메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 76, Issue 1, 2009, Pages 219-259

Does private equity create wealth? the effects of private equity and derivatives on corporate governance

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 66249098556     PISSN: 00419494     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Conference Paper
Times cited : (42)

References (170)
  • 1
    • 66249125793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The earliest and best-known paper is Michael C. Jensen, Eclipse of the Public Corporation, 67 Harv Bus Rev 61, 67 (Sept/Oct 1989) (positing that private-equity-owned firms would do a better job of managing free cash flow than public companies). For further discussion of this literature, see Part II.
    • The earliest and best-known paper is Michael C. Jensen, Eclipse of the Public Corporation, 67 Harv Bus Rev 61, 67 (Sept/Oct 1989) (positing that private-equity-owned firms would do a better job of managing free cash flow than public companies). For further discussion of this literature, see Part II.
  • 2
    • 66249135764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Derivatives are generally defined to include options, futures and forward contracts, and swaps, as well as financial products with derivative contracts embedded in them such as convertible securities, insurance, and reinsurance
    • Derivatives are generally defined to include options, futures and forward contracts, and swaps, as well as financial products with derivative contracts embedded in them such as convertible securities, insurance, and reinsurance.
  • 3
    • 66249088117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dan Wilchins, Private Equity Is Viewed As a Shock Absorber, Intl Herald Trib 17 (July 1, 2008) (stating that banks are in dire need of capital and suggesting that private equity may be able to provide it).
    • Dan Wilchins, Private Equity Is Viewed As a "Shock Absorber," Intl Herald Trib 17 (July 1, 2008) (stating that banks are in "dire need of capital" and suggesting that private equity may be able to provide it).
  • 4
    • 84868937434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Policy Statement on Equity Investments in Banks and Bank Holding Companies 9-10 (Sept 22, 2008), to be codified at 12 CFR §online at http://www.federalreseive.gov/ newsevents/press/bcreg/bcreg20080922bl.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009). In certain circumstances, the new rules permit investors to hold up to 15 percent of the voting power and 33 percent of the total equity without being deemed a controlling shareholder (and thereby being subject to regulation as a bank holding company).
    • See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Policy Statement on Equity Investments in Banks and Bank Holding Companies 9-10 (Sept 22, 2008), to be codified at 12 CFR §online at http://www.federalreseive.gov/ newsevents/press/bcreg/bcreg20080922bl.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009). In certain circumstances, the new rules permit investors to hold up to 15 percent of the voting power and 33 percent of the total equity without being deemed a controlling shareholder (and thereby being subject to regulation as a bank holding company).
  • 5
    • 66249126071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at 10. They may also appoint one member of the board of directors.
    • See id at 10. They may also appoint one member of the board of directors.
  • 6
    • 66249134375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 6
    • Id at 6.
  • 7
    • 66249119482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Flowers, Not His Firm, Buys a Bank
    • Sept 24
    • Peter Lattman, Flowers, Not His Firm, Buys a Bank, Wall St J C6 (Sept 24, 2008).
    • (2008) Wall St J , vol.C6
    • Lattman, P.1
  • 8
    • 66249142436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Peter Lattman and Damian Paletta, Fed Gives Funds More Leeway to Buy Banks, Wall St J A1 (Sept 23, 2008) (discussing how the increased flexibility given to private-equity firms will enable them to make investments in some bank holding companies where they had been reluctant to do so over the last few months);
    • See Peter Lattman and Damian Paletta, Fed Gives Funds More Leeway to Buy Banks, Wall St J A1 (Sept 23, 2008) (discussing how the increased flexibility given to private-equity firms will enable them to "make investments in some bank holding companies where they had been reluctant to do so over the last few months");
  • 9
    • 66249105792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Lex Column, Beyond Buyouts, Fin Times 12 (Apr 9,2008) (describing a private-equity firm's multi-billion dollar investment to recapitalize Washington Mutual as indicating where private equity's cash piles will go next).
    • The Lex Column, Beyond Buyouts, Fin Times 12 (Apr 9,2008) (describing a private-equity firm's "multi-billion dollar investment to recapitalize Washington Mutual" as indicating "where private equity's cash piles will go next").
  • 10
    • 66249121163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael Jensen explains that this common practice is referred to as strip financing, which Jensen defines as investors holding roughly proportional 'strips' of all securities in the capital structure and thereby reducing any conflicts of interest among the classes of claimants at firms. Michael C. Jensen, Corporate Control and the Politics of Finance, 4 J Applied Corp Fin 13, 25 (Summer 1991).
    • Michael Jensen explains that this common practice is referred to as "strip financing," which Jensen defines as investors holding "roughly proportional 'strips' of all securities in the capital structure" and thereby reducing any conflicts of interest among the classes of claimants at firms. Michael C. Jensen, Corporate Control and the Politics of Finance, 4 J Applied Corp Fin 13, 25 (Summer 1991).
  • 11
    • 84868937433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Andrew Metrick and Ayako Yasuda, The Economics of Private Equity Funds *2 (University of Pennsylvania, The Wharton School, Department of Finance Working Paper, Sept 2007), online at http://finance.wharton.upenn. edu/∼rlwctr/papers/0717.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • See Andrew Metrick and Ayako Yasuda, The Economics of Private Equity Funds *2 (University of Pennsylvania, The Wharton School, Department of Finance Working Paper, Sept 2007), online at http://finance.wharton.upenn. edu/∼rlwctr/papers/0717.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 12
    • 66249134697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at *2
    • Id at *2.
  • 13
    • 66249122179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at*3
    • Id at*3.
  • 14
    • 66249143869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is especially the case since existing investors have been identified as interested in private-equity investments and are most likely to become limited partners in future funds, provided they did well in prior funds
    • This is especially the case since existing investors have been identified as interested in private-equity investments and are most likely to become limited partners in future funds, provided they did well in prior funds.
  • 15
    • 66249142435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Metrick and Yasuda, The Economics of Private Equity Funds at *6-13 (cited in note 8) (developing an expected-revenue model for private-equity firms).
    • Metrick and Yasuda, The Economics of Private Equity Funds at *6-13 (cited in note 8) (developing an expected-revenue model for private-equity firms).
  • 16
    • 0041908288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James F. Cotter and Sarah W. Peck, The Structure of Debt and Active Equity Investors: The Case of the Buyout Specialist, 59 J Fm Econ 101,102-03 (2001) (discussing the various combinations of debt-subordinated, senior, long-term, and short-term-and third-party equity that leveraged buyout shops use to purchase the publicly held shares of target companies).
    • James F. Cotter and Sarah W. Peck, The Structure of Debt and Active Equity Investors: The Case of the Buyout Specialist, 59 J Fm Econ 101,102-03 (2001) (discussing the various combinations of debt-subordinated, senior, long-term, and short-term-and third-party equity that leveraged buyout shops use to purchase the publicly held shares of target companies).
  • 17
    • 66249091338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 111-12 (finding that buyout specialists purchased a median 51.6 percent of the common stock of target companies in a sample of sixty-four LBOs, while target firm managers held 20 percent and third-party equity investors held the remaining 28.4 percent of the shares).
    • Id at 111-12 (finding that buyout specialists purchased a median 51.6 percent of the common stock of target companies in a sample of sixty-four LBOs, while target firm managers held 20 percent and third-party equity investors held the remaining 28.4 percent of the shares).
  • 18
    • 0000706823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steven N. Kaplan, The Effects of Management Buyouts on Operating Performance and Value, 24 J Fin Econ 217,246 (1989).
    • Steven N. Kaplan, The Effects of Management Buyouts on Operating Performance and Value, 24 J Fin Econ 217,246 (1989).
  • 19
    • 0001066475 scopus 로고
    • Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers, 76
    • Top-level managers frequently receive 15-20 percent of the equity, See also
    • See also Michael C. Jensen, Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers, 76 Am Econ Rev 323, 326 (1986) ("Top-level managers frequently receive 15-20 percent of the equity.").
    • (1986) Am Econ Rev , vol.323 , pp. 326
    • Jensen, M.C.1
  • 20
    • 66249115412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael C. Jensen, The Economic Case for Private Equity (and Some Concerns) *15 (Harvard NOM Research Paper No 07-02, Nov 2007), online at http://ssrn.com/abstract=963530 (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • Michael C. Jensen, The Economic Case for Private Equity (and Some Concerns) *15 (Harvard NOM Research Paper No 07-02, Nov 2007), online at http://ssrn.com/abstract=963530 (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 21
    • 78649265105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Eclipse of Private Equity
    • See
    • See Brian Cheffins and John Armour, The Eclipse of Private Equity, 33 Del J Corp L 1, 13-14 (2008).
    • (2008) 33 Del J Corp , vol.L 1 , pp. 13-14
    • Cheffins, B.1    Armour, J.2
  • 22
    • 35448993296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Equity, Private Lives
    • describing how private-equity-owned firms' boards are different from public company boards and far more involved in assisting the company, Nov 27
    • Geoffrey Colvin and Ram Charan, Private Equity, Private Lives, Fortune 190 (Nov 27, 2006) (describing how private-equity-owned firms' boards are different from public company boards and "far more involved in assisting the company");
    • (2006) Fortune , vol.190
    • Colvin, G.1    Charan, R.2
  • 23
    • 66249097875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cotter and Peck, 59 J Fin Econ at 137 (cited in note 13) (Thus, buyout specialists are likely to more effectively monitor managers by having more seats on the board and by having smaller boards.).
    • Cotter and Peck, 59 J Fin Econ at 137 (cited in note 13) ("Thus, buyout specialists are likely to more effectively monitor managers by having more seats on the board and by having smaller boards.").
  • 24
    • 39649123740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ronald J. Gilson and Charles K. Whitehead, Deconstructing Equity: Public Ownership, Agency Costs, and Complete Capital Markets, 108 Colum L Rev 231, 259-60 (2008) (suggesting that private ownership increases the value of a firm in part through reduced agency costs resulting from a more active boarďof directors).
    • Ronald J. Gilson and Charles K. Whitehead, Deconstructing Equity: Public Ownership, Agency Costs, and Complete Capital Markets, 108 Colum L Rev 231, 259-60 (2008) (suggesting that private ownership increases the value of a firm in part through "reduced agency costs" resulting from a more active boarďof directors).
  • 25
    • 66249147001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jensen, Economic Case at *15 (cited in note 16).
    • Jensen, Economic Case at *15 (cited in note 16).
  • 26
    • 66249139340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Viral V. Acharya and Conor Kehoe, Corporate Governance and Value Creation' Evidence from Private Equity *34 (London Business School Working Paper, May 2008), online at http://www.bvca.co. uk/pdf.php?id=901&filename=corporate-governance-and-value-creation: evidence-from-private-equity (visited Jan 11, 2009); Francesca Cornelli and Oguzhan Karakas,
    • See, for example, Viral V. Acharya and Conor Kehoe, Corporate Governance and Value Creation' Evidence from Private Equity *34 (London Business School Working Paper, May 2008), online at http://www.bvca.co. uk/pdf.php?id=901&filename=corporate-governance-and-value-creation: evidence-from-private-equity (visited Jan 11, 2009); Francesca Cornelli and Oguzhan Karakas,
  • 27
    • 66249141071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Equity and Corporate Governance: Do LBOs Have More Effective Boards?, in Globalization of Alternative Investments Working Papers 1: The Global Economic Impact of Private Equity Report 2008 65, 72 (World Economic Forum 2008), online at http://www.weforum.org/ pdf/cgi/pe/Full-Report.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009);
    • Private Equity and Corporate Governance: Do LBOs Have More Effective Boards?, in Globalization of Alternative Investments Working Papers Volume 1: The Global Economic Impact of Private Equity Report 2008 65, 72 (World Economic Forum 2008), online at http://www.weforum.org/ pdf/cgi/pe/Full-Report.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009);
  • 28
    • 66249096817 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Gertner and Steven N. Kaplan, The Valuemaximizing Board *13 (NBER Working Paper, Dec 1996), online at http://faculty.chicagobooth. edu/steven.kaplan/research/gerkap.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • Robert Gertner and Steven N. Kaplan, The Valuemaximizing Board *13 (NBER Working Paper, Dec 1996), online at http://faculty.chicagobooth. edu/steven.kaplan/research/gerkap.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 29
    • 66249087035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cheffins and Armour, 33 Del J Corp L at 14 (cited in note 17).
    • See Cheffins and Armour, 33 Del J Corp L at 14 (cited in note 17).
  • 30
    • 66249130744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jensen, Economic Case at *16 (cited in note 16).
    • Jensen, Economic Case at *16 (cited in note 16).
  • 31
    • 84993848601 scopus 로고
    • The Modern Industrial Revolution, Exit, and the Failure of Internal Control Systems, 48
    • See
    • See Michael C. Jensen, The Modern Industrial Revolution, Exit, and the Failure of Internal Control Systems, 48 J Fin 831, 863 (1993);
    • (1993) J Fin , vol.831 , pp. 863
    • Jensen, M.C.1
  • 32
    • 66249089246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jensen, Economic Case at *16 (cited in note 16).
    • Jensen, Economic Case at *16 (cited in note 16).
  • 33
    • 66249103442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These buyers would value any improvements in operating performance at the portfolio company created by the selling private-equity owners according to whether they believe that such gains will be temporary or permanent. This gives the private-equity seller an incentive to
    • These buyers would value any improvements in operating performance at the portfolio company created by the selling private-equity owners according to whether they believe that such gains will be temporary or permanent. This gives the private-equity seller an incentive to
  • 34
    • 66249088447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ensure that the changes will persist. In the case of a strategic buyer, this would mean that the acquirer would have to be convinced that its management could replicate the private-equity firm's success in improving risk management or any other sources of the improved operating performance. In a reverse LBO, potential investors would need to see that the newly public firm could duplicate its past success with a less concentrated ownership structure. In this regard, these investors could take comfort from evidence that operating performance improvements at reverse LBO firms persist for at least several years after the firm returns to public ownership. See Gertner and Kaplan, The Value-maximizing Board at *17, table 1 (cited in note 21).
    • ensure that the changes will persist. In the case of a strategic buyer, this would mean that the acquirer would have to be convinced that its management could replicate the private-equity firm's success in improving risk management or any other sources of the improved operating performance. In a reverse LBO, potential investors would need to see that the newly public firm could duplicate its past success with a less concentrated ownership structure. In this regard, these investors could take comfort from evidence that operating performance improvements at reverse LBO firms persist for at least several years after the firm returns to public ownership. See Gertner and Kaplan, The Value-maximizing Board at *17, table 1 (cited in note 21).
  • 35
    • 66249094678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Daniel A. Wingerd, The Private Equity Market: History and Prospects, Investment Policy Mag 26, 30 (Sept/Oct 1997) (describing how the weak stock market and inadequate supply of qualified entrepreneurs led to poor conditions for venture capital in the 1970s).
    • Daniel A. Wingerd, The Private Equity Market: History and Prospects, Investment Policy Mag 26, 30 (Sept/Oct 1997) (describing how the weak stock market and inadequate supply of qualified entrepreneurs led to poor conditions for venture capital in the 1970s).
  • 36
    • 66249122875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at 30-32 (arguing that regulatory changes in 1980 meant that outside managers of plan assets in the venture arena could now be paid proportionately to their success, a vital element in the venture capitalists' mode of doing business);
    • See id at 30-32 (arguing that regulatory changes in 1980 meant that "outside managers of plan assets in the venture arena could now be paid proportionately to their success, a vital element in the venture capitalists' mode of doing business");
  • 37
    • 66249128737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Valentine V. Craig, Merchant Banking: Past and Present, 14 FDIC Banking Review 29,30 (Sept 2001), online at http://www.fdic.gov/ bank/analytical/bankmg/2001sep/br2001vl4n1art2.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009) (describing the history of the private-equity market in the United States from the 1800s to the present).
    • Valentine V. Craig, Merchant Banking: Past and Present, 14 FDIC Banking Review 29,30 (Sept 2001), online at http://www.fdic.gov/ bank/analytical/bankmg/2001sep/br2001vl4n1art2.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009) (describing the history of the private-equity market in the United States from the 1800s to the present).
  • 38
    • 84868940111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Viral V. Acharya, Julian Franks, and Henri Servaes, Private Equity: Boom or Bust?, 19 J Applied Corp Fm 44, 44 (Fall 2007) (describing how new private-equity or LBO transactions amounted to $500 billion globally, of which $200 billion was spent in the United States and $140 billion in Europe).
    • Viral V. Acharya, Julian Franks, and Henri Servaes, Private Equity: Boom or Bust?, 19 J Applied Corp Fm 44, 44 (Fall 2007) (describing how new private-equity or LBO transactions amounted to $500 billion globally, of which $200 billion was spent in the United States and $140 billion in Europe).
  • 39
    • 66249126957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steven Rattner, How the Levers Fell Off the Buyout Machine, Fin Tunes 13 (Mar 25, 2008) (noting how the value of leveraged buyouts announced between July 2007 and March 2008 equaled less than half the amount achieved in June 2007 alone).
    • Steven Rattner, How the Levers Fell Off the Buyout Machine, Fin Tunes 13 (Mar 25, 2008) (noting how the value of leveraged buyouts announced between July 2007 and March 2008 equaled "less than half the amount achieved in June 2007 alone").
  • 41
    • 66249104088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Serena Ng and Liz Rappaport, Is Debt Thaw on Borrowed Time? Buyout Bids, Stock Buybacks, Junk Issues Offer Hope, but Some See Short Window, Wall St J C1 (May 15, 2008) (summarizing leveraged-lending executives' worries that a March to May 2008 improvement in the credit markets was a short-term window of opportunity for [private-equity] issuers).
    • See Serena Ng and Liz Rappaport, Is Debt Thaw on Borrowed Time? Buyout Bids, Stock Buybacks, Junk Issues Offer Hope, but Some See Short Window, Wall St J C1 (May 15, 2008) (summarizing leveraged-lending executives' worries that a March to May 2008 improvement in the credit markets was "a short-term window of opportunity for [private-equity] issuers").
  • 43
    • 66249092084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at 67
    • See id at 67.
  • 44
    • 66249135419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 45
    • 66249112277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Luc Renneboog and Tomas Simons, Public-to-private Transactions: LBOs, MBOs, MBIs and IBOs *10 (ECGI Finance Working Paper No 94/2005, Aug 2005), online at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=796047 (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • Luc Renneboog and Tomas Simons, Public-to-private Transactions: LBOs, MBOs, MBIs and IBOs *10 (ECGI Finance Working Paper No 94/2005, Aug 2005), online at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=796047 (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 47
    • 33749030268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This was demonstrated by Dan Galai and Ronald W. Masulis, The Option Pricing Model and the Risk Factor of Stock, 3 J Fin Econ 53,58-61 1976, concluding that the systemic risk of the firm, and of its equity, is not only a positive function of its leverage, but that it is a positive function of the face value of debt [as well as several other factors
    • This was demonstrated by Dan Galai and Ronald W. Masulis, The Option Pricing Model and the Risk Factor of Stock, 3 J Fin Econ 53,58-61 (1976) (concluding that "the systemic risk of the firm [ ] and of its equity [ ] is not only a positive function of its leverage ... but that it is a positive function of the face value of debt [as well as several other factors]");
  • 48
    • 66249144223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Merton, On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates, 29 J Fin 449, 466-67 (1974) (showing that until some inflection point, the return equity investors demand from a firm increases faster than the ratio of the firm's market debt to equity);
    • Robert Merton, On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates, 29 J Fin 449, 466-67 (1974) (showing that until some inflection point, the return equity investors demand from a firm increases faster than the ratio of the firm's market debt to equity);
  • 49
    • 84944831991 scopus 로고
    • A Mean-variance Synthesis of Corporate Financial Theory, 28
    • quantifying the effect of financial leverage on the risk of a firm and its corresponding expected equity rate of return
    • Mark E. Rubinstein, A Mean-variance Synthesis of Corporate Financial Theory, 28 J Fin 167, 176-77 (1973) (quantifying the effect of financial leverage on the risk of a firm and its corresponding expected equity rate of return).
    • (1973) J Fin , vol.167 , pp. 176-177
    • Rubinstein, M.E.1
  • 50
    • 66249124772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cotter and Peck, 59 J Fin Econ at 111-12 (cited in note 13) (comparing the incentives of the three types of controlling investors-management, buyout specialists, and outside investors).
    • Cotter and Peck, 59 J Fin Econ at 111-12 (cited in note 13) (comparing the incentives of the three types of controlling investors-management, buyout specialists, and outside investors).
  • 51
    • 66249145155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 52
    • 85011716131 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity, 23
    • forthcoming
    • Steven N. Kaplan and Per Strömberg, Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity, 23 J Econ Perspectives (forthcoming 2009).
    • (2009) J Econ Perspectives
    • Kaplan, S.N.1    Strömberg, P.2
  • 53
    • 66249129499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Acharya and Kehoe, Corporate Governance and Value Creation at *6 (cited in note 21) (reporting that one-third of CEOs are replaced within the first 100 days of an LBO and twothirds are gone within four years).
    • Acharya and Kehoe, Corporate Governance and Value Creation at *6 (cited in note 21) (reporting that one-third of CEOs are replaced within the first 100 days of an LBO and twothirds are gone within four years).
  • 54
    • 0000357552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bengt Holmström and Steven N. Kaplan, Corporate Governance and Merger Activity in the United States: Making Sense of the 1980s and 1990s, 15 J Econ Persp 121, 136 (2001) (arguing that LBOs disappeared in the 1990s because they were no longer needed).
    • See Bengt Holmström and Steven N. Kaplan, Corporate Governance and Merger Activity in the United States: Making Sense of the 1980s and 1990s, 15 J Econ Persp 121, 136 (2001) (arguing that LBOs disappeared in the 1990s because "they were no longer needed").
  • 55
    • 66249087737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lucian Bebchuk has been an outspoken advocate of this position. See generally, for example, Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried, Pay without Performance: The Unfulfilled Promise of Executive Compensation (Harvard 2004).
    • Lucian Bebchuk has been an outspoken advocate of this position. See generally, for example, Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried, Pay without Performance: The Unfulfilled Promise of Executive Compensation (Harvard 2004).
  • 56
    • 66249138989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, id at 1-10
    • See, for example, id at 1-10.
  • 57
    • 0040164420 scopus 로고
    • Little, Brown, The increase in hedge fund shareholder activism over the past decade may be pushing boards to a more balanced weighing of shareholder and manager interests Hedge funds' high success rates in their activist endeavors have heightened director sensitivity to their interests
    • Melvin Aron Eisenberg, The Structure of the Corporation: A Legal Analysis 146-48 (Little, Brown 1976). The increase in hedge fund shareholder activism over the past decade may be pushing boards to a more balanced weighing of shareholder and manager interests Hedge funds' high success rates in their activist endeavors have heightened director sensitivity to their interests.
    • (1976) The Structure of the Corporation: A Legal Analysis , pp. 146-148
    • Aron Eisenberg, M.1
  • 58
    • 47749145674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Alon Brav, et al, Hedge Fund Activism, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance, 63 J Fin 1729, 1733 (2008) (arguing that because hedge funds occupy an important middle ground between internal monitoring by large shareholders and external monitoring by buyout firms, they are in a potentially unique position to reduce the agency costs associated with the separation of ownership and control).
    • See Alon Brav, et al, Hedge Fund Activism, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance, 63 J Fin 1729, 1733 (2008) (arguing that because hedge funds occupy an "important middle ground" between internal monitoring by large shareholders and external monitoring by buyout firms, they are in a "potentially unique position to reduce the agency costs associated with the separation of ownership and control").
  • 59
    • 84868955796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Pub L No 107-204, 116 Stat 745, codified at 15 USC §7201 et seq.
    • Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Pub L No 107-204, 116 Stat 745, codified at 15 USC §7201 et seq.
  • 60
    • 84868955795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 USC §7262
    • 15 USC §7262.
  • 61
    • 22744451767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the Making of Quack Corporate Governance, 114
    • reporting that the cost of being public more than doubled after SOX and that it imposed a far more significant burden on small firms than on large companies, See, for example
    • See, for example, Roberta Romano, The Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the Making of Quack Corporate Governance, 114 Yale L J 1521, 1588 (2005) (reporting that the cost of being public more than doubled after SOX and that it imposed a "far more significant burden" on small firms than on large companies).
    • (2005) Yale L J , vol.1521 , pp. 1588
    • Romano, R.1
  • 62
    • 66249115654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Going Private but Staying Public: Reexamining the Effect of Sarbanes-Oxley on Firms' Going-private Decisions, 76
    • discussing how most going-private transactions require the target firm to issue high-yield debt securities, which effectively requires [the firm] to comply with SOX
    • Robert P. Bartlett III, Going Private but Staying Public: Reexamining the Effect of Sarbanes-Oxley on Firms' Going-private Decisions, 76 U Chi L Rev 7, 9 (2009) (discussing how most going-private transactions require the target firm to issue high-yield debt securities, which "effectively requires [the firm] to comply with SOX").
    • (2009) U Chi L Rev , vol.7 , pp. 9
    • Bartlett III, R.P.1
  • 63
    • 34547094805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Was the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 Really This Costly? A Discussion of Evidence from Event Studies and Going Private Decisions
    • See, 146
    • See Christian Leuz, Was the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 Really This Costly? A Discussion of Evidence from Event Studies and Going Private Decisions, 44 J Acct & Econ 146, 161 (2007).
    • (2007) J Acct & Econ , vol.44 , pp. 161
    • Leuz, C.1
  • 64
    • 66249111243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 65
    • 34548061297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Luc Renneboog, Tomas Simons, and Mike Wright, Why Do Public Firms Go Private in the UK?, 13 J Corp Fin 591, 597-98 (2007) (discussing how going private results in the elimination of the direct and indirect costs associated with maintaining a stock exchange listing).
    • Luc Renneboog, Tomas Simons, and Mike Wright, Why Do Public Firms Go Private in the UK?, 13 J Corp Fin 591, 597-98 (2007) (discussing how going private results in "the elimination of the direct and indirect costs associated with maintaining a stock exchange listing").
  • 66
    • 84935412596 scopus 로고
    • Going Private: Minority Freezeouts and Stockholder Wealth, 27
    • See
    • See Harry DeAngelo, Linda DeAngelo, and Edward M. Rice, Going Private: Minority Freezeouts and Stockholder Wealth, 27 J L & Econ 367, 400 (1984).
    • (1984) J L & Econ , vol.367 , pp. 400
    • DeAngelo, H.1    DeAngelo, L.2    Rice, E.M.3
  • 67
    • 84868937423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Renneboog and Simons, Public-to-private at *13 (cited in note 35) (estimating savings of $30,000 to $200,000 in service costs from going private).
    • Renneboog and Simons, Public-to-private at *13 (cited in note 35) (estimating savings of $30,000 to $200,000 in service costs from going private).
  • 68
    • 66249102762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jana P. Fidrmuc, Peter Roosenboom, and Dick van Dijk, Do Private Equity Investors Take Firms Private for Different Reasons? *1 (Working Paper, Feb 2007), online at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=968101 (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • Jana P. Fidrmuc, Peter Roosenboom, and Dick van Dijk, Do Private Equity Investors Take Firms Private for Different Reasons? *1 (Working Paper, Feb 2007), online at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=968101 (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 69
    • 0001661240 scopus 로고
    • Management Buyouts
    • See, 730
    • See Louis Lowenstein, Management Buyouts, 85 Colum L Rev 730, 780 (1985).
    • (1985) Colum L Rev , vol.85 , pp. 780
    • Lowenstein, L.1
  • 70
    • 66249106824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brav, et al, 63 J Fin at 1742 (cited in note 45).
    • Brav, et al, 63 J Fin at 1742 (cited in note 45).
  • 71
    • 66249124382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If a hostile offer is pending or imminent, however, it may be difficult to win a shareholder vote to approve a dual class recapitalization. Under these circumstances, an LBO or an MBO seems more likely to be a successful defense
    • If a hostile offer is pending or imminent, however, it may be difficult to win a shareholder vote to approve a dual class recapitalization. Under these circumstances, an LBO or an MBO seems more likely to be a successful defense.
  • 72
    • 66249100326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Renneboog and Simons, Public-to-private at *16-17 (cited in note 35) (summarizing academic literature that found a positive correlation between potential tax savings and the likelihood of going private).
    • See Renneboog and Simons, Public-to-private at *16-17 (cited in note 35) (summarizing academic literature that found a positive correlation between potential tax savings and the likelihood of going private).
  • 73
    • 84977728066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Steven N. Kaplan, Management Buyouts: Evidence on Taxes As a Source of Value, 44 J Fin 611, 623-24 (1989) (estimating the potential value of the tax benefits involved in an MBO for companies facing a 15 percent and a 46 percent marginal tax rate, respectively). Kaplan estimates that a company receives even higher benefits if it elects to make a step-up in basis. See id.
    • See Steven N. Kaplan, Management Buyouts: Evidence on Taxes As a Source of Value, 44 J Fin 611, 623-24 (1989) (estimating the potential value of the tax benefits involved in an MBO for companies facing a 15 percent and a 46 percent marginal tax rate, respectively). Kaplan estimates that a company receives even higher benefits if it elects to make a step-up in basis. See id.
  • 74
    • 0010719276 scopus 로고
    • Management Buy-outs: The Sources and Sharing of Wealth between Insiders and Outside Shareholders
    • 82
    • George M. Frankfurter and Erdal Gunay, Management Buy-outs: The Sources and Sharing of Wealth between Insiders and Outside Shareholders, 32 Q Rev Econ & Fm 82, 93 (1992);
    • (1992) Q Rev Econ & Fm , vol.32 , pp. 93
    • Frankfurter, G.M.1    Gunay, E.2
  • 75
    • 66249137249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lowenstein, 85 Colum L Rev at 731 (cited in note 56) (Transactions of such suspiciously little economic and social value require reappraisal.).
    • Lowenstein, 85 Colum L Rev at 731 (cited in note 56) ("Transactions of such suspiciously little economic and social value require reappraisal.").
  • 76
    • 66249092551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Renneboog and Simons, Public-to-private at *17 (cited in note 35) (arguing that going-private decisions by US firms in the 1980s were frequently motivated by anti-takeover defense strategies rather than the opportunity to appropriate tax benefits).
    • See Renneboog and Simons, Public-to-private at *17 (cited in note 35) (arguing that going-private decisions by US firms in the 1980s were frequently motivated by "anti-takeover defense strategies" rather than the opportunity to appropriate tax benefits).
  • 77
    • 66249132821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Metropolitan Life Insurance Company v RJR Nabisco, 716 F Supp 1504, 1526 (SDNY 1989).
    • See Metropolitan Life Insurance Company v RJR Nabisco, 716 F Supp 1504, 1526 (SDNY 1989).
  • 78
    • 38249022619 scopus 로고
    • Wealth Effects of Going Private for Senior Securities, 23
    • indicating that a buyout may allow management to reduce other stakeholders' claims on a firm's cash flows by, for example, cutting back staff, See
    • See Laurentius Marais, Katherine Schipper, and Abbie Smith, Wealth Effects of Going Private for Senior Securities, 23 J Fin Econ 155, 159 (1989) (indicating that a buyout may allow management to reduce other stakeholders' claims on a firm's cash flows by, for example, cutting back staff).
    • (1989) J Fin Econ , vol.155 , pp. 159
    • Marais, L.1    Schipper, K.2    Smith, A.3
  • 79
    • 66249139689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Renneboog and Simons, Public-to-private at *10 (cited in note 35).
    • See Renneboog and Simons, Public-to-private at *10 (cited in note 35).
  • 80
    • 66249145157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Marais, Schipper, and Smith, 23 J Fm Econ at 157 (cited in note 64) (finding pervasive downgradings ... of Moody's debt ratings following successful buyout proposals but indicating that there was insufficient evidence to generalize about the effects of a buyout on bond prices); Yakov Amihud, Leveraged Management Buyouts: Causes and Consequences 5 (Dow Jones-Irwin 1989).
    • Marais, Schipper, and Smith, 23 J Fm Econ at 157 (cited in note 64) (finding "pervasive downgradings ... of Moody's debt ratings following successful buyout proposals" but indicating that there was insufficient evidence to generalize about the effects of a buyout on bond prices); Yakov Amihud, Leveraged Management Buyouts: Causes and Consequences 5 (Dow Jones-Irwin 1989).
  • 81
    • 0011595191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Mark I. Weinstein, Bond Systematic Risk and the Option Pricing Model, 38 J Fm 1415, 1424-26 (1983).
    • See also Mark I. Weinstein, Bond Systematic Risk and the Option Pricing Model, 38 J Fm 1415, 1424-26 (1983).
  • 82
    • 66249145519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Arthur Warga and Ivo Welch, Bondholder Losses in Leveraged Buyouts, 6 Rev Fin Stud 959, 979 (1993) (concluding that in successful LBOs from 1985-1989, the typical bondholder lost 6 percent of the risk-adjusted value of his bonds within four months of the LBO announcement);
    • See Arthur Warga and Ivo Welch, Bondholder Losses in Leveraged Buyouts, 6 Rev Fin Stud 959, 979 (1993) (concluding that in successful LBOs from 1985-1989, the typical bondholder lost 6 percent of the risk-adjusted value of his bonds within four months of the LBO announcement);
  • 83
    • 0039798189 scopus 로고
    • Event Risk, Covenants, and Bondholder Returns in Leveraged Buyouts, 27
    • reporting that [b]onds that contain covenants, experience abnormal gains while those that do not, suffer abnormal losses
    • Paul Asquith and Thierry A. Wizman, Event Risk, Covenants, and Bondholder Returns in Leveraged Buyouts, 27 J Fin Econ 195, 212 (1990) (reporting that "[b]onds that contain covenants ... experience abnormal gains" while those "that do not... suffer abnormal losses").
    • (1990) J Fin Econ , vol.195 , pp. 212
    • Asquith, P.1    Wizman, T.A.2
  • 85
    • 84868946796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The evidence shows that post-LBO firms report small increases in employment levels, but fail to expand employment levels as fast as the rest of their industry. See Steve Thompson and Mike Wright, Corporate Governance: The Role of Restructuring Transactions, 105 Econ J 690, 697 (1995); Kaplan and Strömberg, J Econ Persp at 17-18 (cited in note 40).
    • The evidence shows that post-LBO firms report small increases in employment levels, but fail to expand employment levels as fast as the rest of their industry. See Steve Thompson and Mike Wright, Corporate Governance: The Role of Restructuring Transactions, 105 Econ J 690, 697 (1995); Kaplan and Strömberg, J Econ Persp at 17-18 (cited in note 40).
  • 86
    • 66249132445 scopus 로고
    • Reversions of Excess Pension Assets after Takeovers, 21
    • estimating that pension fund reversions account for approximately 11 percent of takeover wealth gains, See
    • See Jeffrey Pontiff, Andrei Shleifer, and Michael S. Weisbach, Reversions of Excess Pension Assets after Takeovers, 21 RAND J Econ 600, 601 (1990) (estimating that pension fund reversions account for approximately 11 percent of takeover wealth gains).
    • (1990) RAND J Econ , vol.600 , pp. 601
    • Pontiff, J.1    Shleifer, A.2    Weisbach, M.S.3
  • 87
    • 66249105124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 17CFR 240.10b5-l
    • 17CFR 240.10b5-l.
  • 88
    • 66249134373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Topps Co Shareholders Litigation, 924 A2d 951, 963 (Del Ch 2007) (Few contexts are more important to stockholders than the pendency of a transaction in which they exchange their shares for cash and the company is taken private.).
    • In re Topps Co Shareholders Litigation, 924 A2d 951, 963 (Del Ch 2007) ("Few contexts are more important to stockholders than the pendency of a transaction in which they exchange their shares for cash and the company is taken private.").
  • 89
    • 0000907091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert C. Merton, Financial Innovation and the Management and Regulation of Financial Institutions, 19 J Banking & Fin 461, 462 (1995) (claiming that the rise of derivative products could have just as easily been framed as greatly reducing risks in the system).
    • See Robert C. Merton, Financial Innovation and the Management and Regulation of Financial Institutions, 19 J Banking & Fin 461, 462 (1995) (claiming that the "rise of derivative products could have just as easily been framed as greatly reducing risks in the system").
  • 90
    • 66249105790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Gilson and Whitehead, 108 Colum L Rev at 235 (cited in note 19) (suggesting that risk management [focused] at the firm level may be more efficient than broadband risk-bearing by diversified shareholders);
    • See also Gilson and Whitehead, 108 Colum L Rev at 235 (cited in note 19) (suggesting that "risk management [focused] at the firm level may be more efficient than broadband risk-bearing by diversified shareholders");
  • 91
    • 0042099885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Derivatives in a Dynamic Environment, 88
    • characterizing equity as a risk-management device
    • Myron S. Scholes, Derivatives in a Dynamic Environment, 88 Am Econ Rev 350, 364, 366-67 (1998) (characterizing equity as a "risk-management device").
    • (1998) Am Econ Rev , vol.350 , Issue.364 , pp. 366-367
    • Scholes, M.S.1
  • 93
    • 66249083931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 466
    • Id at 466.
  • 94
    • 66249083933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 95
    • 66249097876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. See also Scholes, 88 Am Econ Rev at 366 (cited in note 73) (Ways will be found through financial engineering to provide private entities with the advantages of the public market-risk sharing, liquidity, and pricing signals-while retaining the advantages of the private market-lower disclosure and agency costs.).
    • Id. See also Scholes, 88 Am Econ Rev at 366 (cited in note 73) ("Ways will be found through financial engineering to provide private entities with the advantages of the public market-risk sharing, liquidity, and pricing signals-while retaining the advantages of the private market-lower disclosure and agency costs.").
  • 96
    • 34250795250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Sarbanes-Oxley Act and Firms' Going-private Decisions
    • Many studies find that SOX has led many small US firms to go private. See, for example, 116, Another study documents that many LBO firms were small and had IPOs in the prior five years
    • Many studies find that SOX has led many small US firms to go private. See, for example, Ellen Engel, Rachel M. Hayes, and Xue Wang, The Sarbanes-Oxley Act and Firms' Going-private Decisions, 44 J Acct & Econ 116, 118 (2007). Another study documents that many LBO firms were small and had IPOs in the prior five years.
    • (2007) J Acct & Econ , vol.44 , pp. 118
    • Engel, E.1    Hayes, R.M.2    Wang, X.3
  • 97
    • 66249131795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hamid Mehran and Stavros Peristiani, Financial Visibility and the Decision to Go Private *3-4 (Federal Reserve Bank of New York Working Paper, July 2007), online at http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/economists/ peristiani/ mehran-peristiani.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • See Hamid Mehran and Stavros Peristiani, Financial Visibility and the Decision to Go Private *3-4 (Federal Reserve Bank of New York Working Paper, July 2007), online at http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/economists/ peristiani/ mehran-peristiani.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 98
    • 66249145156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, David J. Denis and Diane K. Denis, Leveraged Recaps and the Curbing of Corporate Overinvestment, in Donald H. Chew and Stuart L. Gillan, eds, Corporate Governance at the Crossroads 318, 320 (McGraw-Hill 2005) (surveying twenty-nine leveraged recapitalizations completed between 1984 and 1988, and concluding that these companies outperformed the market by 26 percent, on average);
    • See, for example, David J. Denis and Diane K. Denis, Leveraged Recaps and the Curbing of Corporate Overinvestment, in Donald H. Chew and Stuart L. Gillan, eds, Corporate Governance at the Crossroads 318, 320 (McGraw-Hill 2005) (surveying twenty-nine leveraged recapitalizations completed between 1984 and 1988, and concluding that these companies outperformed the market by 26 percent, on average);
  • 99
    • 84989026853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Anju Seth and John Easterwood, Strategic Redirection in Large Management Buyouts: The Evidence from Post-buyout Restructuring Activity, 14 Strategic Mgmt J 251, 258 (1993) (describing how conglomerates and other firms with unrelated divisions divested assets post-buyout in order to focus on their core businesses);
    • Anju Seth and John Easterwood, Strategic Redirection in Large Management Buyouts: The Evidence from Post-buyout Restructuring Activity, 14 Strategic Mgmt J 251, 258 (1993) (describing how conglomerates and other firms with unrelated divisions divested assets post-buyout in order to focus on their core businesses);
  • 101
    • 66249118787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Galai and Masulis, 3 J Fin Econ at 57 (cited in note 37) (analogizing an optionholder who has claim to the slice of a stock's price distribution to the right of the exercise price at maturity date to a firm's stockholder who has a claim to the slice of the firm's price distribution to the right of the face value of the firm's debt at its maturity date).
    • See Galai and Masulis, 3 J Fin Econ at 57 (cited in note 37) (analogizing an optionholder who has "claim to the slice of a stock's price distribution to the right of the exercise price at maturity date" to a firm's stockholder who has a "claim to the slice of the firm's price distribution to the right of the face value of the firm's debt at its maturity date").
  • 102
    • 85015692260 scopus 로고
    • The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, 81
    • defining a European option as a security giving the right to buy or sell an asset, subject to certain conditions, on a specified future date, See also
    • See also Fischer Black and Myron Scholes, The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, 81 J Pol Econ 637, 637 (1973) (defining a "European option" as a "security giving the right to buy or sell an asset, subject to certain conditions,... on a specified future date").
    • (1973) J Pol Econ , vol.637 , pp. 637
    • Black, F.1    Scholes, M.2
  • 103
    • 66249108370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As we noted in Part II.H, an LBO may create increased conflicts of interest among the firm's debt and equity holders. When private-equity firms purchase both debt and equity interests in their portfolio firm, especially if they do so in a strip financing investment, see note 7, this will better align the private-equity firm's interests with those of both debt and equity investors in the post-buyout company.
    • As we noted in Part II.H, an LBO may create increased conflicts of interest among the firm's debt and equity holders. When private-equity firms purchase both debt and equity interests in their portfolio firm, especially if they do so in a strip financing investment, see note 7, this will better align the private-equity firm's interests with those of both debt and equity investors in the post-buyout company.
  • 105
    • 0038465465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Costly Is Financial (Not Economic) Distress? Evidence from Highly Leveraged Transactions That Became Distressed, 53
    • Gregor Andrade and Steven N. Kaplan, How Costly Is Financial (Not Economic) Distress? Evidence from Highly Leveraged Transactions That Became Distressed, 53 J Fin 1443, 1483 (1998);
    • (1998) J Fin , vol.1443 , pp. 1483
    • Andrade, G.1    Kaplan, S.N.2
  • 106
    • 84950240854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steven N. Kaplan and Jeremy C. Stein, The Evolution of Buyout Pricing and Financial Structure in the 1980s. 108 Q J Econ 313, 313-14 (1993) (finding that fees taken by buyout shops, investment banks, and lenders trended upwards during the boom in buyouts during the late 1980s growing from between 2.05 percent and 2.66 percent before 1985 to between 3.69 percent and 5.97 percent in 1988).
    • Steven N. Kaplan and Jeremy C. Stein, The Evolution of Buyout Pricing and Financial Structure in the 1980s. 108 Q J Econ 313, 313-14 (1993) (finding that fees taken by buyout shops, investment banks, and lenders trended upwards during the boom in buyouts during the late 1980s growing from between 2.05 percent and 2.66 percent before 1985 to between 3.69 percent and 5.97 percent in 1988).
  • 107
    • 66249122876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Evidence that this concern is not economically important has been found by Gregor Andrade and Steven Kaplan. They studied a sample of highly leveraged transactions that subsequently became financially distressed and estimated the effects of distress on firm value. They report that [f]rom pretransaction to distress resolution, the sample firms experience a small increase in value. In other words, the net effect of the [highly leveraged transaction] and distress is to leave value slightly higher. Andrade and Kaplan, 53 J Fin at 1487 cited in note 82, arguing that this evidence strongly suggests that highly leveraged transactions earned positive risk-adjusted returns
    • Evidence that this concern is not economically important has been found by Gregor Andrade and Steven Kaplan. They studied a sample of highly leveraged transactions that subsequently became financially distressed and estimated the effects of distress on firm value. They report that "[f]rom pretransaction to distress resolution, the sample firms experience a small increase in value. In other words, the net effect of the [highly leveraged transaction] and distress is to leave value slightly higher." Andrade and Kaplan, 53 J Fin at 1487 (cited in note 82) (arguing that this evidence "strongly suggests" that highly leveraged transactions earned positive risk-adjusted returns).
  • 108
    • 84868946797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent research suggests that these club deals may result in private-equity firms paying lower prices when acquiring firms unless the targeted firm has high institutional stock ownership. See generally Micah S. Officer, Oguzhan Ozbas, and Berk A. Sensoy, Club Deals in Leveraged Buyouts *2 USC Marshall School of Business Working Paper MKT 10-08, July 2008, online at, visited Jan 11, 2009, finding that target shareholders received on average 10 percent less in club deals and suggesting that these findings are consistent with the view that club deals may be detrimental to passive, dispersed shareholders of publicly-traded corporations
    • Recent research suggests that these club deals may result in private-equity firms paying lower prices when acquiring firms unless the targeted firm has high institutional stock ownership. See generally Micah S. Officer, Oguzhan Ozbas, and Berk A. Sensoy, Club Deals in Leveraged Buyouts *2 (USC Marshall School of Business Working Paper MKT 10-08, July 2008), online at http://ssrn. com/abstract=1128404 (visited Jan 11, 2009) (finding that target shareholders received on average 10 percent less in club deals and suggesting that these findings are "consistent with the view that club deals may be detrimental to passive, dispersed shareholders of publicly-traded corporations").
  • 109
    • 66249115413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Audra L. Boone and J. Harold Mulherin, Do Private Equity Consortiums Impede Takeover Competition? *7 (AFA 2009 San Francisco Meetings Paper, May 2008), online at http:// ssrn.com/abstract=1104224 (visited Jan 11, 2009) (reporting that the median number of bidders in consortium deals is 2.84). Boone and Mulherin estimate that target returns for private equity consortium bidders from sixty-three days before the takeover until completion were not measurably different than for private-equity firms bidding alone.
    • See Audra L. Boone and J. Harold Mulherin, Do Private Equity Consortiums Impede Takeover Competition? *7 (AFA 2009 San Francisco Meetings Paper, May 2008), online at http:// ssrn.com/abstract=1104224 (visited Jan 11, 2009) (reporting that the median number of bidders in consortium deals is 2.84). Boone and Mulherin estimate that target returns for "private equity consortium bidders" from sixty-three days before the takeover until completion were "not measurably different" than for private-equity firms bidding alone.
  • 110
    • 66249117434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at *19-20
    • Id at *19-20.
  • 111
    • 66249131418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Viral V. Acharya and Timothy C. Johnson, More Insiders, More Insider Trading: Evidence from Private Equity Buyouts *1 (London Business School Working Paper, Nov 2007), online at http://facultyresearch. london.edu/docs/Acharya-Johnson-Insider-Trading-Takeoverspdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • See Viral V. Acharya and Timothy C. Johnson, More Insiders, More Insider Trading: Evidence from Private Equity Buyouts *1 (London Business School Working Paper, Nov 2007), online at http://facultyresearch. london.edu/docs/Acharya-Johnson-Insider-Trading-Takeoverspdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 112
    • 66249143868 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To see a measure of the rapid growth of derivatives trading and outstanding contracts, see the summaries of annual levels of exchange-traded and over-the-counter (OTC) derivative contracts reported by the International Swaps and Derivatives Association, Summaries of Market Survey Results, online at http://www.isda.org/statistics/recent.html (visited Jan 11, 2009). For US bank derivatives activity,
    • To see a measure of the rapid growth of derivatives trading and outstanding contracts, see the summaries of annual levels of exchange-traded and over-the-counter (OTC) derivative contracts reported by the International Swaps and Derivatives Association, Summaries of Market Survey Results, online at http://www.isda.org/statistics/recent.html (visited Jan 11, 2009). For US bank derivatives activity,
  • 113
    • 66249114439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Comptroller of the Currency Administrator of National Banks, OCC's Quarterly Report on Bank Derivatives Activities, online at http://www.occtreas.gov/deriv/deriv.htm (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • see Comptroller of the Currency Administrator of National Banks, OCC's Quarterly Report on Bank Derivatives Activities, online at http://www.occtreas.gov/deriv/deriv.htm (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 115
    • 84868937424 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Companies have between sixty and ninety days after the end of their fiscal year to file their Form 10-K and between forty and forty-five days after the end of each fiscal quarter to file their Form 10-Q. See Form 10-K, General Instructions A(2, online at, visited Jan 11, 2009);
    • Companies have between sixty and ninety days after the end of their fiscal year to file their Form 10-K and between forty and forty-five days after the end of each fiscal quarter to file their Form 10-Q. See Form 10-K, "General Instructions" A(2), online at http://www.sec.gov/about/ forms/form10-k.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009);
  • 116
    • 66249091701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Form 10-Q, General Instructions A(1), online at http://www.sec.gov/about/forms/form10-q.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • Form 10-Q, "General Instructions" A(1), online at http://www.sec.gov/about/forms/form10-q.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 118
    • 66249115069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scholes, 88 Am Econ Rev at 367 (cited in note 73) (noting how standard accounting does not decompose profitability into profits from market forces and profits from managerial efforts, nor does it describe the sensitivities of the firm's profit and loss to market factors). In an earlier paper, Scholes states, A whole new system of risk accounting must be developed. Current accounting systems concentrate on static valuations Swaps, foreign exchange contracts, and other OTC derivatives have no initial value. As a result, they are 'off balance sheet.' There is no place for them in the current accounting world.
    • Scholes, 88 Am Econ Rev at 367 (cited in note 73) (noting how standard accounting does not "decompose profitability into profits from market forces and profits from managerial efforts, nor does it describe the sensitivities of the firm's profit and loss to market factors"). In an earlier paper, Scholes states, "A whole new system of risk accounting must be developed. Current accounting systems concentrate on static valuations Swaps, foreign exchange contracts, and other OTC derivatives have no initial value. As a result, they are 'off balance sheet.' There is no place for them in the current accounting world."
  • 119
    • 21344461605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Global Financial Markets, Derivative Securities, and Systemic Risks, 12
    • Myron S Scholes, Global Financial Markets, Derivative Securities, and Systemic Risks, 12 J Risk & Uncertainty 271, 284 (1996).
    • (1996) J Risk & Uncertainty , vol.271 , pp. 284
    • Scholes, M.S.1
  • 121
    • 66249090298 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 122
    • 66249145518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 89 for a discussion of the time lags for filing Forms 10-K and 10-Q.
    • See note 89 for a discussion of the time lags for filing Forms 10-K and 10-Q.
  • 123
    • 66249148775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, the changing composition of mortgage pools, which many mortgage-backed securities allow, increases the difficulty of valuing these pools on a mark-to-market basis
    • For example, the changing composition of mortgage pools, which many mortgage-backed securities allow, increases the difficulty of valuing these pools on a mark-to-market basis.
  • 124
    • 84868946798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is the one good reason for relying on an exchange-clearing corporation to be the counterparty in all trades. Unfortunately, most derivative trades occur off the floors of derivative exchanges. See International Swaps and Derivatives Association, Summaries of Market Survey Results (2008, online at visited Jan 11, 2009, cited in note 87, reporting that by mid-2008, the notional amount of off-exchange interest rate derivatives had grown to $464.7 trillion
    • This is the one good reason for relying on an exchange-clearing corporation to be the counterparty in all trades. Unfortunately, most derivative trades occur off the floors of derivative exchanges. See International Swaps and Derivatives Association, Summaries of Market Survey Results (2008), online at http://www.isda.org/statistics/recent.html (visited Jan 11, 2009) (cited in note 87) (reporting that by mid-2008, the notional amount of off-exchange interest rate derivatives had grown to $464.7 trillion).
  • 125
    • 67849092906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enterprise Risk Management: Theory and Practice
    • 8
    • Brian W. Nocco and René M. Stulz, Enterprise Risk Management: Theory and Practice, 18 J Applied Corp Fin 8, 15 (2006).
    • (2006) J Applied Corp Fin , vol.18 , pp. 15
    • Nocco, B.W.1    Stulz, R.M.2
  • 126
    • 66249083241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Senior Manager's Guide to Integrated Risk Management
    • See, Winter
    • See Lisa K. Meulbroek, A Senior Manager's Guide to Integrated Risk Management, 14 J Applied Corp Fin 56, 61 (Winter 2002).
    • (2002) 14 J Applied Corp Fin , vol.56 , pp. 61
    • Meulbroek, L.K.1
  • 127
    • 66249087738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 19 J Banking & Fin at 472 (cited in note 73); Scholes
    • Merton, 19 J Banking & Fin at 472 (cited in note 73); Scholes, 88 Am Econ Rev at 364 (cited in note 73).
    • Am Econ Rev at 364 (cited in note 73) , vol.88
    • Merton1
  • 128
    • 66249131419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Andrew S. Grove, Stigmatizing Business, Wash Post A23 (July 17, 2002) ([S]tock exchanges should require that boards of directors be predominantly made up of independent members having no financial relationship with the company.).
    • See, for example, Andrew S. Grove, Stigmatizing Business, Wash Post A23 (July 17, 2002) ("[S]tock exchanges should require that boards of directors be predominantly made up of independent members having no financial relationship with the company.").
  • 129
    • 23844525494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Growth of Executive Pay, 21
    • finding that compensation growth cannot be explained by changes in firm size, performance, or industry mix, See, for example
    • See, for example, Lucian Bebchuk and Yaniv Grinstein, The Growth of Executive Pay, 21 Oxford Rev Econ Policy 283, 284 (2005) (finding that compensation growth cannot be explained by changes in firm size, performance, or industry mix);
    • (2005) Oxford Rev Econ Policy , vol.283 , pp. 284
    • Bebchuk, L.1    Grinstein, Y.2
  • 130
    • 66249084991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael C. Jensen and Kevin Murphy. Remuneration: Where We've Been, How We Got to Here, What Are the Problems, and How to Fix Them *29 (Harvard Business School Working Paper No 04-28, ECGI Finance Working Paper No 44/2004, July 2004), online at http://ssrn.com/abstract=561305 (visited Jan 11, 2009) (discussing how giving large compensation packages despite poor performance is not in the best interests of the firm);
    • Michael C. Jensen and Kevin Murphy. Remuneration: Where We've Been, How We Got to Here, What Are the Problems, and How to Fix Them *29 (Harvard Business School Working Paper No 04-28, ECGI Finance Working Paper No 44/2004, July 2004), online at http://ssrn.com/abstract=561305 (visited Jan 11, 2009) (discussing how giving large compensation packages despite poor performance is not in the best interests of the firm);
  • 131
    • 66249102761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jensen, 48 J Fin at 866-67 (cited in note 24) (Without the direction of an independent leader, it is much more difficult for [a] board to perform its critical function.).
    • Jensen, 48 J Fin at 866-67 (cited in note 24) ("Without the direction of an independent leader, it is much more difficult for [a] board to perform its critical function.").
  • 132
    • 67449106320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Byoung-Hyoun Hwang and Seoyoung Kim, It Pays to Have Friends. J Fin Econ (forthcoming 2009), online at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1195313 (visited Jan 11, 2009) (finding that from 1996 to 2005, 87 percent of Fortune 100 boards could be classified as conventionally independent, whereas only 62 percent could be classified as socially independent).
    • See Byoung-Hyoun Hwang and Seoyoung Kim, It Pays to Have Friends. J Fin Econ (forthcoming 2009), online at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1195313 (visited Jan 11, 2009) (finding that from 1996 to 2005, 87 percent of Fortune 100 boards could be classified as "conventionally independent," whereas only 62 percent could be classified as "socially independent").
  • 133
    • 66249129126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ronald Masulis and Shawn Mobbs find that given their firm-specific knowledge, inside directors can be very beneficial to board decisionmaking, especially when they have some independence and serve on the boards of high-tech and other information-intensive firms. See Ronald W. Masulls and Shawn Mobbs, Are All Inside Directors the Same? CEO Entrenchment or Board Enhancement *3 (Third Annual Conference on Empirical Studies Paper, American Finance Association 2009 San Francisco Meetings Paper, Mar 2008), online at http://ssrn.com/abstract= 1108036 (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • Ronald Masulis and Shawn Mobbs find that given their firm-specific knowledge, inside directors can be very beneficial to board decisionmaking, especially when they have some independence and serve on the boards of high-tech and other information-intensive firms. See Ronald W. Masulls and Shawn Mobbs, Are All Inside Directors the Same? CEO Entrenchment or Board Enhancement *3 (Third Annual Conference on Empirical Studies Paper, American Finance Association 2009 San Francisco Meetings Paper, Mar 2008), online at http://ssrn.com/abstract= 1108036 (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 134
    • 66249116419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For evidence of LBO board activity, see generally Acharya and Kehoe, Corporate Governance and Value Creation: Evidence from Private Equity (cited in note 21) (finding that evidence from private-equity transactions in the United Kingdom from 1996 to 2004 indicates that buyout firms take an active stance on firm ownership and governance);
    • For evidence of LBO board activity, see generally Acharya and Kehoe, Corporate Governance and Value Creation: Evidence from Private Equity (cited in note 21) (finding that evidence from private-equity transactions in the United Kingdom from 1996 to 2004 indicates that buyout firms take an active stance on firm ownership and governance);
  • 135
    • 66249134041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cornelli and Karakas, Private Equity and Corporate Governance: Do LBOs Have More Effective Boards? (cited in note 21) (finding that private-equity board members are more actively involved in complex transactions than board members backed by nonfinancial sponsors);
    • Cornelli and Karakas, Private Equity and Corporate Governance: Do LBOs Have More Effective Boards? (cited in note 21) (finding that private-equity board members are more actively involved in complex transactions than board members backed by nonfinancial sponsors);
  • 136
    • 66249089608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gertner and Kaplan, The Valuemaximizing Board (cited in note 21) (finding that as compared to public companies, the boards of private-equity-controlled firms are smaller, control larger equity stakes, and meet less frequently, while directors are younger and have shorter tenures).
    • Gertner and Kaplan, The Valuemaximizing Board (cited in note 21) (finding that as compared to public companies, the boards of private-equity-controlled firms are smaller, control larger equity stakes, and meet less frequently, while directors are younger and have shorter tenures).
  • 137
    • 66249128383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One implication of this is that FIs are unlikely to be serious competitors to the privateequity firms. This is especially true given the various regulatory constraints they face in holding significant amounts of equity in illiquid, privately held firms. The one exception to this statement is the creation of venture capital subsidiaries by some major commercial banks
    • One implication of this is that FIs are unlikely to be serious competitors to the privateequity firms. This is especially true given the various regulatory constraints they face in holding significant amounts of equity in illiquid, privately held firms. The one exception to this statement is the creation of venture capital subsidiaries by some major commercial banks.
  • 139
    • 66249121508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is surprising that banking authorities have not required banks to move this derivatives market-making activity to a centralized exchange where transparency is enhanced and bank exposure to counterparty default risk is greatly reduced
    • It is surprising that banking authorities have not required banks to move this derivatives market-making activity to a centralized exchange where transparency is enhanced and bank exposure to counterparty default risk is greatly reduced.
  • 141
    • 66249090991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 142
    • 66249147679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 477 predicting that central banks and other government policymakers are likely to become increasingly familiar with derivatives and the advanced financial technology used by financial institutions
    • Id at 477 (predicting that central banks and other government policymakers are "likely to become increasingly familiar" with derivatives and the "advanced financial technology" used by financial institutions).
  • 144
    • 66249087389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a detailed discussion of the accounting treatment of derivatives, see generally, McGraw-Hill
    • For a detailed discussion of the accounting treatment of derivatives, see generally Mark A.Trombley, Accounting for Derivatives and Hedging (McGraw-Hill 2003).
    • (2003) Accounting for Derivatives and Hedging
    • Trombley, M.A.1
  • 145
    • 66249147002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See General Accounting Office (GAO), Financial Derivatives: Actions Needed to Protect the Financial System, Report No GAO/GGD-94-133 to Congressional Requesters 12 (May 1994), online at http://archive.gao.gov/ t2pbat3/151647.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009), which earlier raised these concerns, and Scholes, 12 J Risk & Uncertainty at 273 (cited in note 90), which gave a critical response to the GAO report.
    • See General Accounting Office (GAO), Financial Derivatives: Actions Needed to Protect the Financial System, Report No GAO/GGD-94-133 to Congressional Requesters 12 (May 1994), online at http://archive.gao.gov/ t2pbat3/151647.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009), which earlier raised these concerns, and Scholes, 12 J Risk & Uncertainty at 273 (cited in note 90), which gave a critical response to the GAO report.
  • 146
    • 66249113637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • More recently, see International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report: Containing Systemic Risks and Restoring Financial Soundness 87 (Apr 2008), online at http://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/GFSR/ 2008/01/pdf/text.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009) (summarizing evidence that from July 2007 to April 2008, increased market volatility and higher default risks of potential counterparties made prices so unreliable that no trading took place at those prices).
    • More recently, see International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report: Containing Systemic Risks and Restoring Financial Soundness 87 (Apr 2008), online at http://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/GFSR/ 2008/01/pdf/text.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009) (summarizing evidence that from July 2007 to April 2008, increased market volatility and higher default risks of potential counterparties made prices so unreliable that "no trading took place at those prices").
  • 147
    • 66249133717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kenneth Scott argues that this trend is driven in part by legal liability from the In re Caremark decision of the Delaware Chancery Court and SOX's emphasis on internal controls and audit committees, but perhaps more importantly by the financial advantages to firms from adopting risk management. See Kenneth E. Scott, The Role of Corporate Governance in Coping with Risks and Unknowns *7-8 (Stanford Law and Economics Olin Working Paper No 356, Apr 2008), online at http://www.law.stanford.edu/publications/details/3993 (visited Jan 11, 2009),
    • Kenneth Scott argues that this trend is driven in part by legal liability from the In re Caremark decision of the Delaware Chancery Court and SOX's emphasis on internal controls and audit committees, but perhaps more importantly by the financial advantages to firms from adopting risk management. See Kenneth E. Scott, The Role of Corporate Governance in Coping with Risks and Unknowns *7-8 (Stanford Law and Economics Olin Working Paper No 356, Apr 2008), online at http://www.law.stanford.edu/publications/details/3993 (visited Jan 11, 2009),
  • 148
    • 66249085329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing In re Caremark International Inc Derivative Litigation, 698 A2d 959 (Del Ch 1996). See also Gilson and Whitehead, 108 Colum L Rev at 249 (cited in note 19) (stating that corporate risk management has only emerged in the last thirty years).
    • citing In re Caremark International Inc Derivative Litigation, 698 A2d 959 (Del Ch 1996). See also Gilson and Whitehead, 108 Colum L Rev at 249 (cited in note 19) (stating that corporate risk management has only emerged in the last thirty years).
  • 150
    • 66249105791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nocco and Stulz, 18 J Applied Corp Fin at 8 (cited in note 96).
    • Nocco and Stulz, 18 J Applied Corp Fin at 8 (cited in note 96).
  • 151
    • 66249134374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 152
    • 66249086000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 10
    • Id at 10.
  • 153
    • 66249129500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • us See Ont Gadiesh and Hugh MacArthur, Lessons from Private Equity Any Company Can Use 62-67 (Harvard Business 2008) (discussing how private-equity investors focus on forward-looking operational metrics such as revenue churn, retention rates, and return on invested capital);
    • us See Ont Gadiesh and Hugh MacArthur, Lessons from Private Equity Any Company Can Use 62-67 (Harvard Business 2008) (discussing how private-equity investors focus on forward-looking operational metrics such as revenue churn, retention rates, and return on invested capital);
  • 154
    • 66249093953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thompson and Wright, 105 Econ J at 701 (cited in note 69) (evaluating the extent that LBOs are an innovation in corporate governance and how far they remedy the agency problems associated with diffuse shareholdings and management control).
    • Thompson and Wright, 105 Econ J at 701 (cited in note 69) (evaluating the extent that LBOs are an innovation in corporate governance and how far they remedy the agency problems associated with diffuse shareholdings and management control).
  • 155
    • 0000139691 scopus 로고
    • Moral Hazard and Observability, 10
    • developing a model of optimal risk-sharing between principals and agents when the principal can monitor only the outcome of the agent's actions, For the pathbreaking article on this point, see
    • For the pathbreaking article on this point, see Bengt Holmström, Moral Hazard and Observability, 10 Bell J Econ 74, 75-80 (1979) (developing a model of optimal risk-sharing between principals and agents when the principal can monitor only the outcome of the agent's actions).
    • (1979) Bell J Econ , vol.74 , pp. 75-80
    • Holmström, B.1
  • 156
    • 66249091340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is worth noting that a small board reduces the financial cost of creating good director incentives
    • It is worth noting that a small board reduces the financial cost of creating good director incentives.
  • 157
    • 66249097878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An interesting issue worthy of empirical documentation is the percentage of privateequity directors who have substantial financial expertise
    • An interesting issue worthy of empirical documentation is the percentage of privateequity directors who have substantial financial expertise.
  • 158
    • 66249122877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Editorial, The Banks and Private Equity, NY Tunes WK9 (Aug 3, 2008) (indicating that the previous rules discouraged private-equity investment in the financial sector because privateequity firms could not gain control over target banks).
    • Editorial, The Banks and Private Equity, NY Tunes WK9 (Aug 3, 2008) (indicating that the previous rules discouraged private-equity investment in the financial sector because privateequity firms could not gain control over target banks).
  • 159
    • 66249126395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See text accompanying note 4 for a discussion of this change
    • See text accompanying note 4 for a discussion of this change.
  • 160
    • 66249119138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The most likely reason for this is that private-equity firms are unwilling to be regulated by the Federal Reserve as financial holding companies, which would be one result of them acquiring an FI. If this is correct, then the Federal Reserve needs to consider relaxing this rule. Presumably it would make its decision by weighing the cost-benefit tradeoffs of allowing large, loosely regulated capital injections from private-equity firms and closer risk monitoring versus the potentially negative impact of a reduction in federal oversight of these institutions
    • The most likely reason for this is that private-equity firms are unwilling to be regulated by the Federal Reserve as financial holding companies, which would be one result of them acquiring an FI. If this is correct, then the Federal Reserve needs to consider relaxing this rule. Presumably it would make its decision by weighing the cost-benefit tradeoffs of allowing large, loosely regulated capital injections from private-equity firms and closer risk monitoring versus the potentially negative impact of a reduction in federal oversight of these institutions.
  • 161
    • 66249140718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Given the federal government's decision to become a large stakeholder in many FIs through its recent investments in those firms under the Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP), it is interesting to speculate over whether the Federal Reserve should have considered creating much greater incentives for private-equity investors to invest in FIs. Presumably the privateequity firms would create stronger forward-looking risk monitoring controls at FIs (as well as better monitoring of compensation levels) than what the federal government has been able to do as of the time that this Article went to press.
    • Given the federal government's decision to become a large stakeholder in many FIs through its recent investments in those firms under the Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP), it is interesting to speculate over whether the Federal Reserve should have considered creating much greater incentives for private-equity investors to invest in FIs. Presumably the privateequity firms would create stronger forward-looking risk monitoring controls at FIs (as well as better monitoring of compensation levels) than what the federal government has been able to do as of the time that this Article went to press.
  • 162
    • 66249148774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James Cotter and Sarah Peck find that sophisticated buyout shops use less short-term debt and need less senior debt because these private-equity investors do a better job of monitoring their portfolio companies. See Cotter and Peck, 59 J Fin Econ at 123-24 cited in note 13
    • James Cotter and Sarah Peck find that sophisticated buyout shops use less short-term debt and need less senior debt because these private-equity investors do a better job of monitoring their portfolio companies. See Cotter and Peck, 59 J Fin Econ at 123-24 (cited in note 13).
  • 163
    • 66249091339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Charles K. Whitehead, The Evolution of Debt: Covenants, the Credit Market and Corporate Governance *23-24 (Boston University School of Law Working Paper No 8-26, Jan 2009), online at http://www.bu.edu/law/faculty/ scholarship/workingpapers/documents/WhiteheadC090208.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
    • See Charles K. Whitehead, The Evolution of Debt: Covenants, the Credit Market and Corporate Governance *23-24 (Boston University School of Law Working Paper No 8-26, Jan 2009), online at http://www.bu.edu/law/faculty/ scholarship/workingpapers/documents/WhiteheadC090208.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009).
  • 164
    • 66249121832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One seemingly contradictory piece of evidence is the recent popularity of covenant-lite debt when institutional investors were competing to lend to private-equity borrowers. This appears to represent a serious failure in the commercial bank decisionmaking process that has had adverse consequences See Acharya, Franks, and Servaes, 19 J Applied Corp Fin at 52 cited in note 28, characterizing covenant-lite loans as a manifestation of weak lending standards and incentives to monitor
    • One seemingly contradictory piece of evidence is the recent popularity of covenant-lite debt when institutional investors were competing to lend to private-equity borrowers. This appears to represent a serious failure in the commercial bank decisionmaking process that has had adverse consequences See Acharya, Franks, and Servaes, 19 J Applied Corp Fin at 52 (cited in note 28) (characterizing covenant-lite loans as "a manifestation of weak lending standards and incentives to monitor").
  • 165
    • 66249110916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thompson and Wright, 105 Econ J at 692-93 (cited in note 69).
    • Thompson and Wright, 105 Econ J at 692-93 (cited in note 69).
  • 166
    • 66249113284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Nishant Dass and Massimo Massa, The Bank-firm Relationships Tradeoff between Better Governance and Greater Information Asymmetry *4 (INSEAD Working Paper, Sept 2008), online at http://fic.wharton.upenn.edu/fic/corporate%20finance%202006/Massa.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009) (finding that public firms that have a more exclusive relationship with their lending banks experience roughly a 1 percent increase in information asymmetry (insider trading) for every 10 percent increase in exclusivity).
    • See, for example, Nishant Dass and Massimo Massa, The Bank-firm Relationships Tradeoff between Better Governance and Greater Information Asymmetry *4 (INSEAD Working Paper, Sept 2008), online at http://fic.wharton.upenn.edu/fic/corporate%20finance%202006/Massa.pdf (visited Jan 11, 2009) (finding that public firms that have a more exclusive relationship with their lending banks experience roughly a 1 percent increase in information asymmetry (insider trading) for every 10 percent increase in exclusivity).
  • 168
    • 66249092552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Martin Arnold, USS Commits to US Buy-out Fund, Fin Times 21 (June 18, 2008) (describing UK pension funds joining the trend of US and Canadian pension funds by investing in private-equity buyout funds).
    • See, for example, Martin Arnold, USS Commits to US Buy-out Fund, Fin Times 21 (June 18, 2008) (describing UK pension funds joining the trend of US and Canadian pension funds by investing in private-equity buyout funds).
  • 169
    • 66249147324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.