메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 76, Issue 1, 2009, Pages 367-439

A market in litigation risk

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 66249127929     PISSN: 00419494     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Conference Paper
Times cited : (60)

References (191)
  • 1
    • 33846600262 scopus 로고
    • The Path of the Law, 10
    • O.W. Holmes, The Path of the Law, 10 Harv L Rev 457, 461 (1897).
    • (1897) Harv L Rev , vol.457 , pp. 461
    • Holmes, O.W.1
  • 2
    • 0347038981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Changes in the Legal Profession Reflect Changes in Civil Procedure, 84
    • See
    • See Jonathan T. Molot, How Changes in the Legal Profession Reflect Changes in Civil Procedure, 84 Va L Rev 955, 969 (1998).
    • (1998) Va L Rev , vol.955 , pp. 969
    • Molot, J.T.1
  • 3
    • 0347572360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Transactional Model of Adjudication. 89
    • See
    • See William B. Rubenstein, A Transactional Model of Adjudication. 89 Georgetown L J 371, 372 (2001);
    • (2001) Georgetown L J , vol.371 , pp. 372
    • Rubenstein, W.B.1
  • 5
    • 66249118121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also, 60 Fla L Rev 125, 140 , T]he dispute resolution process is an exercise in risk management wherein risk and return are traded
    • See also Robert J. Rhee. Tort Arbitrage, 60 Fla L Rev 125, 140 (2008) ("[T]he dispute resolution process is an exercise in risk management wherein risk and return are traded.").
    • (2008) Tort Arbitrage
    • Rhee, R.J.1
  • 6
    • 33748521982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Unexpected Value of Litigation: A Real Options Perspective, 58
    • Lawsuits and investment projects have much in common, See
    • See Joseph Grundfest and Peter Huang, The Unexpected Value of Litigation: A Real Options Perspective, 58 Stan L Rev 1267, 1269 (2006) ("Lawsuits and investment projects have much in common.").
    • (2006) Stan L Rev , vol.1267 , pp. 1269
    • Grundfest, J.1    Huang, P.2
  • 7
    • 66249144222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of changing attitudes toward legal risk management a generation ago, see Detlev F. Vagts, Legal Opinions in Quantitative Terms: The Lawyer As Haruspex or Bookie?, 34 Bus Lawyer 421, 421-29 (1979). For a discussion of just how unsophisticated the financial modeling of litigation remains when compared to the modeling of other business decisions, see Grundfest and Huang, 58 Stan L Rev at 1271 (cited in note 4).
    • For a discussion of changing attitudes toward legal risk management a generation ago, see Detlev F. Vagts, Legal Opinions in Quantitative Terms: The Lawyer As Haruspex or Bookie?, 34 Bus Lawyer 421, 421-29 (1979). For a discussion of just how unsophisticated the financial modeling of litigation remains when compared to the modeling of other business decisions, see Grundfest and Huang, 58 Stan L Rev at 1271 (cited in note 4).
  • 8
    • 66249140015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See notes 30-31 and accompanying text
    • See notes 30-31 and accompanying text.
  • 9
    • 66249086678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I do not weigh in on the question of how lawyers can best manage risk by reaching a cost-effective resolution with the opposing party. For a discussion of those issues, see Ronald J. Gilson and Robert H. Mnookin, Disputing through Agents: Cooperation and Conflict between Lawyers in Litigation, 94 Colum L Rev 509, 512 (1994, arguing that by applying their skills, lawyers can play an extraordinarily constructive role in disputes-as peacemakers who facilitate efficient and fair resolution of conflict when their clients do not do so for themselves);
    • I do not weigh in on the question of how lawyers can best manage risk by reaching a cost-effective resolution with the opposing party. For a discussion of those issues, see Ronald J. Gilson and Robert H. Mnookin, Disputing through Agents: Cooperation and Conflict between Lawyers in Litigation, 94 Colum L Rev 509, 512 (1994) (arguing that by applying their skills, lawyers "can play an extraordinarily constructive role in disputes-as peacemakers who facilitate efficient and fair resolution of conflict when their clients do not do so for themselves");
  • 11
    • 66249131791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Costs of Civil Justice, 80
    • In most cases, the plaintiff can sell res judicata only to the defendant, and the defendant can buy it only from the plaintiff, See
    • See Geoffrey Miller, On the Costs of Civil Justice, 80 Tex L Rev 2115, 2115 (2002) ("In most cases, the plaintiff can sell res judicata only to the defendant, and the defendant can buy it only from the plaintiff").
    • (2002) Tex L Rev , vol.2115 , pp. 2115
    • Miller, G.1
  • 12
    • 79956135915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See J.B. Heaton, The Risk Finance of Class Action Settlement Pressure, 4 J Risk Fin 75, 80 (Spring 2003) (explaining that while companies are better situated to bear the financial risk of litigation than typical defendants, they simply do not have the specialized and case-specific knowledge necessary to price the risk).
    • See J.B. Heaton, The Risk Finance of Class Action Settlement Pressure, 4 J Risk Fin 75, 80 (Spring 2003) (explaining that while companies are better situated to bear the financial risk of litigation than typical defendants, they "simply do not have the specialized and case-specific knowledge necessary to price the risk").
  • 13
    • 66249133147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also In re Rhone-Poulenc Rorer Inc, 51 F3d 1293, 1298 (7th Cir 1995) (discussing how the defendant, a large corporation, might be pressured to settle rather than contest plaintiffs' claims given the dramatic uncertainty with respect to the value of the final judgment);
    • See also In re Rhone-Poulenc Rorer Inc, 51 F3d 1293, 1298 (7th Cir 1995) (discussing how the defendant, a large corporation, might be pressured to settle rather than contest plaintiffs' claims given the dramatic uncertainty with respect to the value of the final judgment);
  • 16
    • 66249139337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at 26
    • See id at 26.
  • 17
    • 66249137905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at 27-28
    • See id at 27-28.
  • 18
    • 66249140349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at 39-67
    • See id at 39-67.
  • 20
    • 0347875874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Stephen B. Burbank and Linda J. SUberman, Civil Procedure Reform in Comparative Context: The United States of America, 45 Am J Comp L 675, 676 (1997) (Litigation reform efforts in the United States have sounded a consistent theme of the need to reduce expense and delay.).
    • See, for example, Stephen B. Burbank and Linda J. SUberman, Civil Procedure Reform in Comparative Context: The United States of America, 45 Am J Comp L 675, 676 (1997) ("Litigation reform efforts in the United States have sounded a consistent theme of the need to reduce expense and delay.").
  • 21
    • 84977345194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some would say that it is inefficient for public companies to buy any sort of insurance, as their investors can hold a diverse portfolio of stocks and in this manner spread the risk of a catastrophic event befalling any one company. For a discussion of why companies nonetheless insure, see generally Louis De Alessi, Why Corporations Insure, 25 Econ Inq 429 (1987).
    • Some would say that it is inefficient for public companies to buy any sort of insurance, as their investors can hold a diverse portfolio of stocks and in this manner spread the risk of a catastrophic event befalling any one company. For a discussion of why companies nonetheless insure, see generally Louis De Alessi, Why Corporations Insure, 25 Econ Inq 429 (1987).
  • 23
    • 66249094295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Cooter, Towards a Market in Unmatured Tort Claims, 75 Va L Rev 383, 394 (1989, It is beyond the scope of this Article to make a broader argument on why companies are willing to pay premiums for insurance policies or hedge contracts of any sort. Proceeding from the reality that companies do hedge or insure against all sorts of risks, this Article asks whether lawyers might create a market mechanism for the transfer of legal risk that is of the sort widely available today for a variety of other risks. It may be worth noting, however, one argument in favor of insuring legal risks in particular: namely, that litigation risk is a specialized risk that a specialized legal insurer might be better suited to price and manage than the companies that currently must bear it. If companies are forced to bear litigation risk themselves, markets may misprice it (artificially depressing a company's share price, for example, and corporate managers may mismanage it for example, by allowi
    • Robert Cooter, Towards a Market in Unmatured Tort Claims, 75 Va L Rev 383, 394 (1989). It is beyond the scope of this Article to make a broader argument on why companies are willing to pay premiums for insurance policies or hedge contracts of any sort. Proceeding from the reality that companies do hedge or insure against all sorts of risks, this Article asks whether lawyers might create a market mechanism for the transfer of legal risk that is of the sort widely available today for a variety of other risks. It may be worth noting, however, one argument in favor of insuring legal risks in particular: namely, that litigation risk is a specialized risk that a specialized legal insurer might be better suited to price and manage than the companies that currently must bear it. If companies are forced to bear litigation risk themselves, markets may misprice it (artificially depressing a company's share price, for example), and corporate managers may mismanage it (for example, by allowing risk aversion to lead them to pay more to settle a suit than it is worth so as to resolve the matter and put it behind them).
  • 25
    • 0042403685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Information Content of Litigation Participation Securities: The Case of CalFed Bancorp, 60
    • For an example of how plaintiffs' claims might not only be transferred, but securitized and traded on an exchange, see
    • For an example of how plaintiffs' claims might not only be transferred, but securitized and traded on an exchange, see Benjamin C. Esty, The Information Content of Litigation Participation Securities: The Case of CalFed Bancorp, 60 J Fin Econ 371, 394 (1999).
    • (1999) J Fin Econ , vol.371 , pp. 394
    • Esty, B.C.1
  • 26
    • 66249121823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For market-based proposals under which plaintiffs' attorneys and/or third-party capital providers would bid for class action lawsuits in an auction setting, see Jonathan R. Macey and Geoffrey P. Miller, A Market Approach to Tort Reform via Rule 23, 80 Cornell L Rev 909, 913-15 (1995) (suggesting that one of the benefits of such a system would be to better align the interests of plaintiffs' attorneys with the interests of the class members);
    • For market-based proposals under which plaintiffs' attorneys and/or third-party capital providers would bid for class action lawsuits in an auction setting, see Jonathan R. Macey and Geoffrey P. Miller, A Market Approach to Tort Reform via Rule 23, 80 Cornell L Rev 909, 913-15 (1995) (suggesting that one of the benefits of such a system would be to better align the interests of plaintiffs' attorneys with the interests of the class members);
  • 27
    • 66249107524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jonathan R. Macey and Geoffrey P. MUler, The Plaintiffs' Attorney's Role in Class Action and Derivative Litigation: Economic Analysis and Recommendations for Reform, 58 U Chi L Rev 1, 105-16 (1991).
    • Jonathan R. Macey and Geoffrey P. MUler, The Plaintiffs' Attorney's Role in Class Action and Derivative Litigation: Economic Analysis and Recommendations for Reform, 58 U Chi L Rev 1, 105-16 (1991).
  • 28
    • 0035565153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consider David B. Wilkins and G. Mitu Gulati, What Law Students Think They Know about Law Firms, 69 U Cin L Rev 1213, 1213 (2001) (Although the majority of legal scholarship continues to focus on law, a number of academics have begun to investigate the norms, institutions, and practices of lawyers.);
    • Consider David B. Wilkins and G. Mitu Gulati, What Law Students Think They Know about Law Firms, 69 U Cin L Rev 1213, 1213 (2001) ("Although the majority of legal scholarship continues to focus on law, a number of academics have begun to investigate the norms, institutions, and practices of lawyers.");
  • 29
    • 0033456405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David B. Wilkins, The Professional Responsibility of Professional Schools to Teach about the Profession, 49 J Legal Educ 76, 76 (1999) (lamenting the law school's systematic and pervasive failure to study and to teach about the profession).
    • David B. Wilkins, The Professional Responsibility of Professional Schools to Teach about the Profession, 49 J Legal Educ 76, 76 (1999) (lamenting "the law school's systematic and pervasive failure to study and to teach about the profession").
  • 30
    • 66249089234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Part III.D.2
    • See Part III.D.2.
  • 31
    • 66249104080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Part I.A.2
    • See Part I.A.2.
  • 32
    • 66249126061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Many litigation-triggering events are not covered by conventional liability insurance policies, which exclude "business risks" and conventional commercial contract disputes. See notes 25-27 and accompanying text.
    • notes 25-27 and accompanying text
  • 33
    • 66249137244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Miller, 80 Tex L Rev at 2116 (cited in note 8) ([T]he value of the claim to be sold is often very difficult to appraise. Litigation claims are unique, not fungible, and often involve important elements of value known only to one party at the outset of the transaction.).
    • See Miller, 80 Tex L Rev at 2116 (cited in note 8) ("[T]he value of the claim to be sold is often very difficult to appraise. Litigation claims are unique, not fungible, and often involve important elements of value known only to one party at the outset of the transaction.").
  • 34
    • 66249134359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the effects on the plaintiffs' side of substituting a third-party capital provider for a contingent-fee plaintiffs' attorney, see, 47 DePaul L Rev 321
    • For a discussion of the effects on the plaintiffs' side of substituting a third-party capital provider for a contingent-fee plaintiffs' attorney, see Samuel R. Gross, We Could Pass a Law ... What Might Happen If Contingent Fees Were Banned, 47 DePaul L Rev 321, 325-30 (1998).
    • (1998) We Could Pass a Law ... What Might Happen If Contingent Fees Were Banned , pp. 325-330
    • Gross, S.R.1
  • 35
    • 66249096109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *9 (cited in note 17).
    • See Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *9 (cited in note 17).
  • 36
    • 66249138591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the companion paper on plaintiff-side risk transfers, I highlight the shortcomings of contingent fee arrangements and the need for a more robust market in litigation claims that would enable plaintiffs to monetize portions of their claims and offload the risk of collecting nothing. See id at *24-25
    • In the companion paper on plaintiff-side risk transfers, I highlight the shortcomings of contingent fee arrangements and the need for a more robust market in litigation claims that would enable plaintiffs to monetize portions of their claims and offload the risk of collecting nothing. See id at *24-25.
  • 37
    • 66249139675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mass Tort Treatment of Pharmaceutical Product Liability Cases in England, 73
    • In England, plaintiffs and defendants alike can buy after-the- event litigation insurance to cover their opponents' legal fees in case they should lose and be subject to fee shifting. See, for example
    • In England, plaintiffs and defendants alike can buy "after-the- event" litigation insurance to cover their opponents' legal fees in case they should lose and be subject to fee shifting. See, for example, David Wilkinson and Adam Blanchard, Mass Tort Treatment of Pharmaceutical Product Liability Cases in England, 73 Defense Counsel J 264, 273-74 (2006).
    • (2006) Defense Counsel J , vol.264 , pp. 273-274
    • Wilkinson, D.1    Blanchard, A.2
  • 39
    • 66249111960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard W. Painter, Litigating on a Contingency:A Monopoly of Champions or a Market for Champerty?, 71 Chi-Kent L Rev 625, 631-32 (1995) (suggesting that British rules against champerty-allowing third parties to insure a plaintiff for the cost of the defendant's legal fees - increases the market power of contingent-fee plaintiffs' lawyers, and often leads to higher fees).
    • Richard W. Painter, Litigating on a Contingency:A Monopoly of Champions or a Market for Champerty?, 71 Chi-Kent L Rev 625, 631-32 (1995) (suggesting that British rules against champerty-allowing third parties to insure a plaintiff for the cost of the defendant's legal fees - increases the market power of contingent-fee plaintiffs' lawyers, and often leads to higher fees).
  • 40
    • 66249147669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, conventional liability insurance covers the risk both of a litigation-triggering event and of a range of potential judgments or settlements, just as fire insurance covers the risk both of a fire starting and of the fire doing more or less damage. When an insurer writes liability insurance policies or fire insurance policies, it knows that among those few policyholders who end up suffering fires or accidents covered by their policies, it will pay small claims to those who suffer small losses and large claims to those who suffer large losses. But actuaries pricing these policies in the first instance can lump policyholders into large homogenous categories and need not consider the array of distinguishing features that a lawyer would consider in pricing a lawsuit after a litigation-triggering event has occurred
    • Of course, conventional liability insurance covers the risk both of a litigation-triggering event and of a range of potential judgments or settlements, just as fire insurance covers the risk both of a fire starting and of the fire doing more or less damage. When an insurer writes liability insurance policies or fire insurance policies, it knows that among those few policyholders who end up suffering fires or accidents covered by their policies, it will pay small claims to those who suffer small losses and large claims to those who suffer large losses. But actuaries pricing these policies in the first instance can lump policyholders into large homogenous categories and need not consider the array of distinguishing features that a lawyer would consider in pricing a lawsuit after a litigation-triggering event has occurred.
  • 41
    • 66249097488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Jack H. Friedenthal, et al, Civil Procedure: Cases and Materials 966-70 (9th ed 2005) (discussing Denman v Spain, 135 So2d 195 (Miss 1961), in which the court held that verdicts could not be based on possibilities).
    • See, for example, Jack H. Friedenthal, et al, Civil Procedure: Cases and Materials 966-70 (9th ed 2005) (discussing Denman v Spain, 135 So2d 195 (Miss 1961), in which the court held that verdicts could not be based on "possibilities").
  • 42
    • 66249126382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Charles Nesson, The Evidence or the Event: On Judicial Proof and the Acceptability of Verdicts, 98 Harv L Rev 1357, 1379 & n 70, 1380 (1985) (noting that probabilistic evidence is insufficient to support a verdict);
    • See Charles Nesson, The Evidence or the Event: On Judicial Proof and the Acceptability of Verdicts, 98 Harv L Rev 1357, 1379 & n 70, 1380 (1985) (noting that probabilistic evidence is insufficient to support a verdict);
  • 43
    • 66249102410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lawrence Tribe, Trial by Mathematics: Precision and Ritual in the Legal Process, 84 Harv L Rev 1329, 1340-43, 1349 (1971) (presenting various hypothetical situations involving statistical evidence and noting that none would be sufficient to support a verdict).
    • Lawrence Tribe, Trial by Mathematics: Precision and Ritual in the Legal Process, 84 Harv L Rev 1329, 1340-43, 1349 (1971) (presenting various hypothetical situations involving statistical evidence and noting that none would be sufficient to support a verdict).
  • 44
    • 33845742528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aggregation and Its Discontents: Class Settlement Pressure, Class-wide Arbitration, and CAFA
    • See, for example, 2006
    • See, for example, Richard A. Nagareda, Aggregation and Its Discontents: Class Settlement Pressure, Class-wide Arbitration, and CAFA, 106 Colum L Rev 1872, 1905-06 (2006).
    • (2006) Colum L Rev , vol.106 , pp. 1872
    • Nagareda, R.A.1
  • 45
    • 0002254318 scopus 로고
    • The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13
    • Settlements do not require complete agreement on the value of the suit. So long as the plaintiffs and defendant's values do not differ by more than the combined legal fees to be saved by a settlement, there will be a range within which settlement is feasible. See generally
    • Settlements do not require complete agreement on the value of the suit. So long as the plaintiffs and defendant's values do not differ by more than the combined legal fees to be saved by a settlement, there will be a range within which settlement is feasible. See generally George L. Priest and Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J Legal Stud 1 (1984);
    • (1984) J Legal Stud , vol.1
    • Priest, G.L.1    Klein, B.2
  • 46
    • 0002844329 scopus 로고
    • Suit, Settlement, and Trial: A Theoretical Analysis under Alternative Methods for the Allocation of Legal Costs, 11
    • performing a cost-benefit analysis of whether and when plaintiffs will bring suit under the American, British, plaintiff-favoring, and defendant-favoring systems of adjudication
    • Steven Shavell, Suit, Settlement, and Trial: A Theoretical Analysis under Alternative Methods for the Allocation of Legal Costs, 11 J Legal Stud 55 (1982) (performing a cost-benefit analysis of whether and when plaintiffs will bring suit under the American, British, plaintiff-favoring, and defendant-favoring systems of adjudication).
    • (1982) J Legal Stud , vol.55
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 47
    • 0346249902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Don't Try: Civil Jury Verdicts in a System Geared to Settlement, 44
    • J]ury verdicts are rarely compromises, When a civil dispute ends in trial there is almost always a clear loser, and usually a clear winner as well, See
    • See Samuel Gross and Kent Syverud, Don't Try: Civil Jury Verdicts in a System Geared to Settlement, 44 UCLA L Rev 1, 7 (1996) ("[J]ury verdicts are rarely compromises ... When a civil dispute ends in trial there is almost always a clear loser, and usually a clear winner as well.").
    • (1996) UCLA L Rev , vol.1 , pp. 7
    • Gross, S.1    Syverud, K.2
  • 48
    • 84868947919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To take a simple example, if the plaintiff and defendant think there is roughly a 50 percent chance of a $1 million verdict and a 50 percent chance of a defense verdict, the settlement range might be around $500,000 (between $450,000 and $550,000 if each side expects $50,000 in legal fees, and yet a jury verdict would likely come in well outside that settlement range either at $1 million or $0
    • To take a simple example, if the plaintiff and defendant think there is roughly a 50 percent chance of a $1 million verdict and a 50 percent chance of a defense verdict, the settlement range might be around $500,000 (between $450,000 and $550,000 if each side expects $50,000 in legal fees), and yet a jury verdict would likely come in well outside that settlement range (either at $1 million or $0).
  • 49
    • 66249090985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of how imbalances in risk preferences may skew settlements away from the merits, and render settlements between plaintiffs and defendants less accurate than the sale of claims to third-party capital providers, see Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *6 cited in note 17, Whereas a one-time, risk-averse plaintiff forced to sell to a repeat-player, risk-neutral defendant may be coerced into an unduly low settlement, a plaintiff free to shop her claim around and sell it in the open market will not be as easily coerced into a low settlement
    • For a discussion of how imbalances in risk preferences may skew settlements away from the merits - and render settlements between plaintiffs and defendants less accurate than the sale of claims to third-party capital providers - see Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *6 (cited in note 17). Whereas a one-time, risk-averse plaintiff forced to sell to a repeat-player, risk-neutral defendant may be coerced into an unduly low settlement, a plaintiff free to shop her claim around and sell it in the open market will not be as easily coerced into a low settlement.
  • 51
    • 84868950589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joseph M. Perillo, 7 Corbin on Contracts § 28.20 (Matthew Bender rev ed 2002) (discussing the implications of nondisclosure on the enforceability of contracts).
    • Joseph M. Perillo, 7 Corbin on Contracts § 28.20 (Matthew Bender rev ed 2002) (discussing the implications of nondisclosure on the enforceability of contracts).
  • 52
    • 66249145510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I discuss below the conflicts of interest that would arise if the lawyers representing the defendant were to absorb risk from the client-and become the client's counterparty rather than simply its agent. See notes 75-77 and accompanying text
    • I discuss below the conflicts of interest that would arise if the lawyers representing the defendant were to absorb risk from the client-and become the client's counterparty rather than simply its agent. See notes 75-77 and accompanying text.
  • 53
    • 66249108680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the ethical problems lawyers would face, and might try to overcome, if they were to serve both as client representatives and market participants, see Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *39-40 (cited in note 17).
    • For a discussion of the ethical problems lawyers would face, and might try to overcome, if they were to serve both as client representatives and market participants, see Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *39-40 (cited in note 17).
  • 54
    • 66249112938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I discuss below the most promising possible structures See notes 58-65 and accompanying text.
    • I discuss below the most promising possible structures See notes 58-65 and accompanying text.
  • 55
    • 66249097863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The effect of information sharing on privilege and work product is addressed below. See notes 109-10 and accompanying text.
    • The effect of information sharing on privilege and work product is addressed below. See notes 109-10 and accompanying text.
  • 56
    • 66249125447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This solution is not ideal as it could yield additional litigation between the defendant and counterparty after the suit with the plaintiff is complete
    • This solution is not ideal as it could yield additional litigation between the defendant and counterparty after the suit with the plaintiff is complete.
  • 57
    • 66249112940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Parts I. C and III.D.1.
    • See Parts I. C and III.D.1.
  • 58
    • 66249149126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In contrast, where there is no business deal pending-and the defendant does not need to satisfy a third party who is more concerned about the litigation than it is-there may be an insurmountable bid-ask spread between the defendant (who would want to dispose of the lawsuit at a low price) and a potential litigation insurer who would only be willing to accept the liability at a comparatively high price
    • In contrast, where there is no business deal pending-and the defendant does not need to satisfy a third party who is more concerned about the litigation than it is-there may be an insurmountable "bid-ask spread" between the defendant (who would want to dispose of the lawsuit at a low price) and a potential litigation insurer (who would only be willing to accept the liability at a comparatively high price).
  • 59
    • 0346408815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consider Michael Klausner, Geoffrey Miller, and Richard Painter, Second Opinions in Litigation,84
    • discussing costs of obtaining second opinions on litigation
    • Consider Michael Klausner, Geoffrey Miller, and Richard Painter, Second Opinions in Litigation,84 Va L Rev 1411, 1418 (1998) (discussing costs of obtaining "second opinions" on litigation).
    • (1998) Va L Rev , vol.1411 , pp. 1418
  • 60
    • 66249118468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at 1420 noting that [s]econd opinions will tend to be more attractive when larger stakes are involved
    • See id at 1420 (noting that "[s]econd opinions will tend to be more attractive" when larger stakes are involved).
  • 61
    • 84868958846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In fact, the few insurers who offer litigation buyout policies typically charge diligence fees up front to look at the risk. See, for example, American Insurance Group, Inc, Litigation Buyout Insurance: Questions and Answers 3, online at, visited Jan 11, 2009
    • In fact, the few insurers who offer litigation buyout policies typically charge diligence fees up front to look at the risk. See, for example, American Insurance Group, Inc, Litigation Buyout Insurance: Questions and Answers 3, online at http://www.aig.com/aigweb/internet/en/files/Mkt-LBG- Questions%20and%20Answers-tcm20-73192.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 62
    • 66249124762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Part I.A.2
    • See Part I.A.2.
  • 63
    • 66249083235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Hewlett-Packard Co v Bausch & Lomb Inc, 115 FRD 308, 312 (ND Cal 1987) (holding that attorney-cUent privilege was not waived when a party voluntarily disclosed its attorney's opinion letter to a nonparty with whom it was in the process of negotiating a transaction).
    • See, for example, Hewlett-Packard Co v Bausch & Lomb Inc, 115 FRD 308, 312 (ND Cal 1987) (holding that attorney-cUent privilege was not waived when a party voluntarily disclosed its attorney's opinion letter to a nonparty with whom it was in the process of negotiating a transaction).
  • 64
    • 66249086672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although some courts have distinguished between common business interests and common legal interests and afforded protection only to the latter, when one entity purchases another and assumes its habilities, this generally will create a common legal interest between the defendant and the potential purchaser assuming its liabilities
    • Although some courts have distinguished between "common business interests" and "common legal interests" and afforded protection only to the latter, when one entity purchases another and assumes its habilities, this generally will create a common legal interest between the defendant and the potential purchaser assuming its liabilities.
  • 65
    • 66249141392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at 308. The same should be true when a company's liabilities are divided among a purchaser and a litigation-specific risk bearer.
    • See id at 308. The same should be true when a company's liabilities are divided among a purchaser and a litigation-specific risk bearer.
  • 66
    • 66249112602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A private-equity firm purchasing a company need not only evaluate pending or threatened lawsuits but also must value the target company's other assets and liabilities
    • A private-equity firm purchasing a company need not only evaluate pending or threatened lawsuits but also must value the target company's other assets and liabilities.
  • 67
    • 66249120810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kandel v Tocher, 256 NYS2d 898, 899 (App Div 1965) (protecting privilege for liability insurer);
    • See Kandel v Tocher, 256 NYS2d 898, 899 (App Div 1965) (protecting privilege for liability insurer);
  • 68
    • 66249134687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ogden v Allstate Insurance Co, 441 NYS2d 667, 668-69 (Sup Ct, Chenango County 1982) (distinguishing between liability insurance or litigation insurance, where common interest privilege would apply, and coverage other than liability insurance).
    • Ogden v Allstate Insurance Co, 441 NYS2d 667, 668-69 (Sup Ct, Chenango County 1982) (distinguishing between "liability insurance" or "litigation insurance," where common interest privilege would apply, and "coverage other than liability insurance").
  • 69
    • 66249084270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ogden, 447 NYS2d at 668-70 (discussing treatment of litigation-risk transfers under insurance law).
    • See Ogden, 447 NYS2d at 668-70 (discussing treatment of litigation-risk transfers under insurance law).
  • 70
    • 66249137243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Figure 1 is based on a Monte Carlo simulation with five thousand runs of forty lawsuits accumulated over five years The model assumes some ramp up, with four suite taken in the first year, six in the second year, eight in the third year, ten in the fourth year, and twelve in the fifth year, The model uses a lognormal distribution of damages awards for each lawsuit, with a remote chance of a very large award and a much higher probability of a smaller award, as that reflects experience in many cases where plaintiffs use the remote possibility of a large damages award to induce defendants to settle. The actual shape of distributions for each suit depends upon three core variables: chances of liability, size of mean damages award, and range of awards surrounding that mean. To simplify the model, I allowed three potential values for each variable. Thus, each suit in the pool had a likelihood of liability of 25 percent, 50 percent, or 75 percent, even though in reality the chances of lia
    • Figure 1 is based on a Monte Carlo simulation with five thousand runs of forty lawsuits accumulated over five years (The model assumes some ramp up, with four suite taken in the first year, six in the second year, eight in the third year, ten in the fourth year, and twelve in the fifth year.) The model uses a lognormal distribution of damages awards for each lawsuit - with a remote chance of a very large award and a much higher probability of a smaller award - as that reflects experience in many cases where plaintiffs use the remote possibility of a large damages award to induce defendants to settle. The actual shape of distributions for each suit depends upon three core variables: chances of liability, size of mean damages award, and range of awards surrounding that mean. To simplify the model, I allowed three potential values for each variable. Thus, each suit in the pool had a likelihood of liability of 25 percent, 50 percent, or 75 percent, even though in reality the chances of liability for a suit might range from 0 (in a frivolous suit) to 100 percent. The mean damages award for each suit was $20 million, $50 million, or $100 million, though in real life the mean might be anywhere. Finally, to represent the range of possible damages awards surrounding the mean - and to see whether the case is more predictable and has only a narrow range of possible outcomes, or less predictable and has a broader range of possible outcomes - there was a volatility (or standard deviation) assigned to each case ranging from multiples of 0.5, 1.0, or 1.5 times the mean. Because a litigation insurer would not know in advance how many cases will be small, medium, or large, and whether those cases will be more or less risky in terms of the range of damages awards and the chances of liability, I allowed the computer to select the value for each of these three variables at random. Further variables assigned by the computer included likelihood of going to trial (10 percent, 30 percent, 50 percent), duration of litigation (one, two, or three years for settled cases versus two, three, or four years for tried cases), and premium levels (which were set at a 20 percent premium over the actuarially fair level).
  • 71
    • 66249134360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The model assumed a capitalization in line with that of many insurance companies (1.4 premium-to-surplus ratio), and permitted an insurer either to be fuUy capitalized in advance (paid-in capital) or to allocate capital to this line of business as cases come in (callable capital). See, for example, Hanover Insurance Group, Inc, Q1 2008 Earnings Results slide 18, online at http://www.hanover.com/thg/investors/pdf/2008Q1.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • The model assumed a capitalization in line with that of many insurance companies (1.4 premium-to-surplus ratio), and permitted an insurer either to be fuUy capitalized in advance ("paid-in capital") or to allocate capital to this line of business as cases come in ("callable capital"). See, for example, Hanover Insurance Group, Inc, Q1 2008 Earnings Results slide 18, online at http://www.hanover.com/thg/investors/pdf/2008Q1.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 72
    • 66249118474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The model permitted capital and premiums to be invested passively at a 5 percent fixed risk-free rate or actively at a floating rate that a more aggressive capital provider, like an investment fund, might employ. One can see from the shapes of the curves - the narrow band of outcomes for passive strategy and wider spread of outcomes for the active investment strategy - that investment risk may very weU exceed litigation risk. (To approximate investment fund returns, the model used data from the actual investment performance of one investment fund manager whose performance has produced a mean rate of return in the 10 to 15 percent range and a volatility of about 5 to 6 percent.)
    • The model permitted capital and premiums to be invested "passively" at a 5 percent fixed risk-free rate or "actively" at a floating rate that a more aggressive capital provider, like an investment fund, might employ. One can see from the shapes of the curves - the narrow band of outcomes for passive strategy and wider spread of outcomes for the active investment strategy - that investment risk may very weU exceed litigation risk. (To approximate investment fund returns, the model used data from the actual investment performance of one investment fund manager whose performance has produced a mean rate of return in the 10 to 15 percent range and a volatility of about 5 to 6 percent.)
  • 73
    • 66249139687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The model simply assumed a premium that was 20 percent in excess of what would be actuarially fair for the risk involved
    • The model simply assumed a premium that was 20 percent in excess of what would be actuarially fair for the risk involved.
  • 74
    • 66249105782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The risk reflected in the Figure 1 flows from the fact that an underwriter will know there is a range of possible outcomes for each case. This Figure 2 reflects the further risk that an underwriter may make mistakes when it evaluates a suit and fixes a premium. The various dots on the Figure indicate the average return and standard deviation from that mean that a risk bearer would expect if, instead of pricing things accurately (the Base Case, it charged too low a premium (50 Percent Premium, was unable to settle (No Settlements, was forced to pay more than expected in settlements or judgments (Outcomes 1.5x, or was to lose when it proceeded to trial (D Loses All Trials, The remaining dots reflect the risk of a case pool half as large as expected (50 Percent Case Pool) and of poor investment returns Investment 50 Percent Lower
    • The risk reflected in the Figure 1 flows from the fact that an underwriter will know there is a range of possible outcomes for each case. This Figure 2 reflects the further risk that an underwriter may make mistakes when it evaluates a suit and fixes a premium. The various dots on the Figure indicate the average return and standard deviation from that mean that a risk bearer would expect if, instead of pricing things accurately (the "Base Case"), it charged too low a premium (50 Percent Premium), was unable to settle (No Settlements), was forced to pay more than expected in settlements or judgments (Outcomes 1.5x), or was to lose when it proceeded to trial (D Loses All Trials). The remaining dots reflect the risk of a case pool half as large as expected (50 Percent Case Pool) and of poor investment returns (Investment 50 Percent Lower).
  • 75
    • 66249087025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An insurer likely would not want to take a case, however, where the threatened judgment might be large enough to drive the original defendant into insolvency. In such a case, the very provision of insurance, and substitution of a deep-pocketed target, would increase the likely settlement value
    • An insurer likely would not want to take a case, however, where the threatened judgment might be large enough to drive the original defendant into insolvency. In such a case, the very provision of insurance - and substitution of a deep-pocketed target - would increase the likely settlement value.
  • 76
    • 0013115531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consider Kathryn E. Spier and Alan O. Sykes, Capital Structure, Priority Rules, and the Settlement of Civil Claims, 18 Intl Rev L & Econ 187, 187 (1998) ([T]he presence of debt may directly dilute the value of the tort claim, may narrow the bargaining range in negotiations, and may lead to a failure to settle.).
    • Consider Kathryn E. Spier and Alan O. Sykes, Capital Structure, Priority Rules, and the Settlement of Civil Claims, 18 Intl Rev L & Econ 187, 187 (1998) ("[T]he presence of debt may directly dilute the value of the tort claim, may narrow the bargaining range in negotiations, and may lead to a failure to settle.").
  • 77
    • 66249126613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Insurance companies can insure litigation risk by relying on lawyers, rather than actuaries, as their underwriters, and they have done so in some instances. See, for example, CFO Mag November, discussing the expansion of the pending-litigation insurance market
    • Insurance companies can insure litigation risk by relying on lawyers, rather than actuaries, as their underwriters, and they have done so in some instances. See, for example, Russ Banham, Parrying the Litigation Threat, CFO Mag (November 2000) (discussing the expansion of the pending-litigation insurance market).
    • (2000) Parrying the Litigation Threat
    • Banham, R.1
  • 78
    • 66249146687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also notes 28-30 and accompanying text. Anecdotal evidence reveals, however, that insurance capacity is available only in narrow categories of cases and only in relatively small amounts, in part because of the pricing problems identified above and in part because insurers' reinsurance arrangements do not cover these risks.
    • See also notes 28-30 and accompanying text. Anecdotal evidence reveals, however, that insurance capacity is available only in narrow categories of cases and only in relatively small amounts, in part because of the pricing problems identified above and in part because insurers' reinsurance arrangements do not cover these risks.
  • 79
    • 66249112939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Todd V. McMillan, Securitization and the Catastrophe Bond: A Transactional Integration of Industries through a Capacity-enhancing Product of Risk Management, 8 Conn Ins L J 131, 141 (2001) ([A]n investor's return on investment depends on the occurrence or nonoccurrence of the event specified within the risk period covered by the catastrophe bond.... [S]hould a catastrophe occur within the risk period, the bondholders will indemnify the insurance company.);
    • See, for example, Todd V. McMillan, Securitization and the Catastrophe Bond: A Transactional Integration of Industries through a Capacity-enhancing Product of Risk Management, 8 Conn Ins L J 131, 141 (2001) ("[A]n investor's return on investment depends on the occurrence or nonoccurrence of the event specified within the risk period covered by the catastrophe bond.... [S]hould a catastrophe occur within the risk period, the bondholders will indemnify the insurance company.");
  • 81
    • 35348988351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Catastrophic Risk and Governance after Hurricane KatruuvA Postscript to Terrorism Risk in a Post-9/11 Economy
    • See also
    • See also Robert J. Rhee, Catastrophic Risk and Governance after Hurricane KatruuvA Postscript to Terrorism Risk in a Post-9/11 Economy, 38 Ariz St L J 581, 581-82 (2006).
    • (2006) 38 Ariz St L , vol.J 581 , pp. 581-582
    • Rhee, R.J.1
  • 83
    • 33845647675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, James P. George, Access to Justice, Costs, and Legal Aid, 54 Am J Comp L 293, 306 (2006) (noting that the insurance industry paid for the Towers Perrin Report, an oftcited study focusing on the costs incurred by insurance companies in annual tort claims, as part of the tort reform battle).
    • See, for example, James P. George, Access to Justice, Costs, and Legal Aid, 54 Am J Comp L 293, 306 (2006) (noting that the insurance industry paid for the Towers Perrin Report, an oftcited study focusing on the costs incurred by insurance companies in annual tort claims, as part of the "tort reform battle").
  • 84
    • 66249112272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id (Tort costs as a percentage of GDP has ... increased by .041 of a percentage point over 20 years, and the [Towers Perrin] Report predicts the increase will continue absent continued tort reform legislation.).
    • Id ("Tort costs as a percentage of GDP has ... increased by .041 of a percentage point over 20 years, and the [Towers Perrin] Report predicts the increase will continue absent continued tort reform legislation.").
  • 85
    • 66249094300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Och-Ziff Capital Management Group LLC, Form Sl 94 (July 2, 2007), online at http://www.secinfo.com/d14D5a.u4G9w.htm (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • See, for example, Och-Ziff Capital Management Group LLC, Form Sl 94 (July 2, 2007), online at http://www.secinfo.com/d14D5a.u4G9w.htm (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 86
    • 66249096419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Josh Friedlander, Hedgies Expand Reach in Reinsurance, Investment Dealers' Dig 8, 9 (May 30, 2005) ([CAT] bonds have proved to be a bridge connecting the massive world of insurance risk to the capital markets.).
    • See Josh Friedlander, Hedgies Expand Reach in Reinsurance, Investment Dealers' Dig 8, 9 (May 30, 2005) ("[CAT] bonds have proved to be a bridge connecting the massive world of insurance risk to the capital markets.").
  • 87
    • 66249121824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert G Sterne and Robert F. Redmond, Surviving the Rocket Docket, The Daily Deal (Mar 13, 2006) (RIM stock was depressed by the legal uncertainty as shown by the surge in Blackberry shares after the [federal court hearing] and in after-market trading.).
    • See Robert G Sterne and Robert F. Redmond, Surviving the Rocket Docket, The Daily Deal (Mar 13, 2006) ("RIM stock was depressed by the legal uncertainty as shown by the surge in Blackberry shares after the [federal court hearing] and in after-market trading.").
  • 88
    • 66249130154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Shares Hit by Suit over E-mail Patents, Chi Trib C2 (Nov 7, 2006) (noting that the stock for Palm Inc, the maker of the Treo smart phone, decreased by 7.6 percent following the news of a patent infringement lawsuit).
    • See also Shares Hit by Suit over E-mail Patents, Chi Trib C2 (Nov 7, 2006) (noting that the stock for Palm Inc, the maker of the Treo smart phone, decreased by 7.6 percent following the news of a patent infringement lawsuit).
  • 89
    • 66249093583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see note 69 discussing changes brought on by a worldwide credit crisis
    • But see note 69 (discussing changes brought on by a worldwide credit crisis).
  • 90
    • 66249140014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An insurance company might be willing to front for a hedge fund if it could become comfortable with the fund's credit risk. Moreover, if the hedge fund were to set up its own regulated reinsurer, something many hedge funds have done-this might enable the fronting insurer to receive full reinsurance credit from regulators for risk passed on to the hedge fund
    • An insurance company might be willing to "front" for a hedge fund if it could become comfortable with the fund's credit risk. Moreover, if the hedge fund were to set up its own regulated reinsurer - something many hedge funds have done-this might enable the fronting insurer to receive full reinsurance credit from regulators for risk passed on to the hedge fund.
  • 91
    • 66249149138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The investment bank could either guarantee payment or else itself do the deal with the defendant and then, in turn, pass along the risk to the investment fund
    • The investment bank could either guarantee payment or else itself do the deal with the defendant and then, in turn, pass along the risk to the investment fund.
  • 92
    • 66249083590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The credit crisis that began while this Article was in the editing stages has changed the landscape of the financial world, forcing Lehman Brothers into bankruptcy, bringing American International Group to the brink of bankruptcy, and casting doubt upon the creditworthiness of a wide array of institutions previously thought to be safe credit risks. With Bear Stearns's acquisition by J.P. Morgan and the decisions of Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs to become bank holding companies, the days of the stand-alone investment bank may now be over. AU of the investment banks that serve as prime brokers for hedge funds may now be affiliated with traditional banks
    • The credit crisis that began while this Article was in the editing stages has changed the landscape of the financial world, forcing Lehman Brothers into bankruptcy, bringing American International Group to the brink of bankruptcy, and casting doubt upon the creditworthiness of a wide array of institutions previously thought to be safe credit risks. With Bear Stearns's acquisition by J.P. Morgan and the decisions of Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs to become bank holding companies, the days of the stand-alone investment bank may now be over. AU of the investment banks that serve as prime brokers for hedge funds may now be affiliated with traditional banks.
  • 93
    • 66249128369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See text accompanying note 63
    • See text accompanying note 63.
  • 94
    • 66249084271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gwyneth Rees, Bulging Pockets-The Increasing Use of Side Pockets in Alternative Investment Vehicles 1 (Walkers May 2007), online at http://www.walkersglobal.com/pubdocs/ Hedge%20funds%20and%20Bulging%20Side%20Pockets-G.Rees.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • Gwyneth Rees, Bulging Pockets-The Increasing Use of Side Pockets in Alternative Investment Vehicles 1 (Walkers May 2007), online at http://www.walkersglobal.com/pubdocs/ Hedge%20funds%20and%20Bulging%20Side%20Pockets-G.Rees.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 95
    • 66249087379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 96
    • 66249108363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the value of diversification, see note 52 and accompanying text. See also Figure 1.
    • For a discussion of the value of diversification, see note 52 and accompanying text. See also Figure 1.
  • 97
    • 0348131083 scopus 로고
    • Culture Clash in the Quality of Life in the Law: Changes in the Economics, Diversification and Organization of Lawyering
    • For one example of a similar fee structure imposed on law firms by an insurance company, see
    • For one example of a similar fee structure imposed on law firms by an insurance company, see Carrie Menkel-Meadow, Culture Clash in the Quality of Life in the Law: Changes in the Economics, Diversification and Organization of Lawyering, 44 Case W Res L Rev 621, 655 n 163 (1994).
    • (1994) 44 Case W Res L Rev , vol.621 , Issue.163 , pp. 655
    • Menkel-Meadow, C.1
  • 98
    • 66249133146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consider Carrie Menkel-Meadow, Ethics and the Settlement of Mass Torts: When the Rules Meet the Road, 80 Cornell L Rev 1159, 1182 (1995) (Like their brothers and sisters who have conflicts over contingent fees, hourly fee lawyers also have conflicts with clients over lavish hourly billing that can almost equal the huge verdicts plaintiffs' lawyers trade on.).
    • Consider Carrie Menkel-Meadow, Ethics and the Settlement of Mass Torts: When the Rules Meet the Road, 80 Cornell L Rev 1159, 1182 (1995) ("Like their brothers and sisters who have conflicts over contingent fees, hourly fee lawyers also have conflicts with clients over lavish hourly billing that can almost equal the huge verdicts plaintiffs' lawyers trade on.").
  • 99
    • 66249132815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Part I.A
    • See Part I.A.
  • 100
    • 66249117772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of how such conflicts should be handled under the ABA Model Rules of Professional Conduct, see notes 140-42 and accompanying text
    • For a discussion of how such conflicts should be handled under the ABA Model Rules of Professional Conduct, see notes 140-42 and accompanying text.
  • 101
    • 66249102755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 16 explaining why corporations insure even if their shareholders hold diverse portfolios of investments
    • See note 16 (explaining why corporations insure even if their shareholders hold diverse portfolios of investments).
  • 102
    • 66249134369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Duane Reade, Inc v St Paul Fire and Marine Insurance Co, 279 F Supp 2d 235, 238-39 (SDNY 2003) (discussing the calculation of business interruption losses).
    • See, for example, Duane Reade, Inc v St Paul Fire and Marine Insurance Co, 279 F Supp 2d 235, 238-39 (SDNY 2003) (discussing the calculation of business interruption losses).
  • 103
    • 66249140348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Weedo v Stone-E-Brick, Inc, 405 A2d 788, 791 (NJ 1979) (noting that the business risk exclusion in commercial liability insurance policies excludes coverage for insured's faulty contract performance but covers incidental property damage caused by that faulty performance).
    • See, for example, Weedo v Stone-E-Brick, Inc, 405 A2d 788, 791 (NJ 1979) (noting that the "business risk" exclusion in commercial liability insurance policies excludes coverage for insured's faulty contract performance but covers incidental property damage caused by that faulty performance).
  • 104
    • 66249129094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Modern Equipment Co v Continental Western Insurance Co, Inc, 355 F3d 1125, 1131 (8th Cir 2004);
    • See also Modern Equipment Co v Continental Western Insurance Co, Inc, 355 F3d 1125, 1131 (8th Cir 2004);
  • 106
    • 0026251236 scopus 로고
    • Getting to No: A Study of Settlement Negotiations and the Selection of Cases for Trial, 90
    • noting that as compared to personal injury litigation, insurance is far from universal in commercial transaction litigation, See
    • See Samuel R. Gross and Kent D. Syverud, Getting to No: A Study of Settlement Negotiations and the Selection of Cases for Trial, 90 Mich L Rev 319, 371-72 (1991) (noting that as compared to personal injury litigation, insurance is far from universal in commercial transaction litigation).
    • (1991) Mich L Rev , vol.319 , pp. 371-372
    • Gross, S.R.1    Syverud, K.D.2
  • 107
    • 66249125698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But consider Eric L. Talley, Public Ownership, Firm Governance, and Litigation Risk, 76 U Chi L Rev 335, 338 (2009) (finding that, at least for securities litigation, the predictive relationship ... between governance choices and prospective litigation risk is relatively (and somewhat surprisingly) modest).
    • But consider Eric L. Talley, Public Ownership, Firm Governance, and Litigation Risk, 76 U Chi L Rev 335, 338 (2009) (finding that, at least for securities litigation, "the predictive relationship ... between governance choices and prospective litigation risk is relatively (and somewhat surprisingly) modest").
  • 108
    • 66249103772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 109
    • 66249087729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Schlagenhauf v Holder, 379 US 104, 114 (1964) (The chain of events leading to an ultimate determination on the merits begins with the injury of the plaintiff).
    • See Schlagenhauf v Holder, 379 US 104, 114 (1964) ("The chain of events leading to an ultimate determination on the merits begins with the injury of the plaintiff").
  • 110
    • 66249149127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Louis Kaplow, The Value of Accuracy in Adjudication: An Economic Analysis, 23 J Legal Stud 307, 308 n 1 (1994) (Some changes in the legal system might make it simultaneously more accurate and cheaper, but it is usually obvious that such changes are desirable (from the economic perspective employed here) and thus analytically uninteresting to consider them.).
    • See Louis Kaplow, The Value of Accuracy in Adjudication: An Economic Analysis, 23 J Legal Stud 307, 308 n 1 (1994) ("Some changes in the legal system might make it simultaneously more accurate and cheaper, but it is usually obvious that such changes are desirable (from the economic perspective employed here) and thus analytically uninteresting to consider them.").
  • 111
    • 11144275163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Principled Minimalism: Restriking the Balance between Judicial Minimalism and Neutral Principles, 90
    • See
    • See Jonathan T. Molot, Principled Minimalism: Restriking the Balance between Judicial Minimalism and Neutral Principles, 90 Va L Rev 1753, 1799 (2007).
    • (2007) Va L Rev , vol.1753 , pp. 1799
    • Molot, J.T.1
  • 112
    • 22744442255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Old Judicial Role for a New Litigation Era, 113
    • Moreover, with the evolution of the class action device, judges have had to take on the additional responsibility of checking its excesses and guarding against both partisanship and agency problems. See
    • See Jonathan T. Molot, An Old Judicial Role for a New Litigation Era, 113 Yale L J 27, 40 (2003). Moreover, with the evolution of the class action device, judges have had to take on the additional responsibility of checking its excesses and guarding against both partisanship and agency problems.
    • (2003) Yale L J , vol.27 , pp. 40
    • Molot, J.T.1
  • 113
    • 33749175703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Fairness Hearing: Adversarial and Regulatory Approaches, 53
    • See, for example
    • See, for example, William B. Rubenstein, The Fairness Hearing: Adversarial and Regulatory Approaches, 53 UCLA L Rev 1435, 1444 (2006);
    • (2006) UCLA L Rev , vol.1435 , pp. 1444
    • Rubenstein, W.B.1
  • 114
    • 0034405886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sweetheart" and "Blackmail" Settlements in Class Actions: Reality and Remedy
    • Bruce Hay and David Rosenberg, "Sweetheart" and "Blackmail" Settlements in Class Actions: Reality and Remedy, 75 Notre Dame L Rev 1377, 1400 (2000).
    • (2000) 75 Notre Dame L Rev , vol.1377 , pp. 1400
    • Hay, B.1    Rosenberg, D.2
  • 115
    • 66249120809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Miller, 80 Tex L Rev at 2115 (cited in note 8) (A lawsuit is essentially a sale. The defendant buys a valuable asset from the plaintiff, in the form of a release of claims if the case is settled, or a verdict with res judicata effect if the case goes to a verdict); Rubenstein, 89 Georgetown L J at 372 (cited in note 3) (In complex class actions, defendants purchase a commodity - finality. They buy from the plaintiffs' representative the plaintiffs' rights to sue.);
    • See, for example, Miller, 80 Tex L Rev at 2115 (cited in note 8) ("A lawsuit is essentially a sale. The defendant buys a valuable asset from the plaintiff, in the form of a release of claims if the case is settled, or a verdict with res judicata effect if the case goes to a verdict"); Rubenstein, 89 Georgetown L J at 372 (cited in note 3) ("In complex class actions, defendants purchase a commodity - finality. They buy from the plaintiffs' representative the plaintiffs' rights to sue.");
  • 116
    • 0038660700 scopus 로고
    • Rational Bargaining and Market Efficiency: Understanding Pennzoil v. Texaco, 75
    • It is through negotiation, not adjudication, that legal conflict is typically resolved
    • Robert H. Mnookin and Robert B. Wilson, Rational Bargaining and Market Efficiency: Understanding Pennzoil v. Texaco, 75 Va L Rev 295, 295 (1989) ("It is through negotiation, not adjudication, that legal conflict is typically resolved.").
    • (1989) Va L Rev , vol.295 , pp. 295
    • Mnookin, R.H.1    Wilson, R.B.2
  • 117
    • 66249104081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Owen M. Fiss, Against Settlement, 93 Yale L J 1073, 1085 (1984) (To be against settlement is only to suggest that when the parties settle, society gets less than what appears, and for a price it does not know it is paying.).
    • But see Owen M. Fiss, Against Settlement, 93 Yale L J 1073, 1085 (1984) ("To be against settlement is only to suggest that when the parties settle, society gets less than what appears, and for a price it does not know it is paying.").
  • 118
    • 66249140006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consider Carrie Menkel-Meadow, Whose Dispute Is It Anyway?: A Philosophical and Democratic Defense of Settlement (in Some Cases), 83 Georgetown L J 2663, 2668 (1995) ([H]ow can we tell good settlements from bad ones, and when should we prefer adjudication to settlement?).
    • Consider Carrie Menkel-Meadow, Whose Dispute Is It Anyway?: A Philosophical and Democratic Defense of Settlement (in Some Cases), 83 Georgetown L J 2663, 2668 (1995) ("[H]ow can we tell good settlements from bad ones, and when should we prefer adjudication to settlement?").
  • 119
    • 66249092544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Part I.C
    • See Part I.C.
  • 120
    • 22744456273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a general discussion, see Michael Abramowicz, On the Alienability of Legal Claims, 114 Yale L J 697 (2005).
    • For a general discussion, see Michael Abramowicz, On the Alienability of Legal Claims, 114 Yale L J 697 (2005).
  • 121
    • 66249088108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I question the wisdom of these restrictions See Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *25 (cited in note 17).
    • I question the wisdom of these restrictions See Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *25 (cited in note 17).
  • 122
    • 66249124375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although one might fear that defense-side risk transfers might undermine deterrence, risk transfers that are priced accurately should have the same deterrent effects as settlements with plaintiffs Indeed, the prohibition in many jurisdictions against insuring punitive damages, based on a fear of freeing the insured ex ante to commit repugnant acts, might not apply to litigation-risk transfers effected after a litigation-triggering event already has occurred. See, for example, Northwestern National Casualty Co v McNulty, 307 F2d 432, 440 5th Cir 1962, noting that if the insured were permitted to shift the burden to an insurance company, punitive damages would serve no useful purpose
    • Although one might fear that defense-side risk transfers might undermine deterrence, risk transfers that are priced accurately should have the same deterrent effects as settlements with plaintiffs Indeed, the prohibition in many jurisdictions against insuring punitive damages - based on a fear of freeing the insured ex ante to commit repugnant acts - might not apply to litigation-risk transfers effected after a litigation-triggering event already has occurred. See, for example, Northwestern National Casualty Co v McNulty, 307 F2d 432, 440 (5th Cir 1962) (noting that if the insured "were permitted to shift the burden to an insurance company, punitive damages would serve no useful purpose").
  • 123
    • 66249094672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scholars have observed how litigation dynamics and bargaining power may depend upon whether the parties are repeat players-like contingent fee plaintiffs' attorneys and insurance companies-or one-time litigants. See, for example, Gross and Syverud, 90 Mich L Rev at 381-82 cited in note 81
    • Scholars have observed how litigation dynamics and bargaining power may
  • 124
    • 66249098643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This would not be true, however, if the original defendant could use the prospect of insolvency to negotiate a lower settlement. See note 57
    • This would not be true, however, if the original defendant could use the prospect of insolvency to negotiate a lower settlement. See note 57.
  • 125
    • 66249102403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, David Rosenberg, Class Actions for Mass Torts: Doing Individual Justice by Collective Means, 62 Ind L J 561, 564 (1986) (Because defendant firms are in a position to spread the litigation costs over the entire class of mass accident claims, while plaintiffs, being deprived of the economies of scale afforded by class actions, can not, the result will usually be that the firms will escape the full loss they have caused.);
    • See, for example, David Rosenberg, Class Actions for Mass Torts: Doing Individual Justice by Collective Means, 62 Ind L J 561, 564 (1986) ("Because defendant firms are in a position to spread the litigation costs over the entire class of mass accident claims, while plaintiffs, being deprived of the economies of scale afforded by class actions, can not, the result will usually be that the firms will escape the full loss they have caused.");
  • 126
    • 66249146999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Marc Galanter, Why the Haves Come Out Ahead: Speculations on the Limits of Legal Change, 9 L & Socy Rev 95, 124-25 (1974) (explaining that the haves enjoy certain advantages in the areas of legal services, institutional facilities, rules, and the parties involved).
    • Marc Galanter, Why the "Haves" Come Out Ahead: Speculations on the Limits of Legal Change, 9 L & Socy Rev 95, 124-25 (1974) (explaining that the "haves" enjoy certain advantages in the areas of legal services, institutional facilities, rules, and the parties involved).
  • 127
    • 0346684476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also generally David Rosenberg, Mass Tort Class Actions: What Defendants Have and Plaintiffs Don't, 37 Harv J on Legis 393 (2000) (exploring the social costs of biasing the allocation of litigation power);
    • See also generally David Rosenberg, Mass Tort Class Actions: What Defendants Have and Plaintiffs Don't, 37 Harv J on Legis 393 (2000) (exploring the "social costs of biasing the allocation of litigation power");
  • 128
    • 66249094675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Herbert M. Kritzer and Susan S. Silbey, eds, In Litigation Do the Haves Still Come Out Ahead? (Stanford 2003).
    • Herbert M. Kritzer and Susan S. Silbey, eds, In Litigation Do the "Haves" Still Come Out Ahead? (Stanford 2003).
  • 129
    • 66249146688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Concept of Equality in Civil Procedure, 23
    • explaining the three types of equality: equipage equality, rule equality, and outcome equality, For an exploration of what scholars mean by procedural equality or inequality, see
    • For an exploration of what scholars mean by procedural "equality" or "inequality," see William B. Rubenstein, The Concept of Equality in Civil Procedure, 23 Cardozo L Rev 1865, 1867-68 (2002) (explaining the three types of equality: equipage equality, rule equality, and outcome equality).
    • (2002) Cardozo L Rev 1865 , pp. 1867-1868
    • Rubenstein, W.B.1
  • 130
    • 66249138597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See notes 73-77 and accompanying text
    • See notes 73-77 and accompanying text.
  • 131
    • 66249127343 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Molot, 84 Va L Rev at 973-74 (cited in note 2) (To the extent that attorneys manipulate legal processes rather than apply the law, the social utility of the legal profession declines.);
    • See, for example, Molot, 84 Va L Rev at 973-74 (cited in note 2) ("To the extent that attorneys manipulate legal processes rather than apply the law, the social utility of the legal profession declines.");
  • 132
    • 66249098635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deborah L. Rhode, Institutionalizing Ethics, 44 Case W Res L Rev 665. 670 (1994) (noting a wide range of partisan practices that obstruct the search for truth).
    • Deborah L. Rhode, Institutionalizing Ethics, 44 Case W Res L Rev 665. 670 (1994) (noting a "wide range of partisan practices that obstruct the search for truth").
  • 133
    • 66249128370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Gross and Syverud, 90 Mich L Rev at 349-50 (cited in note 81).
    • See, for example, Gross and Syverud, 90 Mich L Rev at 349-50 (cited in note 81).
  • 134
    • 66249084272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I address plaintiff-side risk transfers in a companion article. See, Many states already have done away with restrictions on the sale of claims
    • I address plaintiff-side risk transfers in a companion article. See Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *9 (cited in note 17). Many states already have done away with restrictions on the sale of claims.
    • A Market in Litigation Claims at *9 (cited in note 17)
    • Molot1
  • 136
    • 66249103767 scopus 로고
    • A Comprehensive Market Strategy for Tort Reform
    • 435
    • Peter Charles Choharis, A Comprehensive Market Strategy for Tort Reform, 12 Yale J Reg 435, 464 (1995);
    • (1995) Yale J Reg , vol.12 , pp. 464
    • Charles Choharis, P.1
  • 138
    • 0000689962 scopus 로고
    • A Market in Personal Injury Tort Claims, 16
    • Marc J. Shukaitis, A Market in Personal Injury Tort Claims, 16 J Legal Stud 329, 330 (1987).
    • (1987) J Legal Stud , vol.329 , pp. 330
    • Shukaitis, M.J.1
  • 139
    • 66249113278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although I reserve for another article the implications of plaintiff-side risk transfers, see Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *9 cited in note 17, it is worth noting briefly why risk transfere on the plaintiffs' side generally could be expected to enhance plaintiffs' bargaining power. The range of jury awards for many types of lawsuits is thought by many to have a lognormal distribution, with a high incidence of small recoveries and a few large outliers that skew the mean toward a higher amount than the median. See note 52. A one-time plaintiff deciding how much to accept in settlement of such a suit will likely look at the median, asking his lawyer what most plaintiffs in his position would likely recover at trial. The one-time plaintiff will not likely forego an amount that exceeds what most plaintiffs are likely to collect at trial in the hope of winning the lottery and being one of the lucky few plaintiffs who wins a huge, windfall verdict. A repeat-player
    • Although I reserve for another article the implications of plaintiff-side risk transfers, see Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *9 (cited in note 17), it is worth noting briefly why risk transfere on the plaintiffs' side generally could be expected to enhance plaintiffs' bargaining power. The range of jury awards for many types of lawsuits is thought by many to have a lognormal distribution - with a high incidence of small recoveries and a few large outliers that skew the mean toward a higher amount than the median. See note 52. A one-time plaintiff deciding how much to accept in settlement of such a suit will likely look at the median - asking his lawyer what most plaintiffs in his position would likely recover at trial. The one-time plaintiff will not likely forego an amount that exceeds what most plaintiffs are likely to collect at trial in the hope of winning the lottery and being one of the lucky few plaintiffs who wins a huge, windfall verdict. A repeat-player defendant like an insurance company, in contrast, would look at the mean, knowing that if it goes to trial every time, it will eventually lose one of the very large judgments. To the extent that the insurer can offer the plaintiff an offer just above the median, it should be able to strike a settlement for an amount that represents a significant savings off the mean. If we substitute a repeat-player plaintiff for a one-time plaintiff, however, this would enable those on the plaintiffs' side to bargain based on the higher mean, rather than the lower median, and hold out for higher settlements. See notes 93-94.
  • 140
    • 0035649969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of how the participation of repeat-player institutional litigants changes the nature of litigation, see Tom Baker, Blood Money, New Money, and the Moral Economy of Tort Law in Action, 35 L & Socy Rev 275, 277 2001, noting that repeat players are motivated to reach a settlement within the liability insurance limits when the defendant would be paying with his own money
    • For a discussion of how the participation of repeat-player institutional litigants changes the nature of litigation, see Tom Baker, Blood Money, New Money, and the Moral Economy of Tort Law in Action, 35 L & Socy Rev 275, 277 (2001) (noting that repeat players are motivated to reach a settlement within the liability insurance limits when the defendant would be paying with his own money).
  • 141
    • 66249126383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert H. Mnookin, Negotiation, Settlement and the Contingent Fee, 47 DePaul L Rev 363, 365 (1998) (indicating that under an hourly fee arrangement, [i]f discovery is protracted and settlement comes late in the process, defense counsel will be compensated for additional time invested in the case);
    • See Robert H. Mnookin, Negotiation, Settlement and the Contingent Fee, 47 DePaul L Rev 363, 365 (1998) (indicating that under an hourly fee arrangement, "[i]f discovery is protracted and settlement comes late in the process, defense counsel will be compensated for additional time invested in the case");
  • 142
    • 0346720500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Optimal Contingent Fees in a World of Settlement, 26
    • I]f the client controls the settlement decision, she is generally better off using a contingent fee instead of an hourly fee
    • Bruce L. Hay, Optimal Contingent Fees in a World of Settlement, 26 J Legal Stud 259, 260 (1997) ("[I]f the client controls the settlement decision, she is generally better off using a contingent fee instead of an hourly fee.");
    • (1997) J Legal Stud , vol.259 , pp. 260
    • Hay, B.L.1
  • 143
    • 0031324650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jonathan T. Molot, How U.S. Procedure Skews Ton Law Incentives, 73 Ind L J 59, 89-91 (1997) ([I]f each hour of plaintiffs' and defendants' attorneys' time were of equal value (and both sides were equally optimistic about the benefits of proceeding), plaintiffs' attorneys would be more eager to settle than defendants.);
    • Jonathan T. Molot, How U.S. Procedure Skews Ton Law Incentives, 73 Ind L J 59, 89-91 (1997) ("[I]f each hour of plaintiffs' and defendants' attorneys' time were of equal value (and both sides were equally optimistic about the benefits of proceeding), plaintiffs' attorneys would be more eager to settle than defendants.");
  • 144
    • 0000522354 scopus 로고
    • Some Agency Problems in Settlement, 16
    • noting that in a contingent fee arrangement, the lawyer is both the agent of the defendant and the principal with respect to his own interest in the claim
    • Geoffrey P. Miller, Some Agency Problems in Settlement, 16 J Legal Stud 189, 189 (1987) (noting that in a contingent fee arrangement, the lawyer is both the agent of the defendant and the principal with respect to his own interest in the claim).
    • (1987) J Legal Stud , vol.189 , pp. 189
    • Miller, G.P.1
  • 148
    • 66249120459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, where a third-party litigation insurer prices litigation risk for deal participants, the deal participants may choose to use that price as a basis for their negotiations and retain the risk themselves, thereby avoiding having to pay the insurer a premium
    • Indeed, where a third-party litigation insurer prices litigation risk for deal participants, the deal participants may choose to use that price as a basis for their negotiations and retain the risk themselves, thereby avoiding having to pay the insurer a premium.
  • 149
    • 66249104082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As noted earlier, the risk being transferred pursuant to a conventional contingent fee arrangement is somewhat different from that being transferred when defendants buy litigation insurance or when plaintiffs sell claims, See notes 21-24 and accompanying text. Whereas I envision defendants buying protection against higher-than-expected judgments, contingent fee plaintiffs generally are buying protection against higher-than-expected litigation expenses That said, plaintiffs seek this protection in many instances because they fear that their recovery may be too small to cover litigation costs. In these instances the risk driving the risk-transfer decision for the plaintiff is thus the same one that motivates a defendant: namely, the risk that a judgment or settlement will come in higher or lower than expected, In other instances, however, plaintiffs may be forced into a contingent fee even if they are confident of a large recovery because they simply do not have the cash to cover lega
    • As noted earlier, the risk being transferred pursuant to a conventional contingent fee arrangement is somewhat different from that being transferred when defendants buy litigation insurance (or when plaintiffs sell claims). See notes 21-24 and accompanying text. Whereas I envision defendants buying protection against higher-than-expected judgments, contingent fee plaintiffs generally are buying protection against higher-than-expected litigation expenses That said, plaintiffs seek this protection in many instances because they fear that their recovery may be too small to cover litigation costs. In these instances the risk driving the risk-transfer decision for the plaintiff is thus the same one that motivates a defendant: namely, the risk that a judgment or settlement will come in higher or lower than expected. (In other instances, however, plaintiffs may be forced into a contingent fee even if they are confident of a large recovery because they simply do not have the cash to cover legal fees or the ability to borrow it.)
  • 150
    • 66249123708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See notes 47-51 and accompanying text
    • See notes 47-51 and accompanying text.
  • 151
    • 66249140341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FRCP 26(a). But see note 110.
    • FRCP 26(a). But see note 110.
  • 152
    • 66249113621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Upjohn v Untied States, 449 US 383, 396 (1981) (holding that communications between attorneys and clients regarding responses to questionnaires and interview questions are privileged and not subject to discovery);
    • See Upjohn v Untied States, 449 US 383, 396 (1981) (holding that communications between attorneys and clients regarding responses to questionnaires and interview questions are privileged and not subject to discovery);
  • 153
    • 66249097489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hickman v Taylor, 329 US 495, 512 (1947) (holding that, under Rule 26, lawyers are not required to produce private memoranda and personal recollections as part of discovery).
    • Hickman v Taylor, 329 US 495, 512 (1947) (holding that, under Rule 26, lawyers are not required to produce private memoranda and personal recollections as part of discovery).
  • 154
    • 66249106818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even without invoking work product protection, one can interpret the text of the federal rule governing insurance agreements to distinguish after-the-event litigation-risk transfers from conventional insurance policies and to exclude the former from discovery. Rule 26 provides for disclosure of: (1) any insurance agreement under which (2) any person carrying on an insurance business (3) may be liable to satisfy part or all of a judgment which may be entered in the action or to indemnify or reimburse for payments made to satisfy the judgment FRCP 26(a)(1)C, emphasis added, First, as the discussion of insurance regulation below explores, it is far from clear that a litigation-risk transfer agreement would count as an insurance agreement, even if it were offered by a conventional insurance company. See notes 127-35 and accompanying text. Second, where the entity absorbing litigation risk is an investment fund, rather than an insurance
    • Even without invoking work product protection, one can interpret the text of the federal rule governing insurance agreements to distinguish after-the-event litigation-risk transfers from conventional insurance policies and to exclude the former from discovery. Rule 26 provides for disclosure of: "(1) any insurance agreement under which (2) any person carrying on an insurance business (3) may be liable to satisfy part or all of a judgment which may be entered in the action or to indemnify or reimburse for payments made to satisfy the judgment" FRCP 26(a)(1)(C) (emphasis added). First, as the discussion of insurance regulation below explores, it is far from clear that a litigation-risk transfer agreement would count as an "insurance agreement," even if it were offered by a conventional insurance company. See notes 127-35 and accompanying text. Second, where the entity absorbing litigation risk is an investment fund, rather than an insurance company (as I envisioned in Part I), it arguably would not be a "person carrying on an insurance business." Third, to the extent that risk transfers are done to facilitate deals, then the risk transfer might be structured so that the risk bearer would not be "liable to satisfy part or all of a judgment," nor would it have "to indemnify or reimburse" the defendant "for payments made to satisfy the judgment." The hedge contract would protect, not the defendant company itself, but rather an investor in that company seeking to safeguard its investment against a decline in value attributable to a bad outcome in the lawsuit.
  • 155
    • 66249114114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FRE 408
    • See FRE 408.
  • 156
    • 66249107525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See notes 93-95 and accompanying text
    • See notes 93-95 and accompanying text.
  • 157
    • 66249132439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, In re Novak, 932 F2d 1397, 1405, 1407 (11th Cir 1991);
    • See, for example, In re Novak, 932 F2d 1397, 1405, 1407 (11th Cir 1991);
  • 158
    • 66249088114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Heileman Brewing Co v Joseph Oat Corp, 871 F2d 648, 656 (7th Cir 1989).
    • Heileman Brewing Co v Joseph Oat Corp, 871 F2d 648, 656 (7th Cir 1989).
  • 159
    • 66249136930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Such arrangements are not as common on the defense side, for reasons I explore in Part I, see notes 22-23 and accompanying text, but they are by no means extraordinary. I have spoken to a number of lawyers at traditional hourly fee commercial litigation firms that offer what they call alternative billing arrangements along these lines.
    • Such arrangements are not as common on the defense side, for reasons I explore in Part I, see notes 22-23 and accompanying text, but they are by no means extraordinary. I have spoken to a number of lawyers at traditional hourly fee commercial litigation firms that offer what they call "alternative billing arrangements" along these lines.
  • 160
    • 66249129090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I explore the consequences of plaintiff-side risk transfers to third-party capital providers in the next article in my broader project. See Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *9 cited in note 17, Where plaintiffs shift risk through an outright sale of a portion of a claim, rather than through a conventional contingent fee arrangement, neither the introduction of a third-party capital provider nor the sale of more than one-third of the recovery should change the treatment under the discovery rules. My reason for facilitating plaintiff-side risk transfers is that without such a market in legal claims, disparities in resources and risk aversion can sometimes lead to lower plaintiff recoveries than the merits of lawsuits may warrant. By shifting risk to an entity with a diverse pool of litigation risk and ample resources, we can address these disparities and improve plaintiff recoveries where appropriate. Contingent fee arrangements certainly help on this count, but I a
    • I explore the consequences of plaintiff-side risk transfers to third-party capital providers in the next article in my broader project. See Molot, A Market in Litigation Claims at *9 (cited in note 17). Where plaintiffs shift risk through an outright sale of a portion of a claim, rather than through a conventional contingent fee arrangement, neither the introduction of a third-party capital provider nor the sale of more than one-third of the recovery should change the treatment under the discovery rules. My reason for facilitating plaintiff-side risk transfers is that without such a market in legal claims, disparities in resources and risk aversion can sometimes lead to lower plaintiff recoveries than the merits of lawsuits may warrant. By shifting risk to an entity with a diverse pool of litigation risk and ample resources, we can address these disparities and improve plaintiff recoveries where appropriate. Contingent fee arrangements certainly help on this count, but I argue that they do not do enough.
  • 161
    • 66249089141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at *24-25
    • See id at *24-25.
  • 162
    • 66249105464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Part II.A
    • See Part II.A.
  • 163
    • 66249115062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FASB, Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No 5, online at http://www.fasb.org/pdf/fas5.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • FASB, Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No 5, online at http://www.fasb.org/pdf/fas5.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 164
    • 0001109265 scopus 로고
    • Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: A Testable Model of Strategic Behavior, 11
    • See
    • See Robert Cooter, et al, Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: A Testable Model of Strategic Behavior, 11 J Legal Stud 225, 225 (1982).
    • (1982) J Legal Stud , vol.225 , pp. 225
    • Cooter, R.1
  • 165
    • 66249126384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A company that does not want to have to take a reserve for pending litigation might refuse even to consider a litigation-risk transfer for fear that once the lawsuit is priced by an impartial third party, the loss will then become reasonably estimable and it will have to take a reserve. See id. This poses yet another obstacle to the creation of a market in litigation risk
    • A company that does not want to have to take a reserve for pending litigation might refuse even to consider a litigation-risk transfer for fear that once the lawsuit is priced by an impartial third party, the loss will then become reasonably estimable and it will have to take a reserve. See id. This poses yet another obstacle to the creation of a market in litigation risk.
  • 166
    • 66249105117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A risk transfer might also help where a defendant has some conventional liability insurance coverage but its insurer has disputed its obligation to cover the loss A defendant that cannot take full accounting credit for the insurance, because the coverage is in dispute, can buy litigation insurance to cover the coverage dispute and then reduce its accrued liabilities accordingly
    • A risk transfer might also help where a defendant has some conventional liability insurance coverage but its insurer has disputed its obligation to cover the loss A defendant that cannot take full accounting credit for the insurance - because the coverage is in dispute - can buy litigation insurance to cover the coverage dispute and then reduce its accrued liabilities accordingly.
  • 167
    • 66249089941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 69 for a discussion of how the current credit crisis has affected AIG and the feasibility of a market for litigation-risk transfers.
    • See note 69 for a discussion of how the current credit crisis has affected AIG and the feasibility of a market for litigation-risk transfers.
  • 168
    • 84868950585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SEC SEC Charges American International Group and Others in Brightpoint Securities Fraud; AIG Agrees to Pay $10 Million Civil Penalty (Sept 11, 2003), online at http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2003-111. htm (visited Jan 11, 2009) (noting that AIG was fined $10 million for helping Brightpoint conceal $11.9 million in losses). The Brightpoint investigation may have contributed to the reluctance among conventional insurers to participate in the after-the-event litigation insurance market. See note 27 and accompanying text.
    • See SEC SEC Charges American International Group and Others in Brightpoint Securities Fraud; AIG Agrees to Pay $10 Million Civil Penalty (Sept 11, 2003), online at http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2003-111. htm (visited Jan 11, 2009) (noting that AIG was fined $10 million for helping Brightpoint conceal $11.9 million in losses). The Brightpoint investigation may have contributed to the reluctance among conventional insurers to participate in the after-the-event litigation insurance market. See note 27 and accompanying text.
  • 169
    • 66249112941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See notes 63-65 and accompanying text
    • See notes 63-65 and accompanying text.
  • 170
    • 66249090288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See notes 109-10 and accompanying text
    • See notes 109-10 and accompanying text.
  • 171
    • 84868950579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The principal exception to this exemption from federal regulation is for a narrow category of antitrust violations, including boycotts
    • See 15 USC § 1011
    • See 15 USC § 1011. The principal exception to this exemption from federal regulation is for a narrow category of antitrust violations, including boycotts. See 15 USC § 1012(b).
    • See 15 USC § 1012(b)
  • 173
    • 84868958842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NY Ins Law § 1101(b)(1)(A) (McKinney).
    • NY Ins Law § 1101(b)(1)(A) (McKinney).
  • 174
    • 84868950580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NY Ins Law § 1101(a)(1).
    • NY Ins Law § 1101(a)(1).
  • 175
    • 84868950581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NY Ins Law § 1101(a)(2).
    • NY Ins Law § 1101(a)(2).
  • 176
    • 66249109384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See notes 119-29 and accompanying text
    • See notes 119-29 and accompanying text.
  • 177
    • 66249092892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Grundfest and Huang, 58 Stan L Rev at 1277 (cited in note 4) (noting that, under the real options model, it makes sense for a plaintiff to pursue a risk claim with a negative expected value if... the possibility of uncovering some sort of smoking gun that will lead to a [high recovery] is large enough).
    • See Grundfest and Huang, 58 Stan L Rev at 1277 (cited in note 4) (noting that, under the real options model, "it makes sense for a plaintiff to pursue a risk claim with a negative expected value if... the possibility of uncovering some sort of smoking gun that will lead to a [high recovery] is large enough").
  • 178
    • 66249095274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 326 NE2d 288 (NY 1975).
    • 326 NE2d 288 (NY 1975).
  • 179
    • 66249118116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 290-91
    • Id at 290-91.
  • 180
    • 66249119789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 293
    • Id at 293.
  • 181
    • 66249104430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 182
    • 66249100318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulators also consider the company's reinsurance policies to see how much of the risk it has passed on to reinsurers
    • Regulators also consider the company's reinsurance policies to see how much of the risk it has passed on to reinsurers.
  • 183
    • 66249102752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, insurance companies tend to use standard forms for most policies so that each company can look to statistics on claims for the entire industry when pricing policies and setting reserves, and insurance regulators can look to the same industry-wide sources in evaluating the health of each insurer
    • Indeed, insurance companies tend to use standard forms for most policies so that each company can look to statistics on claims for the entire industry when pricing policies and setting reserves, and insurance regulators can look to the same industry-wide sources in evaluating the health of each insurer.
  • 184
    • 66249087730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see note 69 and accompanying text
    • But see note 69 and accompanying text.
  • 185
    • 66249142091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Part I.C
    • See Part I.C.
  • 186
    • 66249086315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Model Rules of Professional Conduct (MRPC), Rule 2.3(a) (ABA 2008).
    • Model Rules of Professional Conduct (MRPC), Rule 2.3(a) (ABA 2008).
  • 187
    • 66249088806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at Rule 2.3b
    • Id at Rule 2.3(b).
  • 188
    • 66249092076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at Rule 1.7(b)4
    • Id at Rule 1.7(b)(4).
  • 189
    • 66249139332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David Luban, The Noblesse Oblige Tradition in the Practice of Law, 41 Vand L Rev 717, 721 n 18 (1988, Brandeis coined the term 'lawyer for the situation' at his confirmation hearings for the Supreme Court. When accused of unethical law practice for simultaneously representing several parties to the same transaction, Brandeis replied that he viewed himself as counsel for the situation rather than for any single party, citing Jerome Frank, The Legal Ethics of Louis D. Brandeis, 17 Stan L Rev 683 (1965, See also Geoffrey C. Hazard, Jr, Ethics in the Practice of Law 58-68 (Yale 1978, John S. Dzienkowski, Lawyers As Intermediaries: The Representation of Multiple Clients in the Modem Legal Profession, 1992 U Ill L Rev 741, 744 n 11 noting that Professor Hazard, as Reporter to the ABA Commission responsible for the Model Code of Professional Responsible, worked to include a provision addressing the lawyer as an intermediary, as argued by Justi
    • See David Luban, The Noblesse Oblige Tradition in the Practice of Law, 41 Vand L Rev 717, 721 n 18 (1988) ("Brandeis coined the term 'lawyer for the situation' at his confirmation hearings for the Supreme Court. When accused of unethical law practice for simultaneously representing several parties to the same transaction, Brandeis replied that he viewed himself as counsel for the situation rather than for any single party."), citing Jerome Frank, The Legal Ethics of Louis D. Brandeis, 17 Stan L Rev 683 (1965). See also Geoffrey C. Hazard, Jr, Ethics in the Practice of Law 58-68 (Yale 1978); John S. Dzienkowski, Lawyers As Intermediaries: The Representation of Multiple Clients in the Modem Legal Profession, 1992 U Ill L Rev 741, 744 n 11 (noting that Professor Hazard, as Reporter to the ABA Commission responsible for the Model Code of Professional Responsible, worked to include a provision addressing the lawyer as an intermediary, as argued by Justice Brandeis).
  • 190
    • 66249122506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Dzienkowski, 1992 U 111 L Rev at 744 n 11 (cited in note 143).
    • See Dzienkowski, 1992 U 111 L Rev at 744 n 11 (cited in note 143).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.