메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 59, Issue 1, 2009, Pages 61-124

Patent infringement as nuisance

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77749270642     PISSN: 00088390     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (17)

References (306)
  • 1
    • 0348068347 scopus 로고
    • Holdouts and Free Riders, 20
    • discussing difficulties common to negotiations that often result in the failure of parties to reach an agreement, See generally
    • See generally Lloyd Cohen, Holdouts and Free Riders, 20 J. LEGAL STUD. 351 (1991) (discussing difficulties common to negotiations that often result in the failure of parties to reach an agreement).
    • (1991) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.351
    • Cohen, L.1
  • 2
    • 77749315160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for 52 Intellectual Property Professors as Amici Curiae in Support of Petitioners, eBay, Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388 (2006) (No. 05-130), 2006 WL 1785363 (arguing that such a settlement amounts to holdup money that is not a legitimate part of the value of a patent, but is instead, a windfall to the patent owner).
    • Brief for 52 Intellectual Property Professors as Amici Curiae in Support of Petitioners, eBay, Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388 (2006) (No. 05-130), 2006 WL 1785363 (arguing that such a settlement amounts to "holdup money" that is "not a legitimate part of the value of a patent," but is instead, "a windfall to the patent owner").
  • 3
    • 34547733961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking, 85 TEX. L. REV. 1991, 1993 (2007) (Such royalty overcharges act as a tax on new products incorporating the patented technology, thereby impeding rather than promoting innovation.).
    • See Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking, 85 TEX. L. REV. 1991, 1993 (2007) ("Such royalty overcharges act as a tax on new products incorporating the patented technology, thereby impeding rather than promoting innovation.").
  • 4
    • 77749318219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., MercExchange, L.L.C. v. eBay, Inc., 401 F.3d 1323, 1338 (Fed. Cir. 2005) ([CJourts have in rare instances exercised their discretion to deny injunctive relief in order to protect the public interest. (quoting Rite-Hite Corp. v. Kelley Co., 56 F.3d 1538, 1547 (Fed. Cir. 1995) (internal quotation marks omitted))), vacated, 547 U.S. 388 (2006).
    • See, e.g., MercExchange, L.L.C. v. eBay, Inc., 401 F.3d 1323, 1338 (Fed. Cir. 2005) ("[CJourts have in rare instances exercised their discretion to deny injunctive relief in order to protect the public interest." (quoting Rite-Hite Corp. v. Kelley Co., 56 F.3d 1538, 1547 (Fed. Cir. 1995) (internal quotation marks omitted))), vacated, 547 U.S. 388 (2006).
  • 5
    • 77749316786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MercExchange, 401 F.3d at 1338 (quoting Richardson v. Suzuki Motor Co., 868 F.2d 1226, 1247 (Fed. Cir. 1989));
    • MercExchange, 401 F.3d at 1338 (quoting Richardson v. Suzuki Motor Co., 868 F.2d 1226, 1247 (Fed. Cir. 1989));
  • 6
    • 77749318216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see, e.g., Connell v. Sears, Roebuck & Co., 722 F.2d 1542, 1548 (Fed. Cir. 1983) ([A] patent is a form of property right, and the right to exclude recognized in a patent is but the essence of the concept of property.);
    • see, e.g., Connell v. Sears, Roebuck & Co., 722 F.2d 1542, 1548 (Fed. Cir. 1983) ("[A] patent is a form of property right, and the right to exclude recognized in a patent is but the essence of the concept of property.");
  • 7
    • 77749318220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schenck v. Nortron Corp., 713 F.2d 782, 786 n.3 (Fed. Cir. 1983) (The patent right is but the right to exclude others, the very definition of 'property.').
    • Schenck v. Nortron Corp., 713 F.2d 782, 786 n.3 (Fed. Cir. 1983) ("The patent right is but the right to exclude others, the very definition of 'property.'").
  • 8
    • 77749315164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MercExchange, 401 F.3d at 1338 (articulating the general rule . . . that a permanent injunction will issue once infringement and validity have been adjudged).
    • MercExchange, 401 F.3d at 1338 (articulating the "general rule . . . that a permanent injunction will issue once infringement and validity have been adjudged").
  • 9
    • 77749315163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cBay, Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388, 392 (2006).
    • cBay, Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388, 392 (2006).
  • 10
    • 84868169271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 391. Several property scholars have begun to point out that this seeming anomaly of a "right to exclude" that is not necessarily enforced as such may simply stem from a fundamental error that was made by the realists in focusing on exclusion as the essence of property
    • may be used
    • Id. at 391. Several property scholars have begun to point out that this seeming anomaly of a "right to exclude" that is not necessarily enforced as such may simply stem from a fundamental error that was made by the realists in focusing on exclusion as the essence of property. In this view, the pre-realist natural and common law tradition is better read to assign property owners "a right to determine exclusively how a thing may be used."
    • In this view, the pre-realist natural and common law tradition is better read to assign property owners a right to determine exclusively how a thing
    • Cohen, L.1
  • 11
    • 77749316783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eric R. Claeys, Property 101: Is Property a Thing or a Bundle?, 32 SEATTLE U. L. REV. 617, 631 (2009);
    • Eric R. Claeys, Property 101: Is Property a Thing or a Bundle?, 32 SEATTLE U. L. REV. 617, 631 (2009);
  • 12
    • 77249161152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Larissa Katz, Exclusion and Exclusivity in Property Law, 58 U. TORONTO L.J. 275, 275 (2008) (arguing that the central concern of the structure of property ownership is not the exclusion of all non-owners from the owned thing but, rather, the preservation of the owner's position as the exclusive agenda setter for the owned thing);
    • see also Larissa Katz, Exclusion and Exclusivity in Property Law, 58 U. TORONTO L.J. 275, 275 (2008) (arguing that the "central concern" of the structure of property ownership "is not the exclusion of all non-owners from the owned thing but, rather, the preservation of the owner's position as the exclusive agenda setter for the owned thing");
  • 13
    • 77749315155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adam Mossoff, Exclusion and Exclusive Use in Patent Law, 22 HARV. J.L. & TECH. 321, 323 (2009) (criticizing the exclusion concept of patents in patent law). As will be discussed infra at notes 69-83 and accompanying text, the work of Henry Smith can be read as partially reconciling these two lines of thought, justifying the enforcement of a right to exclude in economic terms as the most efficient means of allocating the right to determine use.
    • Adam Mossoff, Exclusion and Exclusive Use in Patent Law, 22 HARV. J.L. & TECH. 321, 323 (2009) (criticizing the "exclusion concept of patents" in patent law). As will be discussed infra at notes 69-83 and accompanying text, the work of Henry Smith can be read as partially reconciling these two lines of thought, justifying the enforcement of a "right to exclude" in economic terms as the most efficient means of allocating the right to determine use.
  • 14
    • 77749305881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See eBay, 547 U.S. at 391-93 ([A] plaintiff seeking a permanent injunction must satisfy a four-factor test before a court may grant such relief.).
    • See eBay, 547 U.S. at 391-93 ("[A] plaintiff seeking a permanent injunction must satisfy a four-factor test before a court may grant such relief.").
  • 15
    • 77749318109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 3, at 2035-44 (proposing a model for patent reform that withholds injunctive relief under some circumstances);
    • See, e.g, Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 3, at 2035-44 (proposing a model for patent reform that withholds injunctive relief under some circumstances);
  • 16
    • 54049128155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Vincenzo Denicolò et al, Revisiting Injunctive Relief: Interpreting eBay in High-Tech Industries with Non-Practicing Patent Holders, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 571, 590-91 2008, arguing that courts should not withhold injunctive relief where manufacturer failed to exhibit due diligence in searching for IP rights or where redesign was impossible ex ante
    • see also Vincenzo Denicolò et al., Revisiting Injunctive Relief: Interpreting eBay in High-Tech Industries with Non-Practicing Patent Holders, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 571, 590-91 (2008) (arguing that courts should not withhold injunctive relief where manufacturer failed to exhibit due diligence in searching for IP rights or where redesign was impossible ex ante);
  • 17
    • 34547794065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commentary,
    • Patent Trolls and Patent Remedies, 85 TEX. L. REV. 2111, 2147-48 2007, critiquing as overly broad Lemley and Shapiro's model predicting overcompensation of patent owners resulting from the presumptive availability of injunctive relief
    • John M. Golden, Commentary, "Patent Trolls" and Patent Remedies, 85 TEX. L. REV. 2111, 2147-48 (2007) (critiquing as overly broad Lemley and Shapiro's model predicting " overcompensation" of patent owners resulting from the presumptive availability of injunctive relief);
    • Golden, J.M.1
  • 18
    • 34247133790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mark A. Lemley & Philip J. Weiser, Should Property or Liability Rules Govern Information?, 85 TEX. L. REV 783, 784-85 (2007) ([T]here are a number of cases arising under patent law that should not qualify for injunctive relief, including possibly the eBay case itself....).
    • Mark A. Lemley & Philip J. Weiser, Should Property or Liability Rules Govern Information?, 85 TEX. L. REV 783, 784-85 (2007) ("[T]here are a number of cases arising under patent law that should not qualify for injunctive relief, including possibly the eBay case itself....").
  • 19
    • 77749306084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • eBay, 547 U.S. at 393.
    • eBay, 547 U.S. at 393.
  • 20
    • 77749308171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • declining to adopt a categorical rule premised on a four-factor test
    • See id. (declining to adopt a categorical rule premised on a four-factor test).
    • See id
  • 21
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part II discussing the inefficiency and distributive injustice of holdout power in the context of property
    • See infra Part II (discussing the inefficiency and distributive injustice of holdout power in the context of property).
    • See infra
  • 22
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 5 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 5 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 23
    • 77749313993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part V.B (examining infringement in comparison to trespass and encroachment in comparison to nuisance);
    • See infra Part V.B (examining infringement in comparison to trespass and encroachment in comparison to nuisance);
  • 24
    • 77749305994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Archer v. Greenville Sand & Gravel Co., 233 U.S. 60, 64-65 (1914) (granting injunction as relief for trespass); Urban Site Venture II L.P. v. Levering Assoes., 665 A.2d 1062 (Md. 1995) (granting injunction as relief for encroachment);
    • see also Archer v. Greenville Sand & Gravel Co., 233 U.S. 60, 64-65 (1914) (granting injunction as relief for trespass); Urban Site Venture II L.P. v. Levering Assoes., 665 A.2d 1062 (Md. 1995) (granting injunction as relief for encroachment);
  • 25
    • 84868176619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RICHARD R. POWELL, POWELL ON REAL PROPERTY § 68.09 (Michael Allan Wolf ed., 2009) (discussing injunctions as proper equitable relief for a finding of encroachment).
    • RICHARD R. POWELL, POWELL ON REAL PROPERTY § 68.09 (Michael Allan Wolf ed., 2009) (discussing injunctions as proper equitable relief for a finding of encroachment).
  • 26
    • 77749313995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra Parts IV.B, V.B.
    • See discussion infra Parts IV.B, V.B.
  • 27
    • 77749316709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By ex ante, I mean efforts that occur prior to making the irreversible investments that render one susceptible to holdout.
    • By "ex ante," I mean efforts that occur prior to making the irreversible investments that render one susceptible to holdout.
  • 28
    • 0009992505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Richard A. Epstein, A Clear View of The Cathedral: The Dominance of Property Rules, 106 YALE L.J. 2091, 2092-96 (1997) [hereinafter Epstein, A Clear View];
    • See Richard A. Epstein, A Clear View of The Cathedral: The Dominance of Property Rules, 106 YALE L.J. 2091, 2092-96 (1997) [hereinafter Epstein, A Clear View];
  • 29
    • 10844258847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property and Property Rules, 79
    • hereinafter Smith, Property Rules
    • Henry E. Smith, Property and Property Rules, 79 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1719, 1731 (2004) [hereinafter Smith, Property Rules].
    • (2004) N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.1719 , pp. 1731
    • Smith, H.E.1
  • 31
    • 77749318215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The terms property rule and liability rule stem from Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed. Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089, 1092-93 (1972).
    • The terms "property rule" and "liability rule" stem from Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed. Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089, 1092-93 (1972).
  • 34
    • 77749306008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV.B.
    • See infra Part IV.B.
  • 35
    • 77749315142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 312-16 (1871) (finding that good-faith improvers who make vast improvements to a chattel may retain title).
    • See, e.g., Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 312-16 (1871) (finding that good-faith improvers who make vast improvements to a chattel may retain title).
  • 36
    • 77749306083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 37
    • 77749316753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part V.A (articulating the significant-harm rule).
    • See infra Part V.A (articulating the "significant-harm rule").
  • 38
    • 84868164028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §§822-831 (1977) (outlining the various factors needed to determine an injunction for nuisance);
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §§822-831 (1977) (outlining the various factors needed to determine an injunction for nuisance);
  • 39
    • 77749318198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Madison v. Ducktown Sulphur, Copper & Iron Co., 83 S.W. 658, 667 (Tenn. 1904) (refusing to grant an injunction because of various factors, including the value of the activity creating the nuisance).
    • see also Madison v. Ducktown Sulphur, Copper & Iron Co., 83 S.W. 658, 667 (Tenn. 1904) (refusing to grant an injunction because of various factors, including the value of the activity creating the nuisance).
  • 41
    • 34250678122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Henry E. Smith, Intellectual Property as Property: Delineating Entitlements in Information, 116 YALE L.J. 1742, 1748-49 (2007) [hereinafter Smith, Intellectual Property] (discussing the ability of property rules to reduce information costs by promoting modularity, and arguing that this renders exclusion strategies equally advantageous for intellectual and tangible property).
    • See Henry E. Smith, Intellectual Property as Property: Delineating Entitlements in Information, 116 YALE L.J. 1742, 1748-49 (2007) [hereinafter Smith, Intellectual Property] (discussing the ability of property rules to reduce information costs by promoting modularity, and arguing that this renders exclusion strategies equally advantageous for intellectual and tangible property).
  • 42
    • 77749316769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1795 (asserting that the costs of solidifying an idea protected by IP principles are not fundamentally different than the costs of constructing tangible property).
    • See id. at 1795 (asserting that the costs of solidifying an idea protected by IP principles are not "fundamentally different" than the costs of constructing tangible property).
  • 43
    • 77749316770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally United States v. Blackman, 613 S.E.2d 442, 445-46 (Va. 2005) (defining negative easements as those that convey rights to demand that the owner of the servient tract refrain from certain otherwise permissible uses of his own land and easements in gross as those benefitting individual persons as opposed to those running with tracts of land (citations omitted)).
    • See generally United States v. Blackman, 613 S.E.2d 442, 445-46 (Va. 2005) (defining negative easements as those that "convey rights to demand that the owner of the servient tract refrain from certain otherwise permissible uses of his own land" and easements in gross as those benefitting individual persons as opposed to those running with tracts of land (citations omitted)).
  • 45
    • 77749318209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parallel arguments can be made with respect to copyright law, but there are significant differences between patent law and copyright law that require separate discussion. This Article constructs a general argument and applies it to patent law, leaving the discussion of copyright law for a future project
    • Parallel arguments can be made with respect to copyright law, but there are significant differences between patent law and copyright law that require separate discussion. This Article constructs a general argument and applies it to patent law, leaving the discussion of copyright law for a future project.
  • 46
    • 77749318207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 320 (1871) (mandating that a comparison in value be considered in deciding cases of accession).
    • See, e.g., Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 320 (1871) (mandating that a comparison in value be considered in deciding cases of accession).
  • 47
    • 77749306051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • discussing governance and exclusion regimes, See generally, at
    • See generally Smith, Property Rules, supra note 18, at 1764-68 (discussing governance and exclusion regimes).
    • Property Rules, supra note , vol.18 , pp. 1764-1768
    • Smith1
  • 51
    • 77749306071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 53
    • 77749316773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. If the parties ultimately agree on a price of 400, A realizes a gain of 390, and B realizes a gain of 600. If, however, A and B spent 300 and 400 respectively in order to reach this agreement, the total surplus has been reduced to 290.
    • Id. If the parties ultimately agree on a price of 400, A realizes a gain of 390, and B realizes a gain of 600. If, however, A and B spent 300 and 400 respectively in order to reach this agreement, the total surplus has been reduced to 290.
  • 54
    • 77749306078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., A. MITCHELL POLINSKY, AN INTRODUCTION TO LAW AND ECONOMICS 10 (1983) (referring to this assumption as the assumption of consumer sovereignty);
    • See, e.g., A. MITCHELL POLINSKY, AN INTRODUCTION TO LAW AND ECONOMICS 10 (1983) (referring to this assumption as the "assumption of consumer sovereignty");
  • 55
    • 84868164025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • UDWIG VON MISES, EPISTEMOLOGICAL PROBLEMS OF ECONOMICS 178 (George Reisman trans., Ludwig von Mises Inst. 3d ed. 2003) (1933) ([T]he ultimate relevant cause of the exchange ratios of the market is the fact that the individual, in the act of exchange, prefers a definite quantity of good A to a definite quantity of good B. The reasons he may have for acting exactly thus and not otherwise ⋯ are of absolutely no importance for the determination of a market price.)
    • UDWIG VON MISES, EPISTEMOLOGICAL PROBLEMS OF ECONOMICS 178 (George Reisman trans., Ludwig von Mises Inst. 3d ed. 2003) (1933) ("[T]he ultimate relevant cause of the exchange ratios of the market is the fact that the individual, in the act of exchange, prefers a definite quantity of good A to a definite quantity of good B. The reasons he may have for acting exactly thus and not otherwise ⋯ are of absolutely no importance for the determination of a market price.")
  • 56
    • 77749306075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 20, at 1106-07 (discussing holdout in terms of a divergence between the price demanded and the value which the sellers in actuality attach).
    • See, e.g., Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 20, at 1106-07 (discussing holdout in terms of a divergence between "the price demanded" and "the value which the sellers in actuality attach").
  • 57
    • 77749306073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It may also be based on A's assessment of the subjective utility he will gain from future uses of the resource, in which case the scenario is just another variety of idiosyncratic holdout.
    • It may also be based on A's assessment of the subjective utility he will gain from future uses of the resource, in which case the scenario is just another variety of idiosyncratic holdout.
  • 58
    • 77749318204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 41-42 and accompanying text (discussing Epstein's model of a type of holdout power that gives rise to strategic bargaining and is often considered conducive to market failure).
    • See supra notes 41-42 and accompanying text (discussing Epstein's model of a type of holdout power that gives rise to strategic bargaining and is often considered conducive to market failure).
  • 59
    • 77749316771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In other words, in a market economy selling something is one of the most important things you can do with a resource
    • In other words, in a market economy selling something is one of the most important things you can do with a resource.
  • 60
    • 77749318194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, suppose the highest valued use to which A can put the resource is worth 10, while B's investment would give the resource a value of 1000. Reallocating the resource to B would thus result in a social surplus of 990. If A manages to negotiate a selling price of 800, and each party incurs 50 in transaction costs, we are left with a social surplus of 890, of which 750 is going to A and 140 is going to B.
    • For example, suppose the highest valued use to which A can put the resource is worth 10, while B's investment would give the resource a value of 1000. Reallocating the resource to B would thus result in a social surplus of 990. If A manages to negotiate a selling price of 800, and each party incurs 50 in transaction costs, we are left with a social surplus of 890, of which 750 is going to A and 140 is going to B.
  • 61
    • 21844505837 scopus 로고
    • Property Rules and Liability Rules: The Cathedral in Another Light, 70
    • criticizing the belief that liability rules are better than property rules in situations of high transaction costs
    • James E. Krier & Stewart J. Schwab, Property Rules and Liability Rules: The Cathedral in Another Light, 70 N.Y.U. L. REV. 440, 466 (1995) (criticizing the belief that liability rules are better than property rules in situations of high transaction costs).
    • (1995) N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.440 , pp. 466
    • Krier, J.E.1    Schwab, S.J.2
  • 62
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 43 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 43 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 63
    • 35248865749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posting of Lawrence Solum to Legal Theory Lexicon, July 10
    • See, e.g., Posting of Lawrence Solum to Legal Theory Lexicon, http://lsolum.typepad. com/legal-theory-lexicon/2005/07/legal-theory-le.html (July 10, 2005).
    • (2005) See, e.g
  • 64
    • 77749318182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The classic source is, of course, Locke's justification of private property on the ground that ownership arises when someone hath mixed his [1]abour with, and joyned to it something that is his own, and thereby makes it his [pjroperty. It being by him removed from the common state [n]ature placed it in, it hath by this [1]abour something annexed to it, that exludes the common right of other [m]en. JOHN LOCKE, TWO TREATISES OF GOVERNMENT 288 Peter Lasiert ed, Cambridge Univ. Press 1988, 1690, It ought to, but unfortunately does not, go without saying that when Locke says labour in this context he means productive labor-that is, labor that actually renders the common property more capable of satisfying human wants than it was before
    • The classic source is, of course, Locke's justification of private property on the ground that ownership arises when someone "hath mixed his [1]abour with, and joyned to it something that is his own, and thereby makes it his [pjroperty. It being by him removed from the common state [n]ature placed it in, it hath by this [1]abour something annexed to it, that exludes the common right of other [m]en." JOHN LOCKE, TWO TREATISES OF GOVERNMENT 288 (Peter Lasiert ed., Cambridge Univ. Press 1988) (1690). It ought to, but unfortunately does not, go without saying that when Locke says "labour" in this context he means productive labor-that is, labor that actually renders the common property more capable of satisfying human wants than it was before.
  • 65
    • 77749306059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Adam Mossoff, Locke's Labor Lost, 9 U. CHI. L. SCH. ROUNDTABLE 155, 15861 (2002) (responding to various philosophers who have dismissed Lockean property theory as incoherent or absurd based on their own incoherent or absurd notions as to what qualifies as labor).
    • See Adam Mossoff, Locke's Labor Lost, 9 U. CHI. L. SCH. ROUNDTABLE 155, 15861 (2002) (responding to various philosophers who have dismissed Lockean property theory as incoherent or absurd based on their own incoherent or absurd notions as to what qualifies as "labor").
  • 66
    • 77749318191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wendy J. Gordon, On Owning Information: Intellectual Property and the Restitutionary Impulse, 78 VA. L. REV. 149, 277-78 (1992) (discussing a trend in intellectual property law to treat all appropriations of value created by another as actionable). Gordon notes that judges may feel no need to examine the trend because the restitutionary notion that one deserves to keep the fruits of his labor seems so evidently correct, so evidently in accord with traditional notions of corrective justice and traditional conceptions of the judicial role, that giving legal protection to intellectual products appears to require no special justification.
    • See, e.g., Wendy J. Gordon, On Owning Information: Intellectual Property and the Restitutionary Impulse, 78 VA. L. REV. 149, 277-78 (1992) (discussing a trend in intellectual property law to treat all appropriations of value created by another as actionable). Gordon notes that judges may feel no need to examine the trend because the restitutionary notion that one deserves to keep the "fruits of his labor" seems so evidently correct, so evidently in accord with traditional notions of corrective justice and traditional conceptions of the judicial role, that giving legal protection to intellectual products appears to require no special justification.
  • 67
    • 77749315156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 68
    • 77749306062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter, The Best Right Laws: Value Foundations of the Economic Analysis of Law, 64 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 817, 818 (1989) (A clean answer to the 'paradox of value' is that, while water is more useful and its total utility exceeds diamonds', the relative scarcity of diamonds makes their marginal utility exceed water's.).
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter, The Best Right Laws: Value Foundations of the Economic Analysis of Law, 64 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 817, 818 (1989) ("A clean answer to the 'paradox of value' is that, while water is more useful and its total utility exceeds diamonds', the relative scarcity of diamonds makes their marginal utility exceed water's.").
  • 69
    • 77749306047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Any complete theory of distributive justice along these lines must decide whether and how to distinguish between actions that produce value intentionally (that is, where the increased ability to satisfy human wants is of the type and magnitude that the actor intended to achieve) and actions that do so unintentionally that is, where unforeseen circumstances render the results of one's efforts valuable in a way-or to a degree-that one did not intend
    • Any complete theory of distributive justice along these lines must decide whether and how to distinguish between actions that produce value intentionally (that is, where the increased ability to satisfy human wants is of the type and magnitude that the actor intended to achieve) and actions that do so unintentionally (that is, where unforeseen circumstances render the results of one's efforts valuable in a way-or to a degree-that one did not intend).
  • 70
    • 77749318200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.A.
    • See supra Part II.A.
  • 71
    • 77749315151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B.
    • See supra Part II.B.
  • 72
    • 77749316766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 20, at 1105-10. In Calabresi and Melamed's. terminology, an entitlement protected by injunction is subject to a property rule, which means that taking it without the owner's consent subjects one to severe sanctions designed to be prohibitive.
    • See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 20, at 1105-10. In Calabresi and Melamed's. terminology, an entitlement protected by injunction is subject to a "property rule," which means that taking it without the owner's consent subjects one to severe sanctions designed to be prohibitive.
  • 73
    • 77749306054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • in an amount determined by reference to some collectively determined criteria
    • Id. at 1106. When an entitlement is protected by a "liability rule" on the other hand, taking it without the owner's consent only renders one liable to pay damages to the owner in an amount determined by reference to some collectively determined criteria.
    • at 1106. When an entitlement is protected by a liability rule
  • 74
    • 77749306064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1107
    • Id. at 1107.
  • 75
    • 77749318187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley & Weiser, supra note 10, at 788. Specifically, the objection is not just that courts will not identify damages accurately but that the deviation will be systematic in one direction. As Richard Epstein puts it, the argument is that [t]he risk of undercompensation in such situations is pervasive, thereby undermining investment incentives.
    • See Lemley & Weiser, supra note 10, at 788. Specifically, the objection is not just that courts will not identify damages accurately but that the deviation will be systematic in one direction. As Richard Epstein puts it, the argument is that "[t]he risk of undercompensation in such situations is pervasive," thereby undermining investment incentives.
  • 76
    • 77749318201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As a shorthand, we call this Epstein's Law. Id. at 787-88 (quoting Epstein, A Clear View, supra note 18, at 2093).
    • As a shorthand, we call this "Epstein's Law." Id. at 787-88 (quoting Epstein, A Clear View, supra note 18, at 2093).
  • 77
    • 77749318202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 20, at 1125 (Liability rules represent only an approximation of the value of the object to its original owner and willingness to pay such an approximate value is no indication that it is worth more to the thief than to the owner.).
    • See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 20, at 1125 ("Liability rules represent only an approximation of the value of the object to its original owner and willingness to pay such an approximate value is no indication that it is worth more to the thief than to the owner.").
  • 78
    • 77749306058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra pp. 71-72 (describing a holdout scenario in which the property seller values his property higher than market value to account for subjective factors).
    • See supra pp. 71-72 (describing a holdout scenario in which the property seller values his property higher than market value to account for subjective factors).
  • 79
    • 77749315145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is not actually impossible, in principle, for a takings system to attempt to provide compensation for consequential damages the same way a tort system does; however, such is not the normal practice. See, at
    • See Epstein, A Clear View, supra note 18, at 2093. It is not actually impossible, in principle, for a takings system to attempt to provide compensation for consequential damages the same way a tort system does; however, such is not the normal practice.
    • A Clear View, supra note , vol.18 , pp. 2093
    • Epstein1
  • 80
    • 77749316760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., RICHARD A. EPSTEIN, TAKINGS: PRIVATE PROPERTY AND THE POWER OF EMINENT DOMAIN 51-56, 80-86 (1985) (exploring theories of providing compensation for consequential damages and takings of goodwill).
    • See, e.g., RICHARD A. EPSTEIN, TAKINGS: PRIVATE PROPERTY AND THE POWER OF EMINENT DOMAIN 51-56, 80-86 (1985) (exploring theories of providing compensation for consequential damages and takings of goodwill).
  • 81
    • 77749315137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • observing that the common contracts principle known as the perfect-tender rule is premised on the notion that a merchant is expected to deliver goods, not the value of diose goods in expectation damages, See, at
    • See Epstein, A Clear View, supra note 18, at 2099 (observing that the common contracts principle known as the "perfect-tender rule" is premised on the notion that a merchant is expected to deliver goods, not the value of diose goods in expectation damages).
    • A Clear View, supra note , vol.18 , pp. 2099
    • Epstein1
  • 82
    • 77749318197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 83
    • 77749316743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2093 (Over time, the inefficiencies of a liability system cascade until the security of possession and the security of exchange needed for complex commercial life and a satisfying personal one are no longer available.).
    • See id. at 2093 ("Over time, the inefficiencies of a liability system cascade until the security of possession and the security of exchange needed for complex commercial life and a satisfying personal one are no longer available.").
  • 84
    • 77749316761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.;
    • See id.;
  • 85
    • 77749316745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley & Weiser, supra note 10, at 788 (Epstein's Law holds that would-be purchasers of a property right invariably prefer liability rules and use them as an opportunity for government rent-seeking.).
    • Lemley & Weiser, supra note 10, at 788 ("Epstein's Law holds that would-be purchasers of a property right invariably prefer liability rules and use them as an opportunity for government rent-seeking.").
  • 86
    • 77749306051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • examining the [mjanipulation and the [d]eterioration of [1]iability [s]ignals, See, at
    • See Smith, Property Rules, supra note 18, at 1764-68 (examining the "[mjanipulation and the [d]eterioration of [1]iability [s]ignals").
    • Property Rules, supra note , vol.18 , pp. 1764-1768
    • Smith1
  • 87
    • 77749315146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1753-54.
    • Smith1
  • 88
    • 77749318189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 89
    • 77749318188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1755
    • Id. at 1755.
  • 90
    • 77749318184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1755-56.
  • 91
    • 77749316754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1755
    • Id. at 1755.
  • 92
    • 77749306052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 93
    • 77749316759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 94
    • 77749318145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1755-56.
    • See id. at 1755-56.
  • 95
    • 77749315135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By uncertainty, we do not simply mean risk; rather, we mean risk that cannot be expressed as an actuarial probability. As Smith observes, entrepreneurs profit from the opportunities afforded by uncertainty; if everyone shared identical information about risk, entrepreneurial profit would vanish. Id. at 1725;
    • By uncertainty, we do not simply mean risk; rather, we mean risk that cannot be expressed as an actuarial probability. As Smith observes, entrepreneurs profit from the opportunities afforded by uncertainty; if everyone shared identical information about risk, entrepreneurial profit would vanish. Id. at 1725;
  • 96
    • 77749306006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also LUDWIG VON MISES, HUMAN ACTION: A TREATISE ON ECONOMICS 293 (Henry Regnery Co. 3d rev. ed. 1966) (1949) (If all entrepreneurs were to anticipate correctly the future state of the market, there would be neither profits nor losses.).
    • see also LUDWIG VON MISES, HUMAN ACTION: A TREATISE ON ECONOMICS 293 (Henry Regnery Co. 3d rev. ed. 1966) (1949) ("If all entrepreneurs were to anticipate correctly the future state of the market, there would be neither profits nor losses.").
  • 98
    • 77749313996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1763-64.
    • Smith1
  • 99
    • 77749314000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 100
    • 77749318148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wat 1763
    • Wat 1763.
  • 101
    • 77749316711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1764
    • Id. at 1764.
  • 102
    • 77749306009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 103
    • 77749315140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 104
    • 77749315138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1765
    • Id. at 1765.
  • 105
    • 77749316748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1745-46.
  • 106
    • 77749316749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also id. at 1765.
    • See also id. at 1765.
  • 107
    • 77749306049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. at 1768;
    • See, e.g., id. at 1768;
  • 108
    • 77749315141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also ReMine ex rel. Liley v. Dist. Court of Denver, 709 P.2d 1379, 1382 (Colo. 1985).
    • see also ReMine ex rel. Liley v. Dist. Court of Denver, 709 P.2d 1379, 1382 (Colo. 1985).
  • 110
    • 0001845692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Optimal Standardization in the Law of Property: The Numerus Clausus Principle, 110
    • exploring the numerus clausus principle and noting that it presents the picture of a fixed menu of options from which deviation will not be permitted, see also
    • see also Thomas W. Merrill & Henry E. Smith, Optimal Standardization in the Law of Property: The Numerus Clausus Principle, 110 YALE L.J. 1, 23-24 (2000) (exploring the numerus clausus principle and noting that it "presents the picture of a fixed menu of options from which deviation will not be permitted").
    • (2000) YALE L.J , vol.1 , pp. 23-24
    • Merrill, T.W.1    Smith, H.E.2
  • 111
    • 77749313992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the other hand, the costs of actually enforcing an injunction may outweigh those of enforcing a damages award, as the former requires officials to bring about specific actions pertaining to unique objects, while the latter may be levied against any available property belonging to the defendant
    • On the other hand, the costs of actually enforcing an injunction may outweigh those of enforcing a damages award, as the former requires officials to bring about specific actions pertaining to unique objects, while the latter may be levied against any available property belonging to the defendant.
  • 112
    • 84868182923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Boomer v. Atl. Cement Co., 257 N.E.2d 870, 873 & n.ast; (N.Y. 1970) (denying an injunction that would have shut down a cement plant while noting that the defendant's investment in the plant was in excess of $45, 000,000).
    • See, e.g., Boomer v. Atl. Cement Co., 257 N.E.2d 870, 873 & n.ast; (N.Y. 1970) (denying an injunction that would have shut down a cement plant while noting that the defendant's investment in the plant was "in excess of $45, 000,000").
  • 113
    • 85055298005 scopus 로고
    • Holdouts, Externalities, and the Single Owner: One More Salute to Ronald Coase, 36
    • advocating the single owner device as a useful framework for determining the most beneficial joint output, See
    • See Richard A. Epstein, Holdouts, Externalities, and the Single Owner: One More Salute to Ronald Coase, 36 J.L. & ECON. 553, 556-57 (1993) (advocating the "single owner" device as a useful framework for determining the most beneficial joint output).
    • (1993) J.L. & ECON , vol.553 , pp. 556-557
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 114
    • 77749318147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Smith, Property Rules, supra note 18, at 1753-54 discussing the advantages of low-cost proxy signals inherent in an exclusion strategy system
    • See Smith, Property Rules, supra note 18, at 1753-54 (discussing the advantages of low-cost proxy signals inherent in an exclusion strategy system).
  • 115
    • 0001073135 scopus 로고
    • The Use of Knowledge in Society, 35
    • See
    • See F.A. Hayek, The Use of Knowledge in Society, 35 AM. ECON. REV. 519, 526 (1945).
    • (1945) AM. ECON. REV , vol.519 , pp. 526
    • Hayek, F.A.1
  • 116
    • 77749318146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Epstein, A Clear View, supra note 18, at 2092-93 discussing the use of property rules and the limited applicability of takings under legal supervision
    • See, e.g., Epstein, A Clear View, supra note 18, at 2092-93 (discussing the use of property rules and the limited applicability of takings under legal supervision).
  • 117
    • 77749316706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469 (2005) (upholding the constitutionality of using eminent domain to transfer land from one private owner to another in order to further economic development).
    • But see Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469 (2005) (upholding the constitutionality of using eminent domain to transfer land from one private owner to another in order to further economic development).
  • 118
    • 77749306007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 313-314 (1871).
    • See Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 313-314 (1871).
  • 119
    • 77749313977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 320 refusing to allow plaintiff landowner to recover hoops created by a goodfaith improver from timber cut on plaintiffs land, Although this doctrine had traditionally been conceived in terms of whether the original property still existed in specie, Justice Cooley recognized that for purposes of equity, the key issue was the relative contributions of the improver's labor and the original resource to the value of the new asset: No test which satisfies the reason of the law can be applied in the adjustment of questions of title to chattels by accession, unless it keeps in view the circumstance of relative values. When we bear in mind the fact that what the law aims at is the accomplishment of substantial equity, we shall readily perceive that the fact of the value of the materials having been increased a hundred-fold, is of more importance in the adjustment than any chemical change or mechanical transformation, which, however radical, neither is expensive to th
    • See id. at 320 (refusing to allow plaintiff landowner to recover hoops created by a goodfaith improver from timber cut on plaintiffs land). Although this doctrine had traditionally been conceived in terms of whether the original property still existed in specie, Justice Cooley recognized that for purposes of equity, the key issue was the relative contributions of the improver's labor and the original resource to the value of the new asset: No test which satisfies the reason of the law can be applied in the adjustment of questions of title to chattels by accession, unless it keeps in view the circumstance of relative values. When we bear in mind the fact that what the law aims at is the accomplishment of substantial equity, we shall readily perceive that the fact of the value of the materials having been increased a hundred-fold, is of more importance in the adjustment than any chemical change or mechanical transformation, which, however radical, neither is expensive to the party making it, nor adds materially to the value. There may be complete changes with so little improvement in value, that there could be no hardship in giving the owner of the original materials the improved article; but in the present case, where the defendant's labor-if he shall succeed in sustaining his offer of testimony-will appear to have given the timber in its present condition nearly all its value, all the grounds of equity exist which influence the courts in recognizing a change of title under any circumstances. Id. at 320-21 (articulating Justice Cooley's comparative value theory);
  • 120
    • 77749316681 scopus 로고
    • The Law of Accession of Personal Property, 22
    • discussing the Wetherbee decision to award the defendant the improved property, see also
    • see also Earl C. Arnold, The Law of Accession of Personal Property, 22 COLUM. L. REV. 103, 103-07 (1922) (discussing the Wetherbee decision to award the defendant the improved property).
    • (1922) COLUM. L. REV , vol.103 , pp. 103-107
    • Arnold, E.C.1
  • 121
    • 77749318143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY 17 (9th ed. 2009) (defining accession).
    • BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY 17 (9th ed. 2009) (defining accession).
  • 122
    • 80052612791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Accession and Original Ownership, 1
    • See
    • See Thomas W. Merrill, Accession and Original Ownership, 1 J. LEGAL ANALYSIS 459, 463 (2009).
    • (2009) J. LEGAL ANALYSIS , vol.459 , pp. 463
    • Merrill, T.W.1
  • 123
    • 77749306004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 464-67.
    • See id. at 464-67.
  • 124
    • 77749313987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merrill recognizes that Lockean labor theory can be seen as based on an accession theory, though he later characterizes Locke as unabashedly ground[ing] original ownership of property in first possession- Id. at 465, 497. While elements of both theories are present, I believe the former characterization to be the better reading of Locke's position given his emphasis on the disproportionate extent to which the value of a resource to human beings arises because of the labor invested in it.
    • Merrill recognizes that Lockean labor theory can be seen as based on an accession theory, though he later characterizes Locke as "unabashedly ground[ing] original ownership of property in first possession-" Id. at 465, 497. While elements of both theories are present, I believe the former characterization to be the better reading of Locke's position given his emphasis on the disproportionate extent to which the value of a resource to human beings arises because of the labor invested in it.
  • 125
    • 77749316700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Merrill's framework, this conflict between exclusion and accession would be described not as a conflict over whether to apply an accession rule, but as one over which accession rule to apply-that is, a conflict over which resource should be regarded as having the most prominent relationship to the new value: the tangible property taken without permission or the productive investments of the improver.
    • In Merrill's framework, this conflict between "exclusion" and "accession" would be described not as a conflict over whether to apply an accession rule, but as one over which accession rule to apply-that is, a conflict over which resource should be regarded as having the most prominent relationship to the new value: the tangible property taken without permission or the productive investments of the improver.
  • 127
    • 77749313990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 313 (1871).
    • Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 313 (1871).
  • 128
    • 77749318133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (finding that to award all of the value of the improved good to the original owner is so opposed to all legal idea of justice and right and to the rules which regulate the recovery of damages generally, that if permitted by the law at all, it must stand out as an anomaly and must rest upon peculiar reasons);
    • Id. (finding that to award all of the value of the improved good to the original owner "is so opposed to all legal idea of justice and right and to the rules which regulate the recovery of damages generally, that if permitted by the law at all, it must stand out as an anomaly and must rest upon peculiar reasons");
  • 129
    • 77749316695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Arnold, supra note 95, at 106 (showing that even before Cooley's articulation of the comparative value theory, courts recognized an exception to the owner's claim in 'cases in which the accession of value to the raw material is so far beyond the original value, as to impress on the reason of mankind, the injustice of permitting the bona fide producer of that increased value, to be deprived of it' (quoting Lampton's Ex'rs v. Preston's Ex'rs, 24 Ky. (1 J.J. Marsh.) 454, 461 (1829)).
    • see also Arnold, supra note 95, at 106 (showing that even before Cooley's articulation of the comparative value theory, courts recognized an exception to the owner's claim in '"cases in which the accession of value to the raw material is so far beyond the original value, as to impress on the reason of mankind, the injustice of permitting the bona fide producer of that increased value, to be deprived of it'" (quoting Lampton's Ex'rs v. Preston's Ex'rs, 24 Ky. (1 J.J. Marsh.) 454, 461 (1829)).
  • 130
    • 0041337627 scopus 로고
    • Mistaken Improvers of Real Estate, 64
    • See
    • See Kelvin H. Dickinson, Mistaken Improvers of Real Estate, 64 N.C. L. REV. 37, 38-39 (1985);
    • (1985) N.C. L. REV , vol.37 , pp. 38-39
    • Dickinson, K.H.1
  • 131
    • 46149083082 scopus 로고
    • Improving the Lot of the Trespassing Improver, 11
    • John Henry Merryman, Improving the Lot of the Trespassing Improver, 11 STAN. L. REV. 456, 465 (1959).
    • (1959) STAN. L. REV , vol.456 , pp. 465
    • Henry Merryman, J.1
  • 132
    • 77749305999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See L.C. Warden, Mandatory Injunction to Compel Removal of Encroachments by Adjoining Landowner, 28 A.L.R. 2D 679, 686-91 (1953) (collecting cases).
    • See L.C. Warden, Mandatory Injunction to Compel Removal of Encroachments by Adjoining Landowner, 28 A.L.R. 2D 679, 686-91 (1953) (collecting cases).
  • 133
    • 77749318139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Proctor v. Huntington, 192 P.3d 958, 964 (Wash. Ct. App. 2008) (footnote omitted) (citations omitted).
    • Proctor v. Huntington, 192 P.3d 958, 964 (Wash. Ct. App. 2008) (footnote omitted) (citations omitted).
  • 134
    • 77749318142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 22 Mich, at
    • Wetherbee, 22 Mich, at 319-20.
    • Wetherbee , pp. 319-320
  • 135
    • 77749318074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and economics analysis would have us believe there is no real difference between the two scenarios-Coase tells us that if the improvement is efficient and transaction costs are low, the injunction will result not in actual destruction but in a transfer payment. Such reasoning, however, is fundamentally at odds with the traditions governing equitable injunctions. These extraordinary interventions are intended to prevent or rectify harms that no lucre can salve; to seek one merely as a bargaining chip is to belie the necessary avowal that money damages are inadequate. Thus, courts of equity tend to assume that an injunction will be enforced if granted, and ask whether this result would be oppressive, using some analysis similar to the one stated by the court in Proctor
    • Law and economics analysis would have us believe there is no real difference between the two scenarios-Coase tells us that if the improvement is efficient and transaction costs are low, the injunction will result not in actual destruction but in a transfer payment. Such reasoning, however, is fundamentally at odds with the traditions governing equitable injunctions. These extraordinary interventions are intended to prevent or rectify harms that no lucre can salve; to seek one merely as a bargaining chip is to belie the necessary avowal that money damages are inadequate. Thus, courts of equity tend to assume that an injunction will be enforced if granted, and ask whether this result would be "oppressive," using some analysis similar to the one stated by the court in Proctor.
  • 136
    • 77749305979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Arnold, supra note 95, at 106 (discussing the injustice of permitting the bona fide producer of... increased value, to be deprived of it).
    • Cf. Arnold, supra note 95, at 106 (discussing the "injustice of permitting the bona fide producer of... increased value, to be deprived of it").
  • 137
    • 77749313966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wetherbee, 22 Mich, at 313 (Where vicious motive or reckless disregard of right are not involved, to inflict upon a person who has taken the property of another ... is so opposed to all legal idea of justice and right. . . .);
    • See Wetherbee, 22 Mich, at 313 ("Where vicious motive or reckless disregard of right are not involved, to inflict upon a person who has taken the property of another ... is so opposed to all legal idea of justice and right. . . .");
  • 138
    • 77749306000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arnold, supra note 95, at 108;
    • Arnold, supra note 95, at 108;
  • 139
    • 77749318129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Warden, supra note 105, at 705-09 (collecting cases illustrating the proposition that [w]here an encroachment... is intentional or wilful, a mandatory injunction will ordinarily be granted to compel its removal, without regard for the relative conveniences or hardships which may result).
    • Warden, supra note 105, at 705-09 (collecting cases illustrating the proposition that "[w]here an encroachment... is intentional or wilful, a mandatory injunction will ordinarily be granted to compel its removal, without regard for the relative conveniences or hardships which may result").
  • 140
    • 77749313922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wetherbee, 22 Mich, at 311-12.
    • See Wetherbee, 22 Mich, at 311-12.
  • 141
    • 77749318140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 312.
    • See id. at 312.
  • 142
    • 77749318121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 143
    • 77749305997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 320.
    • See id. at 320.
  • 144
    • 45249104151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This way of modeling the problem is inspired by Stewart E. Sterk, although he does not purport to define good faith in this manner. Steward E. Sterk, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Uncertainty About Property Rights, 106 MICH. L. REV. 1285, 1302-05 (2008, In fact, Sterk's analysis shows the range of inefficient searches to be much broader than those for which S < pH, because one must consider not only the harm to the putative owner but the cost to the would-be improver of abstaining from use A, Only where this avoidance cost is less than H but greater than pH would certainty as to property rights result in a decision by the improver to abstain from an otherwise inefficient use of the property
    • This way of modeling the problem is inspired by Stewart E. Sterk, although he does not purport to define good faith in this manner. Steward E. Sterk, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Uncertainty About Property Rights, 106 MICH. L. REV. 1285, 1302-05 (2008). In fact, Sterk's analysis shows the range of inefficient searches to be much broader than those for which S < pH, because one must consider not only the harm to the putative owner but the cost to the would-be improver of abstaining from use (A). Only where this avoidance cost is less than H but greater than pH would certainty as to property rights result in a decision by the improver to abstain from an otherwise inefficient use of the property.
  • 145
    • 77749316701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1306-08.
    • See id. at 1306-08.
  • 146
    • 77749305991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. Carroll Towing Co., 159 F.2d 169, 173-74 (2d Cir. 1947).
    • See United States v. Carroll Towing Co., 159 F.2d 169, 173-74 (2d Cir. 1947).
  • 147
    • 77749318117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Richard W. Wright, Hand, Posner, and the Myth of the Hand Formula, 4 THEORETICAL INQUIRES L. 145 (2003) (arguing that no one, even judges who espouse the Hand formula, actually uses it to resolve negligence cases).
    • But see Richard W. Wright, Hand, Posner, and the Myth of the "Hand Formula, " 4 THEORETICAL INQUIRES L. 145 (2003) (arguing that no one, even judges who espouse the Hand formula, actually uses it to resolve negligence cases).
  • 148
    • 77749305992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sterk, supra note 115, at 1308-11
    • Sterk, supra note 115, at 1308-11.
  • 149
    • 77749305984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sterk's demonstration that liability rules lead to fewer inefficient searches than property rules assumes that would-be improvers make decisions based on actual knowledge of H, an assumption that Sterk acknowledges to be often unrealistic. Id. at 1318. This does not invalidate Sterk's conclusion that property rules are likely to lead to inefficient searches that would not take place under a liability regime; it merely means that this fact alone does not call for wholesale abandonment of property rules, as Sterk himself points out.
    • Sterk's demonstration that liability rules lead to fewer inefficient searches than property rules assumes that would-be improvers make decisions based on actual knowledge of H, an assumption that Sterk acknowledges to be "often unrealistic." Id. at 1318. This does not invalidate Sterk's conclusion that property rules are likely to lead to inefficient searches that would not take place under a liability regime; it merely means that this fact alone does not call for wholesale abandonment of property rules, as Sterk himself points out.
  • 151
    • 77749305989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion supra notes 115-17 and accompanying text.
    • See discussion supra notes 115-17 and accompanying text.
  • 152
    • 77749318136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wetherbee, 22 Mich, at 320-21.
    • See Wetherbee, 22 Mich, at 320-21.
  • 153
    • 77749313989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 312
    • Id. at 312.
  • 154
    • 77749318128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Griffin v. Red Run Lodge, Inc., 610 F.2d 1198, 1202 (4th Cir. 1979) (noting that to establish innocent obstruction of an easement, a defendant would have to show it reasonably had no notice of the [plaintiffs'] rights, or that, with knowledge of those rights, it made a good faith effort to locate an [improvement] ... but strayed . . . because of a good faith error by an independent surveyor as to the boundaries of the easement).
    • See, e.g., Griffin v. Red Run Lodge, Inc., 610 F.2d 1198, 1202 (4th Cir. 1979) (noting that to establish innocent obstruction of an easement, a "defendant would have to show it reasonably had no notice of the [plaintiffs'] rights, or that, with knowledge of those rights, it made a good faith effort to locate an [improvement] ... but strayed . . . because of a good faith error by an independent surveyor as to the boundaries of the easement").
  • 155
    • 77749318132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Stroup v. Codo, 212 N.E.2d 518, 520 (III. App. Ct. 1965) (defendant's contractor made measurements from stakes at corners of lot shown on plat);
    • See, e.g., Stroup v. Codo, 212 N.E.2d 518, 520 (III. App. Ct. 1965) (defendant's contractor made measurements from stakes at corners of lot shown on plat);
  • 156
    • 77749305980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Urban Site Venture II L.P. v. Levering Assoes. L.P., 665 A.2d 1062, 1067 (Md. 1995) (defendant relied on survey that contradicted earlier survey);
    • Urban Site Venture II L.P. v. Levering Assoes. L.P., 665 A.2d 1062, 1067 (Md. 1995) (defendant relied on survey that contradicted earlier survey);
  • 157
    • 77749305988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dundalk Holding Co. v. Easter, 137 A.2d 667 (Md. 1958) (defendant relied on surveyor);
    • Dundalk Holding Co. v. Easter, 137 A.2d 667 (Md. 1958) (defendant relied on surveyor);
  • 158
    • 77749316621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Proctor v. Huntington, 192 P.3d 958, 962 (Wash. Ct. App. 2008) (defendants relied on surveyor's mistaken identification of boundary marker).
    • Proctor v. Huntington, 192 P.3d 958, 962 (Wash. Ct. App. 2008) (defendants relied on surveyor's mistaken identification of boundary marker).
  • 159
    • 77749313972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • describing the high degree of modularity promoted by the law of accession, See, at
    • See Smith, Intellectual Property, supra note 29, at 1770 (describing the "high degree of modularity" promoted by the law of accession).
    • Intellectual Property, supra note , vol.29 , pp. 1770
    • Smith1
  • 160
    • 77749316673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (describing the court's function in accession).
    • See id. (describing the court's function in accession).
  • 161
    • 77749318077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (noting that by valuing the lesser contribution, the court is able to identify the contribution more easily valued).
    • See id. (noting that by "valuing the lesser contribution," the court is able to identify the contribution more easily valued).
  • 162
    • 77749316680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Proctor, 192 P.3d at 964.
    • Proctor, 192 P.3d at 964.
  • 163
    • 3042734240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusion & Property Rules in the Law of Nuisance, 90
    • hereinafter Smith, Exclusion & Property Rules, See
    • See Henry E. Smith, Exclusion & Property Rules in the Law of Nuisance, 90 VA. L. REV. 965, 993-94 (2004) [hereinafter Smith, Exclusion & Property Rules].
    • (2004) VA. L. REV , vol.965 , pp. 993-994
    • Smith, H.E.1
  • 164
    • 77749313983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 999.
    • See id. at 999.
  • 165
    • 77749316690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (highlighting courts' willingness to recognize the class of tangible but nontrespassory invasions as fitting into the category of nuisance). Beyond this, one might define a further category of nuisance cases involving harms that do not stem from any physical alteration of the resource in question.
    • See id. (highlighting courts' willingness to recognize the class of "tangible but nontrespassory invasions" as fitting into the category of nuisance). Beyond this, one might define a further category of nuisance cases involving harms that do not stem from any physical alteration of the resource in question.
  • 166
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 143 and accompanying text
    • See infra note 143 and accompanying text.
    • See infra
  • 167
    • 77749316685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Madison v. Ducktown Sulphur, Copper & Iron Co., 83 S.W. 658, 659 (Tenn. 1904).
    • Madison v. Ducktown Sulphur, Copper & Iron Co., 83 S.W. 658, 659 (Tenn. 1904).
  • 168
    • 77749313979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 659-60. The Madison nuisance falls into the second category of non-possessory uses, because the defendant copper plant owners were responsible for the movement of something that is not a discrete physical object (smoke) that nevertheless altered the qualities of plaintiff's resources (their farms).
    • Id. at 659-60. The Madison nuisance falls into the second category of non-possessory uses, because the defendant copper plant owners were responsible for the movement of something that is not a discrete physical object (smoke) that nevertheless altered the qualities of plaintiff's resources (their farms).
  • 169
    • 77749316693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 660.
    • See id. at 660.
  • 170
    • 77749316678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ([I]f the injunctive relief sought be granted, the defendants will be compelled to stop operations, and their property will become practically worthless-).
    • See id. ("[I]f the injunctive relief sought be granted, the defendants will be compelled to stop operations, and their property will become practically worthless-").
  • 172
    • 84886338965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • tbl.A comparing the costs of maintaining exclusion and governance strategies
    • See supra tbl.A (comparing the costs of maintaining exclusion and governance strategies).
    • See supra
  • 173
    • 84868176608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §821F (1977) (stating that liability for nuisance exists only to those to whom it causes significant harm);
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §821F (1977) (stating that liability for nuisance exists "only to those to whom it causes significant harm");
  • 174
    • 77749313974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Madison, 83 S.W. at 662 (indicating that to succeed on a claim for nuisance, the injury must be clearly established).
    • see also Madison, 83 S.W. at 662 (indicating that to succeed on a claim for nuisance, "the injury must be clearly established").
  • 175
    • 77749318123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Think about what this means if analogized to the realm of possessory conflicts. It is as though A, in order to prevent B from using his land or chattel (or to recover it from nonconsensual occupation), were required to show that B was actually using the property in a way that caused significant harm. It would not be enough for A merely to show that B was using A's land or chattel without permission.
    • Think about what this means if analogized to the realm of possessory conflicts. It is as though A, in order to prevent B from using his land or chattel (or to recover it from nonconsensual occupation), were required to show that B was actually using the property in a way that caused significant harm. It would not be enough for A merely to show that B was using A's land or chattel without permission.
  • 176
    • 84868169283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §821F (stating that harm must be of a kind that would be suffered by a normal person in the community or by property in normal condition and used for a normal purpose).
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §821F (stating that harm must be "of a kind that would be suffered by a normal person in the community or by property in normal condition and used for a normal purpose").
  • 177
    • 84868167415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. §82 IF cmt. c (explaining that the public nuisance standard of [s]ignificant harm is met by showing particular harm [that] must be significant in character).
    • Id. §82 IF cmt. c (explaining that the public nuisance standard of "[s]ignificant harm" is met by showing "particular harm [that] must be significant in character").
  • 178
    • 77749316677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that this is a question separate from whether liability should result in application of a liability or a property rule
    • Note that this is a question separate from whether liability should result in application of a liability or a property rule.
  • 179
    • 84868169284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §§822-831 (listing multiple factors to be weighed when determining the gravity of a particular harm at issue). These factors include the following: the utility of the use, whether one use outweighs the other, whether this comparison renders the use unreasonable, whether the invasion of the other's interest is intentional, and whether all these things put together result in an actionable nuisance.
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §§822-831 (listing multiple factors to be weighed when determining the gravity of a particular harm at issue). These factors include the following: the utility of the use, whether one use outweighs the other, whether this comparison renders the use unreasonable, whether the invasion of the other's interest is intentional, and whether all these things put together result in an actionable nuisance.
  • 180
    • 77749305986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 181
    • 84868167416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §821D.
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §821D.
  • 182
    • 77749313965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although purely aesthetic nuisances are rarely found to be actionable, some courts have held to the contrary. See Smith, Exclusion & Property Rules, supra note 127, at 999-1000 n.103 providing examples of cases granting relief for aesthetic nuisances and recognizing that modern commentators appear to be favorable to the idea of aesthetic nuisance
    • Although "purely aesthetic nuisances" are rarely found to be actionable, some courts have held to the contrary. See Smith, Exclusion & Property Rules, supra note 127, at 999-1000 n.103 (providing examples of cases granting relief for aesthetic nuisances and recognizing that modern commentators appear to be "favorable to the idea of aesthetic nuisance").
  • 183
    • 77749318073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 998-99
    • Id. at 998-99.
  • 184
    • 77749318076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 998.
    • See id. at 998.
  • 185
    • 77749305982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1000-07.
    • Id. at 1000-07.
  • 186
    • 77749318115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Madison v. Ducktown Sulphur, Copper & Iron Co., 83 S.W. 658 (Tenn. 1904).
    • Madison v. Ducktown Sulphur, Copper & Iron Co., 83 S.W. 658 (Tenn. 1904).
  • 187
    • 77749305981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at 659
    • See id at 659.
  • 190
    • 77749313967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 661
    • Id. at 661.
  • 191
    • 77749316551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • discussing the locational approach to nuisance cases and the resulting reduction in the difficulty in identifying and complying with one's duty to avoid use conflicts, See, at
    • See Smith, Exclusion & Property Rules, supra note 127, at 998-1005 (discussing the locational approach to nuisance cases and the resulting reduction in the difficulty in identifying and complying with one's duty to avoid use conflicts).
    • Exclusion & Property Rules, supra note , vol.127 , pp. 998-1005
    • Smith1
  • 192
    • 77749316664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 128 and accompanying text (discussing Smith's examples of physical phenomena caused by nuisance).
    • See supra note 128 and accompanying text (discussing Smith's examples of physical phenomena caused by nuisance).
  • 193
    • 84868169282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §821D (1977) (A private nuisance is a nontrespassory invasion of another's interest in the private use and enjoyment of land.), with Smith, Exclusion & Property Rules, supra note 127, at 998-1005 (outlining the locational approach).
    • Compare RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §821D (1977) ("A private nuisance is a nontrespassory invasion of another's interest in the private use and enjoyment of land."), with Smith, Exclusion & Property Rules, supra note 127, at 998-1005 (outlining the locational approach).
  • 194
    • 77749313827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Madison, 83 S.W. at 666-67.
    • Madison, 83 S.W. at 666-67.
  • 196
    • 77749308184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 664
    • Id. at 664.
  • 197
    • 77749308183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 660, 666-67.
    • Id. at 660, 666-67.
  • 198
    • 77749313842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 659
    • Id. at 659.
  • 199
    • 77749308181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 666
    • Id. at 666.
  • 200
    • 77749313838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein, A Clear View, supra note 18, at 2102; see also Madison, 83 S.W. at 667 (awarding damages-instead of an injunction-to the plaintiff-farm owners in order to preserve the valuable copper mines operated by defendants).
    • Epstein, A Clear View, supra note 18, at 2102; see also Madison, 83 S.W. at 667 (awarding damages-instead of an injunction-to the plaintiff-farm owners in order to preserve the valuable copper mines operated by defendants).
  • 202
    • 77749305909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 203
    • 77749313826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein's Rule, of course, is not to be confused with Epstein's Law. See supra notes 57-58 and accompanying text (explaining Epstein's Law).
    • Epstein's Rule, of course, is not to be confused with Epstein's Law. See supra notes 57-58 and accompanying text (explaining Epstein's Law).
  • 205
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 60 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 60 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 206
    • 77749318116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part IV.B (discussing the law of accession).
    • See supra Part IV.B (discussing the law of accession).
  • 207
    • 77749313877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I V.B.
    • See supra Part I V.B.
  • 208
    • 77749305882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Madison v. Ducktown Sulphur, Copper & Iron Co., 83 S.W. 658, 660 (Tenn. 1904).
    • See Madison v. Ducktown Sulphur, Copper & Iron Co., 83 S.W. 658, 660 (Tenn. 1904).
  • 209
    • 77749308159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Warden, supra note 105, at 705-09 (Where an encroachment by an adjoining landowner is intentional or wilful, a mandatory injunction will ordinarily be granted to compel its removal, without regard for the relative conveniences or hardships which may result from ordering its removal.).
    • See Warden, supra note 105, at 705-09 ("Where an encroachment by an adjoining landowner is intentional or wilful, a mandatory injunction will ordinarily be granted to compel its removal, without regard for the relative conveniences or hardships which may result from ordering its removal.").
  • 210
    • 77749313874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Proctor v. Huntington, 192 P.3d 958, 964 (Wash. Ct. App. 2008).
    • Proctor v. Huntington, 192 P.3d 958, 964 (Wash. Ct. App. 2008).
  • 211
    • 77749313844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Madison, 83 S.W. at 666-67.
    • Madison, 83 S.W. at 666-67.
  • 212
    • 77749313843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Smith, Exclusion & Property Rules, supra note 127, at 1043 (advocating for a technique that refus[es] a blanket after-the-fact... liability rule approach).
    • See Smith, Exclusion & Property Rules, supra note 127, at 1043 (advocating for a technique that "refus[es] a blanket after-the-fact... liability rule approach").
  • 213
    • 77749313964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.A.
    • See supra Part III.A.
  • 214
    • 77749308180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Iglesias v. Mut. Life Ins. Co., 156 F.3d 237, 243 (1st Cir. 1998) (The equitable doctrine of laches allows a court to dismiss a claim 'where a party's delay in bringing suit was (1) unreasonable, and (2) resulted in prejudice to the opposing party.' (quoting K-Mart Corp. v. Oriental Plaza, Inc., 875 F.2d 907, 911 (1st Cir. 1989))).
    • See, e.g., Iglesias v. Mut. Life Ins. Co., 156 F.3d 237, 243 (1st Cir. 1998) ("The equitable doctrine of laches allows a court to dismiss a claim 'where a party's delay in bringing suit was (1) unreasonable, and (2) resulted in prejudice to the opposing party.'" (quoting K-Mart Corp. v. Oriental Plaza, Inc., 875 F.2d 907, 911 (1st Cir. 1989))).
  • 217
    • 77749316587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, noting that in early U.S. patent law, patents were mainly granted to inventions embodied in some apparatus, a physical thing
    • Id. (noting that in early U.S. patent law, patents were mainly granted to inventions "embodied in some apparatus, a physical thing").
  • 218
    • 77749313882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1795-96.
    • See id. at 1795-96.
  • 219
    • 77749305918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1796
    • Id. at 1796.
  • 220
    • 77749318047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1796-97.
  • 221
    • 77749305972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. at 1785 (asserting that governance strategies isolate uses and users in more detail, and thus impose higher informational costs).
    • See, e.g., id. at 1785 (asserting that governance strategies isolate "uses and users in more detail," and thus impose higher informational costs).
  • 222
    • 77749316660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1795.
    • See id. at 1795.
  • 223
    • 77749313928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally JAMES BESSEN & MICHAEL J. MEURER, PATENT FAILURE: HOW JUDGES, BUREAUCRATS, AND LAWYERS PUT INNOVATORS AT RISK 46-72 (2008) (discussing the difficulty of discerning patent boundaries).
    • See generally JAMES BESSEN & MICHAEL J. MEURER, PATENT FAILURE: HOW JUDGES, BUREAUCRATS, AND LAWYERS PUT INNOVATORS AT RISK 46-72 (2008) (discussing the difficulty of discerning patent boundaries).
  • 224
    • 77749313923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the numerus clausus principle as applied to property law-that similar to rights in civil law, property rights must conform to certain standardized forms-see Merrill & Smith, supra note 86, at 4.
    • For a discussion of the numerus clausus principle as applied to property law-that similar to rights in civil law, "property rights must conform to certain standardized forms"-see Merrill & Smith, supra note 86, at 4.
  • 225
    • 84868176606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JON W. BRUCE & JAMES W. ELY, JR., THE LAW OF EASEMENTS AND LICENSES IN LAND §2:10 (2009) ([A] negative easement enables the holder to prevent the owner of the servient estate from doing things the owner would otherwise be entitled to do.).
    • See JON W. BRUCE & JAMES W. ELY, JR., THE LAW OF EASEMENTS AND LICENSES IN LAND §2:10 (2009) ("[A] negative easement enables the holder to prevent the owner of the servient estate from doing things the owner would otherwise be entitled to do.").
  • 226
    • 77749318045 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Modem Law of Servitudes: Reweaving the Ancient Strands, 55
    • observing traditional types of negative easements that were recognized at common law, See
    • See Susan F. French, Toward a Modem Law of Servitudes: Reweaving the Ancient Strands, 55 S. CAL. L. REV. 1261, 1267 (1982) (observing traditional types of negative easements that were recognized at common law);
    • (1982) S. CAL. L. REV , vol.1261 , pp. 1267
    • French, S.F.1
  • 227
    • 77749313926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also United States v. Blackman, 613 S.E.2d 442, 446 (Va. 2005) (The traditional negative easements recognized at common law were those created to protect the flow of air, light, and artificial streams of water, and to ensure the subjacent and lateral support of buildings or land.).
    • see also United States v. Blackman, 613 S.E.2d 442, 446 (Va. 2005) ("The traditional negative easements recognized at common law were those created to protect the flow of air, light, and artificial streams of water, and to ensure the subjacent and lateral support of buildings or land.").
  • 228
    • 84868167411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BRUCE & ELY, supra note 184, at §2:10 (A negative easement does not permit the holder to enter or use the servient estate; it limits the right of the servient owner to utilize the servient owner's own land. Historically a negative easement was considered appurtenant.);
    • See BRUCE & ELY, supra note 184, at §2:10 ("A negative easement does not permit the holder to enter or use the servient estate; it limits the right of the servient owner to utilize the servient owner's own land. Historically a negative easement was considered appurtenant.");
  • 229
    • 77749318108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Blackman, 613 S.E.2d at 446 (explaining that negative easements are, by their nature, easements appurtenant, as their intent is to benefit an adjoining or nearby parcel of land).
    • see also Blackman, 613 S.E.2d at 446 (explaining that negative easements "are, by their nature, easements appurtenant, as their intent is to benefit an adjoining or nearby parcel of land").
  • 230
    • 84868167412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF PROPERTY: SERVITUDES §2.6(2) (1998) (The benefit of a servitude may be granted to a person who is not a party to the transaction that creates the servitude.).
    • See RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF PROPERTY: SERVITUDES §2.6(2) (1998) ("The benefit of a servitude may be granted to a person who is not a party to the transaction that creates the servitude.").
  • 231
    • 77749316553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Brace v. United States, 72 Fed. Cl. 337, 364 (Fed. Cl. 2006), affd, 250 Fed. App'x 359 (Fed. Cir. 2007) (noting that forty-seven states have enacted legislation allowing for conservation easements because the equitable enforcement of negative easements in gross was prohibited). For a general description of the uncertainty and difficulties inherent in the creation of enforceable conservation easements under traditional common law rules that negative easements could not be transferred,
    • See, e.g., Brace v. United States, 72 Fed. Cl. 337, 364 (Fed. Cl. 2006), affd, 250 Fed. App'x 359 (Fed. Cir. 2007) (noting that forty-seven states have enacted legislation allowing for conservation easements because "the equitable enforcement" of negative easements in gross was prohibited). For a general description of the "uncertainty and difficulties" inherent in the creation of enforceable conservation easements under traditional common law rules that negative easements could not be transferred,
  • 232
    • 84868169280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF PROPERTY: SERVITUDES §1.6 cmt. a. As a result, there was widespread enactment of statutes to overcome the problematic common law rules, and in 1981, the Uniform Conservation Easement Act was announced.
    • see RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF PROPERTY: SERVITUDES §1.6 cmt. a. As a result, there was "widespread enactment of statutes" to overcome the problematic common law rules, and in 1981, the Uniform Conservation Easement Act was announced.
  • 233
    • 77749318042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.;
    • Id.;
  • 234
    • 84868176607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also id. §2.6 cmt. a. (Early law prohibited the creation of servitude benefits in gross and the creation of servitude benefits in persons who were not immediate parties to the transaction.).
    • see also id. §2.6 cmt. a. ("Early law prohibited the creation of servitude benefits in gross and the creation of servitude benefits in persons who were not immediate parties to the transaction.").
  • 235
    • 77749313880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally JESSE DUKEMINIER & JAMES E. KRIER, PROPERTY 855-57 (5th ed. 2002) (outlining the history of restrictions on negative easements in England that were later adopted by U.S. courts);
    • See generally JESSE DUKEMINIER & JAMES E. KRIER, PROPERTY 855-57 (5th ed. 2002) (outlining the history of restrictions on negative easements in England that were later adopted by U.S. courts);
  • 236
    • 84868182917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RICHARD R. POWELL, POWELL ON REAL PROPERTY §34.16 (Michael Allan Wolf ed., Matthew Bender & Co. 2009) (1949) (detailing the evolution of juristic attitudes toward transfer of easements in gross);
    • RICHARD R. POWELL, POWELL ON REAL PROPERTY §34.16 (Michael Allan Wolf ed., Matthew Bender & Co. 2009) (1949) (detailing the evolution of juristic attitudes toward transfer of easements in gross);
  • 237
    • 77749305938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John L. Hollingshead, Conservation Easements: A Flexible Tool for Land Preservation, 3 ENVTL. LAW. 319, 327 (1997) (noting that where the benefit of an easement is held in gross, some courts do not allow the burden to run with the land).
    • John L. Hollingshead, Conservation Easements: A Flexible Tool for Land Preservation, 3 ENVTL. LAW. 319, 327 (1997) (noting that where the benefit of an easement is held in gross, some courts do not allow the burden to run with the land).
  • 238
    • 77749313919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 86, at 23-24
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 86, at 23-24.
  • 239
    • 77749318070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 19-20
    • Id. at 19-20.
  • 240
    • 45249095392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See
    • §106 2006, granting copyright holders exclusive rights to reproduce, prepare derivative works based on, distribute copies of, and-with respect to some kinds of work-to perform or display the copyrighted work
    • See 17 U.S.C. §106 (2006) (granting copyright holders exclusive rights to reproduce, prepare derivative works based on, distribute copies of, and-with respect to some kinds of work-to perform or display the copyrighted work);
    • 17 U.S.C
  • 241
    • 84868176604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. §271(a) (2006) (defining patent infringement as mak[ing], us[ing], offer[ing] to sell, or sell[ing] any patented invention without authorization).
    • U.S.C. §271(a) (2006) (defining patent infringement as "mak[ing], us[ing], offer[ing] to sell, or sell[ing] any patented invention" without authorization).
  • 242
    • 77749318079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Smith, Intellectual Property, supra note 29, at 1780; see also infra note 238 and accompanying text.
    • Smith, Intellectual Property, supra note 29, at 1780; see also infra note 238 and accompanying text.
  • 243
    • 84868892071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See
    • §271 a, Smith, Intellectual Property, supra note 29, at 1795
    • See 35 U.S.C. §271 (a); Smith, Intellectual Property, supra note 29, at 1795.
    • 35 U.S.C
  • 244
    • 84868169279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This rough calculation is based on information from the U.S. Patent Office concerning the numbers of patents issued per year from 1991 to 2007. See U.S. Patent Statistics Chart: Calendar Years 1963-2007, available at
    • This rough calculation is based on information from the U.S. Patent Office concerning the numbers of patents issued per year from 1991 to 2007. See U.S. Patent Statistics Chart: Calendar Years 1963-2007, available at http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/ac/ido/oeip/taf/us-stat.htm.
  • 245
    • 77749316613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It assumes that maintenance fees on patents of various ages are paid the same percentage of the time that they were in 1998. See also Mark A. Lemley, Rational Ignorance at the Patent Office, 95 Nw. U. L. REV. 1495, 1504 (2001) (recording the [p]ercentage of [p]atents for [w]hich [maintenance [f]ees [w]ere [p]aid in 1998).
    • It assumes that maintenance fees on patents of various ages are paid the same percentage of the time that they were in 1998. See also Mark A. Lemley, Rational Ignorance at the Patent Office, 95 Nw. U. L. REV. 1495, 1504 (2001) (recording the "[p]ercentage of [p]atents for [w]hich [maintenance [f]ees [w]ere [p]aid" in 1998).
  • 246
    • 84922580177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 182, at, comparing the levels of difficulty for running a land title search with that of running a patent search
    • See BESSEN & MEURER, supra note 182, at 51 -68 (comparing the levels of difficulty for running a land title search with that of running a patent search);
    • supra , pp. 51-68
    • BESSEN1    MEURER2
  • 247
    • 77749318075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Merrill & Smith, supra note 86, at 44-45 (arguing that notice of idiosyncratic property rights, even if given through a centralized land register, is insufficient to restrict the information costs on third parties to justifiable levels).
    • cf. Merrill & Smith, supra note 86, at 44-45 (arguing that notice of idiosyncratic property rights, even if given through a centralized land register, is insufficient to restrict the information costs on third parties to justifiable levels).
  • 248
    • 77749318072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BESSEN & MEURER, supra note 182, at 68-71 (discussing the [p]atent [f]lood and observing that firms are [often] sued over patents covering distant technologies).
    • See BESSEN & MEURER, supra note 182, at 68-71 (discussing the "[p]atent [f]lood" and observing that "firms are [often] sued over patents covering distant technologies").
  • 249
    • 77749313920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 86, at 27-33 (discussing problems that would be inherent in the creation of a fanciful servitude-for example, by creating a time-share in a watch).
    • See Merrill & Smith, supra note 86, at 27-33 (discussing problems that would be inherent in the creation of a "fanciful" servitude-for example, by creating a time-share in a watch).
  • 250
    • 77749305945 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BESSEN & MEURER, supra note 182, at 68-71 discussing the various information costs caused by proliferation of IP rights in patent law
    • See BESSEN & MEURER, supra note 182, at 68-71 (discussing the various information costs caused by proliferation of IP rights in patent law).
  • 251
    • 77749313927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 252
    • 77749316552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Again, a patentee is appropriating use privileges from their prior owners. This vests in her-the patentee-in the form of use rights-that is, the right to exclude others from these uses. Although the patentee has taken away the others' privilege to use the patented invention, she is left with only a right to exclude and may not have the privilege to use it herself.
    • Again, a patentee is appropriating use privileges from their prior owners. This vests in her-the patentee-in the form of use rights-that is, the right to exclude others from these uses. Although the patentee has taken away the others' privilege to use the patented invention, she is left with only a right to exclude and may not have the privilege to use it herself.
  • 253
    • 84868169276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 35 U.S.C. §112 2006, requiring that patent applicants provide specifications that include a written description of the invention sufficient to enable any person skilled in the art, to make and use [it, as well as a description of the best mode contemplated by the inventor of carrying out his invention
    • See 35 U.S.C. §112 (2006) (requiring that patent applicants provide specifications that include "a written description of the invention" sufficient "to enable any person skilled in the art ... to make and use [it]," as well as a description of "the best mode contemplated by the inventor of carrying out his invention").
  • 254
    • 84868892071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See
    • §112 describing the requirements for the specifications portion of the patent application
    • See 35 U.S.C. §112 (describing the requirements for the specifications portion of the patent application).
    • 35 U.S.C
  • 255
    • 84868182914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. §102 (setting forth the novelty requirements).
    • U.S.C. §102 (setting forth the novelty requirements).
  • 256
    • 84868176602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. §101 (providing that the invention must be new and useful).
    • U.S.C. §101 (providing that the invention must be "new and useful").
  • 257
    • 84868169277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. §112 mandating that an inventor include specifications in enough detail to enable a person of ordinary skill in the art to build the invention
    • U.S.C. §112 (mandating that an inventor include specifications in enough detail to enable a person of ordinary skill in the art to build the invention).
  • 258
    • 84868182915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. §103 (setting forth the requirements for non-obvious subject matter).
    • U.S.C. §103 (setting forth the requirements for non-obvious subject matter).
  • 259
    • 77749305937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • explaining that a taker will be able to pick out a class of assets that has a higher mean value than the one that the courts have identified, and courts cannot cost-effectively keep up, See, at
    • See Smith, Property Rules, supra note 18, at 1781-83 (explaining that a "taker will be able to pick out a class of assets that has a higher mean value than the one that the courts have identified, and courts cannot cost-effectively keep up").
    • Property Rules, supra note , vol.18 , pp. 1781-1783
    • Smith1
  • 260
    • 84868167409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An example of this type of owner is someone who discovered the invention independently of-but subsequent to-the patentee and discovery, but did not put the invention to public use more than a year before the filing of the patentee's application. See 35 U.S.C. § 102(a)-(b) (stating that such independent discovery and use would not invalidate that patent).
    • An example of this type of owner is someone who discovered the invention independently of-but subsequent to-the patentee and discovery, but did not put the invention to public use more than a year before the filing of the patentee's application. See 35 U.S.C. § 102(a)-(b) (stating that such independent discovery and use would not invalidate that patent).
  • 261
    • 77749316598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Such owners are also likely to place a high idiosyncratic value on the use rights lost, as people often do with things that they feel they have created themselves
    • Such owners are also likely to place a high idiosyncratic value on the use rights lost, as people often do with things that they feel they have created themselves.
  • 262
    • 84868182911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. §103a
    • U.S.C. §103(a).
  • 263
    • 77749305914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rationale here may be valid: we want to afford inventors space within which to prepare a patent application and not force them to keep the invention secret while doing so. Nevertheless, the effect on the value of what is offered to the public in exchange for patent rights is as described
    • The rationale here may be valid: we want to afford inventors space within which to prepare a patent application and not force them to keep the invention secret while doing so. Nevertheless, the effect on the value of what is offered to the public in exchange for patent rights is as described.
  • 264
    • 77749318052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • exploring [r]ights in [information [t]hrough the [l]ens of [accession [l]aw, See generally, at
    • See generally Smith, Intellectual Property, supra note 29, at 1766-77 (exploring "[r]ights in [information [t]hrough the [l]ens of [accession [l]aw").
    • Intellectual Property, supra note , vol.29 , pp. 1766-1777
    • Smith1
  • 265
    • 77749308182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1771
    • Id. at 1771.
  • 266
    • 77749305926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 267
    • 77749305935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 318-20 (1871) (discussing the operation of the law when property is improved and unable to be divided).
    • See, e.g., Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 318-20 (1871) (discussing the operation of the law when property is improved and unable to be divided).
  • 269
    • 77749313915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gordon, supra note 51
    • See Gordon, supra note 51.
  • 270
    • 77749318052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • offering a comparison of IP rights to the law of accession, See generally, at
    • See generally Smith, Intellectual Property, supra note 29, at 1766-77 (offering a comparison of IP rights to the law of accession).
    • Intellectual Property, supra note , vol.29 , pp. 1766-1777
    • Smith1
  • 271
    • 77749316611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See eBay, Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388, 390-91 (2006) (noting that the petitioner, eBay, invested resources to operate a popular website that was accused of infringing a patent held by another company).
    • See eBay, Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388, 390-91 (2006) (noting that the petitioner, eBay, invested resources to operate a popular website that was accused of infringing a patent held by another company).
  • 272
    • 77749313900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley & Weiser, supra note 10, at 797-98 (As a striking example, literally thousands of patents have been identified as essential to the proposed new standards for 3G cellular telephone systems, and more than four hundred patents are necessary to produce a DVD. (citations omitted)).
    • See Lemley & Weiser, supra note 10, at 797-98 ("As a striking example, literally thousands of patents have been identified as essential to the proposed new standards for 3G cellular telephone systems, and more than four hundred patents are necessary to produce a DVD." (citations omitted)).
  • 273
    • 77749305913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, a car is useless without wheels. But one could say the same thing about a car without a gas tank or a car without spark plugs. How would one go about allocating the value of the car according to the relative contributions made by these various components when each of them is equally necessary?
    • For example, a car is useless without wheels. But one could say the same thing about a car without a gas tank or a car without spark plugs. How would one go about allocating the value of the car according to the relative contributions made by these various components when each of them is equally necessary?
  • 274
    • 77749318061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 312 (1871).
    • Wetherbee v. Green, 22 Mich. 311, 312 (1871).
  • 275
    • 77749318043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The same is true in nuisance cases, where the relevant question is not how much of the factory's value is due to the pollution of plaintiffs land, but rather how does the value of the factory compare to the value of plaintiff s land before it was polluted
    • The same is true in nuisance cases, where the relevant question is not "how much of the factory's value is due to the pollution of plaintiffs land," but rather "how does the value of the factory compare to the value of plaintiff s land before it was polluted?"
  • 276
    • 77749318066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 22 Mich. at, 320 discussing the appropriated chattel in this case, which was cut timber
    • See, e.g., Wetherbee, 22 Mich. at 318, 320 (discussing the appropriated chattel in this case, which was cut timber).
    • See, e.g., Wetherbee , pp. 318
  • 277
    • 77749313914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., S.O.S., Inc. v. Payday, Inc., 886 F.2d 1081, 1088 (9th Cir. 1989) (concluding that copyright licenses are assumed to prohibit any use not authorized).
    • See, e.g., S.O.S., Inc. v. Payday, Inc., 886 F.2d 1081, 1088 (9th Cir. 1989) (concluding that "copyright licenses are assumed to prohibit any use not authorized").
  • 278
    • 77749316596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, the consideration may consist of not only money but also of the crosslicensing of the licensee's own intellectual property
    • For example, the consideration may consist of not only money but also of the crosslicensing of the licensee's own intellectual property.
  • 279
    • 77749318055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is necessary to discern a market price for the use at issue, otherwise the calculation of damages would be impractical. See, e.g., Arnold, supra note 95, at 112-13 (noting that in applying the accession doctrine, damages are measured according to the value of the article in its improved state).
    • It is necessary to discern a market price for the use at issue, otherwise the calculation of damages would be impractical. See, e.g., Arnold, supra note 95, at 112-13 (noting that in applying the accession doctrine, damages are measured according to the "value of the article in its improved state").
  • 280
    • 77749318064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the context of the accession rule, courts will likely favor the improver when the improved value is higher than that of the original article. See, e.g, Wetherbee, 22 Mich, at 320
    • In the context of the accession rule, courts will likely favor the improver when the improved value is higher than that of the original article. See, e.g., Wetherbee, 22 Mich, at 320.
  • 281
    • 77749316607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part VI.B.
    • See supra Part VI.B.
  • 282
    • 77749305941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Madison v. Ducktown Sulphur, Copper & Iron Co., 83 S.W. 658, 662 (Tenn. 1904) (determining that courts may give deference to the creator of the nuisance when the nuisance is a legal trade operating in good faith).
    • See, e.g., Madison v. Ducktown Sulphur, Copper & Iron Co., 83 S.W. 658, 662 (Tenn. 1904) (determining that courts may give deference to the creator of the nuisance when the nuisance is a legal trade operating in good faith).
  • 283
    • 77749305936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part VI-VLA.
    • See supra Part VI-VLA.
  • 284
    • 56249144537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David L. Schwartz, Practice Makes Perfect? An Empirical Study of Claim Construction Reversal Rates in Patent Cases, 107 MICH. L. REV. 223, 240, 251-52 2008, studying appealed cases where the trial court was found to have wrongly construed at least one patent term, which occurs 38.8% of the time, and noting that this rate does not improve with the level of patent experience of the trial court
    • See David L. Schwartz, Practice Makes Perfect? An Empirical Study of Claim Construction Reversal Rates in Patent Cases, 107 MICH. L. REV. 223, 240, 251-52 (2008) (studying appealed cases where the trial court was found to have wrongly construed at least one patent term, which occurs 38.8% of the time, and noting that this rate does not improve with the level of patent experience of the trial court).
  • 285
    • 77749305919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wilson Sporting Goods Co. v. Hillerich & Bradsby Co., 442 F.3d 1322, 1326-27 (Fed. Cir. 2006) (holding that without any information about the accused products, the record lacks the complete context for accurate claim construction);
    • See Wilson Sporting Goods Co. v. Hillerich & Bradsby Co., 442 F.3d 1322, 1326-27 (Fed. Cir. 2006) (holding that without any information about the accused products, the "record lacks the complete context for accurate claim construction");
  • 286
    • 77749305883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cheryl Lee Johnson, The Continuing Inability of Judges to Pass Their Markman Tests: Why the Broken System Leaves Judges Behind, Confused and Demoralized, in MARKMAN HEARINGS AND CLAIM CONSTRUCTION IN PATENT LITIGATION 2008, at 65, 71 (Thomas L. Creel 2008) (discussing the chronic inability of judges to consistently construe highly abstruse patent claims cloaked with technical jargon,despitetheirpresumed exegetical skills).
    • Cheryl Lee Johnson, The Continuing Inability of Judges to Pass Their Markman Tests: Why the Broken System Leaves Judges Behind, Confused and Demoralized, in MARKMAN HEARINGS AND CLAIM CONSTRUCTION IN PATENT LITIGATION 2008, at 65, 71 (Thomas L. Creel 2008) (discussing the chronic inability of judges to consistently "construe highly abstruse patent claims cloaked with technical jargon,"despitetheirpresumed exegetical skills).
  • 287
    • 77749313911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part VI.B;
    • See supra Part VI.B;
  • 288
    • 77749318059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, e.g., Agrizap, Inc. v. Woodstream Corp., 520 F.3d 1337, 1339 (Fed. Cir. 2008) (concluding that Agrizap's patent for a device to kill rodents was invalid due to obviousness).
    • see also, e.g., Agrizap, Inc. v. Woodstream Corp., 520 F.3d 1337, 1339 (Fed. Cir. 2008) (concluding that Agrizap's patent for a device to kill rodents was invalid due to obviousness).
  • 289
    • 77749316602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John R. Allison & Mark A. Lemley, Empirical Evidence on the Validity of Litigated Patents, 26 AIPLA Q.J. 185, 194, 205 (1998) (finding that from 1989 to 1996, forty-six percent of final validity decisions by either district courts or the Federal Circuit reported in the U.S.P.Q. found the patent at issue to be invalid);
    • John R. Allison & Mark A. Lemley, Empirical Evidence on the Validity of Litigated Patents, 26 AIPLA Q.J. 185, 194, 205 (1998) (finding that from 1989 to 1996, forty-six percent of "final validity decisions by either district courts or the Federal Circuit reported in the U.S.P.Q." found the patent at issue to be invalid);
  • 290
    • 77749313903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see BESSEN & MEURER, supra note 182, at 277 explaining that although the Patent Office provides a reexamination procedure, firms are often hesitant to use it because it places firms at a disadvantage if subsequent litigation occurs
    • see BESSEN & MEURER, supra note 182, at 277 (explaining that although the Patent Office provides a reexamination procedure, firms are often hesitant to use it because it "places firms at a disadvantage if subsequent litigation occurs").
  • 291
    • 84868167405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also BESSEN & MEURER, supra note 182, at 131-32 for a discussion of the costs of litigation, showing that estimated legal costs of litigating patent suits through trial range from $610,000 to $4.14 million, depending on the amount of damages at stake.
    • See also BESSEN & MEURER, supra note 182, at 131-32 for a discussion of the costs of litigation, showing that estimated legal costs of litigating patent suits through trial range from $610,000 to $4.14 million, depending on the amount of damages at stake.
  • 292
    • 77749305932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 3, at 2032-33 (The average royalty rate granted in all reasonable-royalty cases is 13.13% of the price of the infringing product.).
    • See Lemley & Shapiro, supra note 3, at 2032-33 ("The average royalty rate granted in all reasonable-royalty cases is 13.13% of the price of the infringing product.").
  • 293
    • 0346511083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert P. Merges, Contracting into Liability Rules: Intellectual Property Rights and Collective Rights Organizations, 84 CAL. L. REV. 1293, 1308-16 (1996) (discussing the marketdistorting effects of compulsory license rates in the context of cover songs).
    • See Robert P. Merges, Contracting into Liability Rules: Intellectual Property Rights and Collective Rights Organizations, 84 CAL. L. REV. 1293, 1308-16 (1996) (discussing the marketdistorting effects of compulsory license rates in the context of "cover" songs).
  • 294
    • 84868167408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 35 U.S.C. §284 (2006).
    • See 35 U.S.C. §284 (2006).
  • 295
    • 77749316608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (noting only that damages should be adequate to compensate for the infringement).
    • Id. (noting only that damages should be "adequate to compensate for the infringement").
  • 296
    • 77749316601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inc. v. Advanced Tech. Labs., Inc
    • Cir
    • SRI Int'l, Inc. v. Advanced Tech. Labs., Inc., 127 F.3d 1462, 1464 (Fed. Cir. 1997).
    • (1997) 127 F.3d 1462, 1464 (Fed
    • Int'l, S.1
  • 297
    • 77749305934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Read Corp. v. Portee, Inc., 970 F.2d 816, 826-27 (Fed. Cir. 1992).
    • See Read Corp. v. Portee, Inc., 970 F.2d 816, 826-27 (Fed. Cir. 1992).
  • 298
    • 77749318056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The willfulness standard, in other words, was congruous to the standard for innocent encroachment
    • The willfulness standard, in other words, was congruous to the standard for innocent encroachment.
  • 300
    • 77749305939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 301
    • 77749318054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (Because we abandon the affirmative duty of due care, we also reemphasize that there is no affirmative obligation to obtain opinion of counsel.).
    • Id. ("Because we abandon the affirmative duty of due care, we also reemphasize that there is no affirmative obligation to obtain opinion of counsel.").
  • 302
    • 77749305929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Moore v. Regents of the Univ. of Cal., 793 P.2d 479, 509 (Cal. 1990) (Mosk, J., dissenting) (explaining that property law seeks to protect an object with a related bundle of rights).
    • See, e.g., Moore v. Regents of the Univ. of Cal., 793 P.2d 479, 509 (Cal. 1990) (Mosk, J., dissenting) (explaining that property law seeks to protect an object with a related "bundle of rights").
  • 303
    • 77749313906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., In re Engage, Inc., 544 F.3d 50, 54 (1st Cir. 2008) (noting that receiving a patent gives the owner a property interest-to exclude others from use of the property).
    • See, e.g., In re Engage, Inc., 544 F.3d 50, 54 (1st Cir. 2008) (noting that receiving a patent gives the owner "a property interest-to exclude others from use of the property").
  • 304
    • 77749313878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moral Nuisances, 50
    • discussing the evolving academic and judicial views of aesthetics in nuisance case law, See
    • See John Copeland Nagle, Moral Nuisances, 50 EMORY L.J. 265, 286-87 (2001) (discussing the evolving academic and judicial views of aesthetics in nuisance case law).
    • (2001) EMORY L.J , vol.265 , pp. 286-287
    • Copeland Nagle, J.1
  • 306
    • 77749316606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., SRI Int'l, Inc. v. Advanced Tech. Labs., Inc., 127 F.3d 1462, 1464 (Fed. Cir. 1997) (affirming the award of enhanced damages in a patent infringement action).
    • See, e.g., SRI Int'l, Inc. v. Advanced Tech. Labs., Inc., 127 F.3d 1462, 1464 (Fed. Cir. 1997) (affirming the award of enhanced damages in a patent infringement action).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.