    • 79551562575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In a piece published in 2000, Stephen Calkins made the following observation about the congressional codification of the FTC Unfairness Statement: The Supreme Court has not spoken. No new court of appeals has weighed in. No opinion of the Commission addresses FTC Act Section 5(n). The Commission has not based any new Trade Regulation Rule on the unfairness authority. New initiatives and new thinking are reflected only in consent orders and complaints (a couple of which have led to District Court decisions). In part due to the dearth of binding precedent, the law of FTC unfairness remains indeterminate. Calkins, supra note 77, at 1960 (citations omitted)
    • In a piece published in 2000, Stephen Calkins made the following observation about the congressional codification of the FTC Unfairness Statement: The Supreme Court has not spoken. No new court of appeals has weighed in. No opinion of the Commission addresses FTC Act Section 5(n). The Commission has not based any new Trade Regulation Rule on the unfairness authority. New initiatives and new thinking are reflected only in consent orders and complaints (a couple of which have led to District Court decisions). In part due to the dearth of binding precedent, the law of FTC unfairness remains indeterminate. Calkins, supra note 77, at 1960 (citations omitted);
  • 374
    • 79551566305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 163-64 and accompanying text (discussing adoption of FTC Act §5(n))
    • see also supra notes 163-64 and accompanying text (discussing adoption of FTC Act §5(n)).
  • 375
    • 79551517621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I
    • See supra Part I.
  • 376
    • 79551522222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra Part I
    • See supra Part I.
  • 377
    • 79551558077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Muris Interview, supra note 142, at 10 ("There really was a Reagan Revolution in antitrust and consumer protection. As I like to say, my side won.")
    • See Muris Interview, supra note 142, at 10 ("There really was a Reagan Revolution in antitrust and consumer protection. As I like to say, my side won.").
  • 378
    • 79551568732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 379
    • 79551545921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 163-64 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 163-64 and accompanying text.
  • 380
    • 24144490851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • More than law enforcement: The FTC 's many tools - A conversation with tim muris and bob pitofsky
    • (detailing the nonlitigation role of the FTC)
    • See generally Symposium, More Than Law Enforcement: The FTC 's Many Tools-A Conversation with Tim Muris and Bob Pitofsky, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 773 (2005) (detailing the nonlitigation role of the FTC).
    • (2005) Antitrust L.J. , vol.72 , pp. 773
  • 381
    • 17244369300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Past, present, and future of antitrust enforcement at the federal trade commission
    • 213-14 (citations omitted)
    • Robert Pitofsky, Past, Present, and Future of Antitrust Enforcement at the Federal Trade Commission, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 209,213-14 (2005) (citations omitted).
    • (2005) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 209
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 382
    • 17244382093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Principles for a successful competition agency
    • 176
    • Timothy Muris, Principles for a Successful Competition Agency, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 165, 176 (2005).
    • (2005) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 165
    • Muris, T.1
  • 383
    • 36649023134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economics at the FTC: Pharmaceutical patents dispute settlements and behavioral economics
    • 85 The mission of the FTC's Bureau of Economics is outlined at
    • Michael A. Salinger, Pauline M. Ippolito & Joel L. Schrag, Economics at the FTC: Pharmaceutical Patents Dispute Settlements and Behavioral Economics, 31 REV. INDUS. ORG. 85, 85 (2007). The mission of the FTC's Bureau of Economics is outlined at http://www.ftc.gov/be/about.shtm (last visited Apr. 24, 2008).
    • (2007) Rev. Indus. Org. , vol.31 , pp. 85
    • Salinger, M.A.1    Ippolito, P.M.2    Schrag, J.L.3
  • 384
    • 79551556845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For more information, see (last visited Apr. 29, 2008)
    • For more information, see http://www.ftc.gov/be/consumerbehavior/ (last visited Apr. 29, 2008).
  • 385
    • 79551523955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Salinger et al., supra note 192, at 98 (discussing the conference)
    • See also Salinger et al., supra note 192, at 98 (discussing the conference).
  • 386
    • 79551548941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the sake of brevity and focus, this Article only deals with the FTC's unfairness authority, though the FTC's prohibition on deceptive practices might also be fertile ground for the new paternalism
    • For the sake of brevity and focus, this Article only deals with the FTC's unfairness authority, though the FTC's prohibition on deceptive practices might also be fertile ground for the new paternalism.
  • 387
    • 79551516152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Salinger et al., supra note 192, at 99-100
    • See Salinger et al., supra note 192, at 99-100.
  • 388
    • 79551522221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 362-63 (noting that the total rebate offer volume now ranges from four to ten billion dollars per year and describing the important role rebates play in the high-end electronics industry)
    • See Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 362-63 (noting that the total rebate offer volume now ranges from four to ten billion dollars per year and describing the important role rebates play in the high-end electronics industry).
  • 389
    • 79551573841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 363 (observing that "despite their popularity, few marketing practices have received as much negative press as rebates")
    • See id. at 363 (observing that "despite their popularity, few marketing practices have received as much negative press as rebates").
  • 390
    • 79551522608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These complaints are examined in greater detail in Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 363
    • These complaints are examined in greater detail in Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 363.
  • 391
    • 79551554529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of various types of state legislation on rebates
    • For a discussion of various types of state legislation on rebates,
  • 392
    • 79551553805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 396-98
    • see id. at 396-98.
  • 393
    • 79551510452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 399-400 (discussing various FTC enforcement actions against rebate offerors)
    • See id. at 399-400 (discussing various FTC enforcement actions against rebate offerors).
  • 394
    • 79551505455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One might also press a per se unfairness claim against consumer rebates based upon the price discriminating effect of rebates. The argument proceeds as follows: Rebates facilitate price discrimination because rebates allow sellers to sell a good for two prices: the shelf price paid by consumers who do not participate in the rebate offer, and the after rebate strike price, paid by the consumers who do participate in the rebate offer
    • One might also press a per se unfairness claim against consumer rebates based upon the price discriminating effect of rebates. The argument proceeds as
  • 395
    • 25144435947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Price discrimination after the purchase: Rebates as state-dependent discounts
    • 1131
    • See Yuxin Chen, Sridhar Moorthy & Z. John Zhang, Price Discrimination After the Purchase: Rebates As State-Dependent Discounts, 51 MGMT. Sci. 1131, 1131 (2005);
    • (2005) Mgmt. Sci. , vol.51 , pp. 1131
    • Chen, Y.1    Moorthy, S.2    Zhang, Z.J.3
  • 396
    • 0000467107 scopus 로고
    • A price discrimination theory of coupons
    • (discussing coupons as price-discrimination devices)
    • Chakravarthi Narasimhan, A Price Discrimination Theory of Coupons, 3 MARKETING SCI. 128 (1984) (discussing coupons as price-discrimination devices);
    • (1984) Marketing Sci. , vol.3 , pp. 128
    • Narasimhan, C.1
  • 397
    • 79551507220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 376 n.63 ("[O]ne might argue that (1) it is inherently wrong to sell the same good to different consumers at different prices, or (2) the ability of a firm to price discriminate demonstrates that the firm possesses unlawful market power.")
    • see also Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 376 n.63 ("[O]ne might argue that (1) it is inherently wrong to sell the same good to different consumers at different prices, or (2) the ability of a firm to price discriminate demonstrates that the firm possesses unlawful market power.");
  • 398
    • 38849197345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Much ado about price discrimination
    • 58 (arguing that price discrimination is not inherently unfair). These arguments, while interesting, do not necessarily involve behavioral exploitation, and thus will be bracketed here
    • Alexei M. Marcoux, Much Ado About Price Discrimination, 9 J. MKTS. & MORALITY 57, 58 (2006) (arguing that price discrimination is not inherently unfair). These arguments, while interesting, do not necessarily involve behavioral exploitation, and thus will be bracketed here.
    • (2006) J. Mkts. & Morality , vol.9 , pp. 57
    • Marcoux, A.M.1
  • 399
    • 79551547754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This behavioral law and economics of consumer rebates is covered in greater detail in Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 376-95. The following treatment is
    • This behavioral law and economics of consumer rebates is covered in greater detail in Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 376-95. The following treatment is
  • 400
    • 79551550402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • merely used to illustrate the challenges that behavioral issues raise under FTC unfairness law
    • merely used to illustrate the challenges that behavioral issues raise under FTC unfairness law.
  • 401
    • 77951963656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward a new model of consumer protection: The problem of inflated transaction costs
    • 1639
    • Jeff Sovern, Toward a New Model of Consumer Protection: The Problem of Inflated Transaction Costs, 47 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1635, 1639 (2006) [hereinafter Sovern, Transaction Costs].
    • (2006) Wm. & Mary L. Rev. , vol.47 , pp. 1635
    • Sovern, J.1
  • 402
    • 33745295729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When do you want it? Time, decisions, and public policy
    • 71
    • John G. Lynch, Jr. & Gal Zauberman, When Do You Want It? Time, Decisions, and Public Policy, 25 J. PUB. POL'Y & MKTG. 67, 71 (2006) ("Some people may believe that knowingly offering a rebate that a substantial percentage of consumers are unlikely to redeem (though they believe otherwise) is an unfair competitive practice. However, the FTC appears to operate under a definition of unfairness that makes this outcome unlikely ....").
    • (2006) J. Pub. Pol'y & Mktg. , vol.25 , pp. 67
    • Lynch Jr., J.G.1    Zauberman, G.2
  • 403
    • 79551513585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To date, not a single judicial opinion has held that consumer rebates are per se unfair under §5 of the FTC Act. Just as important, the FTC has never advocated this position (though some consumer rights advocates have gone so far as to suggest that all rebates should be paid at the point of purchase). Nevertheless, even though the concept of unfairness has not been extended in this manner, rebates provide an interesting test of the current FTC unfairness standard. This topic was addressed in Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 403-06. The following treatment of this issue is an expansion and refinement of that discussion
    • To date, not a single judicial opinion has held that consumer rebates are per se unfair under §5 of the FTC Act. Just as important, the FTC has never advocated this position (though some consumer rights advocates have gone so far as to suggest that all rebates should be paid at the point of purchase). Nevertheless, even though the concept of unfairness has not been extended in this manner, rebates provide an interesting test of the current FTC unfairness standard. This topic was addressed in Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 403-06. The following treatment of this issue is an expansion and refinement of that discussion.
  • 404
    • 79551567052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 367
    • See id. at 367 (discussing categories of consumers in a rebate promotion).
  • 405
    • 79551518867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sovern, Transaction Costs, supra note 202, at 1684
    • See Sovern, Transaction Costs, supra note 202, at 1684 (concluding that those who intend to redeem but fail to do so "experience a distortion of their demand function").
  • 406
    • 79551539329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 369-70
    • See Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 369-70 (elaborating on the concept of breakage).
  • 407
    • 79551525011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A way around this conclusion is to say that the redeemer in that case enjoys nonpecuniary benefits from redeeming a rebate, such as the satisfaction brought about by the rebate redemption process. Thus, any consumer who is deprived of the pleasure of successfully redeeming a rebate suffers harm. The use of a non-economic measure for consumer harm, however, creates additional utility measurement and comparison problems.
  • 408
    • 79551533734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jeff Sovern argues that even successful redeemers incur transaction costs: Even consumers who obtain the rebate incur transaction costs that do not benefit society because they must comply with the requirements for the rebate. If the seller simply offered the product at a reduced price, consumers would not have had to fulfill any requirements to obtain the reduced price. Accordingly, the rebate comes at a dearer price than necessary. Sovern, Transaction Costs, supra note 202, at 1685
    • Jeff Sovern argues that even successful redeemers incur transaction costs: Even consumers who obtain the rebate incur transaction costs that do not benefit society because they must comply with the requirements for the rebate. If the seller simply offered the product at a reduced price, consumers would not have had to fulfill any requirements to obtain the reduced price. Accordingly, the rebate comes at a dearer price than necessary. Sovern, Transaction Costs, supra note 202, at 1685.
  • 409
    • 79551507924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Price and prejudice: The case against consumer equality in the information age
    • 562-70
    • See Matthew A. Edwards, Price and Prejudice: The Case Against Consumer Equality in the Information Age, 10 LEWIS & CLARK L. REV. 559, 562-70 (2006) (discussing economic price discrimination).
    • (2006) Lewis & Clark L. Rev. , vol.10 , pp. 559
    • Edwards, M.A.1
  • 410
    • 79551510794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 372-73
    • See Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 372-73 (noting that a firm can learn how much consumers spend, which products are purchased together, and shopping patterns from rebates).
  • 411
    • 79551521124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Presumably other scholars will have different opinions as to who is harmed by rebates; in any event, the discussion serves to show that the concept of consumer injury is not as straightforward in this context as one might presume. Fortunately, the FTC has a staff of expert economists who are far better trained to untangle these issues.
  • 412
    • 79551538956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FTC Unfairness Policy Statement, supra note 123
    • See FTC Unfairness Policy Statement, supra note 123.
  • 413
    • 79551521838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1074
    • Id. at 1074 (internal citation omitted).
  • 414
    • 0347397767 scopus 로고
    • Unfairness and deception at the FTC: Clarifying the commission's role and rules
    • 308
    • Carol T. Crawford, Unfairness and Deception at the FTC: Clarifying the Commission's Role and Rules, 54 ANTITRUST L.J. 303, 308 (1985) (internal citations omitted).
    • (1985) Antitrust L.J. , vol.54 , pp. 303
    • Crawford, C.T.1
  • 415
    • 79551519929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The exact percentages are difficult to determine. For a discussion of rebate redemption rates, see Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 367-69
    • The exact percentages are difficult to determine. For a discussion of rebate redemption rates, see Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 367-69 (summarizing available data on rebate redemption rates, but cautioning that "reliable rebate redemption rates are difficult to obtain") (internal citation omitted).
  • 416
    • 79551521839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 45(n) (2000)
    • 15 U.S.C. § 45(n) (2000).
  • 417
    • 79551563988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 405
    • See Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 405 (suggesting that this approach could lead to the argument that even "an honestly and efficiently managed rebate promotion is unlawful" due to "behavioral economics," but acknowledging that "[regulators or courts might be skeptical of such a claim since many consumers do indeed redeem rebates and avoid the harm being addressed here");
  • 418
    • 79551542820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lynch & Zauberman, supra note 203, at 71-72
    • Lynch & Zauberman, supra note 203, at 71-72 ("Consumers who follow the redemption protocol receive the benefit, and they might point out that those who do not could have easily avoided the financial loss. However, it is highly predictable that in the aggregate, consumers will have low redemption rates.") (internal citation omitted).
  • 419
    • 79551568731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Int'l Harvester Co., 104 F.T.C. 949, 1066 (1984) (discussing safety hazards posed by gasoline-powered tractors) (internal citation omitted)
    • Int'l Harvester Co., 104 F.T.C. 949, 1066 (1984) (discussing safety hazards posed by gasoline-powered tractors) (internal citation omitted);
  • 420
    • 73049094319 scopus 로고
    • 849 F.2d 1354, 1365 11th Cir.
    • see also Orkin Exterminating Co. v. FTC, 849 F.2d 1354, 1365 (11th Cir. 1988) (adopting the FTC's position that "'[c]onsumers may act to avoid injury before it occurs if they have reason to anticipate the impending harm and the means to avoid it, or they may seek to mitigate the damage afterward if they are aware of potential avenues toward that end'" (
    • (1988) Orkin Exterminating Co. v. FTC
  • 422
    • 0038460049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The influence of culture on consumer impulsive buying behavior
    • 163
    • Jacqueline J. Kacen & Julie Anne Lee, The Influence of Culture on Consumer Impulsive Buying Behavior, 12 J. CONSUMER PSYCHOL. 163, 163 (2002) ("Impulsive consumer buying behavior is a widely recognized phenomenon in the United States .... [I]t has been suggested that purchases of new products result more from impulse purchasing than from prior planning.");
    • (2002) J. Consumer Psychol. , vol.12 , pp. 163
    • Kacen, J.J.1    Lee, J.A.2
  • 423
    • 0032087407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Impulse buying: Modeling its precursors
    • 169
    • see also Sharon E. Beatty & M. Elizabeth Ferrell, Impulse Buying: Modeling Its Precursors, 74 J. RETAILING 169, 169 (1998) (noting that "[i]mpulse buying is a pervasive aspect of consumers' behaviors");
    • (1998) J. Retailing , vol.74 , pp. 169
    • Beatty, S.E.1    Elizabeth Ferrell, M.2
  • 424
    • 33947276902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spent resources: Self-regulatory resource availability affects impulse buying
    • Kathleen D. Vohs & Ronald J. Faber, Spent Resources: Self-Regulatory Resource Availability Affects Impulse Buying, 33 J. CONSUMER RES. 537 (2007) (discussing research on impulse buying);
    • (2007) J. Consumer Res. , vol.33 , pp. 537
    • Vohs, K.D.1    Faber, R.J.2
  • 425
    • 79551517261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KDI Sch. of Pub. Pol'y & Mgmt., Working Paper No. 06-09, reviewing literature on impulse buying
    • Kwon Jung & Clement Lim, Impulse Buying Behaviors on the Internet 1-2 (KDI Sch. of Pub. Pol'y & Mgmt., Working Paper No. 06-09, 2006), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=953851(reviewing literature on impulse buying).
    • (2006) Impulse Buying Behaviors on the Internet 1-2
    • Jung, K.1    Lim, C.2
  • 426
    • 34250655759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law & gratuitous promises
    • 922
    • Robert A. Prentice, "Law &" Gratuitous Promises, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 881, 922
    • U. Ill. L. Rev. , vol.2007 , pp. 881
    • Prentice, R.A.1
  • 427
    • 21844481715 scopus 로고
    • Normative influences on impulsive buying behavior
    • quoting 306 internal citations omitted
    • (quoting Dennis W. Rook & Robert J. Fisher, Normative Influences on Impulsive Buying Behavior, 22 J. CONSUMER RES. 305, 306 (1995)) (internal citations omitted).
    • (1995) J. Consumer Res. , vol.22 , pp. 305
    • Rook, D.W.1    Fisher, R.J.2
  • 428
    • 33646589448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cyberspace 2.0
    • 476-77
    • Neil Weinstock Netanel, Cyberspace 2.0, 79 TEX. L. REV. 447, 476-77 (2000) (book review) (internal citation omitted);
    • (2000) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.79 , pp. 447
    • Netanel, N.W.1
  • 429
    • 84926280966 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust market definition: An integrated approach
    • 27 n.78
    • see also Robert G. Harris & Thomas M. Jorde, Antitrust Market Definition: An Integrated Approach, 72 CAL. L. REV. 1, 27 n.78 (1984) ("[M]any retail enterprises exploit human impulsiveness by ... designing the arrangement of products in the store to increase the incidence of 'impulse buying.'");
    • (1984) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 1
    • Harris, R.G.1    Jorde, T.M.2
  • 430
    • 79551531370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Determining the likelihood of confusion in ex parte examination: A trademark examining attorney's perspective
    • 211
    • Paula B. Mays, Determining the Likelihood of Confusion in Ex parte Examination: A Trademark Examining Attorney's Perspective, 89 J. PAT. & TRADEMARK OFF. SOC'Y 207, 211 (2007) ("[M]ost grocers arrange the store aisle to encourage impulse shopping. Candy is placed near the checkout counter along with shocking magazines with such covers as 'Movie Star has alien baby.' Cereal is placed strategically and colorfully displayed in order to attract attention and encourage on-the-spot purchases.").
    • (2007) J. Pat. & Trademark Off. Soc'y , vol.89 , pp. 207
    • Mays, P.B.1
  • 431
    • 79551519589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sovern, Transaction Costs, supra note 202, at 1638-39
    • See Sovern, Transaction Costs, supra note 202, at 1638-39 (arguing that "the transaction costs generated by rebate offers permit manufacturers effectively to charge me unrebated price to most consumers," because "instead of simply paying less for the item from the beginning, as would be true with a sale item, consumers must fill out a form, gather proofs of purchase, and send them to the manufacturer").
  • 432
    • 79551515808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Camerer, Wanting, Liking, and Learning, supra note 11, at 91 n.11, 92
    • See Camerer, Wanting, Liking, and Learning, supra note 11, at 91 n.11, 92
  • 434
    • 0002313488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pleasure, pain, desire, and dread: Hidden core processes of emotion
    • 527
    • see also Kent C. Berridge, Pleasure, Pain, Desire, and Dread: Hidden Core Processes of Emotion, in WELL-BEING: THE FOUNDATIONS OF HEDONIC PSYCHOLOGY 525, 527 (Daniel Kahneman, Ed Diener & Norbert Schwarz eds., 1999) ("If an event was pleasant, it should be remembered as pleasant, expected to be pleasant, and desired again. But it appears that the three types of utility often diverge for outcomes in real life."). Put another way, Ben is experiencing a tension between his experienced utility and his decision utility.
    • Well-Being: The Foundations of Hedonic Psychology , pp. 525
    • Berridge, K.C.1
  • 435
    • 79551532071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Camerer, Wanting, Liking, and Learning, supra note 10, at 90
    • See Camerer, Wanting, Liking, and Learning, supra note 10, at 90 (noting four types of utility: "experienced utility (the hedonic sensation at the time of consumption that Jeremy Bentham had in mind); remembered utility; forecasted utility (a forecast of experienced utility); and finally, the familiar notion of decision utility (numbers an observer could use to rank an agent's revealed preferences)")
  • 436
    • 79551573124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing Kahneman et al., supra note 57, at 376-77
    • (citing Kahneman et al., supra note 57, at 376-77;
  • 437
    • 21344483676 scopus 로고
    • New challenges to the rationality assumption
    • 21
    • Daniel Kahneman, New Challenges to the Rationality Assumption, 150 J. INSTITUTIONAL & THEORETICAL ECON. 18, 21 (1994)).
    • (1994) J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. , vol.150 , pp. 18
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 438
    • 84924098879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are we one self or multiple selves?: Implications for law and public policy
    • See generally Richard A. Posner, Are We One Self or Multiple Selves?: Implications for Law and Public Policy, 3 LEGAL THEORY 23 (1997).
    • (1997) Legal Theory , vol.3 , pp. 23
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 439
    • 70450147190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Precommitment strategies in corporate law: The case of dead hand and no hand pills
    • 5
    • See Stephen M. Bainbridge, Precommitment Strategies in Corporate Law: The Case of Dead Hand and No Hand Pills, 29 J. CORP. L. 1, 5 (2003) ("The ... phenomenon of multiple selves posits that individuals do not have a single utility function, but rather multiple competing utility functions. Because each self orders preferences differently, there is an ever-present risk that the self predominating at a given moment may make decisions not in the complete individual's best interest.");
    • (2003) J. Corp. L. , vol.29 , pp. 1
    • Bainbridge, S.M.1
  • 440
    • 79551572767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Korobkin & Ulen, Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1123
    • Korobkin & Ulen, Rationality Assumption, supra note 7, at 1123 ("Each individual, at any given point of time, might not be the unitary, coherent set of preference orderings imagined by rational choice theory. Rather, each individual may be viewed as a collection of competing preference orderings. If so, then there may be a collective action problem in aggregating the contemporaneous preferences of these multiple selves.").
  • 441
    • 79551545307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Finally, we should note that even if a consumer is harmed by a form of behavioral exploitation, under current unfairness law the harm must be weighed against everyone who benefited from the practice. In the case of placement of certain goods at checkout and impulse purchases, the harm to consumers who make ill-advised purchases must be weighed against the benefits that convenient product placement makes for other consumers. See Camerer, Wanting, Liking, Learning, supra note 11, at 92
    • Finally, we should note that even if a consumer is harmed by a form of behavioral exploitation, under current unfairness law the harm must be weighed against everyone who benefited from the practice. In the case of placement of certain goods at checkout and impulse purchases, the harm to consumers who make ill-advised purchases must be weighed against the benefits that convenient product placement makes for other consumers. See Camerer, Wanting, Liking, Learning, supra note 11, at 92 (qualifying the wanting-learningliking framework's promotion of regulatory paternalism with the precondition that intervention "not cause other harms").
  • 442
    • 79551573840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Whitman, supra note 4, at 4
    • See Whitman, supra note 4, at 4.
  • 443
    • 43249109816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Payday lending
    • A lucid, recent survey of the payday lending business can be found in 169-75
    • A lucid, recent survey of the payday lending business can be found in Michael A. Stegman, Payday Lending, 21 J. ECON. PERSP. 169, 169-75 (2007).
    • (2007) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.21 , pp. 169
    • Stegman, M.A.1
  • 444
    • 34248643173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Just until payday
    • 861-862
    • Ronald J. Mann & Jim Hawkins, Just Until Payday, 54 UCLA L. REV. 855, 861-62 (2007) (internal citation omitted);
    • (2007) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.54 , pp. 855
    • Mann, R.J.1    Hawkins, J.2
  • 445
    • 79551540196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Payday lending-The litigation and legislation that regulate it
    • 427
    • see also Brian A. Glasser & Eric B. Snyder, Payday Lending-The Litigation and Legislation That Regulate It, 1 11 TH ANNUAL CONSUMER FIN. SERV. LITIG INST. 423, 427 (2006) ("A payday loan is a transaction where a consumer borrows against his or her next paycheck. Typically, the consumer provides a recent pay stub as well as a personal check for the loan amount, plus fees, dated for the next payday, when the loan comes due.");
    • (2006) 11th Annual Consumer Fin. Serv. Litig Inst. , vol.1 , pp. 423
    • Glasser, B.A.1    Snyder, E.B.2
  • 446
    • 77957744964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Predatory lending and the military: The law and geography of payday loans in military towns
    • 660
    • Steven M. Graves & Christopher L. Peterson, Predatory Lending and the Military: The Law and Geography of "Payday " Loans in Military Towns, 66 OH. ST. L.J. 653, 660 (2005) (defining payday loans as "high interest rate, rapidly compounding loans meant to tide over cash-short borrowers until their next paycheck").
    • (2005) Oh. St. L.J. , vol.66 , pp. 653
    • Graves, S.M.1    Peterson, C.L.2
  • 447
    • 79551540540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One author sums it up: Critics argue that payday lenders target unsophisticated, cash strapped, and vulnerable people, charge outrageous and usurious fees, and often lead to a cycle of renewal that results in massive magnification of a relatively modest loan amount. Proponents counter that the industry provides a necessary and desirable financial service to a disenfranchised segment of the population ignored or underserved by mainstream banks, and that increased fees directly correspond only to the increased risks that arise from lending to borrowers with an unfavorable credit history.
  • 448
    • 33845636605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A role for payday lenders
    • 235
    • Chad A. Cicconi, A Role for Payday Lenders, 123 BANKING L.J. 235, 235 (2006) (internal citation omitted);
    • (2006) Banking L.J. , vol.123 , pp. 235
    • Cicconi, C.A.1
  • 449
    • 79551547049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fixing payday lending: The potential of greater bank involvement
    • Note, 134
    • see also Michael Bertics, Note, Fixing Payday Lending: The Potential of Greater Bank Involvement, 9 N.C. BANKING INST. 133, 134 (2005) (arguing that "[t]he payday lending market is currently functioning at an equilibrium that is harmful to consumers," and that "the entry of banks into the payday lending market could solve this problem by enhancing the competitive market forces within the industry");
    • (2005) N.C. Banking Inst. , vol.9 , pp. 133
    • Bertics, M.1
  • 450
    • 0035568295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taking the pay out of payday loans: Putting an end to the usurious and unconscionable interest rates charged by payday lenders
    • Comment, 1259
    • Charles A. Bruch, Comment, Taking the Pay Out of Payday Loans: Putting an End to the Usurious and Unconscionable Interest Rates Charged by Payday Lenders, 69 U. CIN. L. REV. 1257, 1259 (2001) (contending that "new federal legislation should be enacted to bring interest rates charged by payday lenders into conformance with traditional limits of usury and unconscionability");
    • (2001) U. Cin. L. Rev. , vol.69 , pp. 1257
    • Bruch, C.A.1
  • 451
    • 43249084655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mayday payday: Can corporate social responsibility save payday lenders?
    • Carmen M. Butler & Niloufar A. Park, Mayday Payday: Can Corporate Social Responsibility Save Payday Lenders?, 3 RUTGERS U. J.L. & URB. POL'Y 119 (2005);
    • (2005) Rutgers U. J.L. & Urb. Pol'y , vol.3 , pp. 119
    • Butler, C.M.1    Park, N.A.2
  • 452
    • 0036863140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Payday loans: Shrewd business or predatory lending?
    • 25-97
    • Creóla Johnson, Payday Loans: Shrewd Business or Predatory Lending?, 87 MINN. L. REV. 1, 25-97 (2002) (surveying numerous deceptive and exploitive payday lending practices);
    • (2002) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.87 , pp. 1
    • Johnson, C.1
  • 453
    • 79551536241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 857
    • Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 857 ("The high interest rates that payday lenders charge have generated a flurry of critical proposals, ranging from calls to end payday lending altogether to proposals for additional disclosures by payday lenders.");
  • 454
    • 79551513219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rational regulation of payday lending
    • Aimee A. Minnich, Rational Regulation of Payday Lending, 16 KAN. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 84 (2006);
    • (2006) Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.16 , pp. 84
    • Minnich, A.A.1
  • 456
    • 13544275845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Payday loans: The case for federal legislation
    • 727
    • See Pearl Chin, Payday Loans: The Case for Federal Legislation, 2004 U. ILL. L. REV. 723, 727 (characterizing typical payday borrowers as "vulnerable customers who do not have access to information or to credit alternatives that would allow comparison shopping");
    • U. Ill. L. Rev. , vol.2004 , pp. 723
    • Chin, P.1
  • 457
    • 79551518172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Payday lending in North Carolina: Now you see it, now you don 7
    • 267
    • Scott A. Hefner, Payday Lending in North Carolina: Now You See It, Now You Don 7, 11 N.C. BANKING INST. 263, 267 (2007) ("The payday lending industry has been charged with targeting minorities, low-income earners, military personnel and the elderly.") (citing Press Release, Office of N.Y. State Att'y Gen., New York Sues to Stop Illegal Payday Lending Scheme (Sept. 24, 2003), http://www.oag.state.ny.us/press/2003/sep/sep24a-03.html;
    • (2007) N.C. Banking Inst. , vol.11 , pp. 263
    • Hefner, S.A.1
  • 458
    • 79551527269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Johnson, supra note 231, at 99
    • Johnson, supra note 231, at 99 (concluding "that payday loan customers are primarily lowto-moderate income consumers who have personal checking accounts").
  • 459
    • 79551508587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Graves & Peterson, supra note 230, at 657-58
    • See Graves & Peterson, supra note 230, at 657-58. Government intervention took the form of a 36% interest rate cap on loans to military members.
  • 461
    • 79551523326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Renuart & Keest, supra note 231, §7.5.5.1, at 293 n.439
    • See Renuart & Keest, supra note 231, §7.5.5.1, at 293 n.439
  • 462
    • 79551512467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Race matters: The concentration of payday lenders in African American neighborhoods in North Carolina
    • available at
    • (citing Uriah King et al., Race Matters: The Concentration of Payday Lenders in African American Neighborhoods in North Carolina, Qr. for Responsible Lending (2005), available at http://www.responsiblelending.org/pdfs/rr006-Race- Matters-Payday-in-NC-0305.pdf).
    • (2005) Qr. for Responsible Lending
    • King, U.1
  • 463
    • 79551555379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For reviews of the conflicting demographic data regarding payday borrowers, see Minnich, supra note 231, at 88
    • For reviews of the conflicting demographic data regarding payday borrowers, see Minnich, supra note 231, at 88.
  • 465
    • 79551534463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rolling over borrowers: Preventing excessive refinancing and other necessary changes in the payday loan industry
    • Note, 2403-07
    • Cf. Richard J. Thomas, Note, Rolling over Borrowers: Preventing Excessive Refinancing and Other Necessary Changes in the Payday Loan Industry, 48 WM. & MARY L. REV. 2401, 2403-07 (2007) (assessing the study's legitimacy in light of its alleged flaws, which include its sponsorship by one of the industry's trade associations, and a small sample size of clients who all borrowed at the same time of year).
    • (2007) Wm. & Mary L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 2401
    • Thomas, R.J.1
  • 466
    • 79551528789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One expert on payday lending states: Researchers have conducted several surveys of the characteristics of payday loan customers and their findings are broadly consistent. All payday loan customers have bank accounts, for this is what makes them eligible for the service. The vast majority is employed and has a household income between $15,000 and $60,000. The customers tend to be young adults; most are under forty years old. Most have children in the household. A strong majority has a high school education; about half have some higher education. Somewhat more than half are women. About half carry major credit cards.
  • 467
    • 33845952555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fringe banking and the rise of payday lending
    • John P. Caskey, Fringe Banking and the Rise of Payday Lending, in CREDIT MARKETS FOR THE POOR 17, 18-19 (2005).
    • (2005) Credit Markets for the Poor , vol.17 , pp. 18-19
    • Caskey, J.P.1
  • 468
    • 79551546309 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stegman, supra note 229, at 173
    • Stegman, supra note 229, at 173.
  • 469
    • 79551556459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I put high in quotation marks because I am not sure how to determine whether a price for something is high, though I suspect that I share the visceral reaction held by many people that these loans are high-cost
    • I put "high" in quotation marks because I am not sure how to determine whether a price for something is high, though I suspect that I share the visceral reaction held by many people that these loans are high-cost.
  • 470
    • 79551541261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stegman, supra note 229, at 170
    • Stegman, supra note 229, at 170;
  • 471
    • 79551555738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Caskey, supra note 236, at 18
    • see also Caskey, supra note 236, at 18 ("Given the short maturity of the loans and the size of the finance charge relative to the size of the loan, the annual percentage rate on payday loans commonly falls between 350 and 1,000 percent.");
  • 472
    • 79551552365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Graves & Peterson, supra note 230, at 661
    • Graves & Peterson, supra note 230, at 661 (average payday loan rates range from 364% to 550%);
  • 473
    • 79551513956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Renuart & Keest, supra note 231, at 295
    • Renuart & Keest, supra note 231, at 295 (calculating the translation of payday loan fees "into annual percentage rates typically not less than 390% and averaging close to 500%, though advocates and credit code enforcement agencies have noted rates of 1300% to 7300%"). Though loans at these rates seem intuitively outrageous and hard to defend, some commentators argue that it is not fair to express payday loan fees in the form of annual percentage rates.
  • 474
    • 79551568393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 903-04
    • Compare Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 903-04 (noting that "studies suggest that requiring APR disclosures on payday loans is ineffective" and claiming that "[i]nterest-rate disclosures are misleading because the amount of the fee charged generally does not depend on the number of days until the borrower's payday"),
  • 475
    • 0347843931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The two-tiered consumer financial services marketplace: The fringe banking system and its challenge to current thinking about the role of usury laws in today's society
    • 603
    • with Lynn Drysdale & Kathleen E. Keest, The Two-Tiered Consumer Financial Services Marketplace: The Fringe Banking System and Its Challenge to Current Thinking About the Role of Usury Laws in Today's Society, 51 S.C. L. REV. 589, 603 (2000) (arguing that APRs enable consumers to comparison shop for credit),
    • (2000) S.C. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 589
    • Drysdale, L.1    Keest, K.E.2
  • 476
    • 79551544947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Usury law, payday loans, and statutory slight of hand: Salience distortion in American credit pricing limits
    • forthcoming manuscript at explaining why the use of the APR is appropriate for payday loans
    • and Christopher L. Peterson, Usury Law, Payday Loans, and Statutory Slight of Hand: Salience Distortion in American Credit Pricing Limits, MINN. L. REV. (forthcoming 2008) (manuscript at 34-35, http://ssrn.com/abstract=1000041) (explaining why the use of the APR is appropriate for payday loans).
    • (2008) Minn. L. Rev. , pp. 34-35
    • Peterson, C.L.1
  • 477
    • 79551510793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 244-45 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 244-45 and accompanying text.
  • 478
    • 79551507923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Or, if one believes that APRs are misleading in this context: Who would choose a $235, two-week loan with a $20 fee? Of course, in some cases, factors other than cost might come into play, such as the reputation of the lender, the level of customer service, and other contract terms, such as late payment penalties.
  • 479
    • 79551515807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Mann and Hawkins explain: In sum, the best case against payday lending is that the market is plagued by cognitive failures, unlikely to be well policed by competitive forces, and likely to generate external costs borne by the rest of society. It is simply not plausible, the argument goes, that a person of ordinary capacity would sensibly decide to borrow money at a rate of 400 percent, using a loan that, in most cases, is likely to remain outstanding for months, if not years. In assessing the weight of this problem, it bears noting that those who will be harmed by the market failure are systematically likely to be far from the top of the distribution of income and wealth.
  • 480
    • 79551521123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 884
    • Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 884;
  • 481
    • 79551534093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also id. at 881
    • see also id. at 881 ("Like most consumer financial transactions, payday lending transactions tax the cognitive capabilities of the typical customer in ways that lead to market failures of one sort or another.").
  • 482
    • 79551516503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 391-92
    • See Edwards, Consumer Rebates, supra note 165, at 391-92 (suggesting that people fall prey to overconfidence when making predictions about their own abilities to produce desirable outcomes, or engaging in unfamiliar activities).
  • 483
    • 79551551990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The precise extent of payday loan rollovers is much debated. See Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 864-65
    • The precise extent of payday loan rollovers is much debated. See Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 864-65 (discussing competing evidence on mis issue).
  • 484
    • 79551553062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Chin, supra note 232, at 729-30
    • See Chin, supra note 232, at 729-30 (offering "examples of borrowers who found themselves buried under a mountain of debt because of multiple rollovers" and concluding that "[w]ith multiple rollovers generating the bulk of revenue for payday lenders, the industry has every incentive to keep its customers in a perpetual cycle of debt");
  • 485
    • 79551546308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Drysdale & Keest, supra note 239, at 605
    • Drysdale & Keest, supra note 239, at 605 ("Much of the concern about short-term fringe lending arises over the question of whether it is, at best, a 'debt treadmill' or at worst, a downward spiral.");
  • 486
    • 77957727793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Payday lending: Do outrageous prices necessarily mean outrageous profits?
    • 207
    • Aaron Huckstep, Payday Lending: Do Outrageous Prices Necessarily Mean Outrageous Profits?, 12 FORDHAM J. CORP. & FIN. L. 203, 207 (2007) ("Payday loan rollovers and renewals nearly always play a role in real-life examples of payday lending gone bad.");
    • (2007) Fordham J. Corp. & Fin. L. , vol.12 , pp. 203
    • Huckstep, A.1
  • 487
    • 79551552709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 896
    • Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 896 ("Many commentators-and a good number of legislators-operate on the assumption that proof that a substantial number of payday loan customers are frequent users self-evidently demonstrates the impropriety of the business."); [B]orrowers, who often find their funds insufficient the next month to cover both their normal expenses and repayment of the payday loan, are forced to refinance, or "roll over," the loan for an additional fee. This cycle may continue until the borrower has refinanced so many times that the total cost of the payday loan far exceeds any late fees or returned check charges that the borrower would have faced had she not taken the loan. This refinancing trap is the most serious consumer interest concern in payday lending.
  • 488
    • 79551554184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas, supra note 235, at 2409
    • Thomas, supra note 235, at 2409.
  • 489
    • 79551534092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stegman, supra note 229, at 176
    • See Stegman, supra note 229, at 176.
  • 490
    • 4043058102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The law and economics of consumer finance
    • 170
    • See Richard Hynes & Eric A. Posner, The Law and Economics of Consumer Finance, 4 AM. L. & ECON. REV. 168, 170 (2002) ("In a perfectly competitive market the interest rate will reflect the time value of money, inflation, and the risk of default.");
    • (2002) Am. L. & Econ. Rev. , vol.4 , pp. 168
    • Hynes, R.1    Posner, E.A.2
  • 491
    • 79551559524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Matthew A. Edwards, supra note 69, at 205-06
    • see also Matthew A. Edwards, supra note 69, at 205-06 (discussing the traits of an efficient credit market);
  • 492
    • 0033412074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The price of money: Consumers' understanding of APRs and contract interest rates
    • 66
    • Jinkook Lee & Jeanne M. Hogarth, The Price of Money: Consumers' Understanding of APRs and Contract Interest Rates, 18 J. PUB. POL'Y & MKTG. 66, 66 (1999) ("In a perfectly efficient financial market, the price of a loan is a function of its risk.").
    • (1999) J. Pub. Pol'y & Mktg. , vol.18 , pp. 66
    • Lee, J.1    Hogarth, J.M.2
  • 493
    • 42149153134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Networks Fin. Inst., Working Paper No. 2006-WP-02, available at
    • See Gregory Elliehausen, Consumers ' Use of High-Price Credit Products: Do They Know What They Are Doing? 20-22 (Networks Fin. Inst., Working Paper No. 2006-WP-02, 2006), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=921909 ("Many high-price credit customers have characteristics that make qualifying for credit difficult.").
    • (2006) Consumers ' Use of High-Price Credit Products: Do They Know What They Are Doing? , pp. 20-22
    • Elliehausen, G.1
  • 494
    • 79551567051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 29
    • Id. at 29 ("Nearly two-thirds of payday loan customers obtained their most recent new advance (not renewal) because of an unexpected expense or shortfall in income. Only 11.9% used a payday loan for a planned expenditure.").
  • 495
    • 79551562903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Drysdale & Keest, supra note 239, at 591
    • Drysdale & Keest, supra note 239, at 591 (referring to the subprime consumer credit market as the '"fringe banking' sector").
  • 496
    • 79551508259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id. (distinguishing the fringe banking sector from the "'prime' consumer credit market," comprised of "purchase money home mortgages and the secondary mortgage market, home equity loans, credit cards, automobile loans and leases that finance the American Dream for most of the middle- and upper-economic quintiles");
  • 497
    • 79551529458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elliehausen, supra note 248, at 2-9
    • Elliehausen, supra note 248, at 2-9 (describing types of loans within the fringe banking sector).
  • 498
    • 79551529454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This was the conclusion of the authors of an FDIC working paper. See FDIC Ctr. Fin. Res., Working Paper No. 2005-09, available at
    • This was the conclusion of the authors of an FDIC working paper. See Mark Flannery & Katherine Samolyk, Payday Lending: Do the Costs Justify the Price? 1, 21 (FDIC Ctr. Fin. Res., Working Paper No. 2005-09, 2005), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/so13/papers.cfm? abstract-id=771624 (concluding that "[t]o a great extent, the 'high' APRs implied by payday loan fees can be justified by the fixed costs of keeping the stores open and the relatively high default losses suffered on these loans");
    • (2005) Payday Lending: Do the Costs Justify the Price? , vol.1 , pp. 21
    • Flannery, M.1    Samolyk, K.2
  • 499
    • 79551508915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Huckstep, supra note 245, at 204
    • Huckstep, supra note 245, at 204 ("[D]espite the common belief, payday lending firms do not always make extraordinary profits.").
  • 500
    • 79551530273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elliehausen, supra note 248, at 34
    • Elliehausen, supra note 248, at 34.
  • 501
    • 79551532769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stegman, supra note 229, at 176
    • See Stegman, supra note 229, at 176 (counseling that "the preferred policy choices will vary according to whether payday loans are viewed as a tolerable high-cost form of emergency short-term credit, or whether they are viewed as a loan at triple-digit annual interest rates").
  • 502
    • 79551519233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is well beyond the scope of this Article to review possible solutions for payday lending abuses. The payday lending literature has many suggestions
    • It is well beyond the scope of this Article to review possible solutions for payday lending abuses. The payday lending literature has many suggestions.
  • 503
    • 79551516151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 905-10
    • See, e.g., Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 905-10 (proposing simplified payday loan disclosures and measures to encourage participation in the market by large and reputable lenders).
  • 504
    • 79551535200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lee & Hogarth, supra note 247, at 66
    • See Lee & Hogarth, supra note 247, at 66 (noting the difficulty of accounting for "price-quality trade-offs" when analyzing the pricing of other products does not exist in "the credit arena, in which the 'product' is money").
  • 505
    • 79551549333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Butler & Park, supra note 231, at 123
    • See Butler & Park, supra note 231, at 123 (detailing social costs of the payday lending business, including "bad credit ratings, lower savings rates, less home ownership, bankruptcies, an increase in the number of people depending on welfare, and the costs of preventing and deterring criminal behavior");
  • 506
    • 79551547055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 884
    • Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 884 (discussing effects of individuals' financial distress on society as a whole).
  • 507
    • 79551570647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Johnson, supra note 231, at 25
    • See Johnson, supra note 231, at 25 (identifying "payday lending practices that deceive and exploit consumers by means that are quintessentially unfair to consumers and also often illegal");
  • 508
    • 79551537161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 866
    • Mann & Hawkins, supra note 230, at 866 (noting the possibility that "mom-and-pop" payday loan providers "operate under the radar in more or less chronic violation of applicable laws governing usury and debt collection");
  • 509
    • 79551553804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 870
    • id. at 870 (stating that fraud and illegal lending are also common in the Internet payday lending sector).
  • 510
    • 79551570639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although clearly, a failure to adhere to the Truth in Lending Act's mandatory disclosure provisions could exacerbate any cognitive or emotional impediments to effective comparison shopping for credit. See Butler & Park, supra note 231, at 123
    • Although clearly, a failure to adhere to the Truth in Lending Act's mandatory disclosure provisions could exacerbate any cognitive or emotional impediments to effective comparison shopping for credit. See Butler & Park, supra note 231, at 123 (discussing how failure to disclose material payday loan terms impedes comparison shopping);
  • 511
    • 79551507922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Johnson, supra note 231, at 37-48
    • Johnson, supra note 231, at 37-48 (discussing payday lender violations of the Truth in Lending Act).
  • 512
    • 79551505453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In his comments on an earlier draft of this Article, Jeff Sovern noted that the issue seems to be a "burden of proof question-how sure must the FTC be before it decides to regulate based upon BLE? I think that Sovern's observation hits a key issue on the head, and this Article has aimed to show that the FTCs institutional history of unfairness theory is likely to make the burden of proof steeper than an uninformed observer would guess. I leave it to others to determine whether this ought to be the case.
  • 513
    • 79551540539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Salinger et al., supra note 192, at 103. Michael A. Salinger was the director of the Bureau of Economics (BE) from 2005-2007
    • See Salinger et al., supra note 192, at 103. Michael A. Salinger was the director of the Bureau of Economics (BE) from 2005-2007.
  • 514
    • 79551547389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Press Release, FTC, Economics Director Michael Salinger to Leave FTC: Michael P. Baye Named New Director of the Bureau of Economics (June 28, 2007), Pauline Ippolito is currently a deputy director at the BE; Diagram, FTC, Federal Trade Commission: Bureau of Economics, http://www.ftc.gov/be/be-org- chart.pdf. Joel L. Schräg is an economist at the BE; FTC, Bureau of Economics, Conference on Behavioral Economics and Consumer Policy: Participant Biographies, http://www.ftc.gov/be/consumerbehavior/docs/bios.pdf. Of course, the paper bears the usual caveat that the views expressed... do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Trade Commission or any individual Commissioner
    • See also Press Release, FTC, Economics Director Michael Salinger to Leave FTC: Michael P. Baye Named New Director of the Bureau of Economics (June 28, 2007), http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2007/06/bedirect.shtm. Pauline Ippolito is currently a deputy director at the BE; Diagram, FTC, Federal Trade Commission: Bureau of Economics, http://www.ftc.gov/be/be-org-chart.pdf. Joel L. Schräg is an economist at the BE; FTC, Bureau of Economics, Conference on Behavioral Economics and Consumer Policy: Participant Biographies, http://www.ftc.gov/be/ consumerbehavior/docs/bios.pdf. Of course, the paper bears the usual caveat that the "views expressed... do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Trade Commission or any individual Commissioner."


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.