메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 42, Issue 2, 2010, Pages 207-227

Taxation and credible commitment left, right, and partisan turnover

(1)  Timmons, Jeffrey F a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77749336614     PISSN: 00104159     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.5129/001041510X12911363509558     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (26)

References (51)
  • 1
    • 0003765613 scopus 로고
    • Urbana-Champaign: University of Illinois Press, 1986
    • For the redistribution hypothesis, see, for example, John D. Stephens, The Transition from Capitalism to Socialism (Urbana-Champaign: University of Illinois Press, 1979 [1986]);
    • (1979) The Transition from Capitalism to Socialism
    • Stephens, J.D.1
  • 4
    • 33746058993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: Why some democracies redistribute more than others
    • April 1006
    • Torben Iversen and David Soskice, "Electoral Institutions and the Politics of Coalitions: Why Some Democracies Redistribute More than Others," American Political Science Review, 100 (April 1006): 165-81.
    • American Political Science Review , vol.100 , pp. 165-181
    • Iversen, T.1    Soskice, D.2
  • 5
    • 84945768987 scopus 로고
    • A note on taxation, development, and representative government
    • For the fiscal contract literature, see Robert H. Bates and Donald D. Lien, "A Note on Taxation, Development, and Representative Government," Politics & Society, 14 (1985): 53-70;
    • (1985) Politics & Society , vol.14 , pp. 53-70
    • Bates, R.H.1    Lien, D.D.2
  • 6
    • 84936628583 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • Margaret Levi, Of Rule and Revenue (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988); and
    • (1988) Of Rule and Revenue
    • Levi, M.1
  • 7
    • 33745025068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The fiscal contract: States, taxes and public services
    • October
    • Jeffrey F. Timmons, "The Fiscal Contract: States, Taxes and Public Services," World Politics, 57 (October 2005): 530-567
    • (2005) World Politics , vol.57 , pp. 530-567
    • Timmons, J.F.1
  • 8
    • 85036779977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The countries are Austria (AUS), Australia (AUL), Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden (SWE), Switzerland (SWZ), United Kingdom, and the United States.
    • The countries are Austria (AUS), Australia (AUL), Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden (SWE), Switzerland (SWZ), United Kingdom, and the United States.
  • 9
    • 77749338657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Readers may also remember torben Iversen's (surprising?) finding that partisanship has no permanent effect on social spending within countries; the results herein show that parties matter once we account for turnover. Iversen
    • Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press
    • Readers may also remember Torben Iversen's (surprising?) finding that partisanship has no permanent effect on social spending within countries; the results herein show that parties matter once we account for turnover. Iversen, Capitalism, Democracy and Welfare (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2005).
    • (2005) Capitalism, Democracy and Welfare
  • 10
    • 0038404981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distribution and redistribution in post-industrial democracies
    • April 2003
    • Stephens, Capitalism to Socialism; Boix, Political Parties; and David Bradley et al., "Distribution and Redistribution in Post-industrial Democracies," World Politics, 55 (April 2003): 193-228.
    • World Politics , vol.55 , pp. 193-228
    • Bradley, D.1
  • 12
    • 84971698875 scopus 로고
    • Politics, institutions, and welfare spending in industrialized democracies, 1960-1982
    • September
    • Alexander Hicks and Duane Swank, "Politics, Institutions, and Welfare Spending in Industrialized Democracies, 1960-1982," American Political Science Review, 86 (September 1992): 658-674
    • (1992) American Political Science Review , vol.86 , pp. 658-674
    • Hicks, A.1    Swank, D.2
  • 13
    • 0000844391 scopus 로고
    • Governmental redistribution in rich capitalist democracies
    • December
    • One notable exception to the rule whereby spending is conflated with redistribution is Alexander Hicks and Duane Swank, "Governmental Redistribution in Rich Capitalist Democracies," Policy Studies Journal, 10 (December 1984): 264-87.
    • (1984) Policy Studies Journal , vol.10 , pp. 264-287
    • Hicks, A.1    Swank, D.2
  • 14
    • 85036779668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Several recent studies (e.g. Iversen and Soskice and Bradley et al.) use microdata from the Luxembourg Income Studies LIS, to make similar claims. Since LIS data are top-coded and do not include indirect taxes, they do not accurately capture taxes for top and bottom income groups.
    • Several recent studies (e.g. Iversen and Soskice and Bradley et al.) use microdata from the Luxembourg Income Studies (LIS, http://www.lisproject.org/ keyfigures/metnods.hrm) to make similar claims. Since LIS data are top-coded and do not include indirect taxes, they do not accurately capture taxes for top and bottom income groups.
  • 15
    • 77749342182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the 2000 LIS survey for the United States, for example, the highest income tax paid by a household was roughly US$400,000; in actuality, the top 15,000 taxpayers paid an average of USS10M each in 1995 my calculations using data from the Internal Revenue Service (IRS Data Book, FY 2002, Publication 55b, Washington, DC, 2002) and Daniel R. and James M. Poterba, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
    • In the 2000 LIS survey for the United States, for example, the highest income tax paid by a household was roughly US$400,000; in actuality, the top 15,000 taxpayers paid an average of USS10M each in 1995 (my calculations using data from the Internal Revenue Service (IRS Data Book, FY 2002, Publication 55b, Washington, DC, 2002) and Daniel R. and James M. Poterba, "The Income and Tax Share of Very High Income Households, 1960-1995," (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 7525, 2000).
    • (2000) The Income and Tax Share of Very High Income Households, 1960-1995 , pp. 7525
  • 19
    • 84971791553 scopus 로고
    • Structural dependence of the state on capital
    • March also see Lindert, Growing Public.
    • Adam Przeworski and Michael Wallerstein, "Structural Dependence of the State on Capital," American Political Science Review, 82 (March 1988): 11-29; also see Lindert, Growing Public.
    • (1988) American Political Science Review , vol.82 , pp. 11-29
    • Przeworski, A.1    Wallerstein, M.2
  • 21
    • 3042850584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Remodeling the competition for capital: How domestic politics erases the race to the bottom
    • April
    • Kato, Regressive Taxation; and Scott J. Basinger and Mark S. Hallerberg, "Remodeling the Competition for Capital: How Domestic Politics Erases the Race to the Bottom," American Political Science Review, 98 (April 2002): 261-276
    • (2002) American Political Science Review , vol.98 , pp. 261-276
    • Basinger, S.J.1    Hallerberg, M.S.2
  • 22
    • 0036323043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The new political economy of taxation in advanced capitalist democracies
    • June and Basinger and Hallerberg, "Remodeling the Competition."
    • The globalization literature finds that veto players retard convergence on tax policy. See Duane W. Swank and Sven Steinmo, "The New Political Economy of Taxation in Advanced Capitalist Democracies," American Journal of Political Science, 46 (June 2002): 642-55; and Basinger and Hallerberg, "Remodeling the Competition."
    • (2002) American Journal of Political Science , vol.46 , pp. 642-655
    • Swank, D.W.1    Steinmo, S.2
  • 23
    • 0043229630 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Redistributive effect, progressivity and differential tax treatment: Personal income taxes in twelve oecd countries
    • April
    • Adam Wagstaff et al., "Redistributive Effect, Progressivity and Differential Tax Treatment: Personal Income Taxes in Twelve OECD Countries," Journal of Public Economics, 72 (April 1999): 73-98.
    • (1999) Journal of Public Economics , vol.72 , pp. 73-98
    • Wagstaff, A.1
  • 24
    • 38248999782 scopus 로고
    • A fairness approach to income tax evasion
    • October
    • Massimo Bordignon, "A Fairness Approach to Income Tax Evasion," Journal of Public Economics, 52 (October1993): 345-62.
    • (1993) Journal of Public Economics , vol.52 , pp. 345-362
    • Bordignon, M.1
  • 25
    • 77749310544 scopus 로고
    • Note on taxation and levi
    • Douglass North, Growth and Structural Change New York: Norton, See also, Bates and Lein
    • Douglass North, Growth and Structural Change (New York: Norton, 1981). See also, Bates and Lein, "Note on Taxation"; and Levi, OfRule and Revenue.
    • (1981) OfRule and Revenue.
  • 26
    • 0001537602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax compliance
    • For summaries, see James Andreoni, Brian Erard, and Jonathan Feinstein, June
    • For summaries, see James Andreoni, Brian Erard, and Jonathan Feinstein, "Tax Compliance," Journal of Economic Literature, 36 (June 1998): 818-60;
    • (1998) Journal of Economic Literature , vol.36 , pp. 818-860
  • 28
    • 85036788925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Quasi-voluntary compliance comes from levi
    • The phrase
    • The phrase "quasi-voluntary compliance" comes from Levi, Of Rule and Revenue.
    • Of Rule and Revenue.
  • 29
    • 0000440641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When does it take a nixon to go to China?
    • March
    • Alex Cuckierman and Mariano Tommasi, "When Does It Take a Nixon to Go to China?" The American Economic Review, 88 (March 1998): 180-197
    • (1998) The American Economic Review , vol.88 , pp. 180-197
    • Cuckierman, A.1    Tommasi, M.2
  • 30
    • 85036797411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax/GDP ratios are supplemented with average effective tax rates (AETR) on factor incomes using the OECD's revised series. For space reasons, those results, as well as a detailed discussion of the strengths and weakness of AETRs, have been confined to the web appendix.
    • Tax/GDP ratios are supplemented with average effective tax rates (AETR) on factor incomes using the OECD's revised series. For space reasons, those results, as well as a detailed discussion of the strengths and weakness of AETRs, have been confined to the web appendix.
  • 31
    • 77749332551 scopus 로고
    • Distributional aspects of a federal value-added tax
    • A 10 percent VAT in the United States, for example, would take 12 percent of gross income from families earning US$10,000, versus 4 percent for families earning US$100,000, according to Edith Brashares, June
    • A 10 percent VAT in the United States, for example, would take 12 percent of gross income from families earning US$10,000, versus 4 percent for families earning US$100,000, according to Edith Brashares, Janet Speyrer, and George Carlson, "Distributional Aspects of a Federal Value-Added Tax," National Tax Journal, 41 (June 1988): 155-74.
    • (1988) National Tax Journal , vol.41 , pp. 155-174
    • Speyrer, J.1    Carlson, G.2
  • 33
    • 0003667909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Northwestern University, University of North Carolina, Duke University, and Indiana University, Left parties include social democrats and communists. All religious parties are considered Christian Democrats.
    • Evelyne Huber, Charles Ragin, John D. Stephens, David Brady, and Jason Beckfield, Comparative Welfare Data Set (Northwestern University, University of North Carolina, Duke University, and Indiana University, 2004). Left parties include social democrats and communists. All religious parties are considered Christian Democrats.
    • (2004) Comparative Welfare Data Set
    • Huber, E.1    Ragin, C.2    Stephens, J.D.3    Brady, D.4    Beckfield, J.5
  • 34
    • 0013442022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Huber et al.'s measure of Left is correlated at 0.98 with Armingeon, Gerber, Leimguber, Beyeler, and Menegale's's measure. There are discrepancies with Right and Center since Christian Democratic parties are not separated out in the latter. Institute of Political Science, University of Berne
    • Huber et al.'s measure of Left is correlated at 0.98 with Armingeon, Gerber, Leimguber, Beyeler, and Menegale's's measure. There are discrepancies with Right and Center since Christian Democratic parties are not separated out in the latter. Klaus Armingeon, Marlène Gerber, Philipp Leimgruber, Michelle Beyeler, and Sarah Menegale, Comparative Political Data Set 1960-2005 (Institute of Political Science, University of Berne, 2007).
    • (2007) Comparative Political Data Set 1960-2005
    • Armingeon, K.1    Gerber, M.2    Leimgruber, P.3    Beyeler, M.4    Menegale, S.5
  • 35
    • 85036798998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Since not all seats are classified every year, we create a residual category (other cabinet) for each of the aforementioned measures. The other cabinet category is meaningless since it also includes rounding error (associated with converting fractions to decimals). We estimate all models with the residual category, but exclude it from tables.
    • Since not all seats are classified every year, we create a residual category (other cabinet) for each of the aforementioned measures. The other cabinet category is meaningless since it also includes rounding error (associated with converting fractions to decimals). We estimate all models with the residual category, but exclude it from tables.
  • 36
    • 85036787363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The three measures have the same minimums and similar means; including more history reduces the maximums and variance (Table 1A in the Appendix). The correlations between the long-run and annual measures are 0.73 for Right Stable; 0.67 for Right Volatile; 0.80 for Left Stable; and 0.60 for Left Volatile.
    • The three measures have the same minimums and similar means; including more history reduces the maximums and variance (Table 1A in the Appendix). The correlations between the long-run and annual measures are 0.73 for Right Stable; 0.67 for Right Volatile; 0.80 for Left Stable; and 0.60 for Left Volatile.
  • 37
    • 85036798726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We initially divided the sample into thirds and created three binary dummies of volatility (most, least, intermediate). But the main identifiable break in the data is between the most volatile countries- approximately one standard deviation above the sample's standard deviation-and everyone else. Given the somewhat arbitrary cut-point, we present jackknifed results. Also note that Cusack's data does not include New Zealand. Rather than arbitrarily put it into either category, we coded it as neutral, weighing Left and Right by 0.5, rather than 0 or 1. A table showing the consequences of classifying New Zealand in various ways is available.
  • 39
    • 85036796820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Our main interest is taxes. We recognize that corporate share of pre-tax national income is imperfect because corporate profits and taxes could track each other under various circumstances. The implicit assumption is that governments manipulate tax bases, not just tax rates.
    • Our main interest is taxes. We recognize that corporate share of pre-tax national income is imperfect because corporate profits and taxes could track each other under various circumstances. The implicit assumption is that governments manipulate tax bases, not just tax rates.
  • 40
    • 77749310541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taking time seriously: Dynamic regression models
    • Penn State University
    • The Bewley Tranformation employed is detailed in Suzanna De Boef and Luke Keele, "Taking Time Seriously: Dynamic Regression Models," mimeo (Penn State University, 2006).
    • (2006) Mimeo
    • De Boef, S.1    Keele, L.2
  • 41
    • 85036798895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The residual and lagged residuals are generally correlated at less than 0.1
    • The residual and lagged residuals are generally correlated at less than 0.1.
  • 42
    • 0002206552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nuisance vs. substance: Specifying and estimating time-series- cross-section models
    • Winter PCSE are shown; clustered SEs can be found in the appendix on the web
    • Neal Beck and Jonathan Katz, "Nuisance vs. Substance: Specifying and Estimating Time-Series- Cross-Section Models," Political Analysis, 6 (Winter 1996): 1-36. PCSE are shown; clustered SEs can be found in the appendix on the web.
    • (1996) Political Analysis , vol.6 , pp. 1-36
    • Beck, N.1    Katz, J.2
  • 43
    • 85036781190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We ran these models with interactions for all partisan categories, but have omitted them to keep the tables manageable. The full table is in the appendix on the web.
    • We ran these models with interactions for all partisan categories, but have omitted them to keep the tables manageable. The full table is in the appendix on the web.
  • 44
    • 85036795587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Including inequality dramatically drops the N, from approximately 500 to approximately 300. With inequality our coefficients and standard errors change dramatically, generally in ways that are favorable to our propositions, especially with corporate taxation. That said, dummy variable regressions (with data, without data) indicate that the changes associated with inequality reflect changes in the sample as much as (if not more than) conditioning on inequality.
  • 45
    • 85036791012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • With the exception of Model 5, the corporate tax models shown include Christian Democrat dominated Italy. When Italy is included, our results are robust as long as corporate profits are not included as a control (i.e., Models 1-3). With Italy and corporate profits our results are rarely significant at conventional levels (Model 4). Italy's mean value for corporate profits/GDP more than two SDs above the OECD mean.
  • 46
    • 85036784963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The absolute values of the confidence intervals overlap.
    • The absolute values of the confidence intervals overlap
  • 47
    • 85036775753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The main discrepancy between the different time frames of partisan influence is the magnitude of the coefficients (rather than their level of significance). More history translates into larger coefficients. We suspect the reason for this difference is that one year provides parties little time to enact policies for their constituents; multiple years, by contrast, allow parties to ramp up benefits.
  • 48
    • 0032391524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cooperation and political economic performance in affluent democratic capitalism
    • DOI 10.1086/231403
    • 35. Alexander Hicks and Lane Kenworthy, "Cooperation and Political Economic Performance in Affluent Democratic Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology, 103 (May 1998): 1631-1672 (Pubitemid 128116805)
    • (1998) American Journal of Sociology , vol.103 , Issue.6 , pp. 1631-1672
    • Hicks, A.1    Kenworthy, L.2
  • 49
    • 34347406510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The korean welfare state: A paradox of expansion in an era of globalisation and economic crisis
    • July OECD, Revenue Statistics.
    • Soonman Kwon and Ian Holliday, "The Korean Welfare State: A Paradox of Expansion in an Era of Globalisation and Economic Crisis," International Journal of Social Welfare, 16 (July 2007): 242-48. OECD, Revenue Statistics.
    • (2007) International Journal of Social Welfare , vol.16 , pp. 242-248
    • Kwon, S.1    Holliday, I.2
  • 50
    • 0034754775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New tools in comparative political economy: The database of political institutions (2001/2003)
    • September
    • Partisan data from Thorsten Beck et al., "New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions (2001/2003)," World Bank Economic Review, 15 (September 2001): 165-76.
    • (2001) World Bank Economic Review , vol.15 , pp. 165-176
  • 51
    • 85036774602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is obviously not a scientific endeavor since we selected on the dependent variable, but it is worth noting that in terms of country-years there is a rough balance between Left and Right in the DPI data. Excluding the EU, the ratio of Left to Right VATs is 21 to 11 in favor of the Left. A table of countries can be found in the web appendix. VAT data from Liam P. Ebrill et al., The Modern VAT (Washington, DC: The International Monetary Fund, 2001)
    • This is obviously not a scientific endeavor since we selected on the dependent variable, but it is worth noting that in terms of country-years there is a rough balance between Left and Right in the DPI data. Excluding the EU, the ratio of Left to Right VATs is 21 to 11 in favor of the Left. A table of countries can be found in the web appendix. VAT data from Liam P. Ebrill et al., The Modern VAT (Washington, DC: The International Monetary Fund, 2001).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.