메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 99, Issue , 2009, Pages 61-91

The size of the economy and the distribution of income in the roman empire

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77950541340     PISSN: 00754358     EISSN: 1753528X     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.3815/007543509789745223     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (226)

References (128)
  • 2
    • 5644241756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Productive to some purpose? The problem of ancient economic growth
    • and more generally the contributions in the same volume, as well as P. Millett, 'Productive to some purpose? The problem of ancient economic growth', in D. J. Mattingly and J. Salmon (eds), Economies Beyond Agriculture in the Classical World (2001), 17-48
    • (2001) Economies Beyond Agriculture in the Classical World , pp. 17-48
    • Millett, P.1
  • 3
    • 2542460115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Framing the debate over growth in the ancient economy
    • W. Scheidel and S. von Reden (eds)
    • R. Saller, 'Framing the debate over growth in the ancient economy', in W. Scheidel and S. von Reden (eds), The Ancient Economy (2002), 251-69
    • (2002) The Ancient Economy , pp. 251-269
    • Saller, R.1
  • 4
    • 33645808167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and in J. G. Manning and I. Morris (eds)
    • and in J. G. Manning and I. Morris (eds), The Ancient Economy (2005), 223-38
    • (2005) The Ancient Economy , pp. 223-238
  • 5
    • 60950034639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Graeco-Roman economy in the super-long run: Lead, copper, and shipwrecks
    • F. de Callataÿ, 'The Graeco-Roman economy in the super-long run: lead, copper, and shipwrecks', JRA 18 (2005), 361-72
    • (2005) JRA , vol.18 , pp. 361-372
    • De Callataÿ, F.1
  • 6
    • 77950526088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The advantages of wealth and luxury": The case for economic growth in the Roman empire
    • Manning and Morris, above
    • R. B. Hitchner, '"The advantages of wealth and luxury": the case for economic growth in the Roman empire', in Manning and Morris, The Ancient Economy op. cit. above, 207-22
    • The Ancient Economy , pp. 207-222
    • Hitchner, R.B.1
  • 7
    • 77449131613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rise and fall of the Roman economy: Population, rents and entitlement
    • P. F. Bang, M. Ikeguchi and H. G. Ziche (eds)
    • W. Jongman, 'The rise and fall of the Roman economy: population, rents and entitlement', in P. F. Bang, M. Ikeguchi and H. G. Ziche (eds), Ancient Economies, Modern Methodologies (2006), 237-54
    • (2006) Ancient Economies, Modern Methodologies , pp. 237-254
    • Jongman, W.1
  • 8
    • 84876413623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The early Roman Empire: Consumption
    • Scheidel, Morris and Saller, above
    • W. Jongman, idem, 'The early Roman Empire: consumption', in Scheidel, Morris and Saller, Ancient Economies, Modern Methodologies op. cit. above, 592-618
    • Ancient Economies, Modern Methodologies , pp. 592-618
    • Jongman, W.1
  • 9
    • 85003749684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gibbon was right: The decline and fall of the Roman economy
    • O. Hekster, G. de Kleijn and D. Slootjes (eds)
    • W. Jongman, idem, 'Gibbon was right: the decline and fall of the Roman economy', in O. Hekster, G. de Kleijn and D. Slootjes (eds), Crises and the Roman Empire (2007), 183-99
    • (2007) Crises and the Roman Empire , pp. 183-199
    • Jongman, W.1
  • 10
    • 34748914193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade and empire: In search of organizing concepts for the Roman economy
    • P. F. Bang, 'Trade and empire: in search of organizing concepts for the Roman economy', P&P 195 (2007), 3-54
    • (2007) P&P , vol.195 , pp. 3-54
    • Bang, P.F.1
  • 11
    • 36849079094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A model of real income growth in Roman Italy
    • W. Scheidel, 'A model of real income growth in Roman Italy', Historia 56 (2007), 322-46
    • (2007) Historia , vol.56 , pp. 322-346
    • Scheidel, W.1
  • 12
    • 77950541781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In search of Roman economic growth
    • W. Scheidel, idem, 'In search of Roman economic growth', JRA 22 (2009)
    • (2009) JRA , vol.22
    • Scheidel, W.1
  • 13
    • 77951863436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Roman economic growth and living standards: Perceptions versus evidence
    • M. Silver, 'Roman economic growth and living standards: perceptions versus evidence', AncSoc 37 (2007), 191-252
    • (2007) AncSoc , vol.37 , pp. 191-252
    • Silver, M.1
  • 14
    • 9144236088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic growth in ancient Greece
    • For economic growth in ancient Greece, cf
    • For economic growth in ancient Greece, cf. I. Morris, 'Economic growth in ancient Greece', Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 160 (2004), 709-42
    • (2004) Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics , vol.160 , pp. 709-742
    • Morris, I.1
  • 15
    • 77949755068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Archaeology, standards of living, and Greek economic history
    • Manning and Morris, above
    • I. Morris, idem, 'Archaeology, standards of living, and Greek economic history', in Manning and Morris, The Ancient Economy op. cit. above, 91-126
    • The Ancient Economy , pp. 91-126
    • Morris, I.1
  • 16
    • 84971752930 scopus 로고
    • Taxes and trade in the Roman Empire (200 B.C.-A.D. 400)
    • K. Hopkins, 'Taxes and trade in the Roman Empire (200 B.C.-A.D. 400)', JRS 70 (1980), 101-25
    • (1980) JRS , vol.70 , pp. 101-125
    • Hopkins, K.1
  • 17
    • 5644277529 scopus 로고
    • Rome, taxes, rents, and trade
    • 'Rome, taxes, rents, and trade', Kodai 6/7 (1995/6), 41-75
    • (1995) Kodai , vol.6-7 , pp. 41-75
  • 19
    • 85196689276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The political economy of the Roman Empire
    • I. Morris and W. Scheidel (eds)
    • 'The political economy of the Roman Empire', in I. Morris and W. Scheidel (eds), The Dynamics of Ancient Empires (2009), 178-204
    • (2009) The Dynamics of Ancient Empires , pp. 178-204
  • 20
    • 84984059044 scopus 로고
    • An estimate of the size and structure of the national product of the early Roman empire
    • Among economists
    • Among economists, R. W. Goldsmith, 'An estimate of the size and structure of the national product of the early Roman empire', Review of Income and Wealth 30 (1984), 263-88
    • (1984) Review of Income and Wealth , vol.30 , pp. 263-288
    • Goldsmith, R.W.1
  • 21
    • 77951808383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Estimating GDP in the early Roman Empire
    • was a pioneering study, with considerable delay followed by E. Lo Cascio (ed.)
    • was a pioneering study, with considerable delay followed by P. Temin, 'Estimating GDP in the early Roman Empire', in E. Lo Cascio (ed.), Innovazione tecnica e progresso economico nel mondo romano (2006), 31-54
    • (2006) Innovazione Tecnica e Progresso Economico Nel Mondo Romano , pp. 31-54
    • Temin, P.1
  • 24
    • 33747237621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An estimate of average income and inequality in Byzantium around year 1000
    • now especially
    • See now especially B. Milanovic, 'An estimate of average income and inequality in Byzantium around year 1000', Review of Income and Wealth 52 (2006), 449-70
    • (2006) Review of Income and Wealth , vol.52 , pp. 449-470
    • Milanovic, B.1
  • 26
    • 84920753194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How prosperous were the Romans? Evidence from Diocletian's Price Edict (301 AD)
    • and also R. C. Allen, 'How prosperous were the Romans? Evidence from Diocletian's Price Edict (301 AD)', University of Oxford, Department of Economics, Discussion Paper Series No. 363 (October 2007), forthcoming in A. Bowman and A. Wilson (eds), Quantifying the Roman Economy (2009)
    • (2009) Quantifying the Roman Economy
    • Allen, R.C.1
  • 27
    • 84974200499 scopus 로고
    • Landholding in the Hermopolite nome in the fourth century A.D
    • Among ancient historians
    • Among ancient historians, A. K. Bowman, 'Landholding in the Hermopolite nome in the fourth century A.D.', JRS 75 (1985), 137-63
    • (1985) JRS , vol.75 , pp. 137-163
    • Bowman, A.K.1
  • 28
    • 84972263294 scopus 로고
    • Landholding in Late Roman Egypt: The distribution of wealth
    • stand out for their use of the rich material from Late Roman Egypt
    • and R. S. Bagnall, 'Landholding in Late Roman Egypt: the distribution of wealth', JRS 82 (1992), 128-49 stand out for their use of the rich material from Late Roman Egypt
    • (1992) JRS , vol.82 , pp. 128-149
    • Bagnall, R.S.1
  • 29
    • 84992828474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Poverty in Pauline Studies: Beyond the so-called New Consensus
    • On Roman inequality more generally, see most recently
    • On Roman inequality more generally, see most recently S. Friesen, 'Poverty in Pauline Studies: beyond the so-called New Consensus', Journal for the Study of the New Testament 26 (2004), 323-61
    • (2004) Journal for the Study of the New Testament , vol.26 , pp. 323-361
    • Friesen, S.1
  • 30
    • 84927061543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stratification, deprivation and quality of life
    • M. Atkins and R. Osborne (eds)
    • and W. Scheidel, 'Stratification, deprivation and quality of life', in M. Atkins and R. Osborne (eds), Poverty in the Roman World (2006), 40-59
    • (2006) Poverty in the Roman World , pp. 40-59
    • Scheidel, W.1
  • 31
    • 70449132483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Access to resources in classical Greece: The egalitarianism of the polis in practice
    • For Greece, cf. P. Cartledge, E. E. Cohen and L. Foxhall (eds), with earlier literature
    • For Greece, cf. L. Foxhall, 'Access to resources in classical Greece: the egalitarianism of the polis in practice', in P. Cartledge, E. E. Cohen and L. Foxhall (eds), Money, Labour and Land (2002), 209-20, with earlier literature
    • (2002) Money, Labour and Land , pp. 209-220
    • Foxhall, L.1
  • 38
    • 79953425905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hunger and power: Theories, models and methods in Roman economic history
    • H. Bongenaar (ed.)
    • W. Jongman, 'Hunger and power: theories, models and methods in Roman economic history', in H. Bongenaar (ed.), Interdependency of Institutions and Private Entrepreneurs (2000), 271
    • (2000) Interdependency of Institutions and Private Entrepreneurs , pp. 271
    • Jongman, W.1
  • 40
    • 79957226338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • La "plèbe moyenne" sous le Haut-Empire romain
    • See also P. Veyne, 'La "plèbe moyenne" sous le Haut-Empire romain', Annales 55 (2000), 1169-99
    • (2000) Annales , vol.55 , pp. 1169-1199
    • Veyne, P.1
  • 41
    • 43849099207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In dealing with the Roman Empire as a whole, it is legitimate to elide the differences between Gross Domestic Product (i.e., expenditure, value added in production, and income generated within a given unit of observation), Gross National Product (GDP plus or minus net receipts from transfers of property or labour income from outside a given unit of observation), and National Disposable Income (GNP plus or minus net current transfers received in money or kind from outside the unit of observation): see Maddison, Contours of the World Economy, 1-2030 AD op. cit. (n. 2), 45. However, these differences do matter in more narrowly focused regional studies, especially in the case of Roman Italy as a net recipient of transfers from its provinces: see below, n. 52
    • Contours of the World Economy, 1-2030 AD , pp. 45
    • Maddison1
  • 43
    • 84876418907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maddison, Contours of the World Economy, 1-2030 AD (2), 382. ibid. (for a mean of $1,350 for a population of some 75 million in the countries listed in the text below)
    • Contours of the World Economy, 1-2030 AD , Issue.2 , pp. 382
    • Maddison1
  • 44
    • 85035998645 scopus 로고
    • quotes at 118-19; italics in original
    • Hopkins, JRS op. cit. (n. 2, 1980), 117-20 (quotes at 118-19; italics in original)
    • (1980) JRS , pp. 117-120
    • Hopkins1
  • 45
    • 79957301381 scopus 로고
    • and cf. Hopkins, JRS op. cit. (n. 2, 1995/6), 45-6 = (n. 2, 2002), 198-9 for the same calculation based on a population of 60m, for a minimum total of HS9bn
    • (1995) JRS , pp. 45-46
    • Hopkins1
  • 50
    • 0002359959 scopus 로고
    • Sitometreia: The role of grain as a staple food in classical antiquity
    • reckoning with mean wheat consumption of 35-40 modii (which he set at 6.75 kg) per average person, a figure that is surely too high: see, e.g., L. Foxhall and H. A. Forbes, 'Sitometreia: the role of grain as a staple food in classical antiquity', Chiron 12 (1982), 41-90
    • (1982) Chiron , vol.12 , pp. 41-90
    • Foxhall, L.1    Forbes, H.A.2
  • 55
    • 84876412322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Demography
    • Scheidel, Morris and Saller, table 3.1 for a conjectural breakdown by region
    • See W. Scheidel, 'Demography', in Scheidel, Morris and Saller, Food and Society in Classical Antiquity (op. cit. (n. 1), 48 table 3.1 for a conjectural breakdown by region
    • Food and Society in Classical Antiquity , pp. 48
    • Scheidel, W.1
  • 56
    • 11144350129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The demography of the Early Roman Empire
    • revising 2nd edn, table 6 (c. 61m in 164 C.E.)
    • revising B. W. Frier, 'The demography of the Early Roman Empire', in CAH XI (2nd edn, 2000), 814 table 6 (c. 61m in 164 C.E.)
    • (2000) CAH , vol.11 , pp. 814
    • Frier, B.W.1
  • 57
    • 84966458783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Roman population size: The logic of the debate
    • If anything, our tally of 70 million may still be too low, given the probable size of Italy's population alone, for which see now W. Scheidel, 'Roman population size: the logic of the debate', in L. de Ligt and S. Northwood (eds), People, Land and Politics (2008), 17-70, in response to even higher but less plausible estimates
    • (2008) People, Land and Politics , pp. 17-70
    • Scheidel, W.1
  • 58
    • 84876413942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Living standards and the economy of the Roman empire (I-III AD)
    • most recently Bowman and Wilson
    • See most recently D. W. Rathbone, 'Living standards and the economy of the Roman empire (I-III AD)', in Bowman and Wilson, People, Land and Politics (op. cit. (n. 3)
    • People, Land and Politics
    • Rathbone, D.W.1
  • 59
    • 84876420900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Real wages in early economies: Evidence for living standards from 1800 BCE to 1300 CE
    • and also in press
    • and also W. Scheidel, 'Real wages in early economies: evidence for living standards from 1800 BCE to 1300 CE', JESHO (in press)
    • JESHO
    • Scheidel, W.1
  • 63
    • 1842752973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A model of demographic and economic change in Roman Egypt after the Antonine plague
    • 8 drachms
    • W. Scheidel, 'A model of demographic and economic change in Roman Egypt after the Antonine plague', JRA 15 (2002), 103 (8 drachms)
    • (2002) JRA , vol.15 , pp. 103
    • Scheidel, W.1
  • 64
    • 84876417319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 9 drachms
    • Rathbone, JRA op. cit. (n. 22) (9 drachms)
    • JRA
    • Rathbone1
  • 67
    • 79957161975 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • for HS800m after 84 C.E
    • (cf. also R. Wolters, Nummi signati (1999), 223 for HS800m after 84 C.E.)
    • (1999) Nummi Signati , pp. 223
    • Wolters, R.1
  • 68
    • 79957083083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and allows for HS100m in municipal taxes, a total that may in fact have been higher. For the significant role of municipal taxation, see now especially H. Schwarz, Soll oder Haben? (2001). Since much government spending occurred in Rome and Italy and at the frontiers, where prices may have been above average, our notional wheat price of HS3.3 per modius may well be on the low side
    • (2001) Soll Oder Haben?
    • Schwarz, H.1
  • 69
    • 84876419374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adult women and minors consume less than adult men
    • See Allen, Soll oder Haben? (op. cit. (n. 3). Adult women and minors consume less than adult men
    • Soll Oder Haben?
    • Allen1
  • 70
    • 84876413388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scheidel, Soll oder Haben? (op. cit. (n. 22), table 2. The equivalent of 300 kg would keep an average person alive and barely clothed
    • Soll Oder Haben?
    • Scheidel1
  • 72
    • 33845890325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nutritious subsistence food systems
    • If all food had been consumed in the form of wheat and there had been no other consumption, 210 kg per year would have sufficed for long-term survival: cf. table XV for mean caloric intake in several developing countries
    • If all food had been consumed in the form of wheat and there had been no other consumption, 210 kg per year would have sufficed for long-term survival: cf. R. D. Graham et al., 'Nutritious subsistence food systems', Advances in Agronomy 92 (2007), 61 table XV for mean caloric intake in several developing countries
    • (2007) Advances in Agronomy , vol.92 , pp. 61
    • Graham, R.D.1
  • 73
    • 84876407878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Allen, Advances in Agronomy op. cit. (n. 3), undertook an equivalent calculation utilizing the price data in Diocletian's Price Edict of 301 C.E. His findings, however, imply an annual mean of only 204 kg of wheat equivalent per average person, which is too low even for bare subsistence covering food, clothing, shelter, and fuel (see n. 28, and below, pp. 83); this suggests that the imposed price controls sufficiently deviate from normal prices to preclude realistic estimates. In any case it is preferable to use actual prices such as those from Egypt
    • Advances in Agronomy
    • Allen1
  • 74
    • 0035180284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The great divergence: Wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War
    • figs 7-8
    • R. C. Allen, 'The great divergence: wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War', Explorations in Economic History 38 (2001), 429 figs 7-8
    • (2001) Explorations in Economic History , vol.38 , pp. 429
    • Allen, R.C.1
  • 75
    • 79957049788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wages, prices, and living standards in China, Japan, and Europe, 1738-1925
    • October
    • Allen et al., 'Wages, prices, and living standards in China, Japan, and Europe, 1738-1925', GPIH Working Paper No. 1 (October 2005)
    • (2005) GPIH Working Paper No. 1
    • Allen1
  • 78
    • 84876420962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • table 6 (welfare ratio); Allen's data at wages
    • Allen, Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World (op. cit. (n. 30), 428 table 6 (welfare ratio); Allen's data at http://www.iisg.nl/hpw/data. php#europe (wages)
    • Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World , pp. 428
    • Allen1
  • 80
    • 85008525589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The amount of wages paid to the quarry-workers at Mons Claudianus
    • H. Cuvigny, 'The amount of wages paid to the quarry-workers at Mons Claudianus', JRS 86 (1996), 139-45
    • (1996) JRS , vol.86 , pp. 139-145
    • Cuvigny, H.1
  • 87
    • 84876415193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a more detailed study of Byzantium, see
    • For a more detailed study of Byzantium, see Milanovic, NBER Working Paper 13550 op. cit. (n. 3)
    • NBER Working Paper 13550 , pp. 71
    • Milanovic1
  • 89
    • 84876406214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the probable size of the imperial budget, see above, n. 26. For France, see table 8
    • For the probable size of the imperial budget, see above, n. 26. For France, see Goldstone, Roman Palestine 200-400op. cit. (n. 31), 205 table 8
    • Roman Palestine 200-400 , pp. 205
    • Goldstone1
  • 90
    • 79957296107 scopus 로고
    • n. 2, 1995/6, 47 = (n. 2, 2002), 201; (n. 2, 2009), 183-4
    • Hopkins, Roman Palestine 200-400op. cit. (n. 2, 1980), 120-2; (n. 2, 1995/6), 47 = (n. 2, 2002), 201; (n. 2, 2009), 183-4
    • (1980) Roman Palestine 200-400 , pp. 120-122
    • Hopkins1
  • 91
    • 84876408678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Maddison, Roman Palestine 200-400op. cit. (n. 2), 47-51, for higher mean income in Italy due to a higher concentration of élite incomes and tax (and rent) transfers from other regions. This issue and its implications for the tax regime merit further investigation
    • Roman Palestine 200-400 , pp. 47-51
    • Maddison1
  • 95
    • 0006591903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We agree with the findings and arguments of Duncan-Jones, Structure and Scale in the Roman Economy (op. cit. (n. 23), 33, 133-5. Although higher-risk investments were associated with higher interest rates (12 per cent rather than the usual 5-6.7 per cent reported for many charitable foundations), such investments would not always have yielded the expected return; and moreover a certain proportion of élite wealth was tied up in non-productive assets without generating regular returns at all. All this suggests that the margins of uncertainty are moderate and that actual average yields did not greatly exceed the conventional rate of 6 per cent
    • Structure and Scale in the Roman Economy , pp. 33
    • Duncan-Jones1
  • 97
    • 84876411192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • private wealth on that scale, see
    • For examples of private wealth on that scale, see Duncan-Jones, The Senate of Imperial Rome (op. cit. (n. 23), 343-4
    • The Senate of Imperial Rome , pp. 343-344
    • Duncan-Jones1
  • 101
    • 84876411718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some senators, of course, barely reached the minimum or relied on the emperor to make up the difference: Talbert, Totus in praediis (op. cit. (n. 56), 52-3
    • Totus in Praediis , pp. 52-53
    • Talbert1
  • 102
    • 84876412944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See briefly Scheidel, Totus in praediis (op. cit. (n. 3), 50 (Plut., Cic. 31.1: 20,000 knights supported Cicero; Dion. Hal. 6.13.4: 5,000 knights annually paraded under Augustus; Strab. 3.5.3, 5.1.7: Gades and Patavium each boasted 500 knights)
    • Totus in Praediis , pp. 50
    • Scheidel1
  • 103
    • 84876412449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that the Trajanic alimentary tables record nine estates with values above the equestrian census threshold in Veleia but only two in Ligures Baebiani: Duncan-Jones, Totus in praediis (op. cit. (n. 23), 211
    • Totus in Praediis , pp. 211
    • Duncan-Jones1
  • 104
    • 79957404372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jongman, Totus in praediis (op. cit. (n. 1, 2006), 248 n. 35 reckons with a minimum of 5,000 knights in Italy but none elsewhere, which must be far from the truth
    • (2006) Totus in Praediis , pp. 248
    • Jongman1
  • 105
    • 0346168731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • W. Jongman, The Economy and Society of Pompeii (1988), 193 n. 5 reckons with 100 cities of 100 councillors each and 330 cities of 30 councillors each, for a total of 20,000 in Roman Italy. Italy had a disproportionately large share of small towns. Towns in Gaul and parts of Spain were less numerous and had larger territories. This accounts for our very rough split. Somewhat different distributions, such as 333 large cities and 667 small ones, would not make a big difference (resulting in 53,300 instead of 65,000 decurions)
    • (1988) The Economy and Society of Pompeii , pp. 193
    • Jongman, W.1
  • 106
    • 0346168731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jongman, The Economy and Society of Pompeii (op. cit. (n. 1, 2006), 248 n. 35, multiplies his estimate for Italy by five to scale up to the entire Empire, for 100,000 decurions overall. This seems too low because it applies the large share of small towns in Italy to other provinces and neglects the larger councils in the East (see below)
    • (2006) The Economy and Society of Pompeii , pp. 248
    • Jongman1
  • 108
    • 63849088641 scopus 로고
    • Roman Asia Minor
    • See T. R. S. Broughton, 'Roman Asia Minor', in ESAR IV (1938), 814 (60 in Cnidus, 100 in Halicarnassus, 450 in Ephesus, 500 in Oenoanda, and 500-650(?) in Thyatira)
    • (1938) ESAR , vol.4 , pp. 814
    • Broughton, T.R.S.1
  • 111
    • 84876418740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duncan-Jones, Die Rechtliche und Soziale Stellung derop. cit. (n. 23), 284-6. In cases in which both the number of councillors and the number of Augustales are known or can be inferred, the latter amounted to 18-20 per cent, 60-67 per cent, 173-218 per cent, and 250 per cent of the former. It is manifestly impossible to deduce an average ratio from these wildly divergent tallies
    • Die Rechtliche und Soziale Stellung der , pp. 284-286
    • Duncan-Jones1
  • 113
    • 0038154365 scopus 로고
    • Pareto's law
    • See J. Persky, 'Pareto's law', Journal of Economic Perspectives 6 (1992), 181-92 for a survey of the debate. For an application to the Forbes 400 (i.e., the 400 richest persons in the United States)
    • (1992) Journal of Economic Perspectives , vol.6 , pp. 181-192
    • Persky, J.1
  • 114
    • 31344468833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Forbes 400 and the Pareto wealth distribution
    • see O. S. Klass et al., 'The Forbes 400 and the Pareto wealth distribution', Economics Letters 90 (2006), 290-5
    • (2006) Economics Letters , vol.90 , pp. 290-295
    • Klass, O.S.1
  • 115
    • 84876413797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and cf. the criticism by Maddison, Economics Lettersop. cit. (n. 2), 47. By contrast, as noted above, the estimate advocated by Milanovic and associates appears to be too high even if we make proper allowance for the considerable uncertainties involved in this kind of exercise
    • Economics Letters , pp. 47
    • Maddison1
  • 116
    • 84876416991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Friesen, Economics Lettersop. cit. (n. 3), 337-47 (imperial élites; regional/provincial élites; municipal élites; moderate surplus resources; stable neat subsistence; at subsistence; below subsistence)
    • Economics Letters , pp. 337-347
    • Friesen1
  • 117
    • 0027721151 scopus 로고
    • New sources and new techniques for the study of secular trends in nutritional status, health, mortality and the process of aging
    • For the notion of average incomes below subsistence, see comparative evidence for eighteenth-century France (R. W. Fogel, 'New sources and new techniques for the study of secular trends in nutritional status, health, mortality and the process of aging', Historical Methods 26 (1993), 5-43) and more recent developing countries
    • (1993) Historical Methods , vol.26 , pp. 5-43
    • Fogel, R.W.1
  • 118
    • 0001897637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The income inequality of France in historical perspective
    • See below, Table 11. Note that this breakdown is similar (yet somewhat more benign: cf. below, at nn. 87-8) to that proposed for late eighteenth-century France where the top 10 per cent of income-earners captured about one-half of all income: see C. Morrisson and W. Snyder, 'The income inequality of France in historical perspective', European Review of Economic History 4 (2000), 74 table 8, and below for similar inequality measures (Gini coefficient)
    • (2000) European Review of Economic History , vol.4 , pp. 74
    • Morrisson, C.1    Snyder, W.2
  • 123
    • 79957410120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These are goods which some people were too poor to consume at all, while the rich would only consume a finite amount of them, rather than an amount that was directly proportionate to their income. Meat is a good example: see Jongman, European Review of Economic Historyop. cit. (n. 1, 2007), 613 for the point that while the very poor may not have eaten any meat and the somewhat better off would have consumed certain amounts, the super-rich could not have ingested vast quantities
    • (2007) European Review of Economic History , pp. 613
    • Jongman1
  • 124
    • 33947599826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • e.g., passim for the supposed dominance of élite and state demand
    • See, e.g., C. Wickham, Framing the Early Middle Ages (2005), passim for the supposed dominance of élite and state demand
    • (2005) Framing the Early middle Ages
    • Wickham, C.1
  • 125
    • 34748817103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond the limits of the "consumer city": A model of the urban and rural economy in the Roman world
    • The best exposition of the 'consumer-city' concept is P. Erdkamp, 'Beyond the limits of the "consumer city": a model of the urban and rural economy in the Roman world', Historia 50 (2001), 332-56. Urban residence did not preclude non-urban sources of income
    • (2001) Historia , vol.50 , pp. 332-356
    • Erdkamp, P.1
  • 126
    • 84876416743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • the hypothetical income scale for large cities
    • cf. the hypothetical income scale for large cities in Friesen, Historia op. cit. (n. 3), 337-47
    • Historia , pp. 337-347
    • Friesen1
  • 127
    • 84876411300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above, n. 52, and cf. for an earlier sketch
    • See above, n. 52, and cf. Scheidel, Historia op. cit. (n. 3), 50-1 for an earlier sketch
    • Historia , pp. 50-51
    • Scheidel1
  • 128
    • 84878976547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an analysis of the nature of Roman economic growth and its built-in constraints, see now Scheidel, Historiaop. cit. (n. 1, 2009)
    • (2009) Historia
    • Scheidel1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.