메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 96, Issue 1, 2010, Pages 57-125

Policy reversal on reverse payments: Why courts should not follow the new doj position on reverse-payment settlements of pharmaceutical patent litigation

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 78651293692     PISSN: 00210552     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (11)

References (328)
  • 1
    • 77958511152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Reverse-payment settlements fit neatly with the parties' incentives. See infra Part II.A. This Article uses the term "reverse-payment settlement" because it is the most commonly used term for this type of settlements. The authors do not intend to imply that reverse payments are backwards or against the parties' interests; only that the payment goes in the opposite direction from the typical patent-infringement case. Some have criticized the "reverse payment" term as suggesting that the settlement is against the parties' interests or is in some way backwards. See Bret Dickey et al., An Economic Assessment of Patent Settlements in the Pharmaceutical Industry, 19 ANNALS HEALTH L. 367, 388 (2010).
  • 2
    • 78651306064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We do not adopt diese terms because although some settlement payments may be in exchange for exclusion from the market, a reverse payment does not necessarily have that effect
    • We do not adopt diese terms because although some settlement payments may be in exchange for exclusion from the market, a reverse payment does not necessarily have that effect.
  • 3
    • 78651318395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1 (2006). The FTC challenges come under section 5 of the FTC Act. See, e.g., Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005)
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1 (2006). The FTC challenges come under section 5 of the FTC Act. See, e.g., Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005).
  • 4
    • 78651327695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Schering-Plough Corp., Docket No. 9297 (F.T.C. June 27, 2002), rev'd, 136 F.T.C. 956 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005)
    • See, e.g., Schering-Plough Corp., Docket No. 9297 (F.T.C. June 27, 2002), http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9297/020627id.pdf, rev'd, 136 F.T.C. 956 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005).
  • 5
    • 78651303098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The substantive laws under which the FTC and the DOJ challenge reverse payments are similar. The FTC challenges reverse payments under the power granted by section 5 of the FTC Act. See 15 U.S.C. § 45 (2006) (allowing the FTC to prevent "unfair methods of competition"). The DOJ challenges reverse payments under section 1 of the Sherman Act. 15 U.S.C. § 1. Because of the Commission's bipartisan nature, it is less directly controlled by the President, so the DOJ and FTC positions have at times diverged
    • The substantive laws under which the FTC and the DOJ challenge reverse payments are similar. The FTC challenges reverse payments under the power granted by section 5 of the FTC Act. See 15 U.S.C. § 45 (2006) (allowing the FTC to prevent "unfair methods of competition"). The DOJ challenges reverse payments under section 1 of the Sherman Act. 15 U.S.C. § 1. Because of the Commission's bipartisan nature, it is less directly controlled by the President, so the DOJ and FTC positions have at times diverged.
  • 6
    • 78651290763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Ark. Carpenters Health & Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG, 604 F.3d 98 (2d Cir.) (per curiam), reh'g en banc denied, Nos. 05-285l-cv(L), 05-2852-cv(CON), 05-2863-cv(CON), 2010 WL 3464382 (2d Cir. Sept. 7, 2010); In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 544 F.3d 1323 (Fed. Cir. 2008); Andrx Pharm., Inc. v. Elan Corp., 421 F.3d 1227 (11th Cir. 2005); Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d 1056; Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 344 F.3d 1294 (11th Cir. 2003); see infra Part II.B
    • E.g., Ark. Carpenters Health & Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG, 604 F.3d 98 (2d Cir.) (per curiam), reh'g en banc denied, Nos. 05-285l-cv(L), 05-2852-cv(CON), 05-2863-cv(CON), 2010 WL 3464382 (2d Cir. Sept. 7, 2010); In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 544 F.3d 1323 (Fed. Cir. 2008); Andrx Pharm., Inc. v. Elan Corp., 421 F.3d 1227 (11th Cir. 2005); Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d 1056; Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 344 F.3d 1294 (11th Cir. 2003); see infra Part II.B.
  • 7
    • 78651298962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 332 F.3d 896, 900 (6th Cir. 2003); see infra Part II.B
    • In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 332 F.3d 896, 900 (6th Cir. 2003); see infra Part II.B.
  • 8
    • 78651295076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for the United States in Response to the Court's Invitation at 10, Ark. Carpenters, 604 F.3d 98 (Nos. 05-2851-cv(L), 05-2852-cv(CON)), 2009 WL 2429249
    • Brief for the United States in Response to the Court's Invitation at 10, Ark. Carpenters, 604 F.3d 98 (Nos. 05-2851-cv(L), 05-2852-cv(CON)), 2009 WL 2429249.
  • 9
    • 78651270501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rule of reason analysis "forbid[s] only those arrangements the anticompetitive consequences of which outweigh their legitimate business justifications." Clamp-All Corp. v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Inst, 851 F.2d 478, 486 (1st Cir. 1988) (Breyer.J.). For a classical statement of the rule of reason, see Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977), where the Court stated: "[T]he factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition."
    • The rule of reason analysis "forbid[s] only those arrangements the anticompetitive consequences of which outweigh their legitimate business justifications." Clamp-All Corp. v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Inst, 851 F.2d 478, 486 (1st Cir. 1988) (Breyer.J.). For a classical statement of the rule of reason, see Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977), where the Court stated: "[T]he factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition."
  • 10
    • 78651338294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 604 F.3d at 108
    • 604 F.3d at 108.
  • 11
    • 78651288645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.B for a description of the DOJ position. The rule of reason is an antitrust analysis that includes no presumption that an activity is procompetitive or anticompetitive. See infra Part II.B
    • See infra Part II.B for a description of the DOJ position. The rule of reason is an antitrust analysis that includes no presumption that an activity is procompetitive or anticompetitive. See infra Part II.B.
  • 12
    • 78651267322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 15 U.S.C. § 15(a) (2006)
    • See 15 U.S.C. § 15(a) (2006).
  • 13
    • 78651287496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part III.B (discussing the procompetitive benefits of reverse-payment settlements)
    • See infra Part III.B (discussing the procompetitive benefits of reverse-payment settlements).
  • 14
    • 78651291850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 98-417, 98 Stat. 1585 (the sections most relevant to reverse-payment settlements are codified as amended in scattered sections of 21 U.S.C.)
    • Pub. L. No. 98-417, 98 Stat. 1585 (the sections most relevant to reverse-payment settlements are codified as amended in scattered sections of 21 U.S.C.).
  • 15
    • 78651273587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 21 U.S.C. § 355(j) (2006)
    • 21 U.S.C. § 355(j) (2006).
  • 16
    • 78651342535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 17
    • 78651322142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id § 355
    • See id § 355.
  • 18
    • 78651307338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 355(j)
    • Id. § 355(j).
  • 19
    • 78651315401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii)
    • Id. § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii).
  • 20
    • 78651338293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii)(IV)
    • See id. § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii)(IV).
  • 21
    • 78651292279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 355 (j)(2)(B)
    • Id. § 355 (j)(2)(B).
  • 22
    • 78651268174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 355(j)(5). The FDA will not approve an ANDA until forty-five days have passed, giving the patent holder a chance to file a patent-infringement suit if it wishes. Id. If the patent holder does file an infringement suit, there is an automatic thirty-month stay of the ANDA, keeping the generic drug off the market while litigation is conducted. Id. Though the Hatch-Waxman Act provides incentives for generic drugs to enter the market, it also provides brand-name drug manufacturers significant protection, allowing them to maintain their market share while patent-infringement litigation commences
    • Id. § 355(j)(5). The FDA will not approve an ANDA until forty-five days have passed, giving the patent holder a chance to file a patent-infringement suit if it wishes. Id. If the patent holder does file an infringement suit, there is an automatic thirty-month stay of the ANDA, keeping the generic drug off the market while litigation is conducted. Id. Though the Hatch-Waxman Act provides incentives for generic drugs to enter the market, it also provides brand-name drug manufacturers significant protection, allowing them to maintain their market share while patent-infringement litigation commences.
  • 23
    • 78651276712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private and state actions may be subsequendy filed
    • Private and state actions may be subsequendy filed.
  • 24
    • 78651300716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv). The process for ANDA approval is much simpler than the process through which new drugs are approved. ANDA filers need not conduct clinical trials - instead, "generic applicants must scientifically demonstrate that their product is bioequivalent (i.e., performs in the same manner as the innovator drug)." Abbreviated New Drug Application (ANDA): Generics, U.S. FOOD & DRUG ADMIN, (last updated Aug. 20, 2010)
    • § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv). The process for ANDA approval is much simpler than the process through which new drugs are approved. ANDA filers need not conduct clinical trials - instead, "generic applicants must scientifically demonstrate that their product is bioequivalent (i.e., performs in the same manner as the innovator drug)." Abbreviated New Drug Application (ANDA): Generics, U.S. FOOD & DRUG ADMIN., http://www.fda.gov/Drugs/ DevelopmentApproval Process/HowDrugsareDevelopedandApproved/ApprovalApplicadons/ AbbreviatedNewDrugApplicationANDAGenerics/default.htm (last updated Aug. 20, 2010).
  • 25
    • 78651270922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David A. Balto, We'll Sell Generics Too: Innovator Drug Makers Are Gaming the Regulatory System and Harming Competition, LEGAL TIMES (D.C.), Mar. 20, 2006, at 39 ("The bounty from challenging a patent is very important. Pharmaceutical patent litigation is a multimillion-dollar proposition. But for the potential reward of six-month exclusivity that represents the vast majority of potential profits from generic entry, many firms might forgo challenging patents.")
    • David A. Balto, We'll Sell Generics Too: Innovator Drug Makers Are Gaming the Regulatory System and Harming Competition, LEGAL TIMES (D.C.), Mar. 20, 2006, at 39 ("The bounty from challenging a patent is very important. Pharmaceutical patent litigation is a multimillion-dollar proposition. But for the potential reward of six-month exclusivity that represents the vast majority of potential profits from generic entry, many firms might forgo challenging patents.").
  • 26
    • 78651312579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pub. L. No. 98-417, § 101, 98 Stat. 1585, 1585-92 (codified as amended at 21 U.S.C. § 355 (j)); Wansheng Jerry Liu, Balancing Accessibility and Sustainability: How To Achieve the Dual Objectives of the Hatch-Waxman Act While Resolving Antitrust Issues in Pharmaceutical Patent Settlement Cases, 18 ALB. L.J. SCI. & TECH. 441, 452-53 (2008)
    • See Pub. L. No. 98-417, § 101, 98 Stat. 1585, 1585-92 (codified as amended at 21 U.S.C. § 355 (j)); Wansheng Jerry Liu, Balancing Accessibility and Sustainability: How To Achieve the Dual Objectives of the Hatch-Waxman Act While Resolving Antitrust Issues in Pharmaceutical Patent Settlement Cases, 18 ALB. L.J. SCI. & TECH. 441, 452-53 (2008).
  • 27
    • 78651295901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Balto, supra note 25
    • Balto, supra note 25.
  • 28
    • 78651289075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 108-173, 117 Stat. 2066 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 21 U.S.C.)
    • Pub. L. No. 108-173, 117 Stat. 2066 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 21 U.S.C.).
  • 29
    • 78651320879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 21 U.S.C. § 355 (j)(5)(D)(i)(I)
    • 21 U.S.C. § 355 (j)(5)(D)(i)(I).
  • 30
    • 78651328515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 31
    • 78651277129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 355 (j)(5)(D)(iii)
    • Id. § 355 (j)(5)(D)(iii).
  • 32
    • 78651270923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1 (2006)
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1 (2006).
  • 33
    • 78651327694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ark. Carpenters Health & Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG, 129 S. Ct. 2828 (2009), denying cert. to 544 F.3d 1323 (Fed. Cir. 2008) (per curiam); Joblove v. Barr Labs, Inc., 551 U.S. 1144 (2007), denying cert, to 466 F.3d 187 (2d Cir. 2005); FTC v. Schering-Plough Corp., 548 U.S. 919 (2006), denying cert. to 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005); Andrx Pharm., Inc. v. Kroger Co., 543 U.S. 939 (2004), denying cert. to 332 F.3d 896 (6th Cir. 2003); Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 543 U.S. 939 (2004), denying cert. to 344 F.3d 1294 (11th Cir. 2003)
    • See, e.g., Ark. Carpenters Health & Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG, 129 S. Ct. 2828 (2009), denying cert. to 544 F.3d 1323 (Fed. Cir. 2008) (per curiam); Joblove v. Barr Labs, Inc., 551 U.S. 1144 (2007), denying cert, to 466 F.3d 187 (2d Cir. 2005); FTC v. Schering-Plough Corp., 548 U.S. 919 (2006), denying cert. to 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005); Andrx Pharm., Inc. v. Kroger Co., 543 U.S. 939 (2004), denying cert. to 332 F.3d 896 (6th Cir. 2003); Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 543 U.S. 939 (2004), denying cert. to 344 F.3d 1294 (11th Cir. 2003).
  • 34
    • 78651327250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 19-20 (1979)
    • Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 19-20 (1979).
  • 35
    • 78651277539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 105 F. Supp. 2d 682, 685 (E.D. Mich. 2000), aff'd, 332 F.3d 896. Cardizem CD is a treatment for chest pain, high blood pressure, and heart attack and stroke prevention. In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 105 F. Supp. 2d 618, 622 (E.D. Mich. 2000), aff'd, 332 F.3d 896 (earlier order on motions to dismiss). Prior to generic entry, the brand-name drug manufacturer, Hoechst AG, was the only supplier in the over $700 million market for these conditions. Id. at 622-23
    • 105 F. Supp. 2d 682, 685 (E.D. Mich. 2000), aff'd, 332 F.3d 896. Cardizem CD is a treatment for chest pain, high blood pressure, and heart attack and stroke prevention. In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 105 F. Supp. 2d 618, 622 (E.D. Mich. 2000), aff'd, 332 F.3d 896 (earlier order on motions to dismiss). Prior to generic entry, the brand-name drug manufacturer, Hoechst AG, was the only supplier in the over $700 million market for these conditions. Id. at 622-23.
  • 36
    • 78651342534 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 622-23
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 622-23.
  • 37
    • 78651303969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 687
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 687.
  • 38
    • 78651306949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 625-26
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 625-26.
  • 39
    • 78651269017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 687, 697. The agreement further stated that if Andrx were to obtain a judgment that the Cardizem CD patent was either invalid or not infringed by Cartia XT, the payments from Hoechst Marion Roussel to Andrx would increase to $100 million per year. Id. at 698
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 687, 697. The agreement further stated that if Andrx were to obtain a judgment that the Cardizem CD patent was either invalid or not infringed by Cartia XT, the payments from Hoechst Marion Roussel to Andrx would increase to $100 million per year. Id. at 698.
  • 40
    • 78651287495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 624
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 624.
  • 41
    • 78651269878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 659. The amendments allowed the alleged infringer to maintain the 180-day exclusivity whether they succeeded in a patent-infringement suit, were not challenged by such a suit, or settled the suit. Id
    • Id. at 659. The amendments allowed the alleged infringer to maintain the 180-day exclusivity whether they succeeded in a patent-infringement suit, were not challenged by such a suit, or settled the suit. Id.
  • 42
    • 78651317567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 647
    • Id. at 647.
  • 43
    • 78651320878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 676-81
    • Id. at 676-81.
  • 44
    • 78651267321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 685. After the antitrust case had been filed, but before the order had been issued, the FTC filed a separate complaint against the parties to the settlement, alleging that the agreement violated the FTC Act. Id. at 690
    • Cardizem, 105 F. Supp. 2d at 685. After the antitrust case had been filed, but before the order had been issued, the FTC filed a separate complaint against the parties to the settlement, alleging that the agreement violated the FTC Act. Id. at 690.
  • 45
    • 78651276092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 685
    • Id. at 685.
  • 46
    • 78651283585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 693
    • Id. at 693.
  • 47
    • 78651345280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 705
    • Id. at 705.
  • 48
    • 78651279614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 49
    • 78651301383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 50
    • 78651297596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 332 F.3d 896, 900 (6th Cir. 2003)
    • In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 332 F.3d 896, 900 (6th Cir. 2003).
  • 51
    • 78651295900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. It held that horizontal market allocations are per se illegal "because they 'have such predictable and pernicious anticompetitive effect, and such limited potential for procompetitive benefit.'" Id. at 906 (quoting State Oil v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10 (1997))
    • Id. It held that horizontal market allocations are per se illegal "because they 'have such predictable and pernicious anticompetitive effect, and such limited potential for procompetitive benefit.'" Id. at 906 (quoting State Oil v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10 (1997)).
  • 52
    • 78651288644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under the law at the time, the settlement of the patent-infringement suit and the agreement not to market the generic "also delayed the entry of other generic competitors, who could not enter until the expiration of [the ANDA filer's] 180-day period of marketing exclusivity." Id. at 907. Under current law, other competitors would not be barred indefinitely from entering the market, but since the 180-day exclusivity is not available to them, they lack a major incentive to bring a generic drug to market. See supra notes 29-32 and accompanying text
    • Under the law at the time, the settlement of the patent-infringement suit and the agreement not to market the generic "also delayed the entry of other generic competitors, who could not enter until the expiration of [the ANDA filer's] 180-day period of marketing exclusivity." Id. at 907. Under current law, other competitors would not be barred indefinitely from entering the market, but since the 180-day exclusivity is not available to them, they lack a major incentive to bring a generic drug to market. See supra notes 29-32 and accompanying text.
  • 53
    • 78651282738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 164 F. Supp. 2d 1340, 1343 (S.D. Fla. 2000), rev'd sub nom. Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 344 F.3d 1294 (11th Cir. 2003)
    • 164 F. Supp. 2d 1340, 1343 (S.D. Fla. 2000), rev'd sub nom. Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 344 F.3d 1294 (11th Cir. 2003).
  • 54
    • 78651306948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1343, 1349 (quoting United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 608 (1972)) (internal quotation marks omitted)
    • Id. at 1343, 1349 (quoting United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 608 (1972)) (internal quotation marks omitted).
  • 55
    • 78651291849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Valley Drug, 344 F.3d at 1295
    • Valley Drug, 344 F.3d at 1295.
  • 56
    • 78651318841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1304 ("If this case merely involved one firm making monthly payments to potential competitors in return for their exiting or refraining from entering the market, we would readily affirm the district court's order. This is not such a case, however, because one of the parties owned a patent.")
    • Id. at 1304 ("If this case merely involved one firm making monthly payments to potential competitors in return for their exiting or refraining from entering the market, we would readily affirm the district court's order. This is not such a case, however, because one of the parties owned a patent.").
  • 57
    • 78651314528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1305
    • Id. at 1305.
  • 58
    • 78651278882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "[A] patentee can choose to exclude everyone from producing the patented article or can choose to be the sole supplier itself or grant exclusive territorial licenses carving up the United States among its licensees." Id. at 1305 (citations omitted)
    • "[A] patentee can choose to exclude everyone from producing the patented article or can choose to be the sole supplier itself or grant exclusive territorial licenses carving up the United States among its licensees." Id. at 1305 (citations omitted).
  • 59
    • 78651338078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1306
    • Id. at 1306.
  • 60
    • 78651311278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1305 ("To the extent that Zenith and Geneva agreed not to market admittedly infringing products before the ⋯ patent expired or was held invalid, the market allocation characterization is inappropriate.")
    • Id. at 1305 ("To the extent that Zenith and Geneva agreed not to market admittedly infringing products before the ⋯ patent expired or was held invalid, the market allocation characterization is inappropriate.").
  • 61
    • 78651307760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1308
    • Id. at 1308.
  • 62
    • 78651345278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "There may be circumstances under which the unreasonableness of a settlement agreement regarding a subsequendy-invalidated or unenforceable patent would be sufficiendy apparent that antitrust liability would not undermine the encouragement of genuine invendon and disclosure." Id
    • "There may be circumstances under which the unreasonableness of a settlement agreement regarding a subsequendy-invalidated or unenforceable patent would be sufficiendy apparent that antitrust liability would not undermine the encouragement of genuine invendon and disclosure." Id.
  • 63
    • 78651310441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1309
    • Id. at 1309.
  • 64
    • 78651264730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1309-10
    • Id. at 1309-10.
  • 65
    • 78651315400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Terazosin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 352 F. Supp. 2d 1279 (S.D. Fla. 2005)
    • In re Terazosin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 352 F. Supp. 2d 1279 (S.D. Fla. 2005).
  • 66
    • 78651330497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Valley Drug, 344 F.3d at 1309
    • See Valley Drug, 344 F.3d at 1309.
  • 67
    • 78651337640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Terazosin, 352 F. Supp. 2d at 1298 ("[T]he mere fact that the patent was, at the time, not set to expire until October 2014 cannot immunize Defendants from antitrust scrutiny of their Agreement.")
    • Terazosin, 352 F. Supp. 2d at 1298 ("[T]he mere fact that the patent was, at the time, not set to expire until October 2014 cannot immunize Defendants from antitrust scrutiny of their Agreement.").
  • 68
    • 78651284480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 69
    • 78651309046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1307-08 (considering the costs of the settlement against the savings and reductions in risk afforded by the settlement, the court found that, since the patent-infringement trial was nearly over, the parties had relatively little to gain by settlement)
    • Id. at 1307-08 (considering the costs of the settlement against the savings and reductions in risk afforded by the settlement, the court found that, since the patent-infringement trial was nearly over, the parties had relatively little to gain by settlement).
  • 70
    • 78651344854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1312-13
    • Id. at 1312-13.
  • 71
    • 78651335977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1313 ("[H]orizontal agreements between competitors are antitrust's most 'suspect' classification, which as a group provoke closer scrutiny than any other arrangement.")
    • Id. at 1313 ("[H]orizontal agreements between competitors are antitrust's most 'suspect' classification, which as a group provoke closer scrutiny than any other arrangement.").
  • 72
    • 78651333236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1314
    • Id. at 1314.
  • 73
    • 78651284921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 402 F.3d 1056, 1066 (11th Cir. 2005)
    • 402 F.3d 1056, 1066 (11th Cir. 2005).
  • 74
    • 78651316274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1058. The plaintiff in the underlying patent-infringement suit, Schering-Plough, was the patent holder of K-Dur 20, a potassium supplement. Id. Two settlements were at issue - one involved a licensing agreement between the parties, and the other, a more typical reverse payment from the patent holder to the ANDA filer. Id. at 1059-61
    • Id. at 1058. The plaintiff in the underlying patent-infringement suit, Schering-Plough, was the patent holder of K-Dur 20, a potassium supplement. Id. Two settlements were at issue - one involved a licensing agreement between the parties, and the other, a more typical reverse payment from the patent holder to the ANDA filer. Id. at 1059-61.
  • 75
    • 78651296736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough Corp., Docket No. 9297, slip op. at 97-98 (F.T.C. June 27, 2002), rev'd, 136 F.T.C. 956 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056
    • Schering-Plough Corp., Docket No. 9297, slip op. at 97-98 (F.T.C. June 27, 2002), http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9297/020627id.pdf, rev'd, 136 F.T.C. 956 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056.
  • 76
    • 78651305635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 101-02 (quoting Cal. Dental Ass'n, 121 F.T.C. 190, 308 (1996)) (internal quotation marks omitted)
    • Id. at 101-02 (quoting Cal. Dental Ass'n, 121 F.T.C. 190, 308 (1996)) (internal quotation marks omitted).
  • 77
    • 78651329195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 99. The judge also specifically found that the license deal for Niacor between Upsher and Schering-Plough was a "bona fide side deal for fair value," and thus the settlement with Upsher was not a reverse-payment settlement, but rather a traditional settlement with a side deal. Id. at 108
    • Id. at 99. The judge also specifically found that the license deal for Niacor between Upsher and Schering-Plough was a "bona fide side deal for fair value," and thus the settlement with Upsher was not a reverse-payment settlement, but rather a traditional settlement with a side deal. Id. at 108.
  • 78
    • 78651291633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough, 136 F.T.C. at 1070
    • Schering-Plough, 136 F.T.C. at 1070.
  • 79
    • 78651277979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 998; see also infra Part III.D.1 (discussing Shapiro's theory that reverse-payment settlements are anticompetitive by nature)
    • Id. at 998; see also infra Part III.D.1 (discussing Shapiro's theory that reverse-payment settlements are anticompetitive by nature).
  • 80
    • 78651319279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough Corp., 136 F.T.C. at 1003
    • Schering-Plough Corp., 136 F.T.C. at 1003.
  • 81
    • 78651284048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. For a more detailed examination of the economic incentives involved in a reverse-payment settlement, see infra Part III
    • Id. For a more detailed examination of the economic incentives involved in a reverse-payment settlement, see infra Part III.
  • 82
    • 78651278883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005)
    • Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005).
  • 83
    • 78651325982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1076
    • Id. at 1076.
  • 84
    • 78651338076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 85
    • 78651281269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1066
    • Id. at 1066.
  • 86
    • 78651301380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is some debate as to whether the validity presumption extends to the antitrust setting. See infra Part II.B.4.a
    • There is some debate as to whether the validity presumption extends to the antitrust setting. See infra Part II.B.4.a.
  • 87
    • 78651312142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d at 1068
    • Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d at 1068.
  • 88
    • 78651325981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The court, like the ALJ, found that the settlement payments were not payments for delay but characterized them as bona fide side deals. Id. at 1070
    • The court, like the ALJ, found that the settlement payments were not payments for delay but characterized them as bona fide side deals. Id. at 1070.
  • 89
    • 78651318840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 421 F.3d 1227 (11th Cir. 2005)
    • 421 F.3d 1227 (11th Cir. 2005).
  • 90
    • 78651287923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1235
    • Id. at 1235.
  • 91
    • 78651302267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 92
    • 78651267319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 466 F.3d 187 (2d Cir. 2006)
    • 466 F.3d 187 (2d Cir. 2006).
  • 93
    • 78651293159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 190
    • Id. at 190.
  • 94
    • 78651343367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 194
    • Id. at 194.
  • 95
    • 78651269016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Under today's law, if an ANDA filer fails to actually market the generic drug widiin a given period of time, it forfeits the exclusivity period. See supra notes 29-31 and accompanying text
    • Id. Under today's law, if an ANDA filer fails to actually market the generic drug widiin a given period of time, it forfeits the exclusivity period. See supra notes 29-31 and accompanying text.
  • 96
    • 78651313656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 195
    • Id. at 195.
  • 97
    • 78651300714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Much of the anticompetitive effect of the tamoxifen settlement is a result of the law as it stood at the time, which allowed the parties to obtain vacatur for the finding of patent invalidity and allowed Barr to maintain the 180-day exclusivity period without using it. Under this law, holding the exclusivity without using it prevented other generic drug manufacturers from entering the market indefinitely, creating a bottleneck through which other generic manufacturers could not pass. To the extent that the courts' decisions rest on these other anticompetitive effects, they are not direcdy relevant here; however, in holding that the plaintiffs had not stated an antitrust cause of action, they necessarily include analyses of the reverse-payment element of the case. See Bruce H. Kobayashi, An Economic Analysis of Relitigation Rules in Intellectual Property Litigation (Apr. 21, 2010) (unpublished manuscript), http://www.law.northwestern.edu/searlecenter/uploads/Kobayashi-Relitigation- Final.pdf.
  • 98
    • 78651263860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 277 F. Supp. 2d 121, 128-29 (E.D.N.Y. 2003), aff'd, 466 F.3d 187
    • In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 277 F. Supp. 2d 121, 128-29 (E.D.N.Y. 2003), aff'd, 466 F.3d 187.
  • 99
    • 78651322556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tamoxifen, 466 F.3d at 199
    • Tamoxifen, 466 F.3d at 199.
  • 100
    • 78651325301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 203 (citing Whitmore ex rel. Simmons v. Arkansas, 495 U.S. 149 (1990) (holding that one death-row inmate does not have standing to challenge the execution of another))
    • Id. at 203 (citing Whitmore ex rel. Simmons v. Arkansas, 495 U.S. 149 (1990) (holding that one death-row inmate does not have standing to challenge the execution of another)).
  • 101
    • 78651292741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 208 (quoting Brief for Plaintiffs Appellants at 15, Tamoxifen, 466 F.3d 187 (No. 03-7641), 2004 WL 3564422) (internal quotation marks omitted)
    • Id. at 208 (quoting Brief for Plaintiffs Appellants at 15, Tamoxifen, 466 F.3d 187 (No. 03-7641), 2004 WL 3564422) (internal quotation marks omitted).
  • 102
    • 78651344852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 103
    • 78651334887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 210
    • Id. at 210.
  • 104
    • 78651309045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 206 ("Heeding the advice of several courts and commentators, we decline to conclude (and repeat that the plaintiffs do not ask us to conclude) that reverse payments are per se violations of the Sherman Act ⋯.")
    • Id. at 206 ("Heeding the advice of several courts and commentators, we decline to conclude (and repeat that the plaintiffs do not ask us to conclude) that reverse payments are per se violations of the Sherman Act ⋯.").
  • 105
    • 78651295899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 213-14. Judge Pooler dissents from the Second Circuit's Tamoxifen ruling. She does not directly endorse a different analysis of reverse payments but argues that the court improperly dismissed the case by granting too much deference to the patent invalidated by the district court and failing to allow discovery on the conspiracy and injuries alleged by plaintiffs. Id. at 224 (Pooler, J., dissenting)
    • Id. at 213-14. Judge Pooler dissents from the Second Circuit's Tamoxifen ruling. She does not directly endorse a different analysis of reverse payments but argues that the court improperly dismissed the case by granting too much deference to the patent invalidated by the district court and failing to allow discovery on the conspiracy and injuries alleged by plaintiffs. Id. at 224 (Pooler, J., dissenting).
  • 106
    • 78651317982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 604 F.3d 98, 106 (2d Cir. 2010) (per curiam)
    • 604 F.3d 98, 106 (2d Cir. 2010) (per curiam).
  • 107
    • 78651335138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 108
    • 78651343366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 109
    • 78651298109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 110
    • See id. at 110.
  • 110
    • 78651278881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scholars, too, have sought ways to dispose of reverse-payment cases without extensive litigation. However, while scholars have identified potential shortcuts to identify the competitive nature of reverse payments, courts have tended to adopt standards that require no close examination of reverse payments' competitive effects
    • Scholars, too, have sought ways to dispose of reverse-payment cases without extensive litigation. However, while scholars have identified potential shortcuts to identify the competitive nature of reverse payments, courts have tended to adopt standards that require no close examination of reverse payments' competitive effects.
  • 111
    • 78651269425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 34-54 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 34-54 and accompanying text.
  • 112
    • 78651340637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B.2 (discussing how the Schering-Plough and Tamoxifen courts looked only at whether the effects of the settlements extended beyond the time period covered by the patents). On the one side, Cardizem and Terazosin make it easy to stop a reverse payment with relatively little analysis; on the other, Schering-Plough and Tamoxifen make it difficult to demonstrate that a reverse-payment settlement has unlawful anticompetitive effects
    • See supra Part II.B.2 (discussing how the Schering-Plough and Tamoxifen courts looked only at whether the effects of the settlements extended beyond the time period covered by the patents). On the one side, Cardizem and Terazosin make it easy to stop a reverse payment with relatively little analysis; on the other, Schering-Plough and Tamoxifen make it difficult to demonstrate that a reverse-payment settlement has unlawful anticompetitive effects.
  • 113
    • 78651306063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc., v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977)
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc., v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977).
  • 114
    • 78651301843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 49-50
    • Id. at 49-50.
  • 115
    • 78651311277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 50 n.16
    • Id. at 50 n.16.
  • 116
    • 78651330075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 19-20 (1979)
    • Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 19-20 (1979).
  • 117
    • 78651345705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clamp-All Corp. v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Inst., 851 F.2d 478, 486 (1st Cir. 1988) (Breyer, J)
    • Clamp-All Corp. v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Inst., 851 F.2d 478, 486 (1st Cir. 1988) (Breyer, J).
  • 118
    • 78651315839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cont'l T.V., 433 U.S. at 49
    • Cont'l T.V., 433 U.S. at 49.
  • 119
    • 78651268172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 120
    • 78651330076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 50
    • Id. at 50.
  • 121
    • 78651333233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We argue below that because the procompetitive and anticompetitive effects of reverse payments are neither clear nor consistent, the rule of reason is the appropriate analysis in such cases. See infra Part III
    • We argue below that because the procompetitive and anticompetitive effects of reverse payments are neither clear nor consistent, the rule of reason is the appropriate analysis in such cases. See infra Part III.
  • 122
    • 78651269015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough Corp., Docket No. 9297, slip op. at 96 (F.T.C. June 27, 2002), ("[B]ecause an agreement to settle patent litigation must be examined in the context in which the agreement arose, the per se approach is not appropriate."), rev'd, 136 F.T.C. 956 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005)
    • Schering-Plough Corp., Docket No. 9297, slip op. at 96 (F.T.C. June 27, 2002), http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9297/020627id ("[B]ecause an agreement to settle patent litigation must be examined in the context in which the agreement arose, the per se approach is not appropriate."), rev'd, 136 F.T.C. 956 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005).
  • 123
    • 78651268173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 124
    • 78651283584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough, 136 F.T.C. at 988
    • Schering-Plough, 136 F.T.C. at 988.
  • 125
    • 78651322140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d 1056. Instead, it subjected the settlement to an analysis of the exclusionary power of the patent and found that because the settlement was within the bounds of the patent, it thus was not subject to antitrust scrutiny. See supra notes 82-88 and accompanying text
    • Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d 1056. Instead, it subjected the settlement to an analysis of the exclusionary power of the patent and found that because the settlement was within the bounds of the patent, it thus was not subject to antitrust scrutiny. See supra notes 82-88 and accompanying text.
  • 126
    • 78651276089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 544 F.3d 1323, 1327 (Fed. Cir. 2008)
    • 544 F.3d 1323, 1327 (Fed. Cir. 2008).
  • 127
    • 78651264728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 363 F. Supp. 2d 514, 541 (E.D.N.Y. 2005), aff'd in part, 544 F.3d 1323, and aff'd in part sub nom. Ark. Carpenters Health & Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG, 604 F.3d 98 (2d Cir.) (per curiam), reh'g en banc denied, Nos. 05-2851-cv(L), 05-2852-cv(CON), 05-2863-v(CON), 2010 WL 3464382 (2d Cir. Sept. 7, 2010)
    • In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 363 F. Supp. 2d 514, 541 (E.D.N.Y. 2005), aff'd in part, 544 F.3d 1323, and aff'd in part sub nom. Ark. Carpenters Health & Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG, 604 F.3d 98 (2d Cir.) (per curiam), reh'g en banc denied, Nos. 05-2851-cv(L), 05-2852-cv(CON), 05-2863-v(CON), 2010 WL 3464382 (2d Cir. Sept. 7, 2010).
  • 128
    • 78651282736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 523 ("The ultimate question - and this is the crux of the matter - is not whether Bayer and Barr had the power to adversely affect competition for ciprofloxacin as a whole, but whether any adverse effects on competition stemming from the Agreements were outside the exclusionary zone of the ⋯ [p]atent. It goes without saying that patents have adverse effects on competition.")
    • Id. at 523 ("The ultimate question - and this is the crux of the matter - is not whether Bayer and Barr had the power to adversely affect competition for ciprofloxacin as a whole, but whether any adverse effects on competition stemming from the Agreements were outside the exclusionary zone of the ⋯ [p]atent. It goes without saying that patents have adverse effects on competition.").
  • 129
    • 78651298960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 535 ("Unless and until the patent is shown to have been procured by fraud, or a suit for its enforcement is shown to be objectively baseless, there is no injury to the market cognizable under existing antitrust law, as long as competition is restrained only within the scope of the patent.")
    • Id. at 535 ("Unless and until the patent is shown to have been procured by fraud, or a suit for its enforcement is shown to be objectively baseless, there is no injury to the market cognizable under existing antitrust law, as long as competition is restrained only within the scope of the patent.").
  • 130
    • 78651276708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ciprofloxacin, 544 F.sd at 1332
    • Ciprofloxacin, 544 F.sd at 1332.
  • 131
    • 78651306489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1332-33
    • Id. at 1332-33.
  • 132
    • 78651301378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Sixth Circuit has held reverse payments to be per se illegal. See supra Part II.B.1 (discussing the Cardizem case). The Federal, Eleventh, and Second Circuits have held that no antitrust scrutiny is available to such settlements. See supra Part II.B (discussing the Terazosin, Schering-Plough, and Ciprofloxacin cases). The Supreme Court has also declined to impose such a consensus. See supra note 33
    • The Sixth Circuit has held reverse payments to be per se illegal. See supra Part II.B.1 (discussing the Cardizem case). The Federal, Eleventh, and Second Circuits have held that no antitrust scrutiny is available to such settlements. See supra Part II.B (discussing the Terazosin, Schering-Plough, and Ciprofloxacin cases). The Supreme Court has also declined to impose such a consensus. See supra note 33.
  • 133
    • 78651282123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 402 F.3d 1056, 1067 (11th Cir. 2005)
    • 402 F.3d 1056, 1067 (11th Cir. 2005).
  • 134
    • 0038159320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, Mark Janis & Mark A. Lemley, Anticompetitive Settlement of Intellectual Property Disputes, 87 MINN. L. REV. 1719, 1725 (2003) ("[T]hese cases should be decided on IP grounds because the agreements ⋯ are pro-competitive if, but only if, the patent in question is valid and infringed.")
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, Mark Janis & Mark A. Lemley, Anticompetitive Settlement of Intellectual Property Disputes, 87 MINN. L. REV. 1719, 1725 (2003) ("[T]hese cases should be decided on IP grounds because the agreements ⋯ are pro-competitive if, but only if, the patent in question is valid and infringed.").
  • 135
    • 78651337639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 466 F.3d 187, 203 (2d Cir. 2006) ("We cannot judge this post-trial, pre-appeal settlement on the basis of the likelihood vel non of [the patent holder's] success had it not settled but rather pursued its appeal.")
    • See, e.g., In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 466 F.3d 187, 203 (2d Cir. 2006) ("We cannot judge this post-trial, pre-appeal settlement on the basis of the likelihood vel non of [the patent holder's] success had it not settled but rather pursued its appeal.").
  • 136
    • 78651272143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d at 1067
    • Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d at 1067.
  • 137
    • 78651325299 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (quoting Simpson v. Union Oil Co. of Cal., 377 U.S. 13, 24 (1964)). In their original context, Justice Douglas used these phrases to distinguish the non-patent price fixing at hand from a 1920s case in which the court allowed General Electric to fix the price of light bulbs, a good for which it then held an active patent. See United States v. Gen. Elec. Co., 272 U.S. 476 (1926) (involving no challenge to General Electric's patent and no administrative scheme to encourage such a challenge)
    • Id. (quoting Simpson v. Union Oil Co. of Cal., 377 U.S. 13, 24 (1964)). In their original context, Justice Douglas used these phrases to distinguish the non-patent price fixing at hand from a 1920s case in which the court allowed General Electric to fix the price of light bulbs, a good for which it then held an active patent. See United States v. Gen. Elec. Co., 272 U.S. 476 (1926) (involving no challenge to General Electric's patent and no administrative scheme to encourage such a challenge).
  • 138
    • 78651273585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 544 F.3d 1323, 1337 (Fed. Cir. 2008)
    • See, e.g., In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 544 F.3d 1323, 1337 (Fed. Cir. 2008).
  • 139
    • 78651295074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 35 U.S.C. § 282 (2006)
    • 35 U.S.C. § 282 (2006).
  • 140
    • 78651274839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 544 F.3d at 1328-34
    • 544 F.3d at 1328-34.
  • 141
    • 78651275660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1333 ("The district court did not treat the Agreements as per se legal. Rather, the court simply recognized that any adverse anti-competitive effects within the scope of the ⋯ patent could not be redressed by antitrust law.")
    • Id. at 1333 ("The district court did not treat the Agreements as per se legal. Rather, the court simply recognized that any adverse anti-competitive effects within the scope of the ⋯ patent could not be redressed by antitrust law.").
  • 142
    • 78651300715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 143
    • 78651325743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Id. at 1337 ("We disagree that analysis of patent validity is appropriate in the absence of fraud or sham litigation. Pursuant to statute, a patent is presumed to be valid, 35 U.S.C. § 282, and patent law bestows the patent holder with 'the right to exclude others from profiting by the patented invention.'" (quoting Dawson Chem. Co. v. Rohm & Haas Co., 448 U.S. 176, 215 (1980))); see also Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, 1066 (11th Cir. 2005) ("[T]he Patent Act essentially provides the patent owner 'with what amounts to a permissible monopoly over the patented work.'" (quoting Telecom Technical Servs. Inc. v. Rolm Co., 388 F.3d 820, 828 (11th Cir. 2004))).
  • 144
    • 78651325300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 466 F.3d 187, 208-09, 209 n.22 (2d Cir. 2005); Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d at 1066
    • See, e.g., In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 466 F.3d 187, 208-09, 209 n.22 (2d Cir. 2005); Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d at 1066.
  • 145
    • 78651267720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g.. Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 283 U.S. 163, 169 (1931)
    • See, e.g.. Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 283 U.S. 163, 169 (1931).
  • 146
    • 78651264305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is important to note that the exclusionary right granted by a patent does not have the same meaning as the antitrust term "monopoly." Just because a patent grants a right to exclude does not mean that the patent holder is protected from antitrust scrutiny. See I11. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28, 37-42 (2006) (distinguishing between a patent and market power - where antitrust scrutiny requires a showing of market power, the presence of a patent does not lead to a presumption that market power exists)
    • It is important to note that the exclusionary right granted by a patent does not have the same meaning as the antitrust term "monopoly." Just because a patent grants a right to exclude does not mean that the patent holder is protected from antitrust scrutiny. See I11. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28, 37-42 (2006) (distinguishing between a patent and market power - where antitrust scrutiny requires a showing of market power, the presence of a patent does not lead to a presumption that market power exists).
  • 147
    • 78651275659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 544 F.3d at 1337 (citing Tamoxifen, 466 F.3d at 208-09). "[T]he essence of the Agreements was to exclude the defendants from profiting from the patented invention." Id. at 1333
    • 544 F.3d at 1337 (citing Tamoxifen, 466 F.3d at 208-09). "[T]he essence of the Agreements was to exclude the defendants from profiting from the patented invention." Id. at 1333.
  • 148
    • 78651276707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Indep. Ink, 547 U.S. at 32-33 (noting that the Federal Circuit upheld the respondent's illegal tying claim, suggesting its patent gave it a monopoly over how it was used)
    • Cf. Indep. Ink, 547 U.S. at 32-33 (noting that the Federal Circuit upheld the respondent's illegal tying claim, suggesting its patent gave it a monopoly over how it was used).
  • 149
    • 78651324875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Recent Cases, Patents - Presumed Validity of Defendant's Patent Relied On as Indicating Noninfringement, 63 HARV. L. REV. 1437, 1460-61 (1950)
    • See Recent Cases, Patents - Presumed Validity of Defendant's Patent Relied On as Indicating Noninfringement, 63 HARV. L. REV. 1437, 1460-61 (1950);
  • 150
    • 78651329193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Lucy Grace Dearce, Deconstructing and Recalibrating the Valley Drug Analysis of Reverse Payments, 47 IDEA 587, 588 (2007) ("While the exclusionary power of a patent cannot be ignored, the courts have improperly presumed infringement and overextended the presumption of validity of a patent merely because one exists.")
    • see also Lucy Grace Dearce, Deconstructing and Recalibrating the Valley Drug Analysis of Reverse Payments, 47 IDEA 587, 588 (2007) ("While the exclusionary power of a patent cannot be ignored, the courts have improperly presumed infringement and overextended the presumption of validity of a patent merely because one exists.").
  • 151
    • 78651292277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 713 F.2d 1530, 1534 (Fed. Cir. 1983)
    • 713 F.2d 1530, 1534 (Fed. Cir. 1983).
  • 152
    • 78651294536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 153
    • 78651291193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1534 n.4; see also Lucent Techs., Inc. v. Gateway, Inc., 580 F.3d 1301, 1321-28 (Fed. Cir. 2009); Manville Sales Corp. v. Paramount Sys., Inc., 917 F.2d 544, 553 (Fed. Cir. 1990)
    • Id. at 1534 n.4; see also Lucent Techs., Inc. v. Gateway, Inc., 580 F.3d 1301, 1321-28 (Fed. Cir. 2009); Manville Sales Corp. v. Paramount Sys., Inc., 917 F.2d 544, 553 (Fed. Cir. 1990).
  • 154
    • 78651271736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Were the language of § 282 clear in its applicability or inapplicability to various proceedings, the title of the chapter would be irrelevant. But here, where there is ambiguity as to the application of the statutory text, the chapter's title may guide interpretation of the statute. See INS v. Nat'l Ctr. for Immigrants' Rights, Inc., 502 U.S. 183, 189 (1991) ("[T]he title of a statute or section can aid in resolving an ambiguity in the legislation's text.")
    • Were the language of § 282 clear in its applicability or inapplicability to various proceedings, the title of the chapter would be irrelevant. But here, where there is ambiguity as to the application of the statutory text, the chapter's title may guide interpretation of the statute. See INS v. Nat'l Ctr. for Immigrants' Rights, Inc., 502 U.S. 183, 189 (1991) ("[T]he title of a statute or section can aid in resolving an ambiguity in the legislation's text.").
  • 155
    • 78651271737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Stratoflex, 713 F.2d at 1534 ("The presumption, like all legal presumptions, is a procedural device, not substantive law. It ⋯ require [s] the decisionmaker to employ a decisional approach that starts with acceptance of the patent claims as valid and that looks to the challenger for proof of the contrary.")
    • See, e.g., Stratoflex, 713 F.2d at 1534 ("The presumption, like all legal presumptions, is a procedural device, not substantive law. It ⋯ require [s] the decisionmaker to employ a decisional approach that starts with acceptance of the patent claims as valid and that looks to the challenger for proof of the contrary.").
  • 156
    • 78651272142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 283 U.S. 163, 174-75 (1931)
    • 283 U.S. 163, 174-75 (1931).
  • 157
    • 78651290762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 168
    • Id. at 168.
  • 158
    • 78651332783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 159
    • 78651333645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 174-75
    • Id. at 174-75.
  • 160
    • 78651285326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 161
    • 78651273021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 175-76
    • Id. at 175-76.
  • 162
    • 78651270920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 169." [T]he necessary effect of patent interchange agreements, and the operations under them, must be carefully examined in order to determine whether violations of the Act result." Id. at 169-70
    • Id. at 169." [T]he necessary effect of patent interchange agreements, and the operations under them, must be carefully examined in order to determine whether violations of the Act result." Id. at 169-70.
  • 163
    • 78651333231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 168-69
    • Id. at 168-69.
  • 164
    • 78651309899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 756 F.2d 852, 855-56 (Fed. Cir. 1985)
    • 756 F.2d 852, 855-56 (Fed. Cir. 1985).
  • 165
    • 78651325741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 166
    • 78651297156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 856
    • Id. at 856.
  • 167
    • 78651329192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, 1066 (11th Cir. 2005); In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 466 F.3d 187, 209 n.22 (2d Cir. 2005)
    • See, e.g., Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, 1066 (11th Cir. 2005); In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 466 F.3d 187, 209 n.22 (2d Cir. 2005).
  • 168
    • 78651288343 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 930 F.2d 867, 868 (Fed. Cir. 1991)
    • 930 F.2d 867, 868 (Fed. Cir. 1991).
  • 169
    • 78651282735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 869
    • Id. at 869.
  • 170
    • 78651330938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 171
    • 78651269424 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 869 (citations omitted); see also Amazon.com, Inc. v. barnesandnoble.com, Inc., 239 F.3d 1343, 1359 (Fed. Cir. 2001) ("When moving for the extraordinary relief of a preliminary injunction, a patentee ⋯ must ⋯ present a clear case supporting the validity of the patent in suit."); Reebok Int'l Ltd. v. J. Baker, Inc., 32 F.3d 1552, 1555-56 (Fed. Cir. 1994) ("A movant seeking a preliminary injunction must establish a reasonable likelihood of success on the merits both with respect to validity and infringement of its patent.")
    • Id. at 869 (citations omitted); see also Amazon.com, Inc. v. barnesandnoble.com, Inc., 239 F.3d 1343, 1359 (Fed. Cir. 2001) ("When moving for the extraordinary relief of a preliminary injunction, a patentee ⋯ must ⋯ present a clear case supporting the validity of the patent in suit."); Reebok Int'l Ltd. v. J. Baker, Inc., 32 F.3d 1552, 1555-56 (Fed. Cir. 1994) ("A movant seeking a preliminary injunction must establish a reasonable likelihood of success on the merits both with respect to validity and infringement of its patent.").
  • 172
    • 78651305634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977) ("The traditional framework of analysis under § 1 of the Sherman Act is familiar and does not require extended discussion ⋯. Under [the rule of reason], the factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition.")
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977) ("The traditional framework of analysis under § 1 of the Sherman Act is familiar and does not require extended discussion ⋯. Under [the rule of reason], the factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition.").
  • 173
    • 78651330494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 49-50
    • Id. at 49-50.
  • 174
    • 78651312577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 175
    • 78651311276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5 (1958)
    • N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5 (1958).
  • 176
    • 78651314526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see In re Terazosin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 352 F. Supp. 2d 1279 (S.D. Fla. 2005)
    • But see In re Terazosin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 352 F. Supp. 2d 1279 (S.D. Fla. 2005).
  • 177
    • 78651293158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Gordon v. Lewistown Hosp., 423 F.3d 184, 210 (3d Cir. 2005) ("[T]he competitive harm is presumed and the defendant must set forth some competitive justification for the restraints.")
    • See, e.g., Gordon v. Lewistown Hosp., 423 F.3d 184, 210 (3d Cir. 2005) ("[T]he competitive harm is presumed and the defendant must set forth some competitive justification for the restraints.").
  • 178
    • 78651284919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756, 770 (1999)
    • Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756, 770 (1999).
  • 179
    • 78651303968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 544 F.3d 1323, 1332-36 (Fed. Cir. 2008) (giving an example of a court's hinting toward a more nuanced rule of reason analysis)
    • See In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 544 F.3d 1323, 1332-36 (Fed. Cir. 2008) (giving an example of a court's hinting toward a more nuanced rule of reason analysis).
  • 180
    • 78651264727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Brief for the United States, supra note 8
    • See Brief for the United States, supra note 8.
  • 181
    • 77749261898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Steven Seidenberg, The Flip Side of "Reverse Payments," A.B.A. J., Feb. 1, 2010, at 17, 18
    • See Steven Seidenberg, The Flip Side of "Reverse Payments," A.B.A. J., Feb. 1, 2010, at 17, 18;
  • 182
    • 78651302266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Helen Cho Eckert, DOJ Formally Aligns Itself with FTC in Opposition To Reverse Payment Settlements, ANTITRUST L. BLOG (Aug. 12, 2009)
    • see also Helen Cho Eckert, DOJ Formally Aligns Itself with FTC in Opposition To Reverse Payment Settlements, ANTITRUST L. BLOG (Aug. 12, 2009), http://www.antitrustlawblog.com/2009/08/articles/doj-formally-aligns-itself- with-ftc-in-opposition-to-reverse-payment-settlements/.
  • 183
    • 78651323159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 21-27
    • Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 21-27.
  • 184
    • 78651302671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Press Release, FTC, FTC Chairman Leibowitz: Eliminating "Pay-for-Delay" Pharmaceutical Settlements Would Save Consumers $3.5 Billion Annually (June 23, 2009)
    • See Press Release, FTC, FTC Chairman Leibowitz: Eliminating "Pay-for-Delay" Pharmaceutical Settlements Would Save Consumers $3.5 Billion Annually (June 23, 2009), http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2009/06/ capspeech.shtm.
  • 185
    • 78651295072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 9
    • Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 9.
  • 186
    • 78651314109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 9-10. This point is well supported. Nearly all courts have been willing to submit reverse payments to some level of antitrust scrutiny. But see In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust litig., 466 F.3d 187, 208 (2d Cir. 2006) ("[S]o long as the patent litigation is neither a sham nor otherwise baseless, the patent holder is seeking to arrive at a settlement in order to protect that to which it is presumably entitled: a lawful monopoly ⋯")
    • Id. at 9-10. This point is well supported. Nearly all courts have been willing to submit reverse payments to some level of antitrust scrutiny. But see In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust litig., 466 F.3d 187, 208 (2d Cir. 2006) ("[S]o long as the patent litigation is neither a sham nor otherwise baseless, the patent holder is seeking to arrive at a settlement in order to protect that to which it is presumably entitled: a lawful monopoly ⋯").
  • 187
    • 78651302265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 14. The economic theories presented in Part I do not necessarily go against this assumption, but each theory balances the sides differently. For example, Shapiro believes the intent is that any agreement that makes consumers worse off than they otherwise would have been violates the law. See infra note 233 and accompanying text
    • Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 14. The economic theories presented in Part I do not necessarily go against this assumption, but each theory balances the sides differently. For example, Shapiro believes the intent is that any agreement that makes consumers worse off than they otherwise would have been violates the law. See infra note 233 and accompanying text.
  • 188
    • 78651340636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The argument is drawn from the scholarship of Professor Carl Shapiro. See infra notes 233-44 and accompanying text
    • The argument is drawn from the scholarship of Professor Carl Shapiro. See infra notes 233-44 and accompanying text.
  • 189
    • 78651327689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 9-10
    • Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 9-10.
  • 190
    • 78651306061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The DOJ concedes that reverse-payment settlements may, in some cases, be procompetitive and so should not be condemned by a per se rule. Id. at 20-21 (citing NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 103-04 (1984))
    • The DOJ concedes that reverse-payment settlements may, in some cases, be procompetitive and so should not be condemned by a per se rule. Id. at 20-21 (citing NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 103-04 (1984)).
  • 191
    • 78651275657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 22. "Absent another explanation for it, such a payment is naturally viewed as consideration for the generic's agreement to delay entry beyond the point that would otherwise reflect the parties' shared view of the likelihood that the patentee would ultimately prevail in the litigation." Id. For an argument that reverse payments are not clearly (or "naturally") procompetitive or anticompetitive, see infra Part III
    • Id. at 22. "Absent another explanation for it, such a payment is naturally viewed as consideration for the generic's agreement to delay entry beyond the point that would otherwise reflect the parties' shared view of the likelihood that the patentee would ultimately prevail in the litigation." Id. For an argument that reverse payments are not clearly (or "naturally") procompetitive or anticompetitive, see infra Part III.
  • 192
    • 78651303516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 26
    • Id. at 26.
  • 193
    • 78651317562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 17 n.4 ("[W]e assume throughout that the patented drug at issue lacks substantial competition from other, non-infringing, products so that the patent holder has monopoly power ⋯. While a large reverse payment may strongly suggest such power, market power cannot be presumed to follow from the existence of a patent, but must be proven.")
    • Id. at 17 n.4 ("[W]e assume throughout that the patented drug at issue lacks substantial competition from other, non-infringing, products so that the patent holder has monopoly power ⋯. While a large reverse payment may strongly suggest such power, market power cannot be presumed to follow from the existence of a patent, but must be proven.").
  • 194
    • 78651267719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 30-31
    • Id. at 30-31.
  • 195
    • 78651325740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 31
    • Id. at 31.
  • 196
    • 78651298959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See, e.g., Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756 (1999) (reversing an application of the quick look rule of reason to restrictions on price and quality claims in advertising); NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 109 (1984) (stating that "no elaborate industry analysis is required to demonstrate the anticompetitive character or naked restrictions on competition (quoting Nat'l Soc'y of Prof'l Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 692 (1978)) (internal quotation marks omitted)); N. Tex. Specialty Physicians v. FTC, 528 F.3d 346 (5th Cir. 2008) (quick look as an appropriate analysis for price-fixing scheme), cert. denied, 129 S. Ct. 1313 (2009).
  • 197
    • 78651280461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cal. Dental Ass'n, 526 U.S. at 770, 776; see supra Part II.B.4.b (discussing quick look analysis)
    • Cal. Dental Ass'n, 526 U.S. at 770, 776; see supra Part II.B.4.b (discussing quick look analysis).
  • 198
    • 78651289903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 429 F.3d 370, 392 (2d Cir. 2005), amended by 466 F.3d 187 (2d Cir. 2006)
    • In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 429 F.3d 370, 392 (2d Cir. 2005), amended by 466 F.3d 187 (2d Cir. 2006).
  • 199
    • 0037982803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James Langenfeld & Wenqing Li, Intellectual Property and Agreements To Settle Patent Disputes: The Case of Settlement Agreements with Payments from Branded to Generic Drug Manufacturers, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 777, 778 (2003)
    • James Langenfeld & Wenqing Li, Intellectual Property and Agreements To Settle Patent Disputes: The Case of Settlement Agreements with Payments from Branded to Generic Drug Manufacturers, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 777, 778 (2003).
  • 200
    • 78651319622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 778-801
    • Id. at 778-801.
  • 201
    • 78651335574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 202
    • 78651305633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Asahi Glass Co. v. Pentech Pharm., Inc., 289 F. Supp. 2d 986, 994 (N.D. I11. 2003) ("A ban on reverse-payment settlements would reduce the incentive to challenge patents by reducing the challenger's settlement options should he be sued for infringement, and so might well be thought anticompetitive.")
    • See Asahi Glass Co. v. Pentech Pharm., Inc., 289 F. Supp. 2d 986, 994 (N.D. I11. 2003) ("A ban on reverse-payment settlements would reduce the incentive to challenge patents by reducing the challenger's settlement options should he be sued for infringement, and so might well be thought anticompetitive.").
  • 203
    • 78651319621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Hatch-Waxman Act presents a special incentive for patent holders to attempt to reach settlements with alleged infringers. If the patent holder can delay the first ANDA filer, other generic manufacturers will face lesser incentives to attempt to enter the same market because the 180-day exclusivity period will not be available to them. See Hatch-Waxman Act, 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv)(2006)
    • The Hatch-Waxman Act presents a special incentive for patent holders to attempt to reach settlements with alleged infringers. If the patent holder can delay the first ANDA filer, other generic manufacturers will face lesser incentives to attempt to enter the same market because the 180-day exclusivity period will not be available to them. See Hatch-Waxman Act, 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv)(2006).
  • 204
    • 0043246455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Limits to Patent Settlements, 34 RAND J. ECON. 391, 397-99 (2003)
    • See Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Limits to Patent Settlements, 34 RAND J. ECON. 391, 397-99 (2003);
  • 205
    • 78651280851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Robert J. Rhee, A Price Theory of Legal Bargaining: An Inquiry into the Selection of Settlement and Litigation Under Uncertainty, 56 EMORY L.J. 619, 620-21 (2006) (describing the "conventional wisdom" that settlement terms are primarily determined by the damages expected and each side's probability of prevailing)
    • see also Robert J. Rhee, A Price Theory of Legal Bargaining: An Inquiry into the Selection of Settlement and Litigation Under Uncertainty, 56 EMORY L.J. 619, 620-21 (2006) (describing the "conventional wisdom" that settlement terms are primarily determined by the damages expected and each side's probability of prevailing).
  • 206
    • 78651312576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A settlement is more likely to occur at the end of discovery, at which point the parties will have as much information as possible regarding their chances of prevailing at trial
    • A settlement is more likely to occur at the end of discovery, at which point the parties will have as much information as possible regarding their chances of prevailing at trial.
  • 207
    • 78651333644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because the Hatch-Waxman Act automatically precludes the generic manufacturer from entering the market for thirty months after filing a patent-infringement suit, negotiated entry during this time is unlikely because even a patent holder that does not believe it will prevail at trial could maintain its exclusivity for these thirty months
    • Because the Hatch-Waxman Act automatically precludes the generic manufacturer from entering the market for thirty months after filing a patent-infringement suit, negotiated entry during this time is unlikely because even a patent holder that does not believe it will prevail at trial could maintain its exclusivity for these thirty months.
  • 208
    • 78651323157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This presumption may not be valid in all circumstances. See infra Part III.C.5 (discussing the decreased marketing efforts by a patent holder after a generic entry)
    • This presumption may not be valid in all circumstances. See infra Part III.C.5 (discussing the decreased marketing efforts by a patent holder after a generic entry).
  • 209
    • 78651310878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shapiro, supra note 202, at 407-08
    • See Shapiro, supra note 202, at 407-08.
  • 210
    • 78651277126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Before generic entry, the brand's profits from a drug can be large because of its ability to restrict output and raise prices. See Figure 3. Once the generic enters, much of the market shifts away from the brand to the generic
    • Before generic entry, the brand's profits from a drug can be large because of its ability to restrict output and raise prices. See Figure 3. Once the generic enters, much of the market shifts away from the brand to the generic.
  • 211
    • 78651314523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This possibility motivates a recently proposed bill. See infra note 313 and accompanying text
    • This possibility motivates a recently proposed bill. See infra note 313 and accompanying text.
  • 212
    • 78651286242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bethany McLean, A Bitter Pill, FORTUNE, Aug. 13, 2001
    • Bethany McLean, A Bitter Pill, FORTUNE, Aug. 13, 2001, available at http://money.cnn.com/magazines/fortune/fortune-archive/2001/08/13/308077/index. htm.
  • 213
    • 78651295491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sumanth Addanki & Alan J. Daskin, Patent Settlement Agreements, in 3 ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, ISSUES IN COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY 2127, 2131 (2008)
    • Sumanth Addanki & Alan J. Daskin, Patent Settlement Agreements, in 3 ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, ISSUES IN COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY 2127, 2131 (2008).
  • 214
    • 78651330935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 215
    • 78651334886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 216
    • 78651298957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV.A for our proposed methods of determining whether a given reverse-payment settlement is procompetitive or anticompetitive
    • See infra Part IV.A for our proposed methods of determining whether a given reverse-payment settlement is procompetitive or anticompetitive.
  • 217
    • 78651295492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Addanki & Daskin, supra note 210, at 2131
    • See, e.g., Addanki & Daskin, supra note 210, at 2131.
  • 218
    • 78651312139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This context can only apply to reverse payments of a certain magnitude. For example, a reverse payment that is more than the generic could make by entering the market cannot be compensation for a shift in the risk assumed
    • This context can only apply to reverse payments of a certain magnitude. For example, a reverse payment that is more than the generic could make by
  • 219
    • 78651300292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Addanki & Daskin, supra note 210, at 2130-31
    • Addanki & Daskin, supra note 210, at 2130-31.
  • 220
    • 78651297153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1758
    • See Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1758.
  • 221
    • 78651306060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying note 279
    • See infra text accompanying note 279.
  • 222
    • 78651286677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Gregory K. Leonard & Rika Onishi Mortimer, Antitrust Implications of Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation Settlements, in NERA ECON. CONSULTING, ECONOMIC APPROACHES TO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY POLICY, LITIGATION, AND MANAGEMENT 251, 261-64 (Gregory K. Leonard & Lauren J. Stiroh eds., 2005)
    • See, e.g., Gregory K. Leonard & Rika Onishi Mortimer, Antitrust Implications of Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation Settlements, in NERA ECON. CONSULTING, ECONOMIC APPROACHES TO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY POLICY, LITIGATION, AND MANAGEMENT 251, 261-64 (Gregory K. Leonard & Lauren J. Stiroh eds., 2005).
  • 223
    • 78651264304 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 264 ("[A] settlement that is consumer welfare reducing may nevertheless be social welfare enhancing.")
    • See id. at 264 ("[A] settlement that is consumer welfare reducing may nevertheless be social welfare enhancing.").
  • 224
    • 78651340033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying Figure 6
    • See infra text accompanying Figure 6.
  • 225
    • 78651314946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leonard & Mortimer, supra note 219, at 261-64
    • Leonard & Mortimer, supra note 219, at 261-64.
  • 226
    • 78651325980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1759
    • See, e.g., Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1759.
  • 227
    • 78651265984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In a well-functioning capital market, an ANDA filer with insufficient resources to pursue a meritorious claim should be able to find financing. In reality, differences in perceptions of the value of the claim may raise the transaction costs of such financing to a prohibitive level
    • In a well-functioning capital market, an ANDA filer with insufficient resources to pursue a meritorious claim should be able to find financing. In reality, differences in perceptions of the value of the claim may raise the transaction costs of such financing to a prohibitive level.
  • 228
    • 78651318837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Leonard & Mortimer, supra note 219, at 257
    • See Leonard & Mortimer, supra note 219, at 257.
  • 229
    • 78651339168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 264 ("We conclude that, with potential disagreements concerning the probability that the plaintiff will win the lawsuit, a settlement may not be feasible without reverse payments.")
    • See id. at 264 ("We conclude that, with potential disagreements concerning the probability that the plaintiff will win the lawsuit, a settlement may not be feasible without reverse payments.").
  • 230
    • 78651294057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 208-09 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 208-09 and accompanying text.
  • 231
    • 78651313397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A settlement, however, that allows entry later than either side's benchmark cannot be explained by these different estimates of chances at trial
    • A settlement, however, that allows entry later than either side's benchmark cannot be explained by these different estimates of chances at trial.
  • 232
    • 78651265986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Keith N. Hylton & Sungjoon Cho, Injunctive and Reverse Settlements in Competition-Blocking Litigation 14 (Bos. Univ. Sch. of Law, Working Paper No. 09-47, 2009)
    • See, e.g., Keith N. Hylton & Sungjoon Cho, Injunctive and Reverse Settlements in Competition-Blocking Litigation 14 (Bos. Univ. Sch. of Law, Working Paper No. 09-47, 2009), available at http://papere.ssm.com/sol3/papers. cfm?abstract-id=1490013.
  • 233
    • 78651315398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Schering-Plough Corp., Docket No. 9297, slip op. at 107 (F.T.C. June 27, 2002), (finding that the side deal was bona fide), rev'd, 136 F.T.C. 956 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005)
    • See Schering-Plough Corp., Docket No. 9297, slip op. at 107 (F.T.C. June 27, 2002), http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9297/020627id.pdf (finding that the side deal was bona fide), rev'd, 136 F.T.C. 956 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005).
  • 234
    • 67249133979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eg., C. Scott Hemphill, An Aggregate Approach to Antitrust: Using New Data and Rulemaking To Preserve Drug Competition, 109 COLUM. L. REV. 629, 633 (2009) ("An aggregate approach ⋯. reveals that these sorts of deals are a frequent component of settlements, but rare outside of settlement. Thus, the overall pattern suggests they provide a disguised means to confer payment"); cf. Schering-Plough, slip op. at 107 (finding that the side deal was bona fide)
    • Eg., C. Scott Hemphill, An Aggregate Approach to Antitrust: Using New Data and Rulemaking To Preserve Drug Competition, 109 COLUM. L. REV. 629, 633 (2009) ("An aggregate approach ⋯. reveals that these sorts of deals are a frequent component of settlements, but rare outside of settlement. Thus, the overall pattern suggests they provide a disguised means to confer payment"); cf. Schering-Plough, slip op. at 107 (finding that the side deal was bona fide).
  • 235
    • 78651332782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hemphill, supra note 231, at 633 (explaining how side deals rarely happen in other contexts)
    • Hemphill, supra note 231, at 633 (explaining how side deals rarely happen in other contexts).
  • 236
    • 78651340635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shapiro, supra note 202, at 391
    • Shapiro, supra note 202, at 391.
  • 237
    • 78651344434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 396. Shapiro defines the phrase "well off" according to the prices paid by consumers for a specific drug. However, because reverse-payment policy balances two worthy goals - keeping drug costs low and encouraging new drug innovation - it is not clear that creating maximum competition in the short term will make consumers the most "well off" in the long term
    • Id. at 396. Shapiro defines the phrase "well off" according to the prices paid by consumers for a specific drug. However, because reverse-payment policy balances two worthy goals - keeping drug costs low and encouraging new drug innovation - it is not clear that creating maximum competition in the short term will make consumers the most "well off" in the long term.
  • 238
    • 78651284044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 393. Shapiro's shift here is subtle. Rights are traditionally found when enforceable, but Shapiro argues that whatever right a patent grants does not reach full strength until actually enforced
    • Id. at 393. Shapiro's shift here is subtle. Rights are traditionally found when enforceable, but Shapiro argues that whatever right a patent grants does not reach full strength until actually enforced.
  • 239
    • 78651263857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 395 ("What the patent grant actually gives the patentholder is the right to sue to prevent others from infringing the patent."). The patent right is imperfect, Shapiro argues, because, inter alia, there are significant costs associated with enforcing a patent. Id
    • Id. at 395 ("What the patent grant actually gives the patentholder is the right to sue to prevent others from infringing the patent."). The patent right is imperfect, Shapiro argues, because, inter alia, there are significant costs associated with enforcing a patent. Id.
  • 240
    • 78651310438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Notably, the existence of patents would seem to go against Shapiro's test. Any legal monopoly will serve to make available drugs more expensive, but the policy we have chosen falls somewhere between absolute competition (cheapest possible drugs) and absolute monopolies (greatest possible incentive to innovate new drugs)
    • Notably, the existence of patents would seem to go against Shapiro's test. Any legal monopoly will serve to make available drugs more expensive, but the policy we have chosen falls somewhere between absolute competition (cheapest possible drugs) and absolute monopolies (greatest possible incentive to innovate new drugs).
  • 241
    • 78651291846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shapiro, supra note 202, at 396
    • See Shapiro, supra note 202, at 396.
  • 242
    • 78651318390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 243
    • 78651334483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 408. Note that the assumption that settlements represent only estimated chances of victory at trial may be unfounded. See supra Part III.C.4
    • Id. at 408. Note that the assumption that settlements represent only estimated chances of victory at trial may be unfounded. See supra Part III.C.4.
  • 244
    • 78651327246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 407-08
    • Id. at 407-08.
  • 245
    • 78651304773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that even with reverse payments, for cases where the generic would not have prevailed at trial, the settlement does increase overall competition, as compared to the outcome had there been a trial
    • Note that even with reverse payments, for cases where the generic would not have prevailed at trial, the settlement does increase overall competition, as compared to the outcome had there been a trial.
  • 246
    • 78651276088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shapiro, supra note 202, at 397
    • Shapiro, supra note 202, at 397.
  • 247
    • 78651283159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 248
    • 78651312140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joshua P. Davis, Applying Litigation Economics to Patent Settlements: Why Reverse Payments Should Be Per Se Illegal, 41 RUTGERS L.J. (forthcoming 2010) (manuscript at 41)
    • Joshua P. Davis, Applying Litigation Economics to Patent Settlements: Why Reverse Payments Should Be Per Se Illegal, 41 RUTGERS L.J. (forthcoming 2010) (manuscript at 41), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1489090.
  • 249
    • 78651273020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 17
    • Id. at 17.
  • 250
    • 78651325297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 7
    • Id. at 7.
  • 251
    • 78651281265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 17
    • Id. at 17.
  • 252
    • 78651278428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 27
    • Id. at 27.
  • 253
    • 78651335136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1720 ("[Patent] settlements involve agreements between the patentee and the accused infringer ⋯. Because these competitors may agree to stop competing ⋯ settlements of IP disputes naturally raise antitrust concerns.")
    • Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1720 ("[Patent] settlements involve agreements between the patentee and the accused infringer ⋯. Because these competitors may agree to stop competing ⋯ settlements of IP disputes naturally raise antitrust concerns.").
  • 254
    • 78651276085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Reverse payments are clearly such a case. Were the patent at issue in the settlement either invalid or not infringed, the agreements not to compete inherent in reverse-payment settlements would be clearly and unreasonably anticompetitive. Id
    • Id. Reverse payments are clearly such a case. Were the patent at issue in the settlement either invalid or not infringed, the agreements not to compete inherent in reverse-payment settlements would be clearly and unreasonably anticompetitive. Id.
  • 255
    • 78651324874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1725
    • Id. at 1725.
  • 256
    • 78651291629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1724
    • Id. at 1724.
  • 257
    • 78651270078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Shapiro, supra note 202 ("If the patent is very strong ⋯ the challenger is unlikely to offer much independent competition to the patentholder if litigation proceeds.")
    • See generally Shapiro, supra note 202 ("If the patent is very strong ⋯ the challenger is unlikely to offer much independent competition to the patentholder if litigation proceeds.").
  • 258
    • 78651274382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1725
    • Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1725.
  • 259
    • 78651294535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1734. "Unfortunately, these inquiries may be the very ones that the settlement agreement itself sought to forestall because of their complexity and uncertainty. That is why it is critical that these inquiries be made no more often than necessary." Id
    • Id. at 1734. "Unfortunately, these inquiries may be the very ones that the settlement agreement itself sought to forestall because of their complexity and uncertainty. That is why it is critical that these inquiries be made no more often than necessary." Id.
  • 260
    • 78651288639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1759
    • Id. at 1759.
  • 261
    • 78651339601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1758-59
    • Id. at 1758-59.
  • 262
    • 78651292275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leonard & Mortimer, supra note 219, at 260-64
    • Leonard & Mortimer, supra note 219, at 260-64.
  • 263
    • 78651269011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 260
    • Id. at 260.
  • 264
    • 78651291189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 261. Leonard and Mortimer also consider the effects that parties' aversion to risk have on reverse-payment settlements. They find that while risk aversion may make parties more likely to engage in a reverse-payment settlement, it does not make that settlement more or less anticompetitive. Id. at 264; see Addanki & Daskin, supra note 210. They argue that a per se rule prohibiting all reverse payments is inappropriate. Instead, reverse payments must be evaluated in context under the rule of reason. Leonard & Mortimer, supra note 219, at 261
    • Id. at 261. Leonard and Mortimer also consider the effects that parties' aversion to risk have on reverse-payment settlements. They find that while risk aversion may make parties more likely to engage in a reverse-payment settlement, it does not make that settlement more or less anticompetitive. Id. at 264; see Addanki & Daskin, supra note 210. They argue that a per se rule prohibiting all reverse payments is inappropriate. Instead, reverse payments must be evaluated in context under the rule of reason. Leonard & Mortimer, supra note 219, at 261.
  • 265
    • 78651269417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1762
    • Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1762.
  • 266
    • 78651314105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 251-55 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 251-55 and accompanying text.
  • 267
    • 78651323156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Daniel A. Crane, Exit Payments in Settlement of Patent Infringement Lawsuits: Antitrust Rules and Economic Implications, 54 FLA. L. REV. 747, 751-52 (2002) (footnote omitted)
    • Daniel A. Crane, Exit Payments in Settlement of Patent Infringement Lawsuits: Antitrust Rules and Economic Implications, 54 FLA. L. REV. 747, 751-52 (2002) (footnote omitted).
  • 268
    • 78651325737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 776 ("The optimal legal position regarding such settlements requires taking into account all of the relevant costs and formulating a rule that harmonizes the competing strands of public policy.")
    • See id. at 776 ("The optimal legal position regarding such settlements requires taking into account all of the relevant costs and formulating a rule that harmonizes the competing strands of public policy.").
  • 269
    • 78651341504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 749 (citing United States v. Singer Mfg. Co., 374 U.S. 174 (1963))
    • See id. at 749 (citing United States v. Singer Mfg. Co., 374 U.S. 174 (1963)).
  • 270
    • 78651322137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 778-79
    • Id. at 778-79.
  • 271
    • 78651270497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 272
    • 78651280850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 344 F.3d 1294, 1307 (11th Cir. 2003) ("Good faith procurement furnishes a complete defense to the antitrust claim.")
    • But see Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 344 F.3d 1294, 1307 (11th Cir. 2003) ("Good faith procurement furnishes a complete defense to the antitrust claim.").
  • 273
    • 78651286675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 264, at 780
    • Crane, supra note 264, at 780.
  • 274
    • 78651291844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 779 ("Courts and antitrust enforcers easily see the costs of permitting the settlement of unmeritorious patent infringement claims - deadweight losses in the form of monopoly pricing dial could be avoided if litigation were required and the patentee's monopolistic claims rejected.")
    • Id. at 779 ("Courts and antitrust enforcers easily see the costs of permitting the settlement of unmeritorious patent infringement claims - deadweight losses in the form of monopoly pricing dial could be avoided if litigation were required and the patentee's monopolistic claims rejected.").
  • 275
    • 78651287491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 782 ("The difficulty is in formulating a way of determining the expected outcome of the lawsuit without requiring a full-blown inquiry into the merits, which would effectively mean the adoption of a no-exit-payment rule.")
    • Id. at 782 ("The difficulty is in formulating a way of determining the expected outcome of the lawsuit without requiring a full-blown inquiry into the merits, which would effectively mean the adoption of a no-exit-payment rule.").
  • 276
    • 78651335971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This Article, too, proposes guidelines for when a court should consider a reverse-payment settlement to be anticompetitive and when it should not. Crane's standards focus on the underlying patent-infringement suit; our standards forego this analysis, which would nullify the value of the settlement, in favor of an examination of the context in which the settlement occurs. See supra Part III
    • This Article, too, proposes guidelines for when a court should consider a reverse-payment settlement to be anticompetitive and when it should not. Crane's standards focus on the underlying patent-infringement suit; our standards forego this analysis, which would nullify the value of the settlement, in favor of an examination of the context in which the settlement occurs. See supra Part III.
  • 277
    • 78651296733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 264, at 779-80
    • Crane, supra note 264, at 779-80.
  • 278
    • 78651275236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 783
    • Id. at 783.
  • 279
    • 78651299409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 785-88
    • Id. at 785-88.
  • 280
    • 78651268167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 792
    • Id. at 792.
  • 281
    • 78651331353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 794-95
    • See id. at 794-95.
  • 282
    • 78651264724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 788
    • Id. at 788.
  • 283
    • 78651341937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Addanki & Daskin, supra note 210, at 2130-32
    • See, e.g., Addanki & Daskin, supra note 210, at 2130-32.
  • 284
    • 78651282732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 264, at 782
    • Crane, supra note 264, at 782.
  • 285
    • 78651274836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 526 U.S. 756 (1999)
    • 526 U.S. 756 (1999).
  • 286
    • 78651328123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 128 F.3d 720, 727-28 (9th Cir. 1997), vacated, 526 U.S. 756
    • 128 F.3d 720, 727-28 (9th Cir. 1997), vacated, 526 U.S. 756.
  • 287
    • 78651333226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cal. Dental Ass'n, 526 U.S. at 774
    • Cal. Dental Ass'n, 526 U.S. at 774.
  • 288
    • 78651316270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 289
    • 78651297152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC, GENERIC DRUG ENTRY PRIOR TO PATENT EXPIRATION: AN FTC STUDY (2002)
    • FTC, GENERIC DRUG ENTRY PRIOR TO PATENT EXPIRATION: AN FTC STUDY (2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/genericdrugstudy.pdf.
  • 290
    • 78651342530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hemphill, supra note 231
    • Hemphill, supra note 231.
  • 291
    • 78651309897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 631
    • Id. at 631.
  • 292
    • 78651322554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 634
    • See id. at 634.
  • 293
    • 78651310436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II (describing the case history of reverse-payment settlements)
    • See supra Part II (describing the case history of reverse-payment settlements).
  • 294
    • 78651277974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • S. 369, 111th Cong. (2009). The U.S. Senate introduced the PAAG bill in February 2009 and placed it on the Senate calendar as item No. 183 by the Senate Judiciary Committee on October 15, 2009. Library of Cong., Bill & Summary Status, THOMAS, (search "S. 369" in "Bill Number" search field; then follow "All Congressional Actions" hyperlink). The House of Representatives has a similar bill, the Protecting Consumer Access to Generic Drugs Act of 2009, H.R. 1706, 111th Cong. (2009), which is still in the House Judiciary Committee
    • S. 369, 111th Cong. (2009). The U.S. Senate introduced the PAAG bill in February 2009 and placed it on the Senate calendar as item No. 183 by the Senate Judiciary Committee on October 15, 2009. Library of Cong., Bill & Summary Status, THOMAS, http://www.thomas.gov (search "S. 369" in "Bill Number" search field; then follow "All Congressional Actions" hyperlink). The House of Representatives has a similar bill, the Protecting Consumer Access to Generic Drugs Act of 2009, H.R. 1706, 111th Cong. (2009), which is still in the House Judiciary Committee.
  • 295
    • 78651339167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 50 (1977)
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 50 (1977).
  • 296
    • 78651329189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5 (1958)
    • N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5 (1958).
  • 297
    • 78651324421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756, 759 (1999)
    • Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756, 759 (1999).
  • 298
    • 78651307754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Other scholars, most notably Crane and Hovenkamp et al., have proposed methods for simplifying the rule of reason inquiry. Unlike the suggestions we present here, Crane and Hovenkamp et al. focus on the strength of the underlying patent-infringement suit Crane argues dial the rule of reason analysis should be guided by the likely outcome of the patent-infringement suit, had it not settled, and provides guidelines for identifying the likely outcome of that case. Crane, supra note 264, at 783. Hovenkamp et al. suggest that a reverse payment must be "no more than the expected value of litigation and collateral costs attending the lawsuit." Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley, supra note 134, at 1759. These methods, focusing on the underlying suit, have a major problem - the outcome of a trial is not knowable without conducting something that closely resembles a trial. Examining the underlying patent-infringement suit in anything other than a cursory way will eliminate the efficiencies that parties hope to gain by settling rather than litigating the underlying suit. Imposing a reexamination of the underlying suit on a settlement would essentially create a per se rule against reverse-payment settlements, simply because parties would have little incentive to settle a case if they will have to litigate the same issues within the context of an antitrust suit.
  • 299
    • 78651340634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Though market power is not a necessary element of a section 1 Sherman Act case, it may be relevant
    • Though market power is not a necessary element of a section 1 Sherman Act case, it may be relevant.
  • 300
    • 78651320048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is not to suggest that market power is a necessary element of an unreasonably anticompetitive agreement. See generally Mark R. Patterson, The Market Power Requirement in Antitrust Rule of Reason Cases: A Rhetorical History, 37 SAN DIEGO L. REV. 1 (2000) (discussing the roles that courts have allowed market power to play in antitrust litigation)
    • This is not to suggest that market power is a necessary element of an unreasonably anticompetitive agreement. See generally Mark R. Patterson, The Market Power Requirement in Antitrust Rule of Reason Cases: A Rhetorical History, 37 SAN DIEGO L. REV. 1 (2000) (discussing the roles that courts have allowed market power to play in antitrust litigation).
  • 301
    • 78651267315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 17 n.4
    • Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 17 n.4.
  • 302
    • 78651317978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 19-20 and accompanying text (discussing ANDA applications and paragraph IV certification)
    • See supra notes 19-20 and accompanying text (discussing ANDA applications and paragraph IV certification).
  • 303
    • 78651300711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 264, at 788
    • Crane, supra note 264, at 788.
  • 304
    • 78651269418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Schering-Plough Corp., 136 F.T.C. 956, 1062 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005)
    • See Schering-Plough Corp., 136 F.T.C. 956, 1062 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005).
  • 305
    • 78651334482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 28
    • See Brief for the United States, supra note 8, at 28.
  • 306
    • 78651275237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 29
    • Id. at 29.
  • 307
    • 78651326399 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Leonard & Mortimer, supra note 219, at 261
    • See Leonard & Mortimer, supra note 219, at 261.
  • 308
    • 78651293155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 264, at 788-91; see also Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 344 F.3d 1294, 1309-10 (11th Cir. 2003) ("It may be that the size of the payment to refrain from competing, sometimes called a 'reverse payment' or an 'exit payment,' raises the suspicion that the parties lacked faith in the validity of the patent ⋯.")
    • Crane, supra note 264, at 788-91; see also Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 344 F.3d 1294, 1309-10 (11th Cir. 2003) ("It may be that the size of the payment to refrain from competing, sometimes called a 'reverse payment' or an 'exit payment,' raises the suspicion that the parties lacked faith in the validity of the patent ⋯.").
  • 309
    • 78651282120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.C.5
    • See supra Part III.C.5.
  • 310
    • 78651296734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Walker Process Equip., Inc. v. Food Mach. & Chem. Corp., 382 U.S. 172 (1965)
    • See, e.g., Walker Process Equip., Inc. v. Food Mach. & Chem. Corp., 382 U.S. 172 (1965).
  • 311
    • 78651265982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This factor comes the closest to an examination of the underlying suit but only engages in a cursory examination to determine whether it was a sham. Any suit that proceeds past the motion-to-dismiss phase is not likely to be a sham
    • This factor comes the closest to an examination of the underlying suit but only engages in a cursory examination to determine whether it was a sham. Any suit that proceeds past the motion-to-dismiss phase is not likely to be a sham.
  • 312
    • 78651336391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 231-32 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 231-32 and accompanying text.
  • 313
    • 78651338755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough Corp., Docket No. 9297, slip op. at 107 (F.T.C. June 27, 2002), (finding that the side deal was bona fide), rev'd, 136 F.T.C. 956 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005); Hemphill, supra note 231, at 633 ("An aggregate approach ⋯. reveals that these sorts of deals are a frequent component of settlements, but rare outside of settlement. Thus, the overall pattern suggests they provide a disguised means to confer payment.")
    • Schering-Plough Corp., Docket No. 9297, slip op. at 107 (F.T.C. June 27, 2002), http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9297/020627id.pdf (finding that the side deal was bona fide), rev'd, 136 F.T.C. 956 (2003), rev'd, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005); Hemphill, supra note 231, at 633 ("An aggregate approach ⋯. reveals that these sorts of deals are a frequent component of settlements, but rare outside of settlement. Thus, the overall pattern suggests they provide a disguised means to confer payment.").
  • 314
    • 78651321279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See Yuki Onoe, Comment, 'Pay-for-Delay' Settlements in Pharmaceutical Litigation: Drawing a fine Line Between Patent Zone and Antitrust Zone, 9 JOHN MARSHALL REV. INTELL. PROP. L. 527, 536 (2009) ("[The rule of reason] involves a detailed three-step analysis starting with the requirement for the plaintiff to prove an 'actual adverse effect on competition as a whole in the relevant market.' If the proof is acceptable, then the defendant must demonstrate procompetitive effects. When the defendant meets the burden, the plaintiff must present 'less restrictive' alternatives. The first step of this analysis is essential and requires determination of whether the 'harm is not only possible but likely and significant.'" (footnotes omitted)).
  • 315
    • 78651289901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 14-16 (1984) (outlining the two possible error types and arguing that prosecuting legitimate conduct is more costly than allowing some anticompetitive conduct to go unchallenged)
    • See Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 14-16 (1984) (outlining the two possible error types and arguing that prosecuting legitimate conduct is more costly than allowing some anticompetitive conduct to go unchallenged);
  • 316
    • 77955889813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Geoffrey A. Manne & Joshua D. Wright, Innovation and the Limits of Antitrust, 6 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 153, 159-68 (2010) (providing a technical analysis of Easterbrook's error-cost framework)
    • See also Geoffrey A. Manne & Joshua D. Wright, Innovation and the Limits of Antitrust, 6 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 153, 159-68 (2010) (providing a technical analysis of Easterbrook's error-cost framework).
  • 317
    • 78651314520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • S. 369, 111th Cong. (2009); see also Protecting Consumer Access to Generic Drugs Act of 2009, H.R. 1706, 111th Cong. (2009) (making reverse payments per se illegal under the FTC Act)
    • S. 369, 111th Cong. (2009); see also Protecting Consumer Access to Generic Drugs Act of 2009, H.R. 1706, 111th Cong. (2009) (making reverse payments per se illegal under the FTC Act).
  • 318
    • 78651289511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Shapiro, supra note 202
    • See, e.g., Shapiro, supra note 202.
  • 319
    • 78651330074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, this error must be weighed against increased competition between brand-name drugs when high profits attract research, development, and marketing of new drugs
    • Of course, this error must be weighed against increased competition between brand-name drugs when high profits attract research, development, and marketing of new drugs.
  • 320
    • 78651288638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Addanki & Daskin, supra note 210
    • See, e.g., Addanki & Daskin, supra note 210.
  • 321
    • 78651272588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • S. 1315, 111th Cong. (2009)
    • S. 1315, 111th Cong. (2009).
  • 322
    • 78651284476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hatch-Waxman Act, 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5) (2006) (allowing the exclusivity period for the generic manufacturer to start immediately following the NDA filing)
    • See Hatch-Waxman Act, 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5) (2006) (allowing the exclusivity period for the generic manufacturer to start immediately following the NDA filing).
  • 323
    • 78651340632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 355 (j)(5)(D)(iii)
    • See id. § 355 (j)(5)(D)(iii).
  • 324
    • 78651343769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • S. 1315
    • S. 1315.
  • 325
    • 78651312575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 326
    • 78651274381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 327
    • 78651270496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, if the first filer chose to forego the exclusivity option, and a subsequent filer opted to take the 180 days, its exclusivity period would exclude all manufacturers except previous ANDA filers who opted to forego the exclusivity period
    • Of course, if the first filer chose to forego the exclusivity option, and a subsequent filer opted to take the 180 days, its exclusivity period would exclude all manufacturers except previous ANDA filers who opted to forego the exclusivity period.
  • 328
    • 78651345273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, the exclusivity period would only bar subsequent entrants, not previous ANDA filers who settled with reverse payments
    • Of course, the exclusivity period would only bar subsequent entrants, not previous ANDA filers who settled with reverse payments.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.