메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 93, Issue 5, 2009, Pages 1820-1870

Shaping supreme court policy through appointments: The impact of a new justice

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 68349111819     PISSN: 00265535     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (8)

References (126)
  • 1
    • 68349100587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DAVID E. LEWIS, THE POLITICS OF PRESIDENTIAL APPOINTMENTS 6-8, 55-58 (2008).
    • See DAVID E. LEWIS, THE POLITICS OF PRESIDENTIAL APPOINTMENTS 6-8, 55-58 (2008).
  • 2
    • 68349095588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Erwin Chemerinsky, Ideology and the Selection of Federal Judges, 36 U.C. DAVIS L. REV. 619, 620 (2003) (Every President in American history, to a greater or lesser extent, has chosen federal judges, in part, based on their ideology.); see also Richard L. Revesz, Environmental Regulation, Ideology, and the D.C. Circuit, 83 VA. L. REV. 1717, 1717-18 (1997) (noting the politici-zation of decision making in environmental cases before the D.C. Circuit and how participating judges generally reflect the views held by the party of the appointing President).
    • See Erwin Chemerinsky, Ideology and the Selection of Federal Judges, 36 U.C. DAVIS L. REV. 619, 620 (2003) ("Every President in American history, to a greater or lesser extent, has chosen federal judges, in part, based on their ideology."); see also Richard L. Revesz, Environmental Regulation, Ideology, and the D.C. Circuit, 83 VA. L. REV. 1717, 1717-18 (1997) (noting the politici-zation of decision making in environmental cases before the D.C. Circuit and how participating judges generally reflect the views held by the party of the appointing President).
  • 3
    • 84869555193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Thomas S. Clark, The Separation of Powers, Court-Curbing and Judicial Legitimacy 14-16 (Nov. 5, 2008) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://userwww.service.emory.edu/̃tclark7/constitutional.pdf (discussing various impetuses behind court-curbing legislation).
    • See Thomas S. Clark, The Separation of Powers, Court-Curbing and Judicial Legitimacy 14-16 (Nov. 5, 2008) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://userwww.service.emory.edu/̃tclark7/constitutional.pdf (discussing various impetuses behind court-curbing legislation).
  • 4
    • 68349089642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THOMAS R. MARSHALL, PUBLIC OPINION AND THE SUPREME COURT 78-79, 97-98, 117 (1989) (noting that a majority of Supreme Court decisions reflect public opinion and that the Supreme Court will seldom defy nationwide public opinion).
    • See THOMAS R. MARSHALL, PUBLIC OPINION AND THE SUPREME COURT 78-79, 97-98, 117 (1989) (noting that a majority of Supreme Court decisions reflect public opinion and that the Supreme Court will seldom defy nationwide public opinion).
  • 5
    • 68349114198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra notes 1-4 (discussing the effectiveness of these tools in varying circumstances).
    • See sources cited supra notes 1-4 (discussing the effectiveness of these tools in varying circumstances).
  • 6
    • 68349090789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David A. Strauss, Memo to the President (and His Opponents): Ideology Still Counts, 102 Nw. U. L. REV. COLLOQUY 49, 50 (2007), http://www.law.northwestern.edu/lawreview/ Colloquy/2007/22/LRCol12007n22Strauss.pdf (discussing how President Franklin Roosevelt proposed legislation to reshape the Court, hoping to assure a majority in favor of his legislative programs, after the Supreme Court declared key features of the New Deal unconstitution-al).
    • See David A. Strauss, Memo to the President (and His Opponents): Ideology Still Counts, 102 Nw. U. L. REV. COLLOQUY 49, 50 (2007), http://www.law.northwestern.edu/lawreview/ Colloquy/2007/22/LRCol12007n22Strauss.pdf (discussing how President Franklin Roosevelt proposed legislation to reshape the Court, hoping to assure a majority in favor of his legislative programs, after the Supreme Court declared key features of the New Deal unconstitution-al).
  • 7
    • 0034146845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charles M. Cameron et al., Strategic Auditing in a Political Hierarchy: An Informational Model of the Supreme Court's Certiorari Decisions, 94 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 101, 113-14 (2000) (noting that the Court can use the certiorari process to enforce its doctrinal preferences throughout the judicial hierarchy).
    • Charles M. Cameron et al., Strategic Auditing in a Political Hierarchy: An Informational Model of the Supreme Court's Certiorari Decisions, 94 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 101, 113-14 (2000) (noting that the Court can use the certiorari process to enforce its doctrinal preferences throughout the judicial hierarchy).
  • 8
    • 68349106201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THE FEDERALIST NO. 70, at 396-97 (Alexander Hamilton) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (discussing the value of a unitary executive where every magistrate would be personally responsible for his behavior, thereby allowing the chief magistrate to take swift and decisive action).
    • See THE FEDERALIST NO. 70, at 396-97 (Alexander Hamilton) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (discussing the value of a unitary executive where every magistrate would be personally responsible for his behavior, thereby allowing the chief magistrate to take swift and decisive action).
  • 10
    • 68349093209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SHELDON GOLDMAN, PICKING FEDERAL JUDGES 68-76 (1997) (Truman and his administration primarily treated judgeships as patronage, in the service of the partisan agenda.); DAVID ALISTAIR YALOF, PURSUIT OF JUSTICES 20, 38-40 (1999) (discussing how President Truman wanted to feel a sense of personal comfort with and loyalty from his Supreme Court nominees).
    • See SHELDON GOLDMAN, PICKING FEDERAL JUDGES 68-76 (1997) ("Truman and his administration primarily treated judgeships as patronage, in the service of the partisan agenda."); DAVID ALISTAIR YALOF, PURSUIT OF JUSTICES 20, 38-40 (1999) (discussing how President Truman wanted to feel a sense of "personal comfort" with and loyalty from his Supreme Court nominees).
  • 11
    • 68349103613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See LEWIS, supra note 1, at 20-21 (Today the federal government employs 2.5 million civilians in full-time positions ....).
    • See LEWIS, supra note 1, at 20-21 ("Today the federal government employs 2.5 million civilians in full-time positions ....").
  • 12
    • 68349117692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Department of Homeland Security, Department Subcomponents & Agencies, http://www.dhs.gov/xabout/structure/ (last visited Apr. 13, 2009) (More than 87, 000 different governmental jurisdictions at the federal, state, and local level have homeland security responsibilities. ).
    • See, e.g., Department of Homeland Security, Department Subcomponents & Agencies, http://www.dhs.gov/xabout/structure/ (last visited Apr. 13, 2009) ("More than 87, 000 different governmental jurisdictions at the federal, state, and local level have homeland security responsibilities. ").
  • 13
    • 32544447546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Emerson H. Tiller & Frank B. Cross, What Is Legal Doctrine?, 100 NW. U. L. REV. 517, 532 (2006) (noting that judges may be less inclined to adhere to strict legal doctrine in cases where the political saliency of the issue is high).
    • Cf. Emerson H. Tiller & Frank B. Cross, What Is Legal Doctrine?, 100 NW. U. L. REV. 517, 532 (2006) (noting that judges may be less inclined to adhere to strict legal doctrine in cases where the political saliency of the issue is high).
  • 14
    • 84971722490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Charles M. Cameron et al, Senate Voting on Supreme Court Nominees: A Neoinstitutional Model, 84 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 525, 532 (1990, hereinafter Cameron et al, Senate Voting, noting that a strong President can successfully nominate a highly qualified and ideologically congruent Justice, Lee Epstein et al, The Increasing Importance of Ideology in the Nomination and Confirmation of Supreme Court Justices, 56 DRAKE L. REV. 609, 631-35 (2008, noting that contemporary Justices may be entrenching their President's views into the law-and may be doing so long after he leaves office, Collectively and consistently, these papers show that presidents can almost always place a nominee on the Court who is seen as well qualified. See, e.g, Charles M. Cameron & Jee-Kwang Park, Voting for Justices: Change and Continuity in Confirmation Voting 1937-2006, at 9-10 2007, unpublished
    • See, e.g., Charles M. Cameron et al., Senate Voting on Supreme Court Nominees: A Neoinstitutional Model, 84 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 525, 532 (1990) [hereinafter Cameron et al., Senate Voting] (noting that a strong President can successfully nominate a highly qualified and ideologically congruent Justice); Lee Epstein et al., The Increasing Importance of Ideology in the Nomination and Confirmation of Supreme Court Justices, 56 DRAKE L. REV. 609, 631-35 (2008) (noting that contemporary Justices "may be entrenching their President's views into the law-and may be doing so long after he leaves office"). Collectively and consistently, these papers show that presidents can almost always place a nominee on the Court who is seen as well qualified. See, e.g., Charles M. Cameron & Jee-Kwang Park, Voting for Justices: Change and Continuity in Confirmation Voting 1937-2006, at 9-10 (2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with authors). More specifically, when the President's co-partisans control the Senate, he can place almost any reasonable nominee on the Court. See id. at 7. Even if the President's copartisans do not control the Senate, a nominee will likely prove successful if her record is void of scandalous behavior, partisan political involvement, or controversial activities and if she is manifestly well qualified for the job. See id. at 10; Epstein et al., supra at 628. And, even when the Senate rejects a nominee, the President can return with an ideologically similar person and achieve success. See Cameron et al., Senate Voting, supra at 532.
  • 15
    • 84869583874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See STEVEN TELES, THE RISE OF THE CONSERVATIVE LEGAL MOVE-MENT 1-2 (2008, identifying the fact that conservatives have made a concerted effort to find and place reliable agents on the Court, Ward Farnsworth, The Use and Limits of Martin-Quinn Scores to Assess Supreme Court Justices, with Special Attention to the Problem of Ideological Drift, 101 Nw. U. L. REV. COLLOQUY 1891, 1901-02 (2007, http://www.law.northwestern.edu/ lawreview/v101/n4/1891/LR101n4Farnsworth.pdf (noting that presidents can act to reduce the chances of future erratic ideological behavior while on the Court by choosing their agents more carefully, see also Charles M. Cameron & Jee-Kwang Park, How Will they Vote? Predicting the Future Behavior of Supreme Court Nominees, 1937-2006, at 4, 14-15, 22-24 2007, unpublished manuscript, on file with authors, available at
    • See STEVEN TELES, THE RISE OF THE CONSERVATIVE LEGAL MOVE-MENT 1-2 (2008) (identifying the fact that conservatives have made a concerted effort to find and place reliable agents on the Court); Ward Farnsworth, The Use and Limits of Martin-Quinn Scores to Assess Supreme Court Justices, with Special Attention to the Problem of Ideological Drift, 101 Nw. U. L. REV. COLLOQUY 1891, 1901-02 (2007), http://www.law.northwestern.edu/ lawreview/v101/n4/1891/LR101n4Farnsworth.pdf (noting that presidents can act to reduce the chances of future erratic ideological behavior while on the Court by choosing their agents more carefully); see also Charles M. Cameron & Jee-Kwang Park, How Will they Vote? Predicting the Future Behavior of Supreme Court Nominees, 1937-2006, at 4, 14-15, 22-24 (2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with authors), available at http://www.princeton.edu/ ̃ccameron/HowWillTheyVote.pdf (describing how improved measures predict future behavior better while also noting that the predictability of nominees has increased substantially over time). But see Lee Epstein et al., Ideological Drift Among Supreme Court Justices: Who, When, and How Important?, 101 NW. U. L. REV. 1483, 1493, 1497, 1519, 1526 (2007) (commenting that some Justices seem to change their voting behavior on case dispositions over time, thus calling into question the ability of presidents to place faithful agents on the Court).
  • 16
    • 0036275492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Bernard Grofman & Timothy J. Brazill, Identifying the Median Justice on the Supreme Court Through Multidimensional Scaling: Analysis of Natural Courts, 112 PUB. CHOICE 55, 57, 63 (2002); Keith Krehbiel, Supreme Court Appointments as a Move-the-Median Game, 51 AM. J. POL. SCI. 231, 235, 238 (2007) (discussing the move-the-median model and its implication for Supreme Court appointments to shift policy objectives of the Court).
    • See, e.g., Bernard Grofman & Timothy J. Brazill, Identifying the Median Justice on the Supreme Court Through Multidimensional Scaling: Analysis of "Natural Courts, " 112 PUB. CHOICE 55, 57, 63 (2002); Keith Krehbiel, Supreme Court Appointments as a Move-the-Median Game, 51 AM. J. POL. SCI. 231, 235, 238 (2007) (discussing the move-the-median model and its implication for Supreme Court appointments to shift policy objectives of the Court).
  • 17
    • 19744372850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Colored Speech: Cross Burnings, Epis-temics, and the Triumph of the Crits?, 93
    • For the majority of Justice Marshall's time on the Court, he was one of the most liberal members, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Guy-Uriel E. Charles, Colored Speech: Cross Burnings, Epis-temics, and the Triumph of the Crits?, 93 GEO. L.J. 575, 624 (2005) ("For the majority of Justice Marshall's time on the Court, he was one of the most liberal members .. . ").
    • (2005) GEO. L.J , vol.575 , pp. 624
    • Charles, G.-U.E.1
  • 18
    • 57849109143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Lee Epstein & Tonja Jacobi, Super Medians, 61 STAN. L. REV. 37, 82 n.183 (2008) (noting commentary suggesting that Justice Thomas is consistently the most conservative voter on the Court).
    • See, e.g., Lee Epstein & Tonja Jacobi, Super Medians, 61 STAN. L. REV. 37, 82 n.183 (2008) (noting commentary suggesting that Justice Thomas is "consistently the most conservative voter on the Court").
  • 19
    • 68349114193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A natural court refers to a Supreme Court whose membership is constant. The departure of a Justice marks the end of one natural court; the arrival of his or her replacement marks the beginning of the next. LEE EPSTEIN ET AL., THE SUPREME COURT COMPENDIUM 313 (1994). Because the bargaining dynamics on a multimembered court reflect its membership, natural courts (rather than annual terms, for instance) form the logical unit for studying bargaining and coalition formation on the Supreme Court. See id. at 303-13 for a listing of Supreme Court natural courts through 1993.
    • A "natural court" refers to a Supreme Court whose membership is constant. The departure of a Justice marks the end of one natural court; the arrival of his or her replacement marks the beginning of the next. LEE EPSTEIN ET AL., THE SUPREME COURT COMPENDIUM 313 (1994). Because the bargaining dynamics on a multimembered court reflect its membership, natural courts (rather than annual terms, for instance) form the logical unit for studying bargaining and coalition formation on the Supreme Court. See id. at 303-13 for a listing of Supreme Court natural courts through 1993.
  • 20
    • 68349090785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Throughout this Article, we label natural courts according to the classifications provided in Harold Spaeth's database. See HAROLD J. SPAETH, THE ORIGINAL UNITED STATES SUPREME COURT JUDICIAL DATABASE (2009), http://www.cas.sc.edu/poli/juri/sctdata.htm. The Spaeth database begins a natural court each time a Justice leaves or joins the Court. As a result, some natural courts identified by the Spaeth database have open seats. Professor Epstein et al. provide an alternative classification that begins a natural court each time a new Justice joins the Court. See EPSTEIN ET AL., supra note 19, at 303-13.
    • Throughout this Article, we label natural courts according to the classifications provided in Harold Spaeth's database. See HAROLD J. SPAETH, THE ORIGINAL UNITED STATES SUPREME COURT JUDICIAL DATABASE (2009), http://www.cas.sc.edu/poli/juri/sctdata.htm. The Spaeth database begins a natural court each time a Justice leaves or joins the Court. As a result, some natural courts identified by the Spaeth database have open seats. Professor Epstein et al. provide an alternative classification that begins a natural court each time a new Justice joins the Court. See EPSTEIN ET AL., supra note 19, at 303-13.
  • 21
    • 68349108928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To these one might add a case selection effect-the difference in type of cases selected following the turnover in membership. For instance: Did the new Court take more or fewer extremely consequential cases than did the pre-vious Court? We will not consider case selection effects in this Article.
    • To these one might add a case selection effect-the difference in type of cases selected following the turnover in membership. For instance: Did the new Court take more or fewer extremely consequential cases than did the pre-vious Court? We will not consider case selection effects in this Article.
  • 22
    • 84869591942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Monopoly Author theory can be seen as the game-theoretic version of the earlier behavioralist attitudinal model, which asserted that Justices vote on the merits in accord with their personal ideologies. See JEFFREY A. SEGAL & HAROLD J. SPAETH, THE SUPREME COURT AND THE ATTITUDINAL MODEL REVISITED 86-97 (2002) (discussing the attitudinal approach in detail); see also infra Part IΠ.C (discussing the Monopoly Author approach).
    • The Monopoly Author theory can be seen as the game-theoretic version of the earlier behavioralist "attitudinal model, " which asserted that Justices vote on the merits in accord with their personal ideologies. See JEFFREY A. SEGAL & HAROLD J. SPAETH, THE SUPREME COURT AND THE ATTITUDINAL MODEL REVISITED 86-97 (2002) (discussing the attitudinal approach in detail); see also infra Part IΠ.C (discussing the Monopoly Author approach).
  • 23
    • 68349088489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SEGAL & SPAETH, supra note 22, at 86
    • See SEGAL & SPAETH, supra note 22, at 86.
  • 24
    • 68349083897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THOMAS H. HAMMOND ET AL., STRATEGIC BEHAVIOR AND POLICY CHOICE ON THE U.S. SUPREME COURT 52 (2005) (noting that Segal and Spaeth's attitudinal model did not provide any kind of carefully specified model to predict whether the justice's earlier behavior is influenced by strategic considerations).
    • See THOMAS H. HAMMOND ET AL., STRATEGIC BEHAVIOR AND POLICY CHOICE ON THE U.S. SUPREME COURT 52 (2005) (noting that Segal and Spaeth's attitudinal model "did not provide any kind of carefully specified model" to predict "whether the justice's earlier behavior is influenced by strategic considerations").
  • 25
    • 68349089639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, id. at 79-215 (applying the Median Voter theorem to develop a formal model of strategic decision making on the Supreme Court, Epstein & Jacobi, supra note 18, at 44-49 same
    • See, e.g., id. at 79-215 (applying the Median Voter theorem to develop a formal model of strategic decision making on the Supreme Court); Epstein & Jacobi, supra note 18, at 44-49 (same).
  • 26
    • 68349103610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Krehbiel, supra note 16, at 232-36; Bryon J. Moraski & Charles R. Shipan, The Politics of Supreme Court Nominations: A Theory of Institutional Constraints and Choices, 43 AM. J. POL. SCI. 1069, 1072-73 (1999); David W. Rohde & Kenneth A. Shepsle, Advising and Consenting on the 60-Vote Senate: Strategic Appointments to the Supreme Court, 69 J. POL. 664, 666-67 (2007).
    • See, e.g., Krehbiel, supra note 16, at 232-36; Bryon J. Moraski & Charles R. Shipan, The Politics of Supreme Court Nominations: A Theory of Institutional Constraints and Choices, 43 AM. J. POL. SCI. 1069, 1072-73 (1999); David W. Rohde & Kenneth A. Shepsle, Advising and Consenting on the 60-Vote Senate: Strategic Appointments to the Supreme Court, 69 J. POL. 664, 666-67 (2007).
  • 27
    • 84869591943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IΠ.A (explaining the role of the Median Voter approach in Supreme Court decision making).
    • See infra Part IΠ.A (explaining the role of the Median Voter approach in Supreme Court decision making).
  • 28
    • 68249159705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ward Farnsworth, Dissents Against Type, 93 MINN. L. REV. 1535, 1536-37 (2009) (noting how most legal realists assume that judges vote according to their policy preferences); Lewis A. Kornhauser, Appeal and Supreme Courts, in VII ENCYCLOPEDIA LAW AND ECONOMICS, CIVIL AND CRIMINAL PROCEDURE 45, 54, 57 (2000), available at http://encyclo. findlaw.com/7200book.pdf (noting in a survey of economic literature on judicial appeals and collegίality of courts that various authors assume judges have an ideal or most-preferred policy).
    • See, e.g., Ward Farnsworth, Dissents Against Type, 93 MINN. L. REV. 1535, 1536-37 (2009) (noting how most legal realists assume that judges vote according to their policy preferences); Lewis A. Kornhauser, Appeal and Supreme Courts, in VII ENCYCLOPEDIA LAW AND ECONOMICS, CIVIL AND CRIMINAL PROCEDURE 45, 54, 57 (2000), available at http://encyclo. findlaw.com/7200book.pdf (noting in a survey of economic literature on judicial appeals and collegίality of courts that various authors assume judges have an ideal or most-preferred policy).
  • 29
    • 68349119624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 28, at, 57 noting that a majority of Supreme Court decision-making theories assume that judges have policy preferences
    • See Kornhauser, supra note 28, at 54, 57 (noting that a majority of Supreme Court decision-making theories assume that judges have policy preferences).
    • supra , pp. 54
    • Kornhauser1
  • 30
    • 24944484789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Daniel R. Pinello, Linking Party to Judicial Ideology in American Courts: A Meta-Analysis, 20 JUST. SYS. J. 219, 221, 240-43 (1999) (analyzing numerous empirical studies that have sought to connect party identification with judicial ideology and concluding that political party affiliation is a dependable measure of ideology in modern American courts).
    • See Daniel R. Pinello, Linking Party to Judicial Ideology in American Courts: A Meta-Analysis, 20 JUST. SYS. J. 219, 221, 240-43 (1999) (analyzing numerous empirical studies that have sought to connect party identification with judicial ideology and concluding that political party affiliation "is a dependable measure of ideology in modern American courts").
  • 31
    • 68349088490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SPAETH, supra note 20
    • SPAETH, supra note 20.
  • 32
    • 68349106199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 53-55
    • Id. at 53-55.
  • 33
    • 0001567226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political Science and the New Legal Realism: A Case of Unfortunate Interdisciplinary Ignorance, 92
    • discussing Segal and Spaeth's use of the Judicial Database in designing their attitudinal model, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Frank B. Cross, Political Science and the New Legal Realism: A Case of Unfortunate Interdisciplinary Ignorance, 92 Nw. U. L. REV. 251, 252, 303 (1997) (discussing Segal and Spaeth's use of the Judicial Database in designing their attitudinal model).
    • (1997) Nw. U. L. REV , vol.251 , Issue.252 , pp. 303
    • Cross, F.B.1
  • 34
    • 26844452938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Joseph Bafumi et al, Practical Issues In Implementing and Understanding Bayesian Ideal Point Estimation, 13 POL. ANALYSIS 171, 171-87 (2005, Michael A. Bailey, Comparable Preference Estimates Across Time and Institutions for the Court, Congress, and Presidency, 51 AM. J. POL. SCI. 433 (2007, Grofman & Brazill, supra note 16, at 55-73; Andrew D. Martin & Kevin M. Quinn, Dynamic Ideal Point Estimation via Markov Chain Monte Carlo for the U.S. Supreme Court, 1953-1999, 10 POL. ANALYSIS 134 (2002, In fact, the scaling methods were originally developed by psychologists to infer latent variables like respondent ability (for example, IQ, based on test performance. See, e.g, R. Darrell Bock, A Brief History of Item Response Theory, 16 EDUC. MEASUREMENT: ISSUES AND PRACTICE 21, 21-33 1997, From the perspective of so-called item res
    • See Joseph Bafumi et al., Practical Issues In Implementing and Understanding Bayesian Ideal Point Estimation, 13 POL. ANALYSIS 171, 171-87 (2005); Michael A. Bailey, Comparable Preference Estimates Across Time and Institutions for the Court, Congress, and Presidency, 51 AM. J. POL. SCI. 433 (2007); Grofman & Brazill, supra note 16, at 55-73; Andrew D. Martin & Kevin M. Quinn, Dynamic Ideal Point Estimation via Markov Chain Monte Carlo for the U.S. Supreme Court, 1953-1999, 10 POL. ANALYSIS 134 (2002). In fact, the scaling methods were originally developed by psychologists to infer latent variables like respondent ability (for example, IQ), based on test performance. See, e.g, R. Darrell Bock, A Brief History of Item Response Theory, 16 EDUC. MEASUREMENT: ISSUES AND PRACTICE 21, 21-33 (1997). From the perspective of so-called "item response theory, " each case is equivalent to a test question, a dispositional vote is equivalent to an answer to the question, and the inferred Justice ideology is equivalent to the respondent's ability. See id. A given answer is not assumed to be correct or incorrect, but rather it is assumed that discriminating questions can differentiate liberal and conservative answers. See id.
  • 35
    • 68349114195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bailey, supra note 34, at 434; Martin & Quinn, supra note 34, at 145-47.
    • See Bailey, supra note 34, at 434; Martin & Quinn, supra note 34, at 145-47.
  • 36
    • 68349087323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Farnsworth, supra note 15, passim
    • See Farnsworth, supra note 15, passim.
  • 37
    • 68349099364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1892-94.
    • See id. at 1892-94.
  • 38
    • 84922070147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 34, at fig.2
    • See Bailey, supra note 34, at 435 fig.2.
    • supra , pp. 435
    • Bailey1
  • 39
    • 68349118453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In similar fashion, the latent respondent ability measures recovered by item response theory typically correlate at .95 or better with the simple percentage of correct answers on the test
    • In similar fashion, the latent respondent ability measures recovered by item response theory typically correlate at .95 or better with the simple percentage of correct answers on the test.
  • 40
    • 68349105426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Farnsworth, supra note 15, at 1892-94 (The Martin-Quinn method keeps track of only one thing: whether a Justice voted to affirm or reverse a case.); Martin & Quinn, supra note 34, at 137. One must make a few other assumptions to tie down the direction of the scale, for example, by assuming that a well-known liberal like William Douglas identifies the liberal end of the scale.
    • See Farnsworth, supra note 15, at 1892-94 ("The Martin-Quinn method keeps track of only one thing: whether a Justice voted to affirm or reverse a case."); Martin & Quinn, supra note 34, at 137. One must make a few other assumptions to tie down the direction of the scale, for example, by assuming that a well-known liberal like William Douglas identifies the liberal end of the scale.
  • 41
    • 68349122002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Martin & Quinn, supra note 34, at 137
    • See Martin & Quinn, supra note 34, at 137.
  • 42
    • 68349087322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bailey, supra note 34, at 434. These assumptions include: no strategic voting on case dispositions, an unchanging mix of cases on the docket, no response by the Justices to outside pressure such as court-curbing legislation, and invariance of the scale to the entry and exit of Justices, among others.
    • See Bailey, supra note 34, at 434. These assumptions include: no strategic voting on case dispositions, an unchanging mix of cases on the docket, no response by the Justices to outside pressure such as court-curbing legislation, and invariance of the scale to the entry and exit of Justices, among others.
  • 43
    • 84869582934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Martin and Quinn have calculated yearly scores. See Martin & Quinn, supra note 34, at 146 tbl.l (reporting posterior density of ideal points of U.S. Supreme Court Justices, 1953-1999, for the constant ideal point model, But these scores are extremely unstable, and we doubt they provide much useful information beyond the lifetime scores. Michael Bailey has estimated similar scores. See Bailey, supra note 34. The Bailey scores are stabilized through bridging techniques used to link actors across time and institutions. Id. at 433-34 explaining data observations and measures used in the methodology, When Bailey's scores are averaged over the two natural courts, they present a picture similar to the lifetime MQ scores and the court-specific percent liberal voting scores. These averages can be calculated from data at
    • Martin and Quinn have calculated yearly scores. See Martin & Quinn, supra note 34, at 146 tbl.l (reporting posterior density of ideal points of U.S. Supreme Court Justices, 1953-1999, for the constant ideal point model). But these scores are extremely unstable, and we doubt they provide much useful information beyond the lifetime scores. Michael Bailey has estimated similar scores. See Bailey, supra note 34. The Bailey scores are stabilized through "bridging techniques" used to "link actors across time and institutions." Id. at 433-34 (explaining data observations and measures used in the methodology). When Bailey's scores are averaged over the two natural courts, they present a picture similar to the lifetime MQ scores and the court-specific percent liberal voting scores. These averages can be calculated from data at http://www.georgetown.edu/ faculty/baileyma/Data.htm.
  • 44
    • 68349118455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cardinal scores for extreme Justices (i.e., Rehnquist and Marshall) can be particularly problematic since by definition there is no more extreme Justice with which to contrast the extremists' voting behavior. As a result, the scaling methods have a hard time pinning down these Justices' scores very precisely.
    • Cardinal scores for extreme Justices (i.e., Rehnquist and Marshall) can be particularly problematic since by definition there is no more extreme Justice with which to contrast the extremists' voting behavior. As a result, the scaling methods have a hard time pinning down these Justices' scores very precisely.
  • 45
    • 68349103612 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally LEE EPSTEIN & JACK KNIGHT, THE CHOICES JUSTICES MAKE (1997) (providing a strategic model of judicial behavior premised on the theory that Justices' votes are shaped by external factors as well as policy preferences); SEGAL & SPAETH, supra note 22 (developing a behavioral model based on the presupposition that Justices' votes are the product of their policy preferences).
    • See generally LEE EPSTEIN & JACK KNIGHT, THE CHOICES JUSTICES MAKE (1997) (providing a strategic model of judicial behavior premised on the theory that Justices' votes are shaped by external factors as well as policy preferences); SEGAL & SPAETH, supra note 22 (developing a behavioral model based on the presupposition that Justices' votes are the product of their policy preferences).
  • 46
    • 84869554129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Theories of Supreme Court decision making can be tested indirectly, for example, by examining predicted patterns of opinion assignment, see Jeffrey R. Lax & Charles M. Cameron, Bargaining and Opinion Assignment on the Supreme Court, 23 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 276 (2007), or by examining patterns in vote fluidity, Jeffrey R. Lax & Kelly T. Rader, Legal Constraints on Supreme Court Decision Making: Do Jurisprudential Regimes Exist?, 71 J. POL. (forthcoming 2009) (manuscript at 2-4), available at http://www.columbia.edu/̃jrl2124/Random%20Regimes.pdf. We, however, emphasize opinion content because our focus is on policy content.
    • Theories of Supreme Court decision making can be tested indirectly, for example, by examining predicted patterns of opinion assignment, see Jeffrey R. Lax & Charles M. Cameron, Bargaining and Opinion Assignment on the Supreme Court, 23 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 276 (2007), or by examining patterns in vote fluidity, Jeffrey R. Lax & Kelly T. Rader, Legal Constraints on Supreme Court Decision Making: Do Jurisprudential Regimes Exist?, 71 J. POL. (forthcoming 2009) (manuscript at 2-4), available at http://www.columbia.edu/̃jrl2124/Random%20Regimes.pdf. We, however, emphasize opinion content because our focus is on policy content.
  • 47
    • 68349091894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JEFFREY ALLAN SEGAL, PREDICTING SUPREME COURT CASES PROBABILISTICALLY: THE SEARCH AND SEIZURE CASES, 1962-1981, at 3-15 (1983).
    • See, e.g., JEFFREY ALLAN SEGAL, PREDICTING SUPREME COURT CASES PROBABILISTICALLY: THE SEARCH AND SEIZURE CASES, 1962-1981, at 3-15 (1983).
  • 48
    • 68349093210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.; Lax & Rader, supra note 46 (manuscript at 4, 20-21).
    • Id.; Lax & Rader, supra note 46 (manuscript at 4, 20-21).
  • 49
    • 0036592680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mark J. Richards & Herbert M. Kritzer, Jurisprudential Regimes in Supreme Court Decision Making, 96 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 305, 305-06 (2002) (positing that changes in the law form different jurisprudential regimes that influence relevant decision-making processes).
    • Mark J. Richards & Herbert M. Kritzer, Jurisprudential Regimes in Supreme Court Decision Making, 96 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 305, 305-06 (2002) (positing that changes in the law form different "jurisprudential regimes" that influence relevant decision-making processes).
  • 50
    • 68349113059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lax & Rader, supra note 46 (manuscript at 3-5).
    • See Lax & Rader, supra note 46 (manuscript at 3-5).
  • 51
    • 68349115406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jonathan P. Kastellec, The Structure of Legal Rules and the Analysis of Judicial Decisions 4-13 (Jan. 30, 2007) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=960190#.
    • Jonathan P. Kastellec, The Structure of Legal Rules and the Analysis of Judicial Decisions 4-13 (Jan. 30, 2007) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=960190#.
  • 52
    • 84869580607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tom S. Clark & Benjamin Lauderdale, Locating Supreme Court Opinions in Doctrine Space (Mar. 23, 2009) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://userwww.service.emory.edu/̃tclark7/doctrine.pdf.
    • Tom S. Clark & Benjamin Lauderdale, Locating Supreme Court Opinions in Doctrine Space (Mar. 23, 2009) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://userwww.service.emory.edu/̃tclark7/doctrine.pdf.
  • 53
    • 68349117691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 6-11
    • Id. at 6-11.
  • 54
    • 68349116565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11-15; see also infra Part III.
    • Id. at 11-15; see also infra Part III.
  • 55
    • 68349111204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clark & Lauderdale, supra note 52, at 18-21
    • Clark & Lauderdale, supra note 52, at 18-21.
  • 56
    • 68349115407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 57
    • 68349102449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ([The] results represent considerable evidence in support of the coalition median model, at least relative to the median justice and author monopoly models.).
    • Id. ("[The] results represent considerable evidence in support of the coalition median model, at least relative to the median justice and author monopoly models.").
  • 58
    • 33846467857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part III
    • See infra Part III.
    • See infra
  • 59
    • 68349095586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Precursor ideas can be found in Chad Westerland, Who Owns the Majority Opinion? An Examination of Policy Making on the U.S. Supreme Court (Aug. 29, 2003) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.allacademic.com/ meta/p62042-index.html, and Cliff Carrubba et al., Does the Median Justice Control the Content of Supreme Court Opinions? (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.law.nyu.edu/ecm-dlv/groups/public/nyu-law- website-academics-colloquia-law-economics-and-politics/documents/documen ts/ ecm-pro-059079.pdf. We do not fully pursue these precursor ideas in this Article.
    • Precursor ideas can be found in Chad Westerland, Who Owns the Majority Opinion? An Examination of Policy Making on the U.S. Supreme Court (Aug. 29, 2003) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.allacademic.com/ meta/p62042-index.html, and Cliff Carrubba et al., Does the Median Justice Control the Content of Supreme Court Opinions? (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.law.nyu.edu/ecm-dlv/groups/public/nyu-law- website-academics-colloquia-law-economics-and-politics/documents/documents/ ecm-pro-059079.pdf. We do not fully pursue these precursor ideas in this Article.
  • 60
    • 68349091895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charles M. Cameron & Lewis A. Kornhauser, Modeling Collegial Courts (3): Judicial Objectives, Opinion Content, Voting and Adjudication Equilibria (L. & Econ. Res. Paper Series, Working Paper No. 08-54, 2008), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id= 1296071.
    • Charles M. Cameron & Lewis A. Kornhauser, Modeling Collegial Courts (3): Judicial Objectives, Opinion Content, Voting and Adjudication Equilibria (L. & Econ. Res. Paper Series, Working Paper No. 08-54, 2008), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id= 1296071.
  • 61
    • 68349106200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see, for example, Bush v. Vera, 517 U.S. 952, 956, 990 (1996), where Justice O'Connor announced the judgment of the Court, wrote a first opinion joined by Chief Justice Rehnquist and Justice Kennedy, and then wrote a second, unjoined concurring opinion.
    • But see, for example, Bush v. Vera, 517 U.S. 952, 956, 990 (1996), where Justice O'Connor announced the judgment of the Court, wrote a first opinion joined by Chief Justice Rehnquist and Justice Kennedy, and then wrote a second, unjoined concurring opinion.
  • 62
    • 68349083895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The simple version of the join technology used here also assumes similar underlying join behavior by the Justices. If a particular Justice displayed idiosyncratic join tendencies-high or low-it would make detection of the most likely opinion location more difficult. Sophisticated statistical methods offer hope of a fix-up to this problem, but we do not pursue this point any further here
    • The simple version of the join technology used here also assumes similar underlying join behavior by the Justices. If a particular Justice displayed idiosyncratic join tendencies-high or low-it would make detection of the most likely opinion location more difficult. Sophisticated statistical methods offer hope of a "fix-up" to this problem, but we do not pursue this point any further here.
  • 63
    • 68349087325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally EPSTEIN ET AL., supra note 19 (calculating many voting indices based on dispositional votes).
    • See generally EPSTEIN ET AL., supra note 19 (calculating many voting indices based on dispositional votes).
  • 64
    • 68349114194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An important precursor to contemporary theory is Edward P. Schwartz, Policy, Precedent, and Power: A Positive Theory of Supreme Court Decision-Making, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 219 (1992, which first attempted to adapt median voter models to collegial courts, id. at 219-21. Another important precursor is Lewis A. Kornhauser, Modeling Collegial Courts. II. Legal Doctrine, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 441 1992, which created a framework, adopted in much recent work, that allows one to distinguish case locations, case dispositions, and opinion content. See id. at 443-59
    • An important precursor to contemporary theory is Edward P. Schwartz, Policy, Precedent, and Power: A Positive Theory of Supreme Court Decision-Making, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 219 (1992), which first attempted to adapt median voter models to collegial courts, id. at 219-21. Another important precursor is Lewis A. Kornhauser, Modeling Collegial Courts. II. Legal Doctrine, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 441 (1992), which created a framework, adopted in much recent work, that allows one to distinguish case locations, case dispositions, and opinion content. See id. at 443-59.
  • 65
    • 68349100582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24; Lax & Cameron, supra note 46. In essence, the theory argues that the Supreme Court is like the floor of Congress (open-rule). Id. at 276.
    • See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24; Lax & Cameron, supra note 46. In essence, the theory argues that the Supreme Court is like the floor of Congress (open-rule). Id. at 276.
  • 67
    • 68349114196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24; Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60; Lax & Cameron, supra note 46. In this model, the Supreme Court is like the closed-rule floor of Congress, where time limits are set on debate and no amendments may be made from the floor. Id. at 276-77.
    • See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24; Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60; Lax & Cameron, supra note 46. In this model, the Supreme Court is like the closed-rule floor of Congress, where time limits are set on debate and no amendments may be made from the floor. Id. at 276-77.
  • 68
    • 70350024746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 46. Here, writing costs afford the author some monopoly power. Id. at
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46. Here, writing costs afford the author some monopoly power. Id. at 276-80.
    • supra , pp. 276-280
    • Lax1    Cameron2
  • 69
    • 68349111203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 60, this model, authors like proximate opinions but seek joins. Id. at
    • See Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60. In this model, authors like proximate opinions but seek joins. Id. at 13.
    • supra , pp. 13
    • Cameron1    Kornhauser2
  • 70
    • 68349089640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PETER C. OKDESHOOK, A POLITICAL THEORY PRIMER 80-86 (1992) (providing a description of the conditions under which voting rules select a Condorcet winner).
    • See PETER C. OKDESHOOK, A POLITICAL THEORY PRIMER 80-86 (1992) (providing a description of the conditions under which voting rules select a Condorcet winner).
  • 71
    • 68349100581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24 (applying the MV model directly to the study of judicial decision making). The MV approach also emerges as a special case in several other models of the Supreme Court. See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 26-28 (explaining that the MV model emerges when the case disposition is unanimous); Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 279-83 (recognizing that the MV model emerges when authoring costs are zero).
    • See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24 (applying the MV model directly to the study of judicial decision making). The MV approach also emerges as a special case in several other models of the Supreme Court. See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 26-28 (explaining that the MV model emerges when the case disposition is unanimous); Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 279-83 (recognizing that the MV model emerges when authoring costs are zero).
  • 72
    • 0030306456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 3 ([C]onsiderable empirical evidence reveals the influential position of the median in legislative settings.). The MV theorem does not require an actual dynamic process, as the players may be able to identify the Condorcet proposal and offer it immediately. See David P. Baron, A Dynamic Theory of Collective Goods Programs, 90 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 316, 316-30 (1996) (detailing a dynamic version of the MV model).
    • See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 3 ("[C]onsiderable empirical evidence reveals the influential position of the median in legislative settings."). The MV theorem does not require an actual dynamic process, as the players may be able to identify the Condorcet proposal and offer it immediately. See David P. Baron, A Dynamic Theory of Collective Goods Programs, 90 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 316, 316-30 (1996) (detailing a dynamic version of the MV model).
  • 73
    • 68349107322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, the MV approach laid out by Hammond et al. does not distinguish between joins and concurrences; case location likewise plays no role in the model. See HAMMOND ET AL, supra note 24, at 260. This is not surprising as the standard MV model was originally developed to study settings like committees or legislatures, in which policymaking does not involve dispute resolution. See id. at 75 recognizing that much of the original research in-volve[d] research on committee decision-making by majority rule, Carrubba et al, supra note 59, at 1, C]onsiderable empirical evidence reveals the influential position of the median voter in legislative settings, The MV approach emerges as a special case in the Entry Blocking model, which does generate case dispositions. See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 279-83. But that model portrays dispositions as wholly incidental to opini
    • Indeed, the MV approach laid out by Hammond et al. does not distinguish between joins and concurrences; case location likewise plays no role in the model. See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24, at 260. This is not surprising as the standard MV model was originally developed to study settings like committees or legislatures, in which policymaking does not involve dispute resolution. See id. at 75 (recognizing that much of the original research "in-volve[d] research on committee decision-making by majority rule"); Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 1 ("[C]onsiderable empirical evidence reveals the influential position of the median voter in legislative settings."). The MV approach emerges as a special case in the Entry Blocking model, which does generate case dispositions. See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 279-83. But that model portrays dispositions as wholly incidental to opinion location; opinion location is taken as central. Id.
  • 74
    • 68349116566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 15-20 (If judicial decisions . . . involve a single, dominant dimension, a straightforward application of the median-voter theorem suggests that the median justice should exercise decisive influence over the content of opinions.).
    • See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 15-20 ("If judicial decisions . . . involve a single, dominant dimension, a straightforward application of the median-voter theorem suggests that the median justice should exercise decisive influence over the content of opinions.").
  • 75
    • 68349091896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Grofman & Brazill, supra note 16, at 58-63 (stating that the identity of the median justice is frequently shifting).
    • See Grofman & Brazill, supra note 16, at 58-63 (stating that the "identity of the median justice is frequently shifting").
  • 76
    • 68349122000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 77
    • 68349086152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 16, at, describing the effect of a new member on the location of the median voter
    • See Krehbiel, supra note 16, at 233 (describing the effect of a new member on the location of the median voter).
    • supra , pp. 233
    • Krehbiel1
  • 79
    • 68349094413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Grofman & Brazill, supra note 16, at 58-63
    • See Grofman & Brazill, supra note 16, at 58-63.
  • 80
    • 68349123030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 81
    • 68349095587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Krehbiel, supra note 16, at 234 (noting that a new Justice on the Court will often not change the Court's median).
    • See Krehbiel, supra note 16, at 234 (noting that a new Justice on the Court will often not change the Court's median).
  • 82
    • 68349087327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 2, 15-20 (laying out the foundational analysis for the MM approach); Westerland, supra note 59, at 8 (speculating prior to Carrubba et al.'s work that such a theory could exist and might be useful in studying the Court).
    • See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 2, 15-20 (laying out the foundational analysis for the MM approach); Westerland, supra note 59, at 8 (speculating prior to Carrubba et al.'s work that such a theory could exist and might be useful in studying the Court).
  • 83
    • 68349093208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 9 (recognizing that the MM model assume[s] that the justices care about the disposition of the case).
    • See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 9 (recognizing that the MM model "assume[s] that the justices care about the disposition of the case").
  • 84
    • 68349108924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. at 5 ([A] justice will not be indifferent as to a rule that is a bit more conservative .. . [or] liberal than she would like but yields the opposite outcome in that particular case.).
    • See, e.g., id. at 5 ("[A] justice will not be indifferent as to a rule that is a bit more conservative .. . [or] liberal than she would like but yields the opposite outcome in that particular case.").
  • 85
    • 68349103597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at, B]argaining over the majority opinion proceeds only among the justices who prefer the disposition adopted by the majority
    • See id. at 15 ("[B]argaining over the majority opinion proceeds only among the justices who prefer the disposition adopted by the majority.").
    • See id , pp. 15
  • 86
    • 68349085052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 12 (Switching sides would require the justices to support a disposition with which they disagree, and they are not willing to do so if they care enough about the disposition. (citation omitted)).
    • See id. at 12 ("Switching sides would require the justices to support a disposition with which they disagree, and they are not willing to do so if they care enough about the disposition." (citation omitted)).
  • 87
    • 68349110058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 7 ([0]ur model predicts that median members of the majority coalition will have disproportional influence over the content of opinions.); see also Westerland, supra note 59, at 14 (Disagreements about the outcome of a case preclude agreement on the majority opinion, which means the majority coalition could be an autonomous bargaining unit.).
    • See id. at 7 ("[0]ur model predicts that median members of the majority coalition will have disproportional influence over the content of opinions."); see also Westerland, supra note 59, at 14 ("Disagreements about the outcome of a case preclude agreement on the majority opinion, which means the majority coalition could be an autonomous bargaining unit.").
  • 88
    • 68349090788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 1 (|T]he median justice typically does not determine the content of Supreme Court decisions.); Grofman & Brazill, supra note 16, at 58-63 (noting that the identity of the median justice is frequently shifting).
    • See Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 1 ("|T]he median justice typically does not determine the content of Supreme Court decisions."); Grofman & Brazill, supra note 16, at 58-63 (noting that the "identity of the median justice is frequently shifting").
  • 89
    • 68349099365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Westerland, supra note 59, at 16 (The only way an opinion author can protect against an opinion from within the majority coalition that is more preferable to a majority of justices in the coalition is to write the opinion at the median of the majority coalition.).
    • See Westerland, supra note 59, at 16 ("The only way an opinion author can protect against an opinion from within the majority coalition that is more preferable to a majority of justices in the coalition is to write the opinion at the median of the majority coalition.").
  • 90
    • 68349108463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The author-opinion diagram for any other connected disposition coalition (say, 7-2, composed of the first seven Justices in the majority and Burger and Rehnquist in the minority) would be a horizontal line, as in Figure 3, but located at the predicted location for that coalition shown in Figure 4.
    • The author-opinion diagram for any other "connected" disposition coalition (say, 7-2, composed of the first seven Justices in the majority and Burger and Rehnquist in the minority) would be a horizontal line, as in Figure 3, but located at the predicted location for that coalition shown in Figure 4.
  • 91
    • 68349113060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The data in the table do not distinguish between a 7-2 and 2-7 coalition, and concern only those cases in which all nine Justices participated.
    • The data in the table do not distinguish between a 7-2 and 2-7 coalition, and concern only those cases in which all nine Justices participated.
  • 92
    • 68349100586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HAMMOND ET AL, supra note 24, at 110
    • See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24, at 110.
  • 93
    • 0001887423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60, at 23. The MA approach has a historic connection with the so-called attitudinal model of Segal and Spaeth, which asserts that Justices are free to vote or write opinions as they please. See generally SEGAL & SPAETH, supra note 22. Unlike the attitudinal model, however, the MA approach is a theory of Supreme Court decision making. Consequently, the individual behavior asserted by Segal and Spaeth must emerge endogenously in a bargaining game played by the Justices. Hammond et al. root one version of the MA approach in a well-known model of take-it-or-leave-it bargaining. See HAMMOND ET AL, supra note 24, at 111; see also Tho-mas Romer & Howard Rosenthal, Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas, and the Status Quo, 33 PUB. CHOICE 27, 27-29 1978, The Entry Blocking model contains the M
    • See Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60, at 23. The MA approach has a historic connection with the so-called attitudinal model of Segal and Spaeth, which asserts that Justices are free to vote or write opinions as they please. See generally SEGAL & SPAETH, supra note 22. Unlike the attitudinal model, however, the MA approach is a theory of Supreme Court decision making. Consequently, the individual behavior asserted by Segal and Spaeth must emerge endogenously in a bargaining game played by the Justices. Hammond et al. root one version of the MA approach in a well-known model of take-it-or-leave-it bargaining. See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24, at 111; see also Tho-mas Romer & Howard Rosenthal, Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas, and the Status Quo, 33 PUB. CHOICE 27, 27-29 (1978). The Entry Blocking model contains the MA approach as a special case, when entry costs for authors other than the designated author are very high. See infra Part III.D. The Gravitational Attraction model also yields an MA result as a special case, when an opinion author is centrally located within a dense cluster of ideal points. See infra Part III.E.
  • 94
    • 68349100583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60, at 23.
    • Cf. Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60, at 23.
  • 95
    • 68349122001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 292 (If the Chief Justice is a member of the initial majority coalition (empirically, this is by far the most common occurrence), he/she assigns the opinion; if not, the senior justice in the majority does so.).
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 292 ("If the Chief Justice is a member of the initial majority coalition (empirically, this is by far the most common occurrence), he/she assigns the opinion; if not, the senior justice in the majority does so.").
  • 96
    • 68349123028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24, at 66-67; Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 278-80.
    • See HAMMOND ET AL., supra note 24, at 66-67; Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 278-80.
  • 97
    • 68349088491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 279 (defining legal quality as clarity, persuasiveness, completeness, or craftsmanship).
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 279 (defining legal quality as "clarity, persuasiveness, completeness, or craftsmanship").
  • 98
    • 68349090787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 295 ([E]ach justice must decide how to allocate effort across all the cases in his/her current portfolio of cases, and the Chief or other justice who assigns an opinion must consider the consequences of a heavier workload not only for the resolution of the instant case but also for all the others in the assignee's portfolio.).
    • See id. at 295 ("[E]ach justice must decide how to allocate effort across all the cases in his/her current portfolio of cases, and the Chief or other justice who assigns an opinion must consider the consequences of a heavier workload not only for the resolution of the instant case but also for all the others in the assignee's portfolio.").
  • 99
    • 68349086153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 276. But see Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 5 (arguing that the requirement that the Court produce not only a judgment affirming or rejecting the lower court's position but also a new judicial rule, will drive a wedge between the content of opinions and the preferred position of the median justice).
    • See id. at 276. But see Carrubba et al., supra note 59, at 5 (arguing that the requirement that the Court produce not only a judgment affirming or rejecting the lower court's position but also a new judicial rule, will "drive a wedge between the content of opinions and the preferred position of the median justice").
  • 100
    • 68349120809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 276
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 276.
  • 101
    • 68349105427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 288.
    • See id. at 288.
  • 102
    • 68349083896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The EB model makes particularly clear predictions about the quality of opinions, as a function of the author's ideal point and other variables. See id. at 282. We cannot address these predictions here, however
    • The EB model makes particularly clear predictions about the quality of opinions, as a function of the author's ideal point and other variables. See id. at 282. We cannot address these predictions here, however.
  • 103
    • 68349108464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, Segal and Spaeth demonstrated how the appointment of Thurgood Marshall solidified the liberal cohesion of the Warren Court. See Harold J. Spaeth & Jeffrey A. Segal, Decisional Trends on the Warren and Burger Courts: Results from the Supreme Court Data Base Project, 73 JUDICATURE 103, 107 (1989). Conversely, the substitution of Clarence Thomas for Thurgood Marshall moved the Rehnquist Court to the right-but not enough to make it a coherent Court. Neal Devins, Ideological Cohesion and Precedent (or Why the Court Only Cares About Precedent When Most Justices Agree with Each Other), 86 N.C. L. REV. 1399, 1404 (2008).
    • For example, Segal and Spaeth demonstrated how the appointment of Thurgood Marshall solidified the liberal cohesion of the Warren Court. See Harold J. Spaeth & Jeffrey A. Segal, Decisional Trends on the Warren and Burger Courts: Results from the Supreme Court Data Base Project, 73 JUDICATURE 103, 107 (1989). Conversely, "the substitution of Clarence Thomas for Thurgood Marshall moved the Rehnquist Court to the right-but not enough to make it a coherent Court." Neal Devins, Ideological Cohesion and Precedent (or Why the Court Only Cares About Precedent When Most Justices Agree with Each Other), 86 N.C. L. REV. 1399, 1404 (2008).
  • 104
    • 68349110059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 287 (postulating that since [e]very nonmedian opinion is vulnerable to some counteroffer, an opinion writer must be as concerned with the stability of his or her opinion-that is, its proximity to the median-as with quality and precedent).
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 287 (postulating that since "[e]very nonmedian opinion is vulnerable to some counteroffer, " an opinion writer must be as concerned with the stability of his or her opinion-that is, its proximity to the median-as with quality and precedent).
  • 105
    • 68349120810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 277.
    • See id. at 277.
  • 106
    • 68349088493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60, at 11
    • See Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60, at 11.
  • 107
    • 68349113062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 30
    • See id. at 30.
  • 108
    • 68349100584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Mathematica computer code used to generate these estimates is available on request from the authors. By moderate values we mean nonzero but not huge writing costs, and non-zero but not overwhelming importance of case clarity. In the example, case disposition value is set to zero, as would hold not only for extreme case locations resulting in a unanimous disposition, but presumably for many or even most cases heard by the Supreme Court
    • The Mathematica computer code used to generate these estimates is available on request from the authors. By "moderate" values we mean nonzero but not huge writing costs, and non-zero but not overwhelming importance of case clarity. In the example, case disposition value is set to zero, as would hold not only for extreme case locations resulting in a unanimous disposition, but presumably for many or even most cases heard by the Supreme Court.
  • 110
    • 68349105428 scopus 로고
    • Potter Stewart, 95
    • See
    • See Terrance Sandalow, Potter Stewart, 95 HARV. L. REV. 6, 6 (1981).
    • (1981) HARV. L. REV , vol.6 , pp. 6
    • Sandalow, T.1
  • 111
    • 68349089641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 8-9.
    • See id. at 8-9.
  • 112
    • 68349111921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also supra tbl.l.
    • See also supra tbl.l.
  • 113
    • 68349123027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 453 U.S. III (1981); fig.8.
    • See 453 U.S. III (1981); fig.8.
  • 114
    • 68349090786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEE HENRY J. ABRAHAM, JUSTICES, PRESIDENTS, AND SENATORS: A HISTORY OF THE U.S. SUPREME COURT APPOINTMENTS FROM WASHINGTON TO CLINTON 256 (1999).
    • SEE HENRY J. ABRAHAM, JUSTICES, PRESIDENTS, AND SENATORS: A HISTORY OF THE U.S. SUPREME COURT APPOINTMENTS FROM WASHINGTON TO CLINTON 256 (1999).
  • 115
    • 68349097894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 255.
    • See id. at 255.
  • 116
    • 68349118454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra fig.8.
    • See supra fig.8.
  • 117
    • 68349110060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra tbl.3.
    • See infra tbl.3.
  • 118
    • 84869556172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part IΠ.C and fig.5.
    • See supra Part IΠ.C and fig.5.
  • 119
    • 68349087326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We score liberals as those with MQ scores less than-.33 (Marshall, Brennan, and Stevens); moderates as those with MQ scores between-.33 and .33 (Blackmun and White); and conservatives as those with scores greater than .33 (Powell, Burger, and Rehnquist).
    • We score liberals as those with MQ scores less than-.33 (Marshall, Brennan, and Stevens); moderates as those with MQ scores between-.33 and .33 (Blackmun and White); and conservatives as those with scores greater than .33 (Powell, Burger, and Rehnquist).
  • 120
    • 68349111920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60, at 30
    • See Cameron & Kornhauser, supra note 60, at 30.
  • 121
    • 68349115408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Lax & Cameron, supra note 46 (hypothesizing that subtle variables such as policy content, writing costs, legal quality, and agenda-setting are crucial considerations in the bargaining and opinion assignment process).
    • See generally Lax & Cameron, supra note 46 (hypothesizing that subtle variables such as policy content, writing costs, legal quality, and agenda-setting are crucial considerations in the bargaining and opinion assignment process).
  • 122
    • 68349110061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We score Justice Blackmun's locations according to the discussion in Part II.
    • We score Justice Blackmun's locations according to the discussion in Part II.
  • 124
    • 68349096728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is a loess regression with spans of one-half and two-thirds for Burger 6 and Burger 7, respectively. These spans somewhat smooth the data but allow their local shapes to remain. For an explanation of nonparametric regression, loess regression, and weighted regression, see DAVID HAND ET AL, PRINCIPLES OF DATA MINING 175-77 2001
    • This is a "loess" regression with spans of one-half and two-thirds for Burger 6 and Burger 7, respectively. These spans somewhat smooth the data but allow their local shapes to remain. For an explanation of nonparametric regression, loess regression, and weighted regression, see DAVID HAND ET AL., PRINCIPLES OF DATA MINING 175-77 (2001).
  • 125
    • 68349100585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 292
    • See Lax & Cameron, supra note 46, at 292.
  • 126
    • 68349088492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We write following the election of Democratic President Barack Ob-ama but before he has had an opportunity to nominate any Justices
    • We write following the election of Democratic President Barack Ob-ama but before he has had an opportunity to nominate any Justices.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.