메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 13, Issue 3, 2010, Pages 623-643

Why soft law dominates international finance - And not trade

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 78649919610     PISSN: 13693034     EISSN: 14643758     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/jiel/jgq026     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (113)

References (80)
  • 1
    • 33745315057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A bottom-up approach to international lawmaking: The tale of three trade finance instruments
    • Customary international law is, as a result, generally regarded as a vaguer and less specific form of international law. See, at 179 noting that customary international law norms must remain vague to ensure that they envelop enough 'state practice' to constitute international law
    • Customary international law is, as a result, generally regarded as a vaguer and less specific form of international law. See Janet Koven Levit, 'A Bottom-Up Approach to International Lawmaking: The Tale of Three Trade Finance Instruments', 30 Yale Journal of International Law 125 (2005), at 179 (noting that customary international law norms must remain vague to ensure that they envelop enough 'state practice' to constitute international law).
    • (2005) Yale Journal of International Law , vol.30 , pp. 125
    • Levit, J.K.1
  • 2
    • 34147162128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The comparative disadvantage of customary international law
    • at 10, visited 14 June 2010
    • John O. McGinnis, 'The Comparative Disadvantage of Customary International Law', 30 Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy 7 (2006), at 10, http://www.law.harvard.edu/students/orgs/jlpp/Vol30-No1-McGinnisonline.pdf (visited 14 June 2010).
    • (2006) Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy , vol.30 , pp. 7
    • McGinnis, J.O.1
  • 3
    • 0030101239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward a positive theory of the most favored nation obligation and its exceptions in the wto/gatt system
    • argument here stems from the fact that the political costs incurred by alienating domestic manufacturers will likely outweigh the political favor curried from domestic consumers. This is because those benefitting in the aggregate most from liberalization-namely individual domestic consumers-will often not be as effective as producers at promoting their interests. See, and, at 28. Furthermore, the domestic political process often assigns disproportionate weight to the interests of domestic producers as compared to those of individual domestic consumers, though of course consuming industries may still wield significant political influence
    • The argument here stems from the fact that the political costs incurred by alienating domestic manufacturers will likely outweigh the political favor curried from domestic consumers. This is because those benefitting in the aggregate most from liberalization-namely individual domestic consumers-will often not be as effective as producers at promoting their interests. See Warren F. Schwartz and Alan O. Sykes, 'Toward a Positive Theory of the Most Favored Nation Obligation and Its Exceptions in the WTO/GATT System', 16 International Review of Law & Economics 27 (1996), at 28. Furthermore, the domestic political process often assigns disproportionate weight to the interests of domestic producers as compared to those of individual domestic consumers, though of course consuming industries may still wield significant political influence.
    • (1996) International Review of Law & Economics , vol.16 , pp. 27
    • Schwartz, W.F.1    Sykes, A.O.2
  • 4
    • 63049134889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This idea has been articulated by a variety of theorists, but for a comprehensive assessment see, Oxford: Oxford University Press
    • This idea has been articulated by a variety of theorists, but for a comprehensive assessment see Andrew Guzman, How International Law Works (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007) 71-111.
    • (2007) How International Law Works , pp. 71-111
    • Guzman, A.1
  • 5
    • 63049134889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • This idea has been articulated by a variety of theorists, but for a comprehensive assessment see Andrew Guzman, How International Law Works (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007) 71-111.
    • (2007) How International Law Works , pp. 71-111
    • Guzman, A.1
  • 6
    • 77957135550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hard vs. soft law: Alternatives, complements, and antagonists in international governance
    • at 718 noting that hard law treaties create mechanisms for the interpretation and elaboration of legal commitments over time
    • Gregory C. Shaffer and Mark A. Pollack, 'Hard vs. Soft Law: Alternatives, Complements, and Antagonists in International Governance', 94 Minnesota Law Review 706 (2010), at 718 (noting that hard law treaties create mechanisms for the interpretation and elaboration of legal commitments over time).
    • (2010) Minnesota Law Review , vol.94 , pp. 706
    • Shaffer, G.C.1    Pollack, M.A.2
  • 7
    • 0034408291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hard and soft law in international governance
    • at 429 noting that treaties establish monitoring provisions to detect noncompliance with the commitments
    • Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, 'Hard and Soft Law in International Governance', 54 International Organization 421 (2000), at 429 (noting that treaties establish monitoring provisions to detect noncompliance with the commitments).
    • (2000) International Organization , vol.54 , pp. 421
    • Abbott, K.W.1    Snidal, D.2
  • 9
    • 26844514814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The transformation of world trade
    • at 25
    • Joost Pauwelyn, 'The Transformation of World Trade', 104 Michigan Law Review 1 (2005), at 25.
    • (2005) Michigan Law Review , vol.104 , pp. 1
    • Pauwelyn, J.1
  • 11
    • 15944422576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The credibility imperative: The political dynamics of retaliation in the world trade organization's dispute resolution mechanism'
    • at 215
    • Jide Nzelibe, 'The Credibility Imperative: The Political Dynamics of Retaliation in the World Trade Organization's Dispute Resolution Mechanism', 6 Theoretical Inquiries in Law 215 (2005), at 215.
    • (2005) Theoretical Inquiries in Law , vol.6 , pp. 215
    • Nzelibe, J.1
  • 12
    • 15944422576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The credibility imperative: The political dynamics of retaliation in the world trade organization's dispute resolution mechanism'
    • Ibid
    • Jide Nzelibe, 'The Credibility Imperative: The Political Dynamics of Retaliation in the World Trade Organization's Dispute Resolution Mechanism', 6 Theoretical Inquiries in Law 215 (2005), at 216.
    • (2005) Theoretical Inquiries in Law , vol.6-215 , pp. 216
    • Nzelibe, J.1
  • 13
    • 17244376445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The legitimacy crisis in investment treaty arbitration: Privatizing public international law through inconsistent decisions
    • discussing the mandate of the WTO Appellate Body
    • Susan D. Franck, 'The Legitimacy Crisis in Investment Treaty Arbitration: Privatizing Public International Law Through Inconsistent Decisions', 73 Fordham Law Review 1521 (2005), n 466 (discussing the mandate of the WTO Appellate Body).
    • (2005) Fordham Law Review , vol.73 , Issue.466 , pp. 1521
    • Franck, S.D.1
  • 14
    • 78649930496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GATS Annex on Financial Services Paragraph 2 a
    • GATS Annex on Financial Services Paragraph 2 (a).
  • 15
    • 78649910705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the shortcomings of the institutional framework in the European Union with regards to financial supervision and its role in the recent financial crisis, see, and, at, Unpublished manuscript, 3 March, on file with author
    • For a discussion of the shortcomings of the institutional framework in the European Union with regards to financial supervision and its role in the recent financial crisis, see Eilis Ferran and Kern Alexander, 'Soft Institutions and Hard-Edged Power: What Role for the European Systemic Risk Board?', at 29 (Unpublished manuscript, 3 March 2010, on file with author).
    • (2010) Soft Institutions and Hard-Edged Power: What Role for the European Systemic Risk Board? , pp. 29
    • Ferran, E.1    Alexander, K.2
  • 16
    • 85055304385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Informal procedure, hard and soft, in international administration
    • For a description of the soft law basis of international standard setting bodies, see generally
    • For a description of the soft law basis of international standard setting bodies, see generally David Zaring, 'Informal Procedure, Hard and Soft, in International Administration', 5 Chicago Journal of International Law 547 (2005);
    • (2005) Chicago Journal of International Law , vol.5 , pp. 547
    • Zaring, D.1
  • 17
    • 0009923726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International law by other means: The twilight existence of international financial regulatory organizations
    • David Zaring, 'International Law by Other Means: The Twilight Existence of International Financial Regulatory Organizations', 33 Texas International Law Journal 281 (1998).
    • (1998) Texas International Law Journal , vol.33 , pp. 281
    • Zaring, D.1
  • 18
    • 69249090199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Treatment differences and political realities in the gaap-ifrs debate
    • first-generation set of rules, promoted under the organization's predecessor organization, The International Accounting Standards Committee, were called the international accounting standards IAS. Later, when the organization changed its name and reorganized in 2001, the IASB incorporated the IAS but now promulgates new rules called international financial reporting standards IFRS. These standards have gained prominence and now rival the US Generally Accepted Accounting Principles GAAP, especially since the European Union adopted IFRS in 2001, though they are generally viewed as more flexible-and lenient-than US standards. See, and, at
    • The first-generation set of rules, promoted under the organization's predecessor organization, The International Accounting Standards Committee, were called the international accounting standards (IAS). Later, when the organization changed its name and reorganized in 2001, the IASB incorporated the IAS but now promulgates new rules called international financial reporting standards (IFRS). These standards have gained prominence and now rival the US Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP), especially since the European Union adopted IFRS in 2001, though they are generally viewed as more flexible-and lenient-than US standards. See William W. Bratton and Lawrence A. Cunningham, 'Treatment Differences and Political Realities in the GAAP-IFRS Debate', 95 Virginia Law Review 989 (2009), at 997-99.
    • (2009) Virginia Law Review , vol.95-989 , pp. 997-999
    • Bratton, W.W.1    Cunningham, L.A.2
  • 19
    • 78649956839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For further information on the CPSS, see Bank for International Settlements, visited 14 June
    • For further information on the CPSS, see Bank for International Settlements, 'CPSS History, Organization, Cooperation', http://www.bis.org/cpss/ cpssinfo01.htm (visited 14 June 2010).
    • (2010) CPSS History, Organization, Cooperation
  • 20
    • 33646587009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Best practices have not been much analyzed from the standpoint of international law, but have been the subject of insightful scholarly examination in the domestic US context. See, New York University Law Review, at 294-350
    • Best practices have not been much analyzed from the standpoint of international law, but have been the subject of insightful scholarly examination in the domestic US context. See David Zaring, 'Best Practices', 81 New York University Law Review 294 (2006), at 294-350.
    • (2006) Best Practices , vol.81 , pp. 294
    • Zaring, D.1
  • 21
    • 78649926909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, the G-20, which represents the economies of leading developed and emerging economies
    • See, for example, the G-20, which represents the economies of leading developed and emerging economies.
  • 22
    • 78649910706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perhaps the most important private legislatures include IASB and IFAC, the international standard-setters for accounting and auditing services noted above
    • Perhaps the most important private legislatures include IASB and IFAC, the international standard-setters for accounting and auditing services (noted above).
  • 23
    • 0003793997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g. Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Basle, September, visited 14 June 2010
    • See, e.g. Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, 'Core Principles for Effective Banking Supervision', Basle, September 1997, http://www.bis.org/publ/ bcbs30a.pdf (visited 14 June 2010);
    • (1997) Core Principles for Effective Banking Supervision
  • 24
    • 20444363347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Association of Insurance Supervisors, visited 14 June 2010
    • International Association of Insurance Supervisors, 'Insurance Core Principles and Methodology' 2003, http://www.iaisweb.org/-temp/Insurance-core- principles-and-methodology.pdf (visited 14 June 2010);
    • (2003) Insurance Core Principles and Methodology
  • 26
    • 70450192325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Technical Committee of the IOSCO, December, visited 14 June 2010
    • The Technical Committee of the IOSCO, 'Code of Conduct Fundamentals for Credit Rating Agencies', December 2004, http://www.treasurers.org/node/3134 (visited 14 June 2010).
    • (2004) Code of Conduct Fundamentals for Credit Rating Agencies
  • 27
    • 0004205937 scopus 로고
    • This realist interpretation of international affairs was first articulated by Kenneth Waltz. See generally, Reading: Addison-Wesley
    • This realist interpretation of international affairs was first articulated by Kenneth Waltz. See generally Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (Reading: Addison-Wesley, 1979).
    • (1979) Theory of International Politics
    • Waltz, K.1
  • 28
    • 78649941265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abbott and Snidal, above, at
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7 at 434;
    • , Issue.7 , pp. 434
  • 29
    • 84976128766 scopus 로고
    • Why are some international agreements informal?
    • at 518 noting that it is less costly to abandon informal commitments
    • Charles Lipson, 'Why Are Some International Agreements Informal?', 45 International Organization 495 (1991), at 518 (noting that it is less costly to abandon informal commitments).
    • (1991) International Organization , vol.45 , pp. 495
    • Lipson, C.1
  • 30
    • 78649957571 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Levit, above, at
    • Levit, above n 1, at 171.
    • , vol.1 , pp. 171
  • 31
    • 62649148804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Soft law: Lessons from congressional practice
    • at 589 discussing 'cheap talk' theories
    • Jacob E. Gersen and Eric A. Posner, 'Soft Law: Lessons from Congressional Practice', 61 Stanford Law Review 573 (2008), at 589 (discussing 'cheap talk' theories).
    • (2008) Stanford Law Review , vol.61 , pp. 573
    • Gersen, J.E.1    Posner, E.A.2
  • 32
    • 78649918661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lipson, above, at, noting that although treaties often contain clauses permitting renegotiation, the process is slow and cumbersome
    • Lipson, above n 25, at 500 (noting that although treaties often contain clauses permitting renegotiation, the process is slow and cumbersome).
    • , vol.25 , pp. 500
  • 33
    • 48949100112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sovereignty and delegation in international organizations
    • at 89 defining sovereignty costs as the distance between the policy a country would implement if it were not a member of an international organization and the policy it enacts once it has joined
    • David Epstein and Sharyn O'Halloran, 'Sovereignty and Delegation in International Organizations', 71 WTR Law & Contemporary Problems 77 (2008), at 89 (defining sovereignty costs as the distance between the policy a country would implement if it were not a member of an international organization and the policy it enacts once it has joined).
    • (2008) WTR Law & Contemporary Problems , vol.71 , pp. 77
    • Epstein, D.1    O'Halloran, S.2
  • 34
    • 58149105499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • University of Pennsylvania Law Review, at 133-38 describing the costs arising when organizations incorporate the laws of foreign or international bodies
    • Michael C. Dorf, 'Dynamic Incorporation of Foreign Law', 157 University of Pennsylvania Law Review 103 (2008), at 133-38 (describing the costs arising when organizations incorporate the laws of foreign or international bodies).
    • (2008) Dynamic Incorporation of Foreign Law , vol.157 , pp. 103
    • Dorf, M.C.1
  • 35
    • 78649932602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at, defining hard law as legally binding obligations that delegate authority for interpreting and implementing the law to international actors
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 421 (defining hard law as legally binding obligations that delegate authority for interpreting and implementing the law to international actors).
    • , vol.7 , pp. 421
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 36
    • 78649934535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Metalclad Corp. v United Mexican States, ICSID Case No ARB (AF)/97/1 (ICSID AF) (30 August 2000). 33 Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 438 (noting that hard law can lead to unanticipated costs because states cannot predict all possible contingencies);
    • , vol.33 , Issue.7 , pp. 438
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 37
    • 78649924968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at, noting that soft law allows states to limit the risk of uncertainty
    • Shaffer and Pollack, above n 6, at 719 (noting that soft law allows states to limit the risk of uncertainty).
    • , vol.6 , pp. 719
    • Shaffer1    Pollack2
  • 38
    • 78649960189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 423.
    • , vol.7 , pp. 423
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 39
    • 78649932971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 441.
    • , vol.7 , pp. 441
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 40
    • 78649939555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 442. Indeed, for some scholars, such vagaries render hard law 'soft'. Donald Langevoort notes, however, that other regulatory strategies are possible, including the targeting of new overlapping areas of interest among jurisdictions.
    • , vol.7 , pp. 442
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 41
    • 78649929404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Global securities regulation after the financial crisis
    • See, noting how the institutionalization of securities markets in both the USA and Europe creates new opportunities for international regulation
    • See 'Global Securities Regulation after the Financial Crisis', Journal of International Economic Law (2010) (noting how the institutionalization of securities markets in both the USA and Europe creates new opportunities for international regulation).
    • (2010) Journal of International Economic Law
  • 42
    • 29444435791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exiting treaties
    • at 1641-2 analyzing the unilateral exit from international agreements
    • Laurence R. Helfer, 'Exiting Treaties', 91 Virginia Law Review 1579 (2005), at 1641-2 (analyzing the unilateral exit from international agreements).
    • (2005) Virginia Law Review , vol.91 , pp. 1579
    • Helfer, L.R.1
  • 43
    • 78649939555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 442.
    • , vol.7 , pp. 442
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 44
    • 78649939555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 442.
    • , vol.7 , pp. 442
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 45
    • 78649913026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 443.
    • , vol.7 , pp. 443
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 47
    • 77950141142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Transnational regulatory networks and their limits
    • See generally, highlighting the limits of networks
    • See generally Pierre-Hugues Verdier, 'Transnational Regulatory Networks and Their Limits', 34 Yale Journal of International Law 113 (2009) (highlighting the limits of networks);
    • (2009) Yale Journal of International Law , vol.34 , pp. 113
    • Verdier, P.1
  • 48
    • 35348965125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What's your sign?-international norms, signals, and compliance
    • see also, at 704
    • see also Charles K. Whitehead, 'What's Your Sign?-International Norms, Signals, and Compliance', 27 Michigan Journal of International Law 695 (2006), at 704.
    • (2006) Michigan Journal of International Law , vol.27 , pp. 695
    • Whitehead, C.K.1
  • 49
    • 12344278322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The architecture of international cooperation: Transgovernmental networks and the future of international law
    • at 30 exemplifying widespread use of MoUs as a cooperation tool
    • Kal Raustiala, 'The Architecture of International Cooperation: Transgovernmental Networks and the Future of International Law', 43 Virginia Journal of International Law 1 (2002), at 30 (exemplifying widespread use of MoUs as a cooperation tool).
    • (2002) Virginia Journal of International Law , vol.43 , pp. 1
    • Raustiala, K.1
  • 50
    • 62649154993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Variation in the intensity of financial regulation: Preliminary evidence and potential implications
    • Though not addressed specifically in this context, Howell Jackson surmises similar possibilities with regard to the under-enforcement of even domestic rules. See, at 286-7 discussing rational under-enforcement and inefficient under-enforcement
    • Though not addressed specifically in this context, Howell Jackson surmises similar possibilities with regard to the under-enforcement of even domestic rules. See Howell Jackson, 'Variation in the Intensity of Financial Regulation: Preliminary Evidence and Potential Implications', 24 Yale Journal on Regulation 253 (2007), at 286-7 (discussing rational under-enforcement and inefficient under-enforcement).
    • (2007) Yale Journal on Regulation , vol.24 , pp. 253
    • Jackson, H.1
  • 51
    • 78649942019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at
    • Ferran and Alexander, above n 15, at 1.
    • , vol.15 , pp. 1
    • Ferran1    Alexander2
  • 52
    • 78649943169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The hardening of soft law in securities regulation
    • See, and, at 885 noting that soft law is relied upon 'because of the need for speed, flexibility and expertise in dealing with fast-breaking developments in capital markets'
    • See Roberta S. Karmel and Claire Kelly, 'The Hardening of Soft Law in Securities Regulation', 34 Brooklyn Journal of International Law 883 (2009), at 885 (noting that soft law is relied upon 'because of the need for speed, flexibility and expertise in dealing with fast-breaking developments in capital markets').
    • (2009) Brooklyn Journal of International Law , vol.34 , pp. 883
    • Karmel, R.S.1    Kelly, C.2
  • 53
    • 78649939909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How international financial law works (and how it doesn't)
    • forthcoming January, at, and 58, noting that international financial regulation is often buttressed by a range of reputational, institutional and market disciplines that render it more coercive than traditional theories of international law predict
    • Chris Brummer, 'How International Financial Law Works (and How It Doesn't) ', Georgetown Law Journal (forthcoming January 2011), at 33 and 58, http://papers.ssrn. - com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=1542829 (noting that international financial regulation is often buttressed by a range of reputational, institutional and market disciplines that render it more coercive than traditional theories of international law predict).
    • (2011) Georgetown Law Journal , pp. 33
    • Brummer, C.1
  • 54
    • 78649960189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 423.
    • , vol.7 , pp. 423
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 55
    • 78649937155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 425 (discussing how some international agreements are viewed as covenants).
    • , vol.7 , pp. 425
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 56
    • 78649948285 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Abbott and Snidal, above n 7, at 424, 427 (discussing how rationalists view international agreements as expressing contractual commitments, usually between states).
    • , vol.7 , pp. 424
    • Abbott1    Snidal2
  • 57
    • 78649946393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at
    • Gersen and Posner, above n 27, at 573.
    • , vol.27 , pp. 573
    • Gersen1    Posner2
  • 58
    • 78649955092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at
    • Chris Brummer, above n 47, at 13.
    • , vol.47 , pp. 13
    • Brummer, C.1
  • 59
    • 0003422432 scopus 로고
    • This point perhaps enjoyed its most famous articulation in corporate law scholarship, especially regards to the 'choice' of states under domestic US corporate law. See, Washington, DC: AEI Press, arguing that firms that choose states with inefficient corporate laws should have lower stock prices
    • This point perhaps enjoyed its most famous articulation in corporate law scholarship, especially regards to the 'choice' of states under domestic US corporate law. See Roberta Romano, The Genius of American Corporate Law (Washington, DC: AEI Press, 1993) (arguing that firms that choose states with inefficient corporate laws should have lower stock prices);
    • (1993) The Genius of American Corporate Law
    • Romano, R.1
  • 60
    • 0002575839 scopus 로고
    • State law, shareholder protection, and the theory of the corporation
    • Ralph K. Winter Jr., 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 Journal of Legal Studies 251 (1977).
    • (1977) Journal of Legal Studies , vol.6 , pp. 251
    • Ralph Jr., K.W.1
  • 61
    • 2442609381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • O'hara, 'information and the cost of capital'
    • See, and, showing that differences in the composition of information between public and private information affect the cost of capital, with investors demanding a higher return to hold stocks with greater private information
    • See David Easley and Maureen O'Hara, 'Information and the Cost of Capital', 59 Journal of Finance 1553 (2004) (showing that differences in the composition of information between public and private information affect the cost of capital, with investors demanding a higher return to hold stocks with greater private information).
    • (2004) Journal of Finance , vol.59 , pp. 1553
    • Easley, D.1    Maureen2
  • 62
    • 84890712521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • this case, the reverse is, not surprisingly, equally applicable. Specifically, where banks or for that matter any financial institution embedded in financial systems as intermediaries are viewed as having insufficient capital to meet their operational requirements or credit obligations, 'runs' on those banks are likely. For a recent description of bank runs over time, see, and, Princeton: Princeton University Press
    • In this case, the reverse is, not surprisingly, equally applicable. Specifically, where banks (or for that matter any financial institution embedded in financial systems as intermediaries) are viewed as having insufficient capital to meet their operational requirements or credit obligations, 'runs' on those banks are likely. For a recent description of bank runs over time, see Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff, This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2009) 144-5.
    • (2009) This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly , pp. 144-145
    • Reinhart, C.M.1    Rogoff, K.S.2
  • 63
    • 84855903488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring securities market efficiency in the regulatory setting
    • Indeed, the very concept of market efficiency is often difficult to discern, and, at 122
    • Indeed, the very concept of market efficiency is often difficult to discern. Randall S. Thomas and James F. Cotter, 'Measuring Securities Market Efficiency in the Regulatory Setting', 63 SUM Law & Contemporary Problems 105 (2005), at 122.
    • (2005) SUM Law & Contemporary Problems , vol.63 , pp. 105
    • Thomas, R.S.1    Cotter, J.F.2
  • 64
    • 0036868524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Racing towards the top?: The impact of cross-listings and stock market competition on international corporate governance
    • See, at 1763
    • See John C. Coffee Jr., 'Racing Towards the Top?: The Impact of Cross-Listings and Stock Market Competition on International Corporate Governance', 102 Columbia Law Review 1757 (2002), at 1763.
    • (2002) Columbia Law Review , vol.102 , pp. 1757
    • John Jr., C.C.1
  • 67
    • 0004153025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, New York: W. W. Norton & Company, discussing conditionality loans via the IMF
    • see also Joseph Stiglitz, Globalization and Its Discontents (New York: W. W. Norton & Company, 2002) 44 (discussing conditionality loans via the IMF);
    • (2002) Globalization and its Discontents , pp. 44
    • Stiglitz, J.1
  • 70
    • 78649939913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at, discussing clubs, standards, and the possibility of expulsion
    • Drezner, above n 58, at 75-7 (discussing clubs, standards, and the possibility of expulsion);
    • , vol.58 , pp. 75-77
    • Drezner1
  • 71
    • 77956201347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Post-american securities regulation
    • see also, at
    • see also Chris Brummer, 'Post-American Securities Regulation', 98 California Law Review 327 (2010), at 364-72.
    • (2010) California Law Review , vol.98-327 , pp. 364-372
    • Brummer, C.1
  • 72
    • 78649911842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Embarrassment caused by deviating from network norms operates, for some, as a kind of social tax. Adhering to network-based standards may encourage praise, and deviation may cause embarrassment or shame that results in a loss of prestige or influence among peer regulators as the violation becomes known to others. See, above, at
    • Embarrassment caused by deviating from network norms operates, for some, as a kind of social tax. Adhering to network-based standards may encourage praise, and deviation may cause embarrassment or shame that results in a loss of prestige or influence among peer regulators as the violation becomes known to others. See Whitehead, above n 42, at 705.
    • , vol.42 , pp. 705
    • Whitehead1
  • 74
    • 84979032358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Monetary Fund, visited 14 June 2010 noting that the voluntary nature of FSAPs is necessary for 'buy-in' among participants
    • International Monetary Fund, 'Factsheet: The Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) ', http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/fsap.htm (visited 14 June 2010) (noting that the voluntary nature of FSAPs is necessary for 'buy-in' among participants).
    • Factsheet: The Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP)
  • 76
    • 78649953237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at, 18, 37-54 discussing the legitimacy concerns regarding the Financial Stability Board, the IMF, and European Systemic Risk Board
    • Ferran and Alexander, above n 15, at 11, 18, 37-54 (discussing the legitimacy concerns regarding the Financial Stability Board, the IMF, and European Systemic Risk Board).
    • , vol.15 , pp. 11
    • Ferran1    Alexander2
  • 77
    • 78649975304 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Ferran and Alexander, above n 15, at 12.
    • , vol.15 , pp. 12
    • Ferran1    Alexander2
  • 78
    • 78649967731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, at, suggesting improvements in the monitoring and information utility to the existing structure of international financial system
    • Brummer, above n 47, at 65 (suggesting improvements in the monitoring and information utility to the existing structure of international financial system).
    • , vol.47 , pp. 65
    • Brummer1
  • 79
    • 78649944524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Brummer, above n 47, at 80.
    • , vol.47 , pp. 80
    • Brummer1
  • 80
    • 78649911459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Brummer, above n 47, at 80.
    • , vol.47 , pp. 80
    • Brummer1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.