메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 87, Issue 7, 2009, Pages 1375-1407

Making presidential and semi-presidential constitutions work

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 69249140998     PISSN: 00404411     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (12)

References (274)
  • 1
    • 0003162328 scopus 로고
    • Presidential or parliamentary democracy: Does it make a difference?
    • Juan J. Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds.
    • Juan J. Linz, Presidential or Parliamentary Democracy: Does It Make a Difference?, in THE Failure of PRESIDENTIAL DEMOCRACY: COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVES 3, 5-44 (Juan J. Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds., 1994).
    • (1994) THE Failure of Presidential Democracy: Comparative Perspectives 3 , pp. 5-44
    • Linz, J.J.1
  • 2
    • 5844383486 scopus 로고
    • Constitutional frameworks and democratic consolidation
    • (using a comparative study of twenty cases of interrupted presidencies in Latin American to illustrate the potential consequences to presidentialism)., E.g., gathering data to contrast pure presidentialism with pure parliamentarism in Latin American and Eastern European countries
    • E.g., Alfred Stepan & Cindy Skach, Constitutional Frameworks and Democratic Consolidation, 46 WORLD POL. 1 (1993) (gathering data to contrast pure presidentialism with pure parliamentarism in Latin American and Eastern European countries);
    • (1993) 46 World Pol. 1
    • Stepan, A.1    Skach, C.2
  • 3
    • 7544234157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Latin American presidencies interrupted
    • Oct., at 5, comparing the survival of a variety of presidential systems in Latin America from 1985-2004 despite interruptions occurring during presidential rule
    • Arturo Valenzuela, Latin American Presidencies Interrupted, J. DEMOCRACY, Oct. 2004, at 5 (comparing the survival of a variety of presidential systems in Latin America from 1985-2004 despite interruptions occurring during presidential rule);
    • (2004) J. Democracy
    • Valenzuela, A.1
  • 4
    • 69249142019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Apr. 25-30, unpublished European Consortium for Political Research workshop paper, available at, (using a comparative study of twenty cases of interrupted presidencies in Latin American to illustrate the potential consequences to presidentialism
    • Leiv Marsteintredet & Einar Berntzen, Latin American Presidentialism: Reducing the Perils of Presidentialism Through Presidential Interruptions (Apr. 25-30, 2006) (unpublished European Consortium for Political Research workshop paper), available at http://www.essex.ac.uk/ecpr/events/jointsessions/ paperarchive/nicosia/ws20/Marsteintredet.pdf (using a comparative study of twenty cases of interrupted presidencies in Latin American to illustrate the potential consequences to presidentialism).
    • (2006) Latin American Presidentialism: Reducing the Perils of Presidentialism Through Presidential Interruptions
    • Marsteintredet, L.1    Berntzen, E.2
  • 5
    • 69249131895 scopus 로고
    • E.g., discussing the potential for success of a new constitution in Poland based on prior constitutional history
    • E.g., Adam Przeworski, DEMOCRACY AND THE MARKET 82-83 (1991) (discussing the potential for success of a new constitution in Poland based on prior constitutional history);
    • (1991) Democracy and the Market 82-83
    • Przeworski, A.1
  • 6
    • 0004220481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 141-147, comparing and predicting the likelihood of survival of the new democratic governments in Eastern European countries
    • ROBERT Zuzowski, POLITICAL CHANGE IN EASTERN EUROPE SINCE 1989, at 141-147 (1998) (comparing and predicting the likelihood of survival of the new democratic governments in Eastern European countries).
    • (1998) Political Change in Eastern Europe Since 1989
    • Zuzowski, R.1
  • 7
    • 0003393527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., discussing the forms of presidentialism that have been used in African political regimes
    • E.g., Michael Bratton & Nicolas van de Walle, DEMOCRATIC EXPERIMENTS IN AFRICA 63-65 (1997) (discussing the forms of presidentialism that have been used in African political regimes);
    • (1997) Democratic Experiments in Africa 63-65
    • Bratton, M.1    Van De Walle, N.2
  • 8
    • 84917086915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Semi-presidentialism in a francophone context
    • Robert Elgie & Sophia Moestrup eds., describing the transitions to democracy in the African francophone countries
    • Gerard Conac, Semi-presidentialism in a Francophone Context, in SEMI-presidentialism Outside Europe 84-87 (Robert Elgie & Sophia Moestrup eds., 2007) (describing the transitions to democracy in the African francophone countries);
    • (2007) Semi-presidentialism Outside Europe 84-87
    • Conac, G.1
  • 9
    • 0038684073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidentialism and clientelism in Africa's emerging party systems
    • examining the types of presidential systems that are emerging in African political systems
    • Nicolas van de Walle, Presidentialism and Clientelism in Africa's Emerging Party Systems, 41 J. MOD. AFR. STUD. 297, 309-11 (2003) (examining the types of presidential systems that are emerging in African political systems).
    • (2003) 41 J. Mod. Afr. Stud. 297 , pp. 309-311
    • Van De Walle, N.1
  • 11
    • 69249095545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stepan & Skach, supra note 2, at 7 (finding that "presidential systems had a democratic underachiever rate 3.4 times greater than did the parliamentary systems"
    • Stepan & Skach, supra note 2, at 7 (finding that "presidential systems had a democratic underachiever rate 3.4 times greater than did the parliamentary systems");
  • 12
    • 0038501269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • June, unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of Chicago, on file with the University of Chicago Library) (finding that presidentialism's correlation to unrest is higher than parliamentarism's correlation to unrest
    • Michael E. Alvarez, Presidentialism and Parliamentarism: Which Works? Which Lasts? 300 (June 1998) (unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of Chicago) (on file with the University of Chicago Library) (finding that presidentialism's correlation to unrest is higher than parliamentarism's correlation to unrest).
    • (1998) Presidentialism and Parliamentarism: Which Works? Which Lasts? 300
    • Alvarez, M.E.1
  • 13
    • 33748532530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., recommending the establishment of a "well-functioning parliament" in response to issues with the presidential system in Ukraine
    • E.g., Paul D'Anieri, UNDERSTANDING UKRAINIAN POLITICS 37-40 (2007) (recommending the establishment of a "well-functioning parliament" in response to issues with the presidential system in Ukraine).
    • (2007) Understanding Ukrainian Politics 37-40
    • D'Anieri, P.1
  • 14
    • 85050777229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hyperpresidentialism and constitutional reform in Argentina
    • E.g., Arend Lijphart & Carlos H. Waisman eds., suggesting a variety of reforms to Argentina's presidential system for the following reasons: first, presidents elected by less than a majority cause "the formation of governments that lack strong popular support"; second, where the president and the legislature represent opposing parties, the legislature has a "strong incentive to savagely oppose the president to increase the opposition's likelihood of winning the next election"; and finally, the president can acquire additional power through the submission of the legislature and the judiciary, which undermines the rule of law
    • E.g., Carlos Santiago Nino, Hyperpresidentialism and Constitutional Reform in Argentina, in INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN IN NEW DEMOCRACIES: EASTERN EUROPE AND LATIN AMERICA 161, 168-169 (Arend Lijphart & Carlos H. Waisman eds., 1996) (suggesting a variety of reforms to Argentina's presidential system for the following reasons: first, presidents elected by less than a majority cause "the formation of governments that lack strong popular support"; second, where the president and the legislature represent opposing parties, the legislature has a "strong incentive to savagely oppose the president to increase the opposition's likelihood of winning the next election"; and finally, the president can acquire additional power through the submission of the legislature and the judiciary, which undermines the rule of law).
    • (1996) Institutional Design in New Democracies: Eastern Europe and Latin America 161 , pp. 168-169
    • Nino, C.S.1
  • 15
    • 69249129841 scopus 로고
    • The perils of presidentialism
    • See, Winter, at 51, 52, 56, arguing that presidentialism is "ineluctably problematic" and that parliamentarism "offers a better hope of preserving democracy" in nations with "deep political cleavages and numerous political parties"
    • See Juan J. Linz, The Perils of Presidentialism, J. DEMOCRACY, Winter 1990, at 51, 52, 56, 55-56 (arguing that presidentialism is "ineluctably problematic" and that parliamentarism "offers a better hope of preserving democracy" in nations with "deep political cleavages and numerous political parties").
    • (1990) J. Democracy , pp. 55-56
    • Linz, J.J.1
  • 16
    • 0003561156 scopus 로고
    • E.g., discussing modifications to the presidential system in order to gain some of the benefits of parliamentarism while also avoiding the issue of stalemate that can occur in a parliamentary system
    • E.g., MICHAEL COPPEDGE, STRONG PARTIES AND LAME DUCKS: PRESIDENTIAL Partyarchy and Factionalism in Venezuela 169-170 (1994) (discussing modifications to the presidential system in order to gain some of the benefits of parliamentarism while also avoiding the issue of stalemate that can occur in a parliamentary system).
    • (1994) Strong Parties and Lameducks: Presidential Partyarchy and Factionalism in Venezuela 169-170
    • Coppedge, M.1
  • 18
    • 0038501188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parliamentarism versus presidentialism in the policy arena
    • Kent Eaton, Parliamentarism Versus Presidentialism in the Policy Arena, 32 COMP. POL. 355, 356 (2000);
    • (2000) 32 Comp. Pol. 355 , pp. 356
    • Eaton, K.1
  • 20
    • 33750205312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidentialism, electoral identifiability, and budget balances in democratic systems
    • E.g.
    • E.g., José Antonio Cheibub, Presidentialism, Electoral Identifiability, and Budget Balances in Democratic Systems, 100 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 353, 354-56 (2006).
    • (2006) 100 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 353 , pp. 354-356
    • Cheibub, J.A.1
  • 21
    • 69249151049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Alvarez, supra note 5 (manuscript at 162-65)
    • E.g., Alvarez, supra note 5 (manuscript at 162-65).
  • 23
    • 0036103281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Democratization, political institutions, and ethnic conflict: a pooled time-series analysis, 1985-1998
    • E.g.
    • E.g., Stephen M. Saideman et al., Democratization, Political Institutions, and Ethnic Conflict: A Pooled Time-Series Analysis, 1985-1998, 35 COMP. POL. STUD. 103 (2002).
    • 35 Comp. Pol. Stud. 103 , pp. 2002
    • Saideman, S.M.1
  • 24
    • 0000124691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unpacking democracy: Presidentialism, parliamentarism, and theories of democratic peace
    • E.g., Summer, at 91
    • E.g., Miriam Fendius Elman, Unpacking Democracy: Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, and Theories of Democratic Peace, SECURITY STUD., Summer 2000, at 91.
    • (2000) Security Stud.
    • Elman, M.F.1
  • 25
    • 14644433628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Veto players, electoral incentives and international commitments: The impact of domestic institutions on intergovernmental organization membership
    • E.g.
    • E.g., Daniel J. Minnich, Veto Players, Electoral Incentives and International Commitments: The Impact of Domestic Institutions on Intergovernmental Organization Membership, 44 EUR. J. POL. RES. 295 (2005).
    • (2005) 44 Eur. J. Pol. Res. 295
    • Minnich, D.J.1
  • 26
    • 0344512435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are you being served? Political accountability and quality of government
    • E.g.
    • E.g., Alicia Adeserà et al., Are You Being Served? Political Accountability and Quality of Government, 19 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 445 (2003);
    • (2003) 19 J.L. Econ. & Org. 445
    • Adeserà, A.1
  • 27
    • 0036269926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional design and democratic performance
    • Summer, at 43
    • Joe Foweraker & Todd Landman, Constitutional Design and Democratic Performance, DEMOCRATIZATION, Summer 2002, at 43;
    • (2002) Democratization
    • Foweraker, J.1    Landman, T.2
  • 28
    • 33644903824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Centripetal democratic governance: A theory and global inquiry
    • 575-80
    • John Gerring et al., Centripetal Democratic Governance: A Theory and Global Inquiry, 99 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 567, 569-70, 575-80 (2005).
    • (2005) 99 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 567 , pp. 569-570
    • Gerring, J.1
  • 29
    • 36949038805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Electoral accountability and the variety of democratic regimes
    • E.g.
    • E.g., David Samuels & Timothy Hellwig, Electoral Accountability and the Variety of Democratic Regimes, 38 BRIT. J. POL. SCI. 65 (2008).
    • (2008) 38 Brit. J. Pol. Sci. 65
    • Samuels, D.1    Hellwig, T.2
  • 30
    • 13344267198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidentialism, parliamentarism, and the provision of collective goods in less-developed countries
    • E.g.
    • 19.E.g., Matthew Sober Shugart, Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, and the Provision of Collective Goods in Less-Developed Countries, 10 CONST. POL. ECON. 53 (1999).
    • (1999) 10 Const. Pol. Econ. 53
    • Shugart, M.S.1
  • 31
    • 33846337177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The "Newest" separation of powers: Semipresidentialism
    • E.g.
    • E.g., Cindy Skach, The "Newest" Separation of Powers: Semipresidentialism, 5 INT'L J. CONST. L. 93, 98 (2007).
    • (2007) 5 Int'l J. Const. L. 93 , pp. 98
    • Skach, C.1
  • 32
    • 21144446720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional roulette: The Russian parliament's battles with the president over appointing a prime minster
    • Eugene D. Mazo, Constitutional Roulette: The Russian Parliament's Battles with the President over Appointing a Prime Minster, 41 STAN. J. INT'LL, 123, 131 (2005).
    • (2005) 41 Stan. J. Int'l L. 123 , pp. 131
    • Mazo, E.D.1
  • 34
    • 69249141211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 140-45
    • Id. at 140-45.
  • 35
    • 69249131894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 145-48
    • Id. at 145-48
  • 36
    • 69249141580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 148
    • Id. at 148.
  • 37
    • 69249120407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 38
    • 69249140810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 152
    • Id. at 152.
  • 39
    • 0004171413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, France created an independently elected presidency in 1958. La Constitution [1958 Const.] art. 6 (Fr.), translated in, Rüdiger Wolfram & Rainer Grote eds.
    • For example, France created an independently elected presidency in 1958. LA CONSTITUTION [1958 CONST.] art. 6 (Fr.), translated in 7 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE WORLD (Rüdiger Wolfram & Rainer Grote eds., 2009).
    • (2009) 7 Constitutions of the Countries of The World
  • 40
    • 84869711579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another example is the Slovak Republic, which amended its Constitution in 1999 to allow direct election of its President by secret ballot for a five-year term. ÚSTAVA SLOVENSKEJ REPUBLIKY [Ostava] [Constitution] art. 101, § 2 (Slovk.), translated in, supra
    • Another example is the Slovak Republic, which amended its Constitution in 1999 to allow direct election of its President by secret ballot for a five-year term. ÚSTAVA SLOVENSKEJ REPUBLIKY [Ostava] [Constitution] art. 101, § 2 (Slovk.), translated in 16 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE WORLD, supra.
    • 16 Constitutions of The Countries of The World
  • 42
    • 69249094391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KONSTYTUCJA RZECZYPOSPOLITEJ POLSKIEJ [KONST. RP] [Constitution] arts. 126-127, 146, 154-162 (Pol.), translated in, supra note 28 (creating an independently elected President who has limited domestic executive and administrative powers but who can select the Council of Ministers to perform those functions, subject to the approval and ongoing support of the Sejm (the lower parliamentary house)
    • KONSTYTUCJA RZECZYPOSPOLITEJ POLSKIEJ [KONST. RP] [Constitution] arts. 126-127, 146, 154-162 (Pol.), translated in 15 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE WORLD, supra note 28 (creating an independently elected President who has limited domestic executive and administrative powers but who can select the Council of Ministers to perform those functions, subject to the approval and ongoing support of the Sejm (the lower parliamentary house));
    • 15 Constitutions of The Countries of The World
  • 44
    • 0036805306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pluralism by default in Moldova
    • Oct., at 127, 130 (describing the elimination of the popularly elected President in Moldova in 2000
    • Lucan A. Way, Pluralism by Default in Moldova, J. DEMOCRACY, Oct. 2002, at 127, 130 (describing the elimination of the popularly elected President in Moldova in 2000).
    • (2002) J. Democracy
    • Way, L.A.1
  • 45
    • 69249134411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The following discussion borrows heavily from CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 166-168
    • The following discussion borrows heavily from CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 166-168
  • 46
    • 69249130241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 166
    • Id. at 166.
  • 47
    • 69249129840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 48
    • 69249089501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 49
    • 69249130672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 50
    • 84869705043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitución Argentina [Const. Arg.] § 90, translated in, supra note 28
    • CONSTITUCÍN ARGENTINA [CONST. ARG] § 90, translated in 1 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE WORLD, supra note 28;
    • 1 Constitutions of the Countries of the World
  • 51
    • 84869711579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constituição Federal [C.F.] art. 14, para. 5 (Braz.), translated in, supra note 28
    • CONSTITUIÇÃO FEDERAL [C.F.] art. 14, para. 5 (Braz.), translated in 3 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE WORLD, supra note 28.
    • 3 Constitutions of The Countries of The World
  • 52
    • 84872512659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • amend. XXII, § 1
    • U.S. CONST. amend. XXII, § 1.
    • U.S. Const.
  • 54
    • 0011088492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Democracy elections and accountability for economic outcomes
    • See, 234-37, Adam Przeworski et al. eds., questioning the link between accountability and democracy
    • See José Antonio Cheibub & Adam Przeworski, Democracy, Elections, and Accountability for Economic Outcomes, in DEMOCRACY, ACCOUNTABILITY, AND REPRESENTATION 222, 230-32, 234-37 (Adam Przeworski et al. eds., 1999) (questioning the link between accountability and democracy);
    • (1999) Democracy, Accountability, and Representation 222 , pp. 230-232
    • Cheibub, J.A.1    Przeworski, A.2
  • 55
    • 79959524014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A better democracy, a better economy
    • Apr./May 1996, at 11, positing that politicians may recognize, but may not act in, the best interests of the citizens, even at the risk of losing an election
    • Adam Przeworski, A Better Democracy, A Better Economy, BOSTON REV., Apr./May 1996, at 11 (positing that politicians may recognize, but may not act in, the best interests of the citizens, even at the risk of losing an election).
    • Boston Rev.
    • Przeworski, A.1
  • 56
    • 69249131460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Linz, supra note 1, at 17
    • Linz, supra note 1, at 17.
  • 57
    • 69249145410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cheibub & Przeworski, supra note 38, at 234
    • Cheibub & Przeworski, supra note 38, at 234.
  • 58
    • 69249083003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 235
    • Id. at 235.
  • 59
    • 69249099884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra subpart II(B)
    • See infra subpart II(B).
  • 60
    • 69249101434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is a large body of literature on legislator term limits in American states, which is relevant for thinking about limits on presidential reelection. For an excellent review of this literature and for an argument about how it can be used to develop and test hypotheses about legislative theories
    • There is a large body of literature on legislator term limits in American states, which is relevant for thinking about limits on presidential reelection. For an excellent review of this literature and for an argument about how it can be used to develop and test hypotheses about legislative theories.
  • 61
    • 69249085095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see, Univ. of Ill. at Springfield, Thank You, Paul Jacob: Term Limits as a Boon to Legislative Scholarship, Presentation at the, Aug. 30, available at
    • see Christopher Z. Mooney, Univ. of Ill. at Springfield, Thank You, Paul Jacob: Term Limits as a Boon to Legislative Scholarship, Presentation at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association (Aug. 30, 2007), available at http://www.igpa.uillinois.edu/system/files/WP152- Mooney%20TermLimits.pdf.
    • (2007) Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association
    • Mooney, C.Z.1
  • 62
    • 21144480405 scopus 로고
    • Presidentialism, multipartism, and democracy: The difficult combination
    • See, e.g., 215-16, arguing that the multiparty system can be the "Achilles' heel" of a president's effectiveness).
    • See, e.g., Scott Mainwaring, Presidentialism, Multipartism, and Democracy: The Difficult Combination, 26 COMP. POL. STUD. 198, 215, 215-16 (1994) (arguing that the multiparty system can be the "Achilles' heel" of a president's effectiveness).
    • (1994) 26 Comp. Pol. Stud. 198 , pp. 215
    • Mainwaring, S.1
  • 63
    • 69249150656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 64
    • 69249140055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 220-22
    • Id. at 220-22.
  • 65
    • 69249145005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 217-18
    • Id. at 217-18.
  • 66
    • 69249086706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 67
    • 33644969195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential coattails and legislative fragmentation
    • See, e.g., concluding from empirical data that the number of presidential candidates influences legislative fragmentation). The following discussion borrows heavily from CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 168-69
    • See, e.g., Matt Golder, Presidential Coattails and Legislative Fragmentation, 50 AM. J. POL. SCI. 34, 41-43 (2006) (concluding from empirical data that the number of presidential candidates influences legislative fragmentation). The following discussion borrows heavily from CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 168-69.
    • (2006) 50 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 34 , pp. 41-43
    • Golder, M.1
  • 68
    • 85044810788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond nightmare and hope: Engineering electoral proportionality in presidential democracies
    • See, observing that the use of single-member districts promotes accountability and strong ties between voters and representatives).
    • See Yen-Tu Su, Beyond Nightmare and Hope: Engineering Electoral Proportionality in Presidential Democracies, 30 J. LEGIS. 205, 240-41 (2004) (observing that the use of single-member districts promotes accountability and strong ties between voters and representatives).
    • (2004) 30 J. Legis. 205 , pp. 240-241
    • Su, Y.-T.1
  • 69
    • 69249085918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 228 ("[T]o restrict the fragmentation of party system, we can decrease the electoral proportionality of legislative elections by imposing a higher electoral threshold.")
    • See id. at 228 ("[T]o restrict the fragmentation of party system, we can decrease the electoral proportionality of legislative elections by imposing a higher electoral threshold.").
  • 70
    • 69249135243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 223 (arguing that imposing a higher threshold of exclusion on the party system can prevent fragmentation)
    • See id. at 223 (arguing that imposing a higher threshold of exclusion on the party system can prevent fragmentation).
  • 71
    • 69249151871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mainwaring, supra note 44, at 225 (arguing that countries could make presidential democracy more viable "by introducing a higher threshold, by reducing district magnitude in proportional systems, or by having concurrent congressional and presidential elections")
    • See Mainwaring, supra note 44, at 225 (arguing that countries could make presidential democracy more viable "by introducing a higher threshold, by reducing district magnitude in proportional systems, or by having concurrent congressional and presidential elections").
  • 72
    • 69249136415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 224-25
    • Id. at 224-25.
  • 73
    • 69249138884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 215-16 (noting that presidents in systems with fewer parties are more likely to enjoy legislative support, which decreases the potential for ideological conflict or immobility of the government)
    • See id. at 215-16 (noting that presidents in systems with fewer parties are more likely to enjoy legislative support, which decreases the potential for ideological conflict or immobility of the government).
  • 74
    • 69249112820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 95-98
    • CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 95-98;
  • 75
    • 0036244093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Minority governments, deadlock situations, and the survival of presidential democracies
    • José Antonio Cheibub, Minority Governments, Deadlock Situations, and the Survival of Presidential Democracies, 35 COMP. POL. STUD. 284, 298-302 (2002);
    • (2002) 35 COMP. POL. STUD. 284 , pp. 298-302
    • Cheibub, J.A.1
  • 76
    • 69249105783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also PRZEWORSKI, ALVAREZ, CHEIBUB & LlMONGI, supra note 5, at 134 (showing that "[p]residential democracies appear particularly vulnerable" when "the largest legislative party controls more than one-third but less than one-half of seats")
    • see also PRZEWORSKI, ALVAREZ, CHEIBUB & LlMONGI, supra note 5, at 134 (showing that "[p]residential democracies appear particularly vulnerable" when "the largest legislative party controls more than one-third but less than one-half of seats").
  • 77
    • 69249145896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 81-83
    • CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 81-83.
  • 78
    • 69249126373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 86-94
    • Id. at 86-94.
  • 79
    • 69249110669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 87-92
    • Id. at 87-92.
  • 81
    • 69249143447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 637
    • Id. at 637.
  • 82
    • 69249084238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 639-41
    • Id. at 639-41.
  • 83
    • 69249139664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 639-40
    • Id. at 639-40.
  • 84
    • 69249114000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 650
    • Id. at 650.
  • 85
    • 77952590505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Instant runoff voting: What Mexico (and Others) could learn
    • Robert Richie, Instant Runoff Voting: What Mexico (and Others) Could Learn, 3 ELECTION L.J. 501, 502 (2004);
    • (2004) 3 Election L.J. 501 , pp. 502
    • Richie, R.1
  • 86
    • 0004080244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, identifying Chile, Columbia, and Ecuador as Latin American nations that use a two-round election system)
    • see also DAVID M. FARRELL, ELECTORAL SYSTEMS: A COMPARATIVE INTRODUCTION 51-52 (2001) (identifying Chile, Columbia, and Ecuador as Latin American nations that use a two-round election system).
    • (2001) Electoral Systems: A Comparative Introduction 51-52
    • Farrell, D.M.1
  • 87
    • 69249149027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FARRELL, supra note 65, at 168
    • FARRELL, supra note 65, at 168.
  • 88
    • 69249117980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Linz, supra note 1, at 21, 21-22 (arguing that two-round elections produce the "dysfunctional consequence[]" of reinforcing party fragmentation rather than encouraging a reduction in the number of parties)
    • See Linz, supra note 1, at 21, 21-22 (arguing that two-round elections produce the "dysfunctional consequence[]" of reinforcing party fragmentation rather than encouraging a reduction in the number of parties).
  • 89
    • 84974284436 scopus 로고
    • The electoral cycle and institutional sources of divided presidential government
    • tbl.A-1
    • Matthew Soberg Shugart, The Electoral Cycle and Institutional Sources of Divided Presidential Government, 89 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 327, 339 tbl.A-1 (1995).
    • (1995) 89 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 327 , pp. 339
    • Shugart, M.S.1
  • 90
    • 69249142422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 91
    • 84872512659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, art. 1, § 2, cl. 1 (requiring a two-year term for representatives)
    • See U.S. CONST., art. 1, § 2, cl. 1 (requiring a two-year term for representatives);
    • U.S. Const.
  • 92
    • 69249125952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. art. I, § 3, cl. 2 (dividing the Senate into thirds, each of which is elected every two years)
    • id. art. I, § 3, cl. 2 (dividing the Senate into thirds, each of which is elected every two years);
  • 93
    • 69249155845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. art. II, § 1, cl. 1 (providing for a four-year presidential term)
    • id. art. II, § 1, cl. 1 (providing for a four-year presidential term).
  • 94
    • 69249108986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Golder, supra note 49, at 40
    • Golder, supra note 49, at 40;
  • 95
    • 69249117981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Shugart, supra note 68, at 330, 330-31 (showing that "the incidence of divided government will be greater" when presidential and legislative elections are nonconcurrent)
    • see also Shugart, supra note 68, at 330, 330-31 (showing that "the incidence of divided government will be greater" when presidential and legislative elections are nonconcurrent)..
  • 96
    • 69249101832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Golder, supra note 49, at 40 (showing this strong coattails effect in concurrent presidential and legislative elections).
    • See Golder, supra note 49, at 40 (showing this strong coattails effect in concurrent presidential and legislative elections).
  • 97
    • 0003843651 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., "Powers are never entirely separate under presidentialism-nor were they intended to be.... [P]residentialism seeks to protect mutual checks, which in turn requires that powers overlap considerably."
    • See, e.g., MATTHEW SOBERG SHUGART & JOHN M. CAREY, PRESIDENTS AND ASSEMBLIES: CONSTITUTIONAL DESIGN AND ELECTORAL DYNAMICS 19 (1992) ("Powers are never entirely separate under presidentialism-nor were they intended to be.... [P]residentialism seeks to protect mutual checks, which in turn requires that powers overlap considerably.").
    • (1992) Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics 19
    • Shugart, M.S.1    Carey, J.M.2
  • 98
    • 69249153616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The following discussion borrows heavily from CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 170-73
    • The following discussion borrows heavily from CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 170-73.
  • 100
    • 69249151872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., id. The majority of Latin American presidential constitutions also mandate a two-thirds majority to override a veto
    • E.g., id. The majority of Latin American presidential constitutions also mandate a two-thirds majority to override a veto.
  • 101
    • 31944433118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential vetoes in Latin American constitutions
    • See, tbl.1, examining the override rule in eighteen Latin American countries).
    • See Eduardo Alemán & Thomas Schwartz, Presidential Vetoes in Latin American Constitutions, 18 J. THEORETICAL POL. 98, 101 tbl.1 (2006) (examining the override rule in eighteen Latin American countries).
    • (2006) 18 J. Theoretical Pol. 98 , pp. 101
    • Alemán, E.1    Schwartz, T.2
  • 104
    • 0001942797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Calling out the tanks or filling out the forms?
    • See generally, John M. Carey & Matthew Soberg Shugart eds., defining, analyzing, and classifying different forms of decree power found in various countries
    • See generally John M. Carey & Matthew Soberg Shugart, Calling Out the Tanks or Filling Out the Forms?, in EXECUTIVE DECREE AUTHORITY 1 (John M. Carey & Matthew Soberg Shugart eds., 1998) (defining, analyzing, and classifying different forms of decree power found in various countries).
    • (1998) Executive Decree Authority 1
    • Carey, J.M.1    Shugart, M.S.2
  • 105
    • 0040520597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Search of the administrative president: Presidential "Decree" powers and policy implementation in the United States
    • supra note 78, at 254, 260-61
    • Brian R. Sala, In Search of the Administrative President: Presidential "Decree" Powers and Policy Implementation in the United States, in EXECUTIVE DECREE AUTHORITY, supra note 78, at 254, 260-61.
    • Executive Decree Authority
    • Brian R. Sala1
  • 106
    • 0007073767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The pen is mightier than the congress: Presidential decree power in Brazil
    • Such vague special circumstances include "relevance," "urgency," and "economic or financial matters, when so required by the national interest." See, e.g., supra note 78, at 197, 202, discussing consideration of "relevance" and "urgency" in Brazil
    • Such vague special circumstances include "relevance," "urgency," and "economic or financial matters, when so required by the national interest." See, e.g., Timothy J. Power, The Pen Is Mightier than the Congress: Presidential Decree Power in Brazil, in EXECUTIVE DECREE AUTHORITY, supra note 78, at 197, 202 (discussing consideration of "relevance" and "urgency" in Brazil);
    • Executive Decree Authority
    • Power, T.J.1
  • 107
    • 0006286778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential usurpation or congressional preference?: The evolution of executive decree authority in Peru
    • supra note 78, at 104, 116 (discussing consideration of "economic or financial matters, when so required by the national interest" in Peru). But decree powers under "special" circumstances are not to be confused with constitutional emergency powers, which allow for the temporary suspension of some constitutional provisions in specified circumstances
    • Gregory Schmidt, Presidential Usurpation or Congressional Preference?: The Evolution of Executive Decree Authority in Peru, in EXECUTIVE DECREE AUTHORITY, supra note 78, at 104, 116 (discussing consideration of "economic or financial matters, when so required by the national interest" in Peru). But decree powers under "special" circumstances are not to be confused with constitutional emergency powers, which allow for the temporary suspension of some constitutional provisions in specified circumstances.
    • Executive Decree Authority
    • Schmidt, G.1
  • 108
    • 0005343999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When the president governs alone: The decretazo in Argentina, 1989-93
    • See, supra note 78, at 33, 34, distinguishing "delegated decree authority" from "emergency powers"
    • See Delia Ferreira Rubio & Matteo Goretti, When the President Governs Alone: The Decretazo in Argentina, 1989-93, in EXECUTIVE DECREE AUTHORITY, supra note 78, at 33, 34 (distinguishing "delegated decree authority" from "emergency powers").
    • Executive Decree Authority
    • Rubio, D.F.1    Goretti, M.2
  • 109
    • 69249107090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carey & Shugart, supra note 78, at 9-12, 10 tbl.1.1, reporting that of the eleven constitutions examined, Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Columbia, Italy, Peru, and Russia have constitutional provisions allowing certain presidential decrees to go into effect immediately
    • See Carey & Shugart, supra note 78, at 9-12, 10 tbl.1.1 (reporting that of the eleven constitutions examined, Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Columbia, Italy, Peru, and Russia have constitutional provisions allowing certain presidential decrees to go into effect immediately).
  • 110
    • 69249154860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (reporting that of the eleven constitutions examined, Ecuador and France have constitutional provisions providing for a time lapse after issuance of certain presidential decrees so that the legislature may take action if desired)
    • See id. (reporting that of the eleven constitutions examined, Ecuador and France have constitutional provisions providing for a time lapse after issuance of certain presidential decrees so that the legislature may take action if desired).
  • 111
    • 69249156650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (reporting that of the eleven constitutions examined, Chile, Columbia, Ecuador, France, Peru, and Russia have constitutional provisions allowing certain presidential decrees to automatically become law without action on the part of the legislature)
    • See id. (reporting that of the eleven constitutions examined, Chile, Columbia, Ecuador, France, Peru, and Russia have constitutional provisions allowing certain presidential decrees to automatically become law without action on the part of the legislature).
  • 112
    • 69249084239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (reporting that of the eleven constitutions examined, Argentina, Brazil, Columbia, France, and Italy have constitutional provisions providing that certain presidential decrees will lapse without action on the part of the legislature)
    • See id. (reporting that of the eleven constitutions examined, Argentina, Brazil, Columbia, France, and Italy have constitutional provisions providing that certain presidential decrees will lapse without action on the part of the legislature).
  • 113
    • 69249142017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., C.F. art. 62 (Braz.) ("In relevant and urgent cases, the President of the Republic may adopt provisional measures with the force of law; such measures shall be submitted immediately to the National Congress."
    • E.g., C.F. art. 62 (Braz.) ("In relevant and urgent cases, the President of the Republic may adopt provisional measures with the force of law; such measures shall be submitted immediately to the National Congress.");
  • 114
    • 84869711579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONSTITUCIÓN POLÍTICA DE LA REPUBLICA DE CHILE [CONST. CHILE] art. 74, translated in, supra note 28 (allowing the President to invoke "the urgency of a project" and thus speed the legislative process
    • CONSTITUCIÓN POLÍTICA DE LA REPUBLICA DE CHILE [CONST. CHILE] art. 74, translated in 4 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE WORLD, supra note 28 (allowing the President to invoke "the urgency of a project" and thus speed the legislative process);
    • 4 Constitutions of The Countries of The World
  • 115
    • 69249084237 scopus 로고
    • [IR. CONST.], art. 24 translated in, supra note 28, allowing the President the opportunity to determine whether a bill is "urgent and immediately necessary for the preservation of the public peace and security"
    • BUNREACHT NA HÉIREANN, 1937 [IR. CONST.], art. 24 translated in 9 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE World, supra note 28 (allowing the President the opportunity to determine whether a bill is "urgent and immediately necessary for the preservation of the public peace and security").
    • (1937) 9 Constitutions of The Countries of The World
    • Héireann, B.N.1
  • 116
    • 69249093196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., C.F. art. 62 (requiring congressional action within sixty days of the President's adoption of provisional measures
    • E.g., C.F. art. 62 (requiring congressional action within sixty days of the President's adoption of provisional measures);
  • 117
    • 69249132288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • mandating that the National Congress respond within thirty days to any bill which the President has deemed urgent
    • CONST. CHILE art. 74 (mandating that the National Congress respond within thirty days to any bill which the President has deemed urgent);
    • Const. Chile Art. 74
  • 118
    • 69249099090 scopus 로고
    • art. 24 (permitting the time frame for considering an urgent bill to be abridged but allowing the specific length of time to be determined by resolution)
    • Ir. CONST., 1937, art. 24 (permitting the time frame for considering an urgent bill to be abridged but allowing the specific length of time to be determined by resolution).
    • (1937) Ir. Const.
  • 119
    • 84878077660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, § 1 (granting all legislative powers to the Senate and House of Representatives)
    • See U.S. CONST, art. 1, § 1 (granting all legislative powers to the Senate and House of Representatives).
    • U.S. Const. Art. 1
  • 120
    • 69249150655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carey & Shugart, supra note 78, at 6 (describing legislative-agenda powers of presidents in various regimes)
    • See Carey & Shugart, supra note 78, at 6 (describing legislative-agenda powers of presidents in various regimes).
  • 121
    • 69249113214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (describing the response of Chile's legislature to the executive's submission of appropriations legislation)
    • See id. (describing the response of Chile's legislature to the executive's submission of appropriations legislation).
  • 122
    • 69249126372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g. (concluding that despite an "exaggerated" Chilean presidency, "the success of the Aylwin and Frei administrations demonstrates that presidentialism can, given certain circumstances, work well in Chile")
    • See, e.g., PETER SIAVELIS, THE PRESIDENT AND CONGRESS IN POSTAUTHORITARIAN CHILE: INSTITUTIONAL CONSTRAINTS TO DEMOCRATIC CONSOLIDATION 191 (2000) (concluding that despite an "exaggerated" Chilean presidency, "the success of the Aylwin and Frei administrations demonstrates that presidentialism can, given certain circumstances, work well in Chile");
    • (2000) The President and Congress in Postauthoritarian Chile: Institutional Constraints to Democratic Consolidation 191
    • Siavelis, P.1
  • 123
    • 69249095544 scopus 로고
    • Mudança constitutional, desempenho do legislativo e consolidação institutional [Constitutional change, legislative performance and institutional consolidation
    • 29 REVISTA BRASILEIRA DE CIÊNCIAS SOCIAS 175, (Braz.), translated in, [hereinafter Figueiredo & Limongi, Constitutional Change] (concluding that the 1988 Brazilian Constitution's maintenance of the President's broad legislative powers are justified because of an otherwise obstructive legislature)
    • Argelina Cheibub Figueiredo & Fernando Limongi, Mudança constitutional, desempenho do legislativo e consolidação institutional [Constitutional Change, Legislative Performance and Institutional Consolidation], 29 REVISTA BRASILEIRA DE CIÊNCIAS SOCIAS 175 (1995) (Braz.), translated in 2000 BRAZILIAN REV. SOC. SCI. (SPECIAL ISSUE) 71, 91-92 [hereinafter Figueiredo & Limongi, Constitutional Change] (concluding that the 1988 Brazilian Constitution's maintenance of the President's broad legislative powers are justified because of an otherwise obstructive legislature);
    • (1995) 2000 Brazilian Rev. Soc. Sci. (Special Issue) 71 , pp. 91-92
    • Figueiredo, A.C.1    Limongi, F.2
  • 124
    • 0041125571 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential power, legislative organization, and party behavior in Brazil
    • 155, 158, [hereinafter Figueiredo & Limongi, Presidential Power] (finding that between 1989 and 1997, bills introduced by Brazilian presidents were successfully enacted 86% of the time largely through presidential engagement with the legislature)
    • Argelina Cheibub Figueiredo & Fernando Limongi, Presidential Power, Legislative Organization, and Party Behavior in Brazil, 32 COMP. POL. 151, 155, 158 (2000) [hereinafter Figueiredo & Limongi, Presidential Power] (finding that between 1989 and 1997, bills introduced by Brazilian presidents were successfully enacted 86% of the time largely through presidential engagement with the legislature);
    • (2000) 32 Comp. Pol. 151
    • Figueiredo, A.C.1    Limongi, F.2
  • 125
    • 1642497464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Agenda power in Brazil's câmara dos deputados, 1989-98
    • contending that President Cardoso's successful creation of an "agenda cartel" in the Brazilian Congress demonstrates that "there is no reason to suppose that he was outside the normal range of success" compared to premiers in foreign parliamentary systems
    • Octavio Amorim Neto, Gary W. Cox & Mathew D. McCubbins, Agenda Power in Brazil's Câmara dos Deputados, 1989-98, 55 WORLD POL. 550, 574 (2003) (contending that President Cardoso's successful creation of an "agenda cartel" in the Brazilian Congress demonstrates that "there is no reason to suppose that he was outside the normal range of success" compared to premiers in foreign parliamentary systems).
    • (2003) 55 World Pol. 550 , pp. 574
    • Neto, O.A.1    Cox, G.W.2    McCubbins, M.D.3
  • 126
    • 69249157881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SLAVELIS, supra note 90, at 23, 151 (observing that the Chilean executive's control of the legislative agenda allows it to be "quite successful in seeing its proposals become laws of the republic" but also lamenting that such agenda control "limits the effectiveness of the legislature as a deliberative body")
    • See SLAVELIS, supra note 90, at 23, 151 (observing that the Chilean executive's control of the legislative agenda allows it to be "quite successful in seeing its proposals become laws of the republic" but also lamenting that such agenda control "limits the effectiveness of the legislature as a deliberative body");
  • 127
    • 0242308502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 90, at 151-52 (arguing that Brazilian presidents' "considerable degree of success in enacting their legislative agenda" is due to "[t]he extensive legislative powers of the president, " which " allow the executive both to control the legislative agenda and to restrict the legislature's 'transformative power'")
    • Figueiredo & Limongi, Presidential Power, supra note 90, at 151-52 (arguing that Brazilian presidents' "considerable degree of success in enacting their legislative agenda" is due to "[t]he extensive legislative powers of the president," which "allow the executive both to control the legislative agenda and to restrict the legislature's 'transformative power'").
    • Presidential Power
    • Figueiredo1    Limongi2
  • 128
    • 85044915328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strong federalism, constraints on the central government, and economic reform in Brazil
    • Edward L. Gibson ed.
    • David J. Samuels & Scott Mainwaring, Strong Federalism, Constraints on the Central Government, and Economic Reform in Brazil, in FEDERALISM AND DEMOCRACY IN LATIN AMERICA 85, 94-95 (Edward L. Gibson ed., 2004).
    • (2004) Federalism and Democracy in Latin America 85 , pp. 94-95
    • Samuels, D.J.1    Mainwaring, S.2
  • 129
    • 4043111088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, noting that Brazil's large economy is highly economically diverse "with huge variations in development level across industries"
    • See Ben GOERTZEl & STEPHAN VLADIMIR BUGAJ, THE PATH TO POSTHUMANITY 379 (2006) (noting that Brazil's large economy is highly economically diverse "with huge variations in development level across industries").
    • (2006) The Path to Posthumanity 379
    • Goertzel, B.1    Bugaj, S.V.2
  • 130
  • 131
    • 0007319324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • discussing the fragility of the Brazilian political party structure and their "weak roots in society"
    • RIORDAN ROETT, BRAZIL: POLITICS IN A PATRIMONIAL SOCIETY 33 (1999) (discussing the fragility of the Brazilian political party structure and their "weak roots in society").
    • (1999) Brazil: Politics in a Patrimonial Society 33
    • Roett, R.1
  • 132
    • 69249152756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Samuels & Mainwaring, supra note 92, at 98 ("An open-list proportional representation system in which states serve as electoral districts forces politicians to compete against members of their own party as well as candidates from other parties for seats.")
    • See Samuels & Mainwaring, supra note 92, at 98 ("An open-list proportional representation system in which states serve as electoral districts forces politicians to compete against members of their own party as well as candidates from other parties for seats.").
  • 133
    • 69249144242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 97 ("In the absence of strong national party organizations and of a national legislature that controls the purse strings, federal deputies rely on state governors to provide political sustenance.")
    • See id. at 97 ("In the absence of strong national party organizations and of a national legislature that controls the purse strings, federal deputies rely on state governors to provide political sustenance.").
  • 134
    • 69249145895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Figueiredo & Limongi, Presidential Power, supra note 90, at 158 (observing that Brazilian presidents have passed their agendas "by building government coalitions through the distribution of ministries to political parties and thereby securing the votes they needed in congress")
    • See Figueiredo & Limongi, Presidential Power, supra note 90, at 158 (observing that Brazilian presidents have passed their agendas "by building government coalitions through the distribution of ministries to political parties and thereby securing the votes they needed in congress")
  • 135
    • 69249132286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The puzzle of party discipline in Brazil
    • 1999, C.F. arts. 66, 84, 64, 61. The legislative success of the government is also aided by the fact that Congress is highly centralized in its organization, with party leaders yielding enough power to bypass the work of permanent committees and set the agenda for the floor. This organization, of course, is not a constitutional feature and resulted from a decision of the assembly itself. However, it is essential for allowing the President to form stable legislative coalitions with a relatively small number of political parties, despite all the forces that conspire against such stability, (reviewing ARGELINA CHEIBUB FlGUEIREDO & FERNANDO LlMONGI NETO, EXECUTIVO E LEGISLATIVO NA NOVA ORDEM CONSTITUCIONAL, THE EXECUTIVE AND LEGISLATIVE BRANCHES IN THE NEW CONSTITUTIONAL ORDER
    • C.F. arts. 66, 84, 64, 61. The legislative success of the government is also aided by the fact that Congress is highly centralized in its organization, with party leaders yielding enough power to bypass the work of permanent committees and set the agenda for the floor. This organization, of course, is not a constitutional feature and resulted from a decision of the assembly itself. However, it is essential for allowing the President to form stable legislative coalitions with a relatively small number of political parties, despite all the forces that conspire against such stability. Octavio Amorim Neto, The Puzzle of Party Discipline in Brazil, 44 LATIN AM. POL. & SOC'Y 127, 132 (2002) (reviewing ARGELINA CHEIBUB FlGUEIREDO & FERNANDO LlMONGI NETO, EXECUTIVO E LEGISLATIVO NA NOVA ORDEM CONSTITUCIONAL [THE EXECUTIVE AND LEGISLATIVE BRANCHES IN THE NEW CONSTITUTIONAL ORDER] 55-67 (1999));
    • (2002) 44 Latin Am. Pol. & Soc'y 127 , vol.132 , pp. 55-67
    • Neto, O.A.1
  • 136
    • 0242308502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, supra note 90, 159-61, showing that in Brazil the tight control of party leaders over other legislators allows the President to influence the legislative agenda
    • see also Figueiredo & Limongi, Presidential Power, supra note 90, 159-61 (showing that in Brazil the tight control of party leaders over other legislators allows the President to influence the legislative agenda);
    • Presidential Power
    • Figueiredo1    Limongi2
  • 137
    • 33745479231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compared to what? Assessing Brazilian political institutions
    • cf., concluding that there is "constant negotiation" between the President and the multiparty Congress, which "is of utmost importance for democratic legitimacy"
    • cf. Leslie Elliott Armijo et al., Compared to What? Assessing Brazilian Political Institutions, 39 COMP. POL. STUD. 759, 768 (2006) (concluding that there is "constant negotiation" between the President and the multiparty Congress, which "is of utmost importance for democratic legitimacy").
    • (2006) 39 Comp. Pol. Stud. 759 , pp. 768
    • Armijo, L.E.1
  • 138
    • 0242308502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally, supra note 90, arguing that presidential legislative powers provide presidents with a mechanism to encourage legislative branch cooperation
    • See generally Figueiredo & Limongi, Presidential Power, supra note 90 (arguing that presidential legislative powers provide presidents with a mechanism to encourage legislative branch cooperation).
    • Presidential Power
    • Figueiredo1    Limongi2
  • 139
    • 69249113604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 167, contending that because "the executive-legislative bargaining process is structured along party lines," it is therefore "rational for each representative to act as a party member and to support the party leaders"
    • See id. at 167 (contending that because "the executive-legislative bargaining process is structured along party lines," it is therefore "rational for each representative to act as a party member and to support the party leaders").
  • 140
    • 69249124718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 168, concluding that the legislature's acceptance of the President's proposals "prevails, because centralized control over the agenda has profound effects on party discipline"
    • See id. at 168 (concluding that the legislature's acceptance of the President's proposals "prevails, because centralized control over the agenda has profound effects on party discipline").
  • 141
    • 69249120031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Amorim Neto, Cox & McCubbins, supra note 90, at 573-74
    • Amorim Neto, Cox & McCubbins, supra note 90, at 573-74.
  • 142
    • 27744433426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under what conditions do presidents resort to decree power? Theory and evidence from the Brazilian case
    • See, e.g., discussing the reasons presidents may choose to use the "extraordinary" decree power rather than "ordinary mechanisms of legislative initiative").
    • See, e.g., Carlos Pereira, Timothy J. Power & Lucio Renno, Under What Conditions Do Presidents Resort to Decree Power? Theory and Evidence from the Brazilian Case, 67 J. POL. 178, 180 (2006) (discussing the reasons presidents may choose to use the "extraordinary" decree power rather than "ordinary mechanisms of legislative initiative").
    • (2006) 67 J. Pol. 178 , pp. 180
    • Pereira, C.1    Power, T.J.2    Renno, L.3
  • 143
    • 69249129839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 144
    • 69249089500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 145
    • 69249083399 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (stipulating that the unilateral perspective "views executive orders or decrees as instruments that the executive uses to bypass adversarial or noncooperative legislative bodies")
    • See id. (stipulating that the unilateral perspective "views executive orders or decrees as instruments that the executive uses to bypass adversarial or noncooperative legislative bodies").
  • 146
    • 69249104755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 186 (suggesting that when "the presidential cabinet's political 'coverage' in Congress" and the degree of "pro-presidential parties' share of seats within the government's floor voting coalition" are high, there is likely to be a strong and "satisfied coalition arrayed behind the president")
    • See id. at 186 (suggesting that when "the presidential cabinet's political 'coverage' in Congress" and the degree of "pro-presidential parties' share of seats within the government's floor voting coalition" are high, there is likely to be a strong and "satisfied coalition arrayed behind the president").
  • 147
    • 69249087099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., concluding from statistical analysis of Latin American governments that presidents who exchange ministerial posts to gain a cooperative legislature usually disproportionately select partisan members
    • E.g., OCTAVIO AMORIM NETO, PRESIDENCIALISMO E GOVERNABILIDADE NAS AMÉRICAS 41 (2006) (concluding from statistical analysis of Latin American governments that presidents who exchange ministerial posts to gain a cooperative legislature usually disproportionately select partisan members).
    • (2006) Presidencialismo e Governabilidade Nas Américas 41
    • Neto, O.A.1
  • 148
    • 69249083398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pereira, Power & Rennó, supra note 103, at 181
    • Pereira, Power & Rennó, supra note 103, at 181.
  • 149
    • 0004117035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutional design and executive decree
    • supra note 78, at 274, 295
    • John M. Carey & Matthew Soberg Shugart, Institutional Design and Executive Decree, in Executive Decree Authority, supra note 78, at 274, 295.
    • Executive Decree Authority
    • Carey, J.M.1    Shugart, M.S.2
  • 150
    • 69249157486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pereira Power & Rennó, supra note 103, at 195 (showing that the data relating to the first term of Brazilian President Fernando Henrique Cardoso is best explained by a delegation theory)
    • See Pereira, Power & Rennó, supra note 103, at 195 (showing that the data relating to the first term of Brazilian President Fernando Henrique Cardoso is best explained by a delegation theory).
  • 151
    • 69249140446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Amorim Neto, Cox & McCubbins, supra note 90, at 560 (arguing that the presidential decrees in Brazil are best thought of as "powerful policy-making instruments]... [that] allow the executive to unilaterally change the status quo")
    • See Amorim Neto, Cox & McCubbins, supra note 90, at 560 (arguing that the presidential decrees in Brazil are best thought of as "powerful policy-making instruments]... [that] allow the executive to unilaterally change the status quo").
  • 152
    • 69249105133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., demonstrating that the institutional constraints on the decree power of the President in the French system greatly influence the ultimate legislation channel
    • See, e.g., JOHN D. HUBER, RATIONALIZING PARLIAMENT 26-27 (1996) (demonstrating that the institutional constraints on the decree power of the President in the French system greatly influence the ultimate legislation channel).
    • (1996) Rationalizing Parliament 26-27
    • Huber, J.D.1
  • 153
    • 14644438566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential diplomacy and the institutional underpinnings of MERCOSUR: An empirical examination
    • See, e.g., pointing out that the intervention of the Brazilian President, via the decree power, in the Brazil-Argentina sugar dispute of 2000 was successful because it was backed by institutional capabilities within the Brazilian system
    • See, e.g., Andrés Malamud, Presidential Diplomacy and the Institutional Underpinnings of MERCOSUR: An Empirical Examination, LATIN AM. RES. REV. 138, 153 (2005) (pointing out that the intervention of the Brazilian President, via the decree power, in the Brazil-Argentina sugar dispute of 2000 was successful because it was backed by institutional capabilities within the Brazilian system).
    • (2005) Latin Am. Res. Rev. 138 , pp. 153
    • Malamud, A.1
  • 154
    • 69249118389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that the institutional perspective, which does not necessarily see a conflict between the executive and the legislature in the former's use of decrees, is often interpreted as a variant of delegation theory. See Pereira, Power & Renno, supra note 103, at 181 (espousing a delegation theory in which "[executive orders also satisfy the preferences of legislators, because legislators are the actors who delegate this power and who have ample opportunity to overturn ... any undesirable presidential policies"). This, however, is not correct. Delegation theory sees the legislature as the principal and the executive as the agent to whom its powers are transferred
    • Note that the institutional perspective, which does not necessarily see a conflict between the executive and the legislature in the former's use of decrees, is often interpreted as a variant of delegation theory. See Pereira, Power & Renno, supra note 103, at 181 (espousing a delegation theory in which "[executive orders also satisfy the preferences of legislators, because legislators are the actors who delegate this power and who have ample opportunity to overturn ... any undesirable presidential policies"). This, however, is not correct. Delegation theory sees the legislature as the principal and the executive as the agent to whom its powers are transferred.
  • 155
    • 69249128484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (noting that many other authors have grounded the delegation theory in principal-agent doctrines). The institutional perspective does not see the two bodies in such a hierarchical relationship; rather, if there is a hierarchy, it is one that institutionally favors the executive only in that it gives that body the ability to lead the process of policy formation
    • See id. (noting that many other authors have grounded the delegation theory in principal-agent doctrines). The institutional perspective does not see the two bodies in such a hierarchical relationship; rather, if there is a hierarchy, it is one that institutionally favors the executive only in that it gives that body the ability to lead the process of policy formation.
  • 156
    • 69249160665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Huber, supra note 113, at 184, 184-188 (analyzing why, "in parliamentary democracies, the cabinet plays a more important role than the parliament in crafting the policies of the state")
    • See HUBER, supra note 113, at 184, 184-188 (analyzing why, "in parliamentary democracies, the cabinet plays a more important role than the parliament in crafting the policies of the state").
  • 157
    • 69249156234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., HUBER, supra note 113, at 31 (summarizing the French government's authority to implement its budget by decree if the legislature does not vote on a budget within the specified time frame)
    • See, e.g., HUBER, supra note 113, at 31 (summarizing the French government's authority to implement its budget by decree if the legislature does not vote on a budget within the specified time frame).
  • 158
    • 69249085093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 29-30 (cataloging these trends and the inability of conventional explanations of executive power to account for them)
    • See id. at 29-30 (cataloging these trends and the inability of conventional explanations of executive power to account for them).
  • 159
    • 69249157069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pereira, Power & Rennó, supra note 103, at 188 (stating that "a study of executive decree authority [from a political perspective]... must provide controls for the very real pressures of macroeconomic management " since presidents regularly use decrees, often by surprise, to deal with "grave socioeconomic crises")
    • See Pereira, Power & Rennó, supra note 103, at 188 (stating that "a study of executive decree authority [from a political perspective]... must provide controls for the very real pressures of macroeconomic management" since presidents regularly use decrees, often by surprise, to deal with "grave socioeconomic crises").
  • 160
    • 0001711715 scopus 로고
    • Executive power and policy-making patterns in France: Gauging the impact of fifth republic institutions
    • See, e.g., (noting how the French executive has used its emergency powers and decrees to create laws that were never voted on by Parliament)
    • See, e.g., John Keeler, Executive Power and Policy-Making Patterns in France: Gauging the Impact of Fifth Republic Institutions, 16 W. EUR. POL. 518, 532 (1993) (noting how the French executive has used its emergency powers and decrees to create laws that were never voted on by Parliament).
    • (1993) 16 W. Eur. Pol. 518 , pp. 532
    • Keeler, J.1
  • 161
    • 69249091146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is, however, a sizeable specific literature on which this perspective is based. I refer to works revolving around the notions of a strong executive and a "rationalized" parliament, which became current in post-WWII Europe and which saw their epitome in the emergence of the French Fifth Republic. These systems sought to create
    • There is, however, a sizeable specific literature on which this perspective is based. I refer to works revolving around the notions of a strong executive and a "rationalized" parliament, which became current in post-WWII Europe and which saw their epitome in the emergence of the French Fifth Republic. These systems sought to create "effective government authority" by structuring executive-legislative relations in such a way as to strengthen the former and to centralize and streamline the latter.
    • "Effective Government Authority" by Structuring Executive-legislative Relations in Such a way as to Strengthen the Former and to Centralize and Streamline the Latter
  • 162
    • 69249146323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HUBER, supra note 113, at 1-2 (illustrating the Fifth Republic's dramatic restriction of institutional arrangements between the French executive and legislature); Keeler, supra note 119, at 520-28 (explaining the Fifth Republic's constitutional articles that allow for the executive to control legislation). As some of the work done on these structures has demonstrated, they did not imply dominance of the executive
    • See HUBER, supra note 113, at 1-2 (illustrating the Fifth Republic's dramatic restriction of institutional arrangements between the French executive and legislature); Keeler, supra note 119, at 520-28 (explaining the Fifth Republic's constitutional articles that allow for the executive to control legislation). As some of the work done on these structures has demonstrated, they did not imply dominance of the executive.
  • 163
    • 69249145004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HUBER, supra note 113, at 23-24 (dispelling the notion that French institutional arrangements ensure presidential supremacy and parliamentary impotence)
    • See HUBER, supra note 113, at 23-24 (dispelling the notion that French institutional arrangements ensure presidential supremacy and parliamentary impotence).
  • 164
    • 2442520584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Government capacities and policy making by decree in Latin America: The cases of Brazil and Argentina
    • See, e.g., Pereira, Power & Rennó, supra note 103, at 182 (arguing that the decree power is correlated to the political environment by noting that the constitutional powers in Brazil between 1988 and 1998 were constant, while the degree of presidential political support was quite volatile). Decree rules in Brazil were changed in 2001 in ways that matter for understanding their usage. See, (explaining that a 2001 amendment to the Brazilian Constitution prohibits the President from reissuing a provisional measure whose term for approval has expired)
    • See, e.g., Pereira, Power & Renń, supra note 103, at 182 (arguing that the decree power is correlated to the political environment by noting that the constitutional powers in Brazil between 1988 and 1998 were constant, while the degree of presidential political support was quite volatile). Decree rules in Brazil were changed in 2001 in ways that matter for understanding their usage. See Gabriel L. Negretto, Government Capacities and Policy Making by Decree in Latin America: The Cases of Brazil and Argentina, 37 COMP. POL. STUD. 531, 544 (2004) (explaining that a 2001 amendment to the Brazilian Constitution prohibits the President from reissuing a provisional measure whose term for approval has expired).
    • (2004) 37 Comp. Pol. Stud. 531 , pp. 544
    • Negretto, G.L.1
  • 165
    • 69249091535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pereira, Power & Rennó, supra note 103, at 188-189 (asserting that certain contextual factors such as presidential popularity and congressional support-factors which vary over time and among administrations-help explain why decrees have been used at such varying rates)
    • See Pereira, Power & Rennó, supra note 103, at 188-189 (asserting that certain contextual factors such as presidential popularity and congressional support-factors which vary over time and among administrations-help explain why decrees have been used at such varying rates).
  • 166
    • 69249087501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We have yet to complete our research so it is not yet available, but the following paragraph reflects what we expect it will show
    • We have yet to complete our research so it is not yet available, but the following paragraph reflects what we expect it will show.
  • 167
    • 0141613987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legislative powers, veto players, and the emergence of delegative democracy: A comparison of presidentialism in the Philippines and South Korea
    • See, Autumn at 68, 93 (urging scholars to analyze the presidentialism of any particular system within the institutional architecture of the constitution and the national party system)
    • See Aurel Croissant, Legislative Powers, Veto Players, and the Emergence of Delegative Democracy: A Comparison of Presidentialism in the Philippines and South Korea, Democratization, Autumn 2003, at 68, 93 (urging scholars to analyze the presidentialism of any particular system within the institutional architecture of the constitution and the national party system).
    • (2003) Democratization
    • Croissant, A.1
  • 168
    • 55749110940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutions and democratic performance in semi-presidential democracies
    • José A. Cheibub & Svitlana Chemykh, Constitutions and Democratic Performance in Semi-presidential Democracies, 9 JAPANESE J. POL. SCI. 269, 273 (2008).
    • (2008) 9 Japanese J. Pol. Sci. 269 , pp. 273
    • Cheibub, J.A.1    Chemykh, S.2
  • 169
    • 69249087098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. at 287-91 (conducting statistical analyses aimed at evaluating the correlation between governmental stability and particular combinations of presidential powers)
    • See, e.g., id. at 287-91 (conducting statistical analyses aimed at evaluating the correlation between governmental stability and particular combinations of presidential powers).
  • 170
    • 69249112017 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., 105, 116, (classifying the United States, Brazil, and the Philippines as presidential; classifying Italy, Germany, and Denmark as parliamentary; and classifying France and Portugal (1976-1982) as semi-presidential)
    • See, e.g., GIOVANNI SARTORI, COMPARATIVE CONSTITUTIONAL ENGINEERING: AN INQUIRY INTO STRUCTURES, INCENTIVES AND OUTCOMES 86, 92, 105, 116, 131-32 (1994) (classifying the United States, Brazil, and the Philippines as presidential; classifying Italy, Germany, and Denmark as parliamentary; and classifying France and Portugal (1976-1982) as semi-presidential);
    • (1994) Comparative Constitutional Engineering: An Inquiry into Structures, Incentives and Outcomes 86 , Issue.92 , pp. 131-132
    • Sartori, G.1
  • 171
    • 69249134407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Skach, supra note 20, at 93 (noting that Ukraine adopted semi-presidentialism as its form of government)
    • Skach, supra note 20, at 93 (noting that Ukraine adopted semi-presidentialism as its form of government).
  • 172
    • 77956452777 scopus 로고
    • Germany 1948-1978: Evolution of the bonn republic
    • See, (stating that the German presidency is a "largely ceremonial position")
    • See Tony Burkett, Germany 1948-1978: Evolution of the Bonn Republic, 32 PARLIAMENTARY AFF. 176, 185 (1978) (stating that the German presidency is a "largely ceremonial position");
    • (1978) 32 Parliamentary Aff. 176 , pp. 185
    • Burkett, T.1
  • 173
    • 84921038477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Denmark: Delegation and accountability in minority situations
    • Kaare Strøm et al. eds., characterizing the Danish monarch's powers as ceremonial not political)
    • Erik Damgaard, Denmark: Delegation and Accountability in Minority Situations, in DELEGATION AND ACCOUNTABILITY IN PARLIAMENTARY DEMOCRACIES 281 (Kaare Strøm et al. eds., 2006) (characterizing the Danish monarch's powers as ceremonial not political);
    • (2006) Delegation and accountability in Parliamentary Democracies 281
    • Damgaard, E.1
  • 174
    • 84887714992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The stumbling block: Freedom, rationality, and legal scholarship
    • remarking that the Italian presidential office is formalistic with minimal effective power
    • Jeanne L. Schroeder, The Stumbling Block: Freedom, Rationality, and Legal Scholarship, 44 WM. & MARY L. REV. 263, 323-24 n.237 (2002) (remarking that the Italian presidential office is formalistic with minimal effective power).
    • (2002) 44 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 263 , Issue.237 , pp. 323-324
    • Schroeder, J.L.1
  • 175
    • 69249149428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SARTORI, supra note 127, at 92 (listing Brazil and the Philippines as countries that are both modeled on the U.S. "prototype" with an executive that is neither appointed nor dismissed by parliamentary vote)
    • See SARTORI, supra note 127, at 92 (listing Brazil and the Philippines as countries that are both modeled on the U.S. "prototype" with an executive that is neither appointed nor dismissed by parliamentary vote).
  • 176
    • 69249124331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 177
    • 69249084681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 43 (listing France, Portugal, and Ukraine as having a mixed system)
    • See CHEIBUB, supra note 22, at 43 (listing France, Portugal, and Ukraine as having a mixed system);
  • 178
    • 69249103547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SARTORI, supra note 127, at 131-32 (listing France and Portugal (from 1976 to 1982) as mixed, semi-presidential systems)
    • SARTORI, supra note 127, at 131-32 (listing France and Portugal (from 1976 to 1982) as mixed, semi-presidential systems).
  • 179
    • 69249133579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra subparts II(A)-(B).
    • See supra subparts II(A)-(B).
  • 180
    • 69249088305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., (noting that Germany's Federal President is "head of state and moral leader," elected by "a federal convention consisting of the members of the upper house of the legislature and an equal number of members elected by the state legislatures")
    • See, e.g., Robert L. Maddex, CONSTITUTIONS OF THE WORLD 170 (3d ed. 2008) (noting that Germany's Federal President is "head of state and moral leader," elected by "a federal convention consisting of the members of the upper house of the legislature and an equal number of members elected by the state legislatures");
    • (2008) Constitutions of the World 170, 3d Ed.
    • Maddex, R.L.1
  • 181
    • 69249098042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 317 (noting that New Zealand recognizes England's monarch as "the sovereign in right of New Zealand" but also noting that she "acts through an appointed representative, the governor-general," who is "commander in chief of the armed forces, but in title only")
    • id. at 317 (noting that New Zealand recognizes England's monarch as "the sovereign in right of New Zealand" but also noting that she "acts through an appointed representative, the governor-general," who is "commander in chief of the armed forces, but in title only").
  • 182
    • 69249101831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., §§7, 13 (providing for direct election of the Australian Senate, for six-year terms, to be elected on a staggered schedule every three years)
    • See, e.g., AUSTL. CONST. §§7, 13 (providing for direct election of the Australian Senate, for six-year terms, to be elected on a staggered schedule every three years);
    • Austl. Const.
  • 183
    • 69249131459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DANMARKS RLGES GRUNDLOV [DR GRUNDLOV] [Constitution] §§ 29, 32 (Den.), translated in, supra note 28 (ordaining that any Danish citizen may vote for Members of Parliament, whose terms expire after four years)
    • DANMARKS RLGES GRUNDLOV [DR GRUNDLOV] [Constitution] §§ 29, 32 (Den.), translated in 5 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE WORLD, supra note 28 (ordaining that any Danish citizen may vote for Members of Parliament, whose terms expire after four years);
    • 5 Constitutions of The Countries of The World
  • 184
    • 84869711579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • COSTITUZIONE [COST.] arts. 55-58, 60-61 (Italy), translated in, supra note 28 (dividing Italy's Parliament into two houses, permitting direct elections of both, and setting terms for both at five years)
    • COSTITUZIONE [COST.] arts. 55-58, 60-61 (Italy), translated in 9 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE WORLD, supra note 28 (dividing Italy's Parliament into two houses, permitting direct elections of both, and setting terms for both at five years).
    • 9 Constitutions of The Countries of The World
  • 185
    • 0003611830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, noting that the "vast majority of European governments use the system of positive parliamentarianism," which requires a vote of investiture by parliament before a new government can assume power but also noting that such a vote is not required in the United Kingdom, the Nordic countries, the French Fifth Republic, Austria, Malta, and Portugal)
    • See Alan Siaroff, COMPARATIVE EUROPEAN PARTY SYSTEMS 105 (2000) (noting that the "vast majority of European governments use the system of positive parliamentarianism," which requires a vote of investiture by parliament before a new government can assume power but also noting that such a vote is not required in the United Kingdom, the Nordic countries, the French Fifth Republic, Austria, Malta, and Portugal).
    • (2000) Comparative European Party Systems 105
    • Siaroff, A.1
  • 186
    • 69249117544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., DR GRUNDLOV § 15 (Den.) (providing only for a parliamentary vote of no confidence)
    • See, e.g., DR GRUNDLOV § 15 (Den.) (providing only for a parliamentary vote of no confidence);
  • 187
    • 84869711579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GRUNDGESETZ FÜR DIE BUNDESREPUBLIK DEUTSCHLAND [GG] [Constitution] art. 68 (F.R.G.), translated in, supra note 28 (permitting a vote of confidence to be brought by the Federal Chancellor)
    • GRUNDGESETZ FÜR DIE BUNDESREPUBLIK DEUTSCHLAND [GG] [Constitution] art. 68 (F.R.G.), translated in 7 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE WORLD, supra note 28 (permitting a vote of confidence to be brought by the Federal Chancellor);
    • 7 Constitutions of The Countries of The World
  • 188
    • 0141882162 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Government accountability in parliamentary democracy
    • see also, supra note 38, at 279, 280-81 (noting that a confidence motion is brought by a government, as opposed to a no-confidence motion, which is brought by its opposition in the legislature)
    • see also Michael Laver & Kenneth A. Shepsle, Government Accountability in Parliamentary Democracy, in DEMOCRACY, ACCOUNTABILITY, AND REPRESENTATION, supra note 38, at 279, 280-81 (noting that a confidence motion is brought by a government, as opposed to a no-confidence motion, which is brought by its opposition in the legislature).
    • Democracy, Accountability, and Representation
    • Laver, M.1    Shepsle, K.A.2
  • 189
    • 69249088716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Laver & Shepsle, supra note 136, at 285-86 (exploring how governments in parliamentary democracies are subject to maintaining the confidence of parliament)
    • See Laver & Shepsle, supra note 136, at 285-86 (exploring how governments in parliamentary democracies are subject to maintaining the confidence of parliament).
  • 190
    • 69249089909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HUBER, supra note 113, at 25 (calling the French President's power of dissolution his "most important one")
    • See HUBER, supra note 113, at 25 (calling the French President's power of dissolution his "most important one").
  • 191
    • 69249159665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sarkozy, elected in France, vows break with past
    • See, May 7, at A1 (reporting that Sarkozy defeated his opponent by 6.2% of the vote, with 84% of the French electorate voting)
    • See Elaine Sciolino, Sarkozy, Elected in France, Vows Break with Past, N.Y. TIMES, May 7, 2007, at A1 (reporting that Sarkozy defeated his opponent by 6.2% of the vote, with 84% of the French electorate voting);
    • (2007) N.Y. Times
    • Sciolino, E.1
  • 192
    • 69249132285 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Violent protests greet Sarkozy's election in France
    • May 8, at A8 (reporting that in the wake of Sarkozy's election protestors set fire to 730 cars across France)
    • Craig S. Smith, Violent Protests Greet Sarkozy's Election in France, N.Y. TIMES, May 8, 2007, at A8 (reporting that in the wake of Sarkozy's election protestors set fire to 730 cars across France).
    • (2007) N.Y. Times
    • Smith, C.S.1
  • 194
    • 2942555465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The changing finnish democracy: Stronger parliamentary accountability, coalescing political parties and weaker external constraints
    • See, (describing how the Finnish government has become more parliamentarized, and the President less powerful, since the new Constitution came into force in 2000)
    • See Tapio Raunio, The Changing Finnish Democracy: Stronger Parliamentary Accountability, Coalescing Political Parties and Weaker External Constraints, 27 SCANDINAVIAN POL. Stud. 133, 133, 149 (2004) (describing how the Finnish government has become more parliamentarized, and the President less powerful, since the new Constitution came into force in 2000).
    • (2004) 27 Scandinavian Pol. Stud. 133 , Issue.133 , pp. 149
    • Raunio, T.1
  • 195
    • 69249155451 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SARTORI, supra note 127, at131-32
    • SARTORI, supra note 127, at 131-32.
  • 196
    • 84869711579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stjórnarskrá Lýôdveldisins Íslands [Stjórnarskrá] [Constitution] (Ice.), translated in, supra note 28
    • STJÓRNARSKRÁ LÝôDVELDISINS ÍSLANDS [STJÓRNARSKRÁ] [Constitution] (Ice.), translated in 8 CONSTITUTIONS OF THE COUNTRIES OF THE WORLD, supra note 28.
    • 8 Constitutions of The Countries of The World
  • 197
    • 69249127284 scopus 로고
    • Die Verfassung des Deutschen Reichs of 1919 [Weimarer Verfassung] [Constitution], translated in, Elmar M. Hucko ed.
    • Die Verfassung des Deutschen Reichs of 1919 [Weimarer Verfassung] [Constitution], translated in THE DEMOCRATIC TRADITION: FOUR GERMAN CONSTITUTIONS 147-190 (Elmar M. Hucko ed., 1923).
    • (1923) The Democratic Tradition: Four German Constitutions 147-90
  • 199
    • 84985817897 scopus 로고
    • A new political system model: Semi-presidential government
    • See, (analyzing the constitutions and political practices of several European countries, including Iceland, France, and Germany under the Weimar Republic, to explain why "relatively homogeneous constitutions are applied in radically different ways")
    • See Maurice Duverger, A New Political System Model: Semi-presidential Government, 8 EUR. J. POL. Res. 165, 177 (1980) (analyzing the constitutions and political practices of several European countries, including Iceland, France, and Germany under the Weimar Republic, to explain why "relatively homogeneous constitutions are applied in radically different ways").
    • (1980) 8 Eur. J. Pol. Res. 165 , pp. 177
    • Duverger, M.1
  • 200
    • 69249129838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SARTORI, supra note 127, at 126-27
    • SARTORI, supra note 127, at 126-27;
  • 201
    • 69249130240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHUGART & CAREY, supra note 73, at 71-72
    • SHUGART & CAREY, supra note 73, at 71-72;
  • 202
    • 69249091147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duverger, supra note 146, at 167
    • Duverger, supra note 146, at 167.
  • 203
    • 69249097616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SARTORI, supra note 127, at 128
    • SARTORI, supra note 127, at 128;
  • 204
    • 69249136414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHUGART & CAREY, supra note 73, at 68
    • SHUGART & CAREY, supra note 73, at 68;
  • 205
    • 69249152755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duverger, supra note 146, at 173
    • Duverger, supra note 146, at 173.
  • 206
    • 69249121021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHUGART & CAREY, supra note 73, at 24
    • SHUGART & CAREY, supra note 73, at 24.
  • 207
    • 69249120632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SARTORI, supra note 127, at 122
    • SARTORI, supra note 127, at 122;
  • 208
    • 69249142016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHUGART & CAREY, supra note 73, at 23
    • SHUGART & CAREY, supra note 73, at 23;
  • 209
    • 69249091953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duverger, supra note 146, at 165
    • Duverger, supra note 146, at 165.
  • 210
    • 69249138475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 53
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 53.
  • 211
    • 69249138883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1958 CONST., art. 8
    • 1958 CONST., art. 8.
  • 212
    • 69249151047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STJÓRNARSKRÁ art. 15
    • STJÓRNARSKRÁ art. 15.
  • 213
    • 69249094000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 24
    • Id. art. 24.
  • 214
  • 215
    • 69249098673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 25
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 25.
  • 216
  • 217
    • 69249160089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weimarer VERFASSUNG, art. 48
    • Weimarer VERFASSUNG, art. 48.
  • 218
    • 69249134408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 48
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 48.
  • 219
    • 69249124717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STJÓRNARSKRÁ art. 28
    • STJÓRNARSKRÁ art. 28.
  • 220
    • 69249113998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 221
    • 69249113213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 73
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 73.
  • 223
    • 69249132287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 10
    • Id. art. 10.
  • 224
    • 69249105132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 68
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 68.
  • 225
    • 69249125543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 52
    • Id. art. 52.
  • 226
    • 69249096790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STJÓRNARSKRÁ art. 25
    • STJÓRNARSKRÁ art. 25.
  • 227
    • 69249084236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 2
    • Id. art. 2.
  • 228
    • 69249099089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 16
    • Id. art. 16.
  • 230
    • 69249130671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 9
    • Id. art. 9.
  • 231
    • 69249112819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 13
    • Id. art. 13.
  • 232
    • 69249122648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 52
    • WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 52.
  • 233
    • 69249098674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is consistent with the lack of consensus in the literature about the effect of presidential powers in semi-presidential democracies. Measures of presidential powers in semi-presidential constitutions are not always important in accounting for variation in the performance of these systems. See, e.g., SHUGART& Carey, supra note 73, at 166, 165-66 (1992) (concluding that granting "great legislative powers" to the president, or "granting shared authority over the composition of the cabinet" are "potentially dangerous arrangement[s] ")
    • This is consistent with the lack of consensus in the literature about the effect of presidential powers in semi-presidential democracies. Measures of presidential powers in semi-presidential constitutions are not always important in accounting for variation in the performance of these systems. See, e.g., SHUGART& Carey, supra note 73, at 166, 165-66 (1992) (concluding that granting "great legislative powers" to the president, or "granting shared authority over the composition of the cabinet" are "potentially dangerous arrangement[s]");
  • 234
    • 33645673954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential powers and consolidation of new post-communist democracies
    • "[P]olitical regimes with stronger executive powers of presidents exhibit worse contemporaneous democratic performance and are less able to consolidate as democracies."
    • Mikhail V. Beliaev, Presidential Powers and Consolidation of New Post-communist Democracies, 39 COMP. POL. STUD. 375, 375 (2006) ("[PJolitical regimes with stronger executive powers of presidents exhibit worse contemporaneous democratic performance and are less able to consolidate as democracies.");
    • (2006) 39 Comp. Pol. Stud. 375 , pp. 375
    • Beliaev, M.V.1
  • 235
    • 0031500135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A politics of institutional choice: Post-communist presidencies
    • stating that formal powers of the presidency "are a significant predictor of progress in economic reform in the countries of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe"
    • Timothy Frye, A Politics of Institutional Choice: Post-communist Presidencies, 30 COMP. POL. STUD. 523, 527 (1997) (stating that formal powers of the presidency "are a significant predictor of progress in economic reform in the countries of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe");
    • (1997) 30 Comp. Pol. Stud. 523 , pp. 527
    • Frye, T.1
  • 236
    • 0034417965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring presidential power
    • finding that "democratic failure is not very likely in" either parliamentary or semi-presidential regimes
    • Lee Kendall Metcalf, Measuring Presidential Power, 33 COMP. POL. STUD. 660, 679, 678-79 (2000) (finding that "democratic failure is not very likely in" either parliamentary or semi-presidential regimes);
    • (2000) 33 Comp. Pol. Stud. 660 , Issue.679 , pp. 678-679
    • Metcalf, L.K.1
  • 237
    • 69249083397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mixed constitutions and democratic performance: Do popularly elected presidents matter in parliamentary systems?
    • Paper Presented at, Dec. 19-21, available at. ("[S]ystems which require the government to obtain parliamentary confidence and at the same time institute a directly elected president are not any different from pure parliamentary systems.")
    • José Antonio Cheibub & Svitlana Chernykh, Mixed Constitutions and Democratic Performance: Do Popularly Elected Presidents Matter in Parliamentary Systems?, Paper Presented at Conference on Separation of Powers at the University of Haifa 21 (Dec. 19-21, 2007), available at http://law.haifa.ac.il/events/events-files/Cheibub%20and%20Chernykh%20Haifa.pdf ("[S]ystems which require the government to obtain parliamentary confidence and at the same time institute a directly elected president are not any different from pure parliamentary systems.").
    • (2007) Conference on Separation of Powers at the University of Haifa 21
    • Cheibub, J.A.1    Chernykh, S.2
  • 238
    • 69249085917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ukraine leader forced to name ex-rival as prime minister
    • Consider, for example, the fact that Viktor Yushchenko, Ukraine's constitutionally strong President and the winner of a hotly contested presidential race in March 2005, finally appointed his opponent in that election, Viktor Yanukovich, as the Prime Minister, Aug. 3, , at A3. This followed a series of attempts to form a government that would exclude Yanukovich's party from the government, which proved politically unviable. Id.
    • Consider, for example, the fact that Viktor Yushchenko, Ukraine's constitutionally strong President and the winner of a hotly contested presidential race in March 2005, finally appointed his opponent in that election, Viktor Yanukovich, as the Prime Minister. Andrew E. Kramer, Ukraine Leader Forced to Name Ex-rival as Prime Minister, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 3, 2006, at A3. This followed a series of attempts to form a government that would exclude Yanukovich's party from the government, which proved politically unviable. Id.
    • (2006) N.Y. Times
    • Kramer, A.E.1
  • 239
    • 69249097615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Raunio, supra note 141, at 133 ("The new unified constitution, in force since March 2000, completed a period of constitutional change that curtailed presidential powers and brought the Finnish political system closer to a standard version of parliamentary democracy.")
    • See Raunio, supra note 141, at 133 ("The new unified constitution, in force since March 2000, completed a period of constitutional change that curtailed presidential powers and brought the Finnish political system closer to a standard version of parliamentary democracy.").
  • 240
    • 69249129252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perustuslaki § 61
    • Perustuslaki § 61.
  • 241
    • 69249145409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 64
    • Id. § 64.
  • 242
    • 0037537341 scopus 로고
    • Cross currents in anglo-american administrative law
    • See, (explaining that in England the "Parliament and the executive are one, and parliamentary majorities form the government")
    • See Paul R. Verkuil, Cross Currents in Anglo-American Administrative Law, 27 WM. & Mary L. REV. 685, 691 (1986) (explaining that in England the "Parliament and the executive are one, and parliamentary majorities form the government").
    • (1986) 27 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 685 , pp. 691
    • Verkuil, P.R.1
  • 243
    • 69249095542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DR GRUNDLOV § 3. The 1953 Constitution allowed for a female head of state by stipulating that the royal power could be inherited by both men and women. Id. § 2. Since 1972, the head of state in Denmark has been a Queen. Yet, at least in its English translation, the Constitution refers throughout to the power of the King, not the Queen or the Monarch. Id. passim
    • DR GRUNDLOV § 3. The 1953 Constitution allowed for a female head of state by stipulating that the royal power could be inherited by both men and women. Id. § 2. Since 1972, the head of state in Denmark has been a Queen. Yet, at least in its English translation, the Constitution refers throughout to the power of the King, not the Queen or the Monarch. Id. passim.
  • 244
    • 69249089499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 2
    • Id. § 2.
  • 245
    • 69249120030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 14
    • Id. § 14.
  • 246
    • 69249095147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional frameworks and fragile democracies: Choosing between parliamentarianism, presidentialism and semi-presidentialism
    • One of the common themes in the literature on democracy and democratization in Eastern Europe is the fact that so many countries adopted a constitution that called for a directly elected president. E.g., (observing that the semi-presidential model is used in much of Eastern Europe)
    • One of the common themes in the literature on democracy and democratization in Eastern Europe is the fact that so many countries adopted a constitution that called for a directly elected president. E.g., Mark Freeman, Constitutional Frameworks and Fragile Democracies: Choosing Between Parliamentarianism, Presidentialism and Semi-presidentialism, 12 PACE INT'L L. REV. 253, 259-62 (2000) (observing that the semi-presidential model is used in much of Eastern Europe);
    • (2000) 12 Pace Int'L L. Rev. 253 , pp. 259-262
    • Freeman, M.1
  • 247
    • 69249117979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stepan & Skach, supra note 2, at 4 n.10 (noting that in Eastern Europe the "norm is a directly elected president"). It is worth noting, however, that the truly remarkable fact about the constitutions these countries adopted is that they all called for a government based on assembly confidence
    • Stepan & Skach, supra note 2, at 4 n.10 (noting that in Eastern Europe the "norm is a directly elected president"). It is worth noting, however, that the truly remarkable fact about the constitutions these countries adopted is that they all called for a government based on assembly confidence.
  • 248
    • 84928441266 scopus 로고
    • Constitutional politics in Poland: A report on the constitutional committee of the polish parliament
    • See, ("[M]any Poles (along with other Eastern Europeans)... view the government as in need of constant parliamentary authorization. Typically, this yields a significant constituency for such arrangements as ... the parliament's power to vote no confidence for the government or any particular minister at any time ...."). As a matter of fact, many countries adopted an effective parliamentary formula even before they wrote a new constitution
    • See Andrzej Rapaczynski, Constitutional Politics in Poland: A Report on the Constitutional Committee of the Polish Parliament, 58 U. CHI. L. REV. 595, 624 (1991) ("[M]any Poles (along with other Eastern Europeans)... view the government as in need of constant parliamentary authorization. Typically, this yields a significant constituency for such arrangements as ... the parliament's power to vote no confidence for the government or any particular minister at any time ...."). As a matter of fact, many countries adopted an effective parliamentary formula even before they wrote a new constitution.
    • (1991) 58 U. Chi. L. Rev. 595 , pp. 624
    • Rapaczynski, A.1
  • 249
    • 84935587497 scopus 로고
    • Constitutionalism in eastern Europe: An introduction
    • See, (describing the constitution-making process in a number of Eastern European countries where the constitution had to be approved by two-thirds of parliament)
    • See Jon Elster, Constitutionalism in Eastern Europe: An Introduction, 58 U. CHI. L. REV. 447, 459-64 (1991) (describing the constitution-making process in a number of Eastern European countries where the constitution had to be approved by two-thirds of parliament).
    • (1991) 58 U. Chi. L. Rev. 447 , pp. 459-464
    • Elster, J.1
  • 250
    • 69249160401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 41 (providing for the election of the President by the whole German people)
    • See WEIMARER VERFASSUNG, art. 41 (providing for the election of the President by the whole German people);
  • 251
    • 53949113163 scopus 로고
    • Parliament and government in a reconstructed Germany, translated and reprinted
    • see also, app. 2 at 1461, Guenther Roth & Claus Wittich eds., (calling for "democratization of the suffrage" in post-WWI Germany).
    • see also Max Weber, Parliament and Government in a Reconstructed Germany, translated and reprinted in 2 MAX WEBER: ECONOMY AND SOCIETY app. 2 at 1461 (Guenther Roth & Claus Wittich eds., 1978) (calling for " democratization of the suffrage" in post-WWI Germany).
    • (1978) 2 Max Weber: Economy and Society
    • Weber, M.1
  • 252
    • 72449196438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political economy and separation of powers
    • See, ("Under the leadership of Charles DeGaulle, France attempted to create a President who would be above the political fray that inevitably surrounds the Parliament, the Prime Minister, and the Prime Minister's Cabinet.")
    • See John C. Reitz, Political Economy and Separation of Powers, 15 TRANSNAT'L L. & CONTEMP. PROBS. 579, 603 (2006) ("Under the leadership of Charles DeGaulle, France attempted to create a President who would be above the political fray that inevitably surrounds the Parliament, the Prime Minister, and the Prime Minister's Cabinet.").
    • (2006) 15 Transnat'l L. & Contemp. Probs. 579 , pp. 603
    • Reitz, J.C.1
  • 253
    • 69249094001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., THE FEDERALIST No. 10, at 76 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (arguing that a "pure democracy," in which there is no check on the will of the majority, is characterized by "turbulence and contention" and is "incompatible with personal security or the rights of property")
    • See, e.g., THE FEDERALIST No. 10, at 76 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (arguing that a "pure democracy," in which there is no check on the will of the majority, is characterized by "turbulence and contention" and is "incompatible with personal security or the rights of property");
  • 254
    • 69249100681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Su, supra note 50, at 234 ("Doubtless, a central objective of traditional constitutionalism is to prevent the tyranny of the majority ....")
    • Su, supra note 50, at 234 ("Doubtless, a central objective of traditional constitutionalism is to prevent the tyranny of the majority ....").
  • 255
    • 69249112018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, (creating a head of state, the Beretitenti, who has no specific term limits and may be removed by a no-confidence vote from the legislature)
    • See CONST. KIRIBATI art. 33 (creating a head of state, the Beretitenti, who has no specific term limits and may be removed by a no-confidence vote from the legislature);
    • Const. Kiribati Art. 33
  • 256
    • 69249109398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§ 3, 7 (creating a President without term limits who is subject to a no-confidence vote from the legislature)
    • CONST. Marsh. Is. art. 5, §§ 3, 7 (creating a President without term limits who is subject to a no-confidence vote from the legislature);
    • CONST. Marsh. Is. Art. 5
  • 257
    • 69249098454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§ 83, 102 (creating a unified head of state and government who is also subject to a no-confidence vote)
    • S. AFR. CONST. 1996 §§ 83, 102 (creating a unified head of state and government who is also subject to a no-confidence vote).
    • S. Afr. Const. 1996
  • 259
    • 69249135644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 102
    • Id. § 102;
  • 261
    • 46749133808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A stormy test for democracy in South Africa
    • Sept. 23, 2006, at A1 (recording the beginning of now-President Jacob Zuma's campaign for the leadership of the ANC and documenting the party's complete stranglehold on political power since Nelson Mandela and the end of apartheid in 1994)
    • Michael Wines, A Stormy Test for Democracy in South Africa, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 23, 2006, at A1 (recording the beginning of now-President Jacob Zuma's campaign for the leadership of the ANC and documenting the party's complete stranglehold on political power since Nelson Mandela and the end of apartheid in 1994).
    • N.Y. Times
    • Wines, M.1
  • 262
    • 69249090319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • World briefing South Africa: ANC claims win with 66% of vote
    • But see, Apr. 25, 2009, at A28 (recording the ANC's latest electoral victory in 2009, which, while resounding, was significantly less than its 70% margin in 2004 and left the party just short of the threshold required to amend the Constitution at will)
    • But see World Briefing South Africa: ANC Claims Win with 66% of Vote, L.A. TIMES, Apr. 25, 2009, at A28 (recording the ANC's latest electoral victory in 2009, which, while resounding, was significantly less than its 70% margin in 2004 and left the party just short of the threshold required to amend the Constitution at will).
    • L.A. Times
  • 263
    • 69249085094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., (referring to the Fifth Republic as "de Gaulle's Republic" and calling its democracy a comparative improvement)
    • See, e.g., Cindy Skach, BORROWING CONSTITUTIONAL DESIGNS 93 & n.1 (2005) (referring to the Fifth Republic as "de Gaulle's Republic" and calling its democracy a comparative improvement);
    • (2005) Borrowing Constitutional designs 93 , Issue.1
    • Skach, C.1
  • 264
    • 77955944088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Latin American hybrid constitutionalism: The united states presidentialism in the civil law melting pot
    • "The stability [of the Fifth Republic] results... from bringing the French model closer to a well-tested parliamentary-cabinet system purged of 'spasmodic' features of quasi-presidentialism or excesses of 'pure' parliamentarism of the Third and Fourth Republic.")
    • Rett R. Ludwikowski, Latin American Hybrid Constitutionalism: The United States Presidentialism in the Civil Law Melting Pot, 21 B.U. INT'L L.J. 29, 59-60 (2003) ("The stability [of the Fifth Republic] results... from bringing the French model closer to a well-tested parliamentary-cabinet system purged of 'spasmodic' features of quasi-presidentialism or excesses of 'pure' parliamentarism of the Third and Fourth Republic.");
    • (2003) 21 B.U. Int'L L.J. 29 , pp. 59-60
    • Ludwikowski, R.R.1
  • 265
    • 84920602047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • France and the Algerian war: From a policy of "Forgetting" to a framework for accountability
    • Note, ("By granting the Executive preponderant power, the Fifth Republic ended the institutional instability that had resulted from parliamentary dominance.")
    • Shiva Eftekhari, Note, France and the Algerian War: From a Policy of "Forgetting" to a Framework for Accountability, 34 COLUM. HUM. RTS. L. REV. 413, 416 (2003) ("By granting the Executive preponderant power, the Fifth Republic ended the institutional instability that had resulted from parliamentary dominance.").
    • (2003) 34 Colum. Hum. Rts. L. Rev. 413 , pp. 416
    • Eftekhari, S.1
  • 266
    • 69249101433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Skach, supra note 189, at 93 & n. 1
    • Skach, supra note 189, at 93 & n. 1.
  • 268
    • 69249106639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 49. These procedures, which have been often used by all governments since 1959, have made the French government highly successful; its rate of legislative success, as defined above, was 69.23% between 1946 and 1958 and 84.8% between 1959 and 1983. Cheibub & Chernykh, supra note 125, at 295 n.l7. Unfortunately, I do not have the information on the years of cohabitation of left and right
    • Id. art. 49. These procedures, which have been often used by all governments since 1959, have made the French government highly successful; its rate of legislative success, as defined above, was 69.23% between 1946 and 1958 and 84.8% between 1959 and 1983. Cheibub & Chernykh, supra note 125, at 295 n.l7. Unfortunately, I do not have the information on the years of cohabitation of left and right.
  • 269
    • 69249097617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HUBER, supra note 113, at 2
    • HUBER, supra note 113, at 2.
  • 270
    • 69249140445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cheibub & Chernykh, supra note 125, at 296. The number of countries with these provisions ranges from eight to over twenty. Id. at n.18. Prior to 1919 there were no democracies that combined a system of assembly confidence with a directly elected president. Id. at 288 n.11. In 1919 both Germany and Finland adopted a mixed constitution, although in Germany the first President was elected by the Parliament and in Finland the President was elected indirectly (although popularly) until 2000. Id.
    • Cheibub & Chernykh, supra note 125, at 296. The number of countries with these provisions ranges from eight to over twenty. Id. at n.18. Prior to 1919 there were no democracies that combined a system of assembly confidence with a directly elected president. Id. at 288 n.11. In 1919 both Germany and Finland adopted a mixed constitution, although in Germany the first President was elected by the Parliament and in Finland the President was elected indirectly (although popularly) until 2000. Id.
  • 271
    • 69249153615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SLAVELIS, supra note 90 (recognizing empirically the efficacy of Chile's strong presidential authority)
    • See SLAVELIS, supra note 90 (recognizing empirically the efficacy of Chile's strong presidential authority);
  • 272
    • 69249141208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cheibub & Chernykh, supra note 125, at 295 (emphasizing the importance of government-strengthening institutional features)
    • Cheibub & Chernykh, supra note 125, at 295 (emphasizing the importance of government-strengthening institutional features);
  • 273
    • 0000651249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Time as a scarce resource: Government control of the agenda
    • Herbert Döring ed., (discussing the balance of power between government and parliament in setting the legislative agenda)
    • Herbert Döring, Time as a Scarce Resource: Government Control of the Agenda, in PARLIAMENTS AND MAJORITY RULE IN WESTERN EUROPE 223, 224-26 (Herbert Döring ed., 1996) (discussing the balance of power between government and parliament in setting the legislative agenda);
    • (1996) Parliaments and Majority Rule in Western Europe 223 , pp. 224-226
    • Döring, H.1
  • 274
    • 69249149427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 90, at 74-77 (describing the powers of the President over the legislative process in Brazil, even after the 1988 Constitution)
    • Figueiredo and Limongi, Constitutional Change, supra note 90, at 74-77 (describing the powers of the President over the legislative process in Brazil, even after the 1988 Constitution).
    • Constitutional Change
    • Figueiredo1    Limongi2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.