메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 20, Issue 2, 2004, Pages 237-272

Rigidity and the Affliction of Capitalist Property: Colonial Land Revenue and the Recasting of Nature

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 61649094311     PISSN: 02576430     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1177/025764300402000204     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (10)

References (152)
  • 2
    • 79959006791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Process of Commercialisation under Colonial Conditions
    • New Delhi
    • Utsa Patnaik, ‘The Process of Commercialisation under Colonial Conditions’, in idem, The Long Transition: Essays on Political Economy, New Delhi, 1999, pp. 252–97.
    • (1999) The Long Transition: Essays on Political Economy , pp. 252-297
    • Patnaik, U.1
  • 6
    • 84998112615 scopus 로고
    • Market and Nature
    • See the chapter titled
    • See the chapter titled ‘Market and Nature’, in The Great Transformation, 1957 pp. 178–91.
    • (1957) The Great Transformation , pp. 178-191
  • 8
    • 77956217066 scopus 로고
    • For an elaboration of the differences in social and political organization between the Garjat and the Mughalbandhi refer to, New Delhi
    • For an elaboration of the differences in social and political organization between the Garjat and the Mughalbandhi refer to B. Pati, Resisting Domination: Peasants, Tribals and the National Movement in Orissa 1920–50, New Delhi, 1993, pp. 1–59.
    • (1993) Resisting Domination: Peasants, Tribals and the National Movement in Orissa 1920–50 , pp. 1-59
    • Pati, B.1
  • 10
    • 79958906646 scopus 로고
    • Minute on Tenures in Orissa, 10 October 1821
    • in G. Toynbee, Cuttack, (Appendix)
    • A. Stirling, ‘Minute on Tenures in Orissa, 10 October 1821’, in G. Toynbee, A Sketch of the History of Orissa from 1803–1828, Cuttack, 1873, p. ix (Appendix).
    • (1873) A Sketch of the History of Orissa from 1803–1828 , pp. ix
    • Stirling, A.1
  • 11
    • 84998135682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • During the Maratha regime, the title of zamindar was given only to the holders of one or more parganas and to the rajas of killas (forts). In the later sanads, however, the terms zamindar and ta'allqdar were used synonymously. Refer to
    • During the Maratha regime, the title of zamindar was given only to the holders of one or more parganas and to the rajas of killas (forts). In the later sanads, however, the terms zamindar and ta'allqdar were used synonymously. Refer to Patra, Orissa, p. 2.
    • Orissa , pp. 2
    • Patra1
  • 13
    • 79958932094 scopus 로고
    • For an account of the revenue administration during the Mughal period see, Calcutta
    • For an account of the revenue administration during the Mughal period see M.A. Haque, Muslim Administration in Orissa (1568–1751 A.D.), Calcutta, 1980, pp. 226–42.
    • (1980) Muslim Administration in Orissa (1568–1751 A.D.) , pp. 226-242
    • Haque, M.A.1
  • 16
    • 84997938150 scopus 로고
    • According to Satish Chandra, the weakening of the Mughal imperial authority and the crisis of the jagirdari system in the eighteenth century led to the abandonment of the old Mughal system of checks and balances in which the faujdar held the administrative power and the jagirdar merely collected the revenue. The collapse of this arrangement gave a powerful fillip to a process of ‘re-feudalization’, wherein revenue collection rights, which included administrative powers, were regularly auctioned to revenue contractors. See, Calcutta, The revenue collector, on the other hand, had no administrative powers
    • According to Satish Chandra, the weakening of the Mughal imperial authority and the crisis of the jagirdari system in the eighteenth century led to the abandonment of the old Mughal system of checks and balances in which the faujdar held the administrative power and the jagirdar merely collected the revenue. The collapse of this arrangement gave a powerful fillip to a process of ‘re-feudalization’, wherein revenue collection rights, which included administrative powers, were regularly auctioned to revenue contractors. See Satish Chandra, The 18th Century in India: Its Economy and the Role of the Marathas, the Jats, the Sikhs and the Afghans, Calcutta, 1982, p. 22. The revenue collector, on the other hand, had no administrative powers.
    • (1982) The 18th Century in India: Its Economy and the Role of the Marathas, the Jats, the Sikhs and the Afghans , pp. 22
    • Chandra, S.1
  • 19
    • 84997855964 scopus 로고
    • Orissa Under Foreign Government, Mughal and Maratha (1568–1803)
    • in N.K. Sahu, ed., Calcutta
    • W.W. Hunter, ‘Orissa Under Foreign Government, Mughal and Maratha (1568–1803)’, in N.K. Sahu, ed., A History of Orissa, Vol. I, Calcutta, 1956, p. 176.
    • (1956) A History of Orissa , vol.1 , pp. 176
    • Hunter, W.W.1
  • 20
    • 84997915894 scopus 로고
    • He does not specify, however, the areas or estates from which this amount was drawn, nor does he clarify the exchange rate for the rupee vis-à-vis the kauri, the currency in which the collections were made. W. Ewer, Commissioner, to B. Bayley, acting Chief Secretary to Government, 13 May 1818, Calcutta, (Henceforth Ewer's Report)
    • He does not specify, however, the areas or estates from which this amount was drawn, nor does he clarify the exchange rate for the rupee vis-à-vis the kauri, the currency in which the collections were made. W. Ewer, Commissioner, to B. Bayley, acting Chief Secretary to Government, 13 May 1818, Selections from the Correspondence on the Settlement of the Khoordah Estate in the District of Pooree, Vol. I, Calcutta, 1879, p. 20 (Henceforth Ewer's Report).
    • (1879) Selections from the Correspondence on the Settlement of the Khoordah Estate in the District of Pooree , vol.1 , pp. 20
  • 22
    • 79958926649 scopus 로고
    • During the Mughal and Maratha periods the chief currency in Orissa was the kauri or cowry, which was a seashell imported from the Maldives. See, Cuttack
    • During the Mughal and Maratha periods the chief currency in Orissa was the kauri or cowry, which was a seashell imported from the Maldives. See B.C. Ray, Foundations of British Orissa, Cuttack, 1960, pp. 187–203.
    • (1960) Foundations of British Orissa , pp. 187-203
    • Ray, B.C.1
  • 23
    • 84919968425 scopus 로고
    • The Cowry Currency in India
    • Also see, April
    • Also see Sushil Chandra De, ‘The Cowry Currency in India’, The Orissa Historical Research Journal, Vol. I, April 1952.
    • (1952) The Orissa Historical Research Journal , vol.1
    • De, S.C.1
  • 24
    • 0004237038 scopus 로고
    • For an enumeration of the various types of rupees in use, consult, Delhi, (reprint)
    • For an enumeration of the various types of rupees in use, consult Henry Yule and A.C. Burnell, Hobson-Jobson, Delhi, 1986 (reprint), pp. 774–76.
    • (1986) Hobson-Jobson , pp. 774-776
    • Yule, H.1    Burnell, A.C.2
  • 25
    • 84993742001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Intransigent Shroffs and the English East India Company Reforms in Bengal (1757–1800)
    • Also see, (henceforth IESHR)
    • Also see Shubra Chakrabarti, ‘Intransigent Shroffs and the English East India Company Reforms in Bengal (1757–1800)’, Indian Economic and Social History Review (henceforth IESHR), 34, 1, 1997, pp. 72–78.
    • (1997) Indian Economic and Social History Review , vol.34 , Issue.1 , pp. 72-78
    • Chakrabarti, S.1
  • 28
  • 29
    • 84998175934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 4th Judge, Calcutta Court of Circuit, to W.B. Bayley, Secretary to Government in the Judicial Department, 3 May 1817, in, The owner of the Mahanadi ferry was granted a jagir of 240 beeghas of land and the grant for the Kathjuri ferry was 200 beeghas
    • E. Watson, 4th Judge, Calcutta Court of Circuit, to W.B. Bayley, Secretary to Government in the Judicial Department, 3 May 1817, in De, Guide to Orissa Records, p. 7. The owner of the Mahanadi ferry was granted a jagir of 240 beeghas of land and the grant for the Kathjuri ferry was 200 beeghas.
    • De, Guide to Orissa Records , pp. 7
    • Watson, E.1
  • 30
    • 79958960757 scopus 로고
    • The History of Orissa under the Mohammedan, Maratha, and English Rule
    • in Sahu, ed.
    • J. Beames, ‘The History of Orissa under the Mohammedan, Maratha, and English Rule’, 1875, in Sahu, ed., A History of Orissa, Vol. II, p. 310.
    • (1875) A History of Orissa , vol.2 , pp. 310
    • Beames, J.1
  • 34
    • 84974138011 scopus 로고
    • State Formation Reconsidered
    • (henceforth MAS)
    • Frank Perlin, ‘State Formation Reconsidered’, Modern Asian Studies (henceforth MAS), 19, 3, 1985, pp. 415–80.
    • (1985) Modern Asian Studies , vol.19 , Issue.3 , pp. 415-480
    • Perlin, F.1
  • 35
    • 79958940369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a view challenging the predatory thesis in Orissa, see, Calcutta
    • For a view challenging the predatory thesis in Orissa, see R.D. Banerji, History of Orissa, Calcutta, 1931, pp. 90–115.
    • (1931) History of Orissa , pp. 90-115
    • Banerji, R.D.1
  • 37
    • 79958940369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a detailed account of the Mughal-Maratha conflict in the Orissa delta see
    • For a detailed account of the Mughal-Maratha conflict in the Orissa delta see Banerji, History of Orissa, pp. 90–115.
    • History of Orissa , pp. 90-115
    • Banerji1
  • 38
    • 3843055356 scopus 로고
    • A peshkashi zamindari was not subject to a detailed assessment of land actually under cultivation while a mal-wajib zamindar was expected to pay revenue on the basis of actual measurement of land under cultivation. See, New Delhi (reprint)
    • A peshkashi zamindari was not subject to a detailed assessment of land actually under cultivation while a mal-wajib zamindar was expected to pay revenue on the basis of actual measurement of land under cultivation. See N.A. Siddiqi, Land Revenue Administration Under the Mughals, New Delhi (reprint), 1989, pp. 22–24.
    • (1989) Land Revenue Administration Under the Mughals , pp. 22-24
    • Siddiqi, N.A.1
  • 39
    • 84997913219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maddox, Final Report, Vol. I, pp. 159–60.
    • Final Report , vol.1 , pp. 159-160
    • Maddox1
  • 40
    • 79958979602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Notes on Akbar's Subahs
    • According to Beames the word killah though referring to a fort was in actual fact a much ‘humbler affair’. It was for the most part merely the house of a zamindar surrounded by an earthen rampart or breastwork and occasionally a rude moat. These skeletal defences were then ‘girdled by a thick belt of bamboo and rattan jungle’, which was intended to prevent incursions from the Mughal cavalry. See
    • According to Beames the word killah though referring to a fort was in actual fact a much ‘humbler affair’. It was for the most part merely the house of a zamindar surrounded by an earthen rampart or breastwork and occasionally a rude moat. These skeletal defences were then ‘girdled by a thick belt of bamboo and rattan jungle’, which was intended to prevent incursions from the Mughal cavalry. See John Beames, ‘Notes on Akbar's Subahs’, p. 96.
    • Beames, J.1
  • 42
    • 84997913219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maddox, Final Report, Vol. I, pp. 159–60.
    • Final Report , vol.1 , pp. 159-160
    • Maddox1
  • 43
    • 79958979602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Notes on Akbar's Subahs
    • According to the Ain-i-Akbari, Orissa in its greatest dimensions when attached to the subah of Bengal in 1592, included five sarkars. The sarkars of Kalinga and Rajamundry were later amalgamated with the subah of Hyderabad. The Marathas, in fact, were only in control of the remaining three sarkars, i.e., Jellasore, Bhadrak and Cuttack. See
    • According to the Ain-i-Akbari, Orissa in its greatest dimensions when attached to the subah of Bengal in 1592, included five sarkars. The sarkars of Kalinga and Rajamundry were later amalgamated with the subah of Hyderabad. The Marathas, in fact, were only in control of the remaining three sarkars, i.e., Jellasore, Bhadrak and Cuttack. See John Beames, ‘Notes on Akbar's Subahs’, pp. 94–106.
    • Beames, J.1
  • 44
    • 79958913109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The qanungo essentially maintained records relating to the interests in the land. The chaudhuri attested revenue papers and was also associated with the tasks of collecting the revenue. In Bengal the title ta'allqdar generally referred to a small zamindar or holder of a zamindari which was recently purchased and was not of long standing. See, 87–91
    • The qanungo essentially maintained records relating to the interests in the land. The chaudhuri attested revenue papers and was also associated with the tasks of collecting the revenue. In Bengal the title ta'allqdar generally referred to a small zamindar or holder of a zamindari which was recently purchased and was not of long standing. See Siddiqi, Land Revenue Administration, pp. 25–28, 87–91.
    • Land Revenue Administration , pp. 25-28
    • Siddiqi1
  • 45
    • 84998007855 scopus 로고
    • In the eighteenth century the appellation ta'allqdar could refer to either a revenue-farmer or a small zamindar. On the whole, a ta'allqdar was smaller than the zamindar and referred to a person who had contracted to pay revenue not only of his own zamindari but for the zamindaris of other persons as well. In effect, the ta'allqdar contracted for only a part of the revenue while the zamindar was responsible for his entire holding. See, Aligarh
    • In the eighteenth century the appellation ta'allqdar could refer to either a revenue-farmer or a small zamindar. On the whole, a ta'allqdar was smaller than the zamindar and referred to a person who had contracted to pay revenue not only of his own zamindari but for the zamindaris of other persons as well. In effect, the ta'allqdar contracted for only a part of the revenue while the zamindar was responsible for his entire holding. See Irfan Habib, The Agrarian System of Mughal India (1556–1707), Aligarh, 1963, pp. 172–73.
    • (1963) The Agrarian System of Mughal India (1556–1707) , pp. 172-173
    • Habib, I.1
  • 47
    • 84998023974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Report on the Settlement Operations in the District of Balasore
    • in Maddox
    • D.H. Kingsford, ‘Report on the Settlement Operations in the District of Balasore’, in Maddox, Final Report, Vol. II, p. 456.
    • Final Report , vol.2 , pp. 456
    • Kingsford, D.H.1
  • 48
    • 84997885449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The early Hindu rulers grouped the revenue villages into khands or bisis which were then apparently transformed into the Mughal pargana. The divisional accountants—khandpatis or bhoimuls—became the chaudhuris and qanungos, while the village pradhan was retitled the muqaddam. See
    • The early Hindu rulers grouped the revenue villages into khands or bisis which were then apparently transformed into the Mughal pargana. The divisional accountants—khandpatis or bhoimuls—became the chaudhuris and qanungos, while the village pradhan was retitled the muqaddam. See Maddox, Final Report, Vol. I, pp. 158–59.
    • Final Report , vol.1 , pp. 158-159
    • Maddox1
  • 50
    • 0005638055 scopus 로고
    • Agrarian Relations and Land Revenue
    • in Tapan Raychaudhuri and Irfan Habib, eds, Delhi
    • I. Habib, ‘Agrarian Relations and Land Revenue’, in Tapan Raychaudhuri and Irfan Habib, eds, The Cambridge Economic History of India, Vol. I, Delhi, 1982, p. 239.
    • (1982) The Cambridge Economic History of India , vol.1 , pp. 239
    • Habib, I.1
  • 54
    • 0347293432 scopus 로고
    • Also see, Oxford, Siddiqi confirms Habib's observation that the volume of produce rents was automatically lower in bad seasons
    • Also see Asiya Siddiqi, Agrarian Change in a Northern Indian State: Uttar Pradesh 1819–1833, Oxford, 1973, pp. 54–65. Siddiqi confirms Habib's observation that the volume of produce rents was automatically lower in bad seasons.
    • (1973) Agrarian Change in a Northern Indian State: Uttar Pradesh 1819–1833 , pp. 54-65
    • Siddiqi, A.1
  • 55
    • 84998055956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N.A. Siddiqi has argued that for crop-sharing, one-half was a maximum demand, rarely implemented, while most rates were pitched at one-ninth, one-fourth and one-third. This pattern of crop-sharing made a wide accommodation for variations in soil types, nature of crops grown, amount of labour and capital involved, etc. In effect, local contexts and circumstances went into the determination of the share. See
    • N.A. Siddiqi has argued that for crop-sharing, one-half was a maximum demand, rarely implemented, while most rates were pitched at one-ninth, one-fourth and one-third. This pattern of crop-sharing made a wide accommodation for variations in soil types, nature of crops grown, amount of labour and capital involved, etc. In effect, local contexts and circumstances went into the determination of the share. See Siddiqi, Land Revenue Administration, pp. 47–48.
    • Land Revenue Administration , pp. 47-48
    • Siddiqi1
  • 57
    • 0007274206 scopus 로고
    • Zamindars and Jotedars: A Study of Rural Politics in Bengal
    • Rajat Ray and Ratna Ray, ‘Zamindars and Jotedars: A Study of Rural Politics in Bengal’, MAS, Vol. 9, 2, 1975.
    • (1975) MAS , vol.9 , Issue.2
    • Ray, R.1    Ray, R.2
  • 58
    • 84998098227 scopus 로고
    • Power Structure and Agricultural Productivity in Eastern India, 1757–1947
    • B.B. Chaudhuri has underlined the importance of these zamindars in the agrarian economy of Bengal by identifying a number of their vital functions such as the maintenance of embankments, irrigation works and even the distribution of water. See, in Meghnad Desai, Susanne Hoeber et al., eds, New Delhi
    • B.B. Chaudhuri has underlined the importance of these zamindars in the agrarian economy of Bengal by identifying a number of their vital functions such as the maintenance of embankments, irrigation works and even the distribution of water. See B.B. Chaudhuri, ‘Power Structure and Agricultural Productivity in Eastern India, 1757–1947’, in Meghnad Desai, Susanne Hoeber et al., eds, Agrarian Power and Agricultural Productivity in Asia, New Delhi, 1984, p. 107.
    • (1984) Agrarian Power and Agricultural Productivity in Asia , pp. 107
    • Chaudhuri, B.B.1
  • 59
    • 0024884830 scopus 로고
    • Agricultural Production, Social Participation and Domination in Late Eighteenth-Century Bengal: Towards an Alternative Explanation
    • Rajat Datta, similarly, has noted some of these indispensable links in rural Bengal, wherein zamindars were the sources for agricultural credit and flood works (pulbandi). See, 1 October
    • Rajat Datta, similarly, has noted some of these indispensable links in rural Bengal, wherein zamindars were the sources for agricultural credit and flood works (pulbandi). See Rajat Datta, ‘Agricultural Production, Social Participation and Domination in Late Eighteenth-Century Bengal: Towards an Alternative Explanation’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 17, 1 October 1989, p. 87.
    • (1989) Journal of Peasant Studies , vol.17 , pp. 87
    • Datta, R.1
  • 61
    • 84998055173 scopus 로고
    • Some Institutional Factors in Providing Capital Inputs and Expansion of Cultivation in Medieval India
    • 1 July
    • Satish Chandra, ‘Some Institutional Factors in Providing Capital Inputs and Expansion of Cultivation in Medieval India’, Indian Historical Review, 3, 1 July 1976, pp. 89–92.
    • (1976) Indian Historical Review , vol.3 , pp. 89-92
    • Chandra, S.1
  • 64
    • 70349545392 scopus 로고
    • New Delhi, Hasan listed the following intermediaries: muqaddam, chaudhuri, ta'allqdar and qanungo. All of these officials were present in the Orissa Mughalbandi
    • Saiyid Nurul Hasan, Thoughts on Agrarian Relations in Mughal India, New Delhi, 1973, pp. 29–32. Hasan listed the following intermediaries: muqaddam, chaudhuri, ta'allqdar and qanungo. All of these officials were present in the Orissa Mughalbandi.
    • (1973) Thoughts on Agrarian Relations in Mughal India , pp. 29-32
    • Hasan, S.N.1
  • 69
    • 0345520981 scopus 로고
    • W.H. Moreland has argued that revenue farming during the Mughal period was concentrated on the financial rather than the ameliorative side of administration. Consequently, revenue farming was a purely extractive arrangement independent of any reciprocal obligations for ensuring conditions of productivity through investments etc. See, Delhi, (second reprint)
    • W.H. Moreland has argued that revenue farming during the Mughal period was concentrated on the financial rather than the ameliorative side of administration. Consequently, revenue farming was a purely extractive arrangement independent of any reciprocal obligations for ensuring conditions of productivity through investments etc. See W.H. Moreland, The Agrarian System of Moslem India, Delhi, 1994 (second reprint), pp. 10–11;
    • (1994) The Agrarian System of Moslem India , pp. 10-11
    • Moreland, W.H.1
  • 71
    • 79959030375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Slow Conquest: Administrative Integration of Malwa into the Maratha Empire 1720–60
    • Stewart Gordon, ‘The Slow Conquest: Administrative Integration of Malwa into the Maratha Empire 1720–60’, in idem, Marathas, pp. 38–45.
    • Marathas , pp. 38-45
    • Gordon, S.1
  • 73
    • 84972343640 scopus 로고
    • Maratha Revenue Farming
    • Also see
    • Also see Wink, ‘Maratha Revenue Farming’, MAS, 17, 4, 1983, pp. 591–612.
    • (1983) MAS , vol.17 , Issue.4 , pp. 591-612
    • Wink1
  • 74
    • 84998121979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some historians of Mughal India, however, view the practice of ijara or revenue farming as having been detrimental to agrarian production. N.A. Siddiqi argues that the rise of the ijaradars in the eighteenth century adversely affected both agriculture and the land revenue administration of the Mughals. See
    • Some historians of Mughal India, however, view the practice of ijara or revenue farming as having been detrimental to agrarian production. N.A. Siddiqi argues that the rise of the ijaradars in the eighteenth century adversely affected both agriculture and the land revenue administration of the Mughals. See Siddiqi, Land Revenue Administration, pp. 97–99.
    • Land Revenue Administration , pp. 97-99
    • Siddiqi1
  • 75
    • 84971951664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also, Habib, however, notes that despite the ‘official disapproval’ of ijara, individual villages that had fallen into ruin were sometimes farmed with the express condition that the revenue farmer would restore them to prosperity
    • See also Habib, Agrarian System, pp. 234–36. Habib, however, notes that despite the ‘official disapproval’ of ijara, individual villages that had fallen into ruin were sometimes farmed with the express condition that the revenue farmer would restore them to prosperity.
    • Agrarian System , pp. 234-236
    • Habib1
  • 76
    • 0002773569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andre Wink has argued that the Mughal and Maratha form of sovereignty relied on a ‘balancing system of continually shifting alliances and rivalries’. See
    • Andre Wink has argued that the Mughal and Maratha form of sovereignty relied on a ‘balancing system of continually shifting alliances and rivalries’. See Wink, Land and Sovereignty, p. 34.
    • Land and Sovereignty , pp. 34
    • Wink1
  • 77
    • 84928091367 scopus 로고
    • The Zamindars and Mughal Power in the Deccan 1685–1712
    • For an insight into the tensions between the intermediary zamindar and the primary zamindar, and their shifting loyalties between the Mughals and Marathas, see
    • For an insight into the tensions between the intermediary zamindar and the primary zamindar, and their shifting loyalties between the Mughals and Marathas, see Muzaffar Alam, ‘The Zamindars and Mughal Power in the Deccan 1685–1712’, IESHR, 11, 1, 1974, pp. 74–91.
    • (1974) IESHR , vol.11 , Issue.1 , pp. 74-91
    • Alam, M.1
  • 78
    • 79959002870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H. Ricketts, Collector of Balasore, to G. Stockwell, Commissioner of Revenue, Cuttack, 20 October 1831, in, Appendix
    • H. Ricketts, Collector of Balasore, to G. Stockwell, Commissioner of Revenue, Cuttack, 20 October 1831, in Toynbee, History of Orissa, Appendix, p. li.
    • History of Orissa , pp. li
    • Toynbee1
  • 80
    • 79958878520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • District of Balasore
    • D.H. Kingsford wrongly gives 1773 as the year for the changes introduced by Raja Ram Pandit. See
    • D.H. Kingsford wrongly gives 1773 as the year for the changes introduced by Raja Ram Pandit. See Kingsford, ‘District of Balasore’, p. 429.
    • Kingsford1
  • 83
    • 84998153732 scopus 로고
    • Ricketts to Stockwell
    • 20 October, Appendix
    • Ricketts to Stockwell, 20 October 1831, Appendix, p. xlvii.
    • (1831) , pp. xlvii
  • 85
    • 79958894394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The History of Orissa
    • 91
    • Beames, ‘The History of Orissa’, p. 317, 91.
    • Beames1
  • 88
    • 0004000174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legibility is described by James Scott as aspects of statecraft directed at rendering societies accessible and malleable to state functions such as taxation, conscription and the prevention of rebellion. See, New Haven
    • Legibility is described by James Scott as aspects of statecraft directed at rendering societies accessible and malleable to state functions such as taxation, conscription and the prevention of rebellion. See James C. Scott, Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed, New Haven, 1998, pp. 1–47.
    • (1998) Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed , pp. 1-47
    • Scott, J.C.1
  • 90
    • 84919953105 scopus 로고
    • Maratha Revenue Administration in Orissa
    • lxxlv
    • Usha Ray, ‘Maratha Revenue Administration in Orissa’, in Bengal Past and Present, Vol. lxxlv, 138–39, 1955, p. 63.
    • (1955) Bengal Past and Present , Issue.138-39 , pp. 63
    • Ray, U.1
  • 91
    • 84998163480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maddox, Final Report, Vol. I, pp. 162–64.
    • Final Report , vol.1 , pp. 162-164
    • Maddox1
  • 92
    • 79958902924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Report on Settlement Operations in the District of Puri
    • in Maddox
    • H. McPherson, ‘Report on Settlement Operations in the District of Puri’, in Maddox, Final Report, Vol. II, pp. 591–92.
    • Final Report , vol.2 , pp. 591-592
    • McPherson, H.1
  • 94
    • 0013540703 scopus 로고
    • ‘… change from social relationships based on “interests” to those based on exclusive claims of ownership has been one of the greatest consequences of the period of British rule.’, New Delhi
    • ‘… change from social relationships based on “interests” to those based on exclusive claims of ownership has been one of the greatest consequences of the period of British rule.’ Ainslie T. Embree, Imagining India: Essays on Indian History, New Delhi, 1987, p. 7.
    • (1987) Imagining India: Essays on Indian History , pp. 7
    • Embree, A.T.1
  • 95
    • 84974151777 scopus 로고
    • Studying a Colonial Economy without Perceiving Colonialism
    • Irfan Habib, ‘Studying a Colonial Economy without Perceiving Colonialism’, Modern Asian Studies, 19, 3, 1985, p. 309.
    • (1985) Modern Asian Studies , vol.19 , Issue.3 , pp. 309
    • Habib, I.1
  • 97
    • 79958878520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • District of Balasore
    • Kingsford, ‘District of Balasore’, p. 430.
    • Kingsford1
  • 98
    • 84998110751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion on the kist timing and the collection schedules, refer to
    • For a discussion on the kist timing and the collection schedules, refer to Maddox, Final Report, Vol. I, pp. 240–42.
    • Final Report , vol.1 , pp. 240-242
    • Maddox1
  • 99
    • 79958940408 scopus 로고
    • Land Relations and Agrarian Development: A Comparative Historical Study of Two Districts in Orissa
    • unpublished Ph.D. thesis, Centre for Development Studies, Thiruvananthapuram
    • Sakti Padhi, ‘Land Relations and Agrarian Development: A Comparative Historical Study of Two Districts in Orissa’, unpublished Ph.D. thesis, Centre for Development Studies, Thiruvananthapuram, 1986, p. 73.
    • (1986) , pp. 73
    • Padhi, S.1
  • 101
    • 84998182119 scopus 로고
    • Collector, to A. Stirling, Secretary to the Commissioner
    • Cuttack, Revenue, December, to 30 September 1818, Several cases are listed in this volume with detailed description of sales
    • W. Trower, Collector, to A. Stirling, Secretary to the Commissioner, Cuttack, CDR, Revenue, Vol. 16, December 1817 to 30 September 1818, pp. 2–6. Several cases are listed in this volume with detailed description of sales.
    • (1817) CDR , vol.16 , pp. 2-6
    • Trower, W.1
  • 103
    • 84998027948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Minute
    • Appendix
    • Stirling, ‘Minute’, Appendix, p. vii.
    • Stirling1
  • 104
    • 84971951664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While Abul Fazl viewed taqqavi as loans for extending cultivation, Todar Mal argued that it was to be given to cultivators only during ‘distressed circumstances’. The taqqavi loans were interest-free and usually made available through the chaudhuris and muqaddams. See
    • While Abul Fazl viewed taqqavi as loans for extending cultivation, Todar Mal argued that it was to be given to cultivators only during ‘distressed circumstances’. The taqqavi loans were interest-free and usually made available through the chaudhuris and muqaddams. See Habib, Agrarian System, pp. 253–55.
    • Agrarian System , pp. 253-255
    • Habib1
  • 105
    • 84998176732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Col. H.S. Jarrett, trans.
    • Ain-i-Akbari, Col. H.S. Jarrett, trans., Vol. LI, pp. 43–44
    • Ain-i-Akbari , vol.51 , pp. 43-44
  • 107
    • 84919955263 scopus 로고
    • Aurangzeb's Farman to Rasikdas: On Problems of Revenue Administration, 1665
    • In a farman to Rasikdas, the Mughal officials were impressed upon to strive for ‘progressively populating the desolate villages’, to get the cultivable land cultivated and even repair old wells and dig new ones. See, in Irfan Habib, ed., Delhi
    • In a farman to Rasikdas, the Mughal officials were impressed upon to strive for ‘progressively populating the desolate villages’, to get the cultivable land cultivated and even repair old wells and dig new ones. See Shireen Moosvi, ‘Aurangzeb's Farman to Rasikdas: On Problems of Revenue Administration, 1665’, in Irfan Habib, ed., Medieval India: Researches in the History of India 1200–1750, Delhi, 1992, pp. 197–206.
    • (1992) Medieval India: Researches in the History of India 1200–1750 , pp. 197-206
    • Moosvi, S.1
  • 109
    • 79958892179 scopus 로고
    • The Social Distribution of Landed Property in Pre-British India: A Historical Survey
    • and, in Irfan Habib, ed., New Delhi
    • and ‘The Social Distribution of Landed Property in Pre-British India: A Historical Survey’, in Irfan Habib, ed., Essays in Indian History, New Delhi, 1995.
    • (1995) Essays in Indian History
  • 110
    • 84973188083 scopus 로고
    • The Zamindar's Share in the Peasant Surplus in the Mughal Empire—Evidence of the Ain-i-Akbari Statistics
    • For an approximation on the zamindar's share of the surplus see
    • For an approximation on the zamindar's share of the surplus see Shireen Moosvi, ‘The Zamindar's Share in the Peasant Surplus in the Mughal Empire—Evidence of the Ain-i-Akbari Statistics’, IESHR, 15, 3, 1978.
    • (1978) IESHR , vol.15 , Issue.3
    • Moosvi, S.1
  • 111
    • 84972014753 scopus 로고
    • Agrarian Society and the Pax Britannica in Northern India in the Early Nineteenth Century
    • Eric Stokes, ‘Agrarian Society and the Pax Britannica in Northern India in the Early Nineteenth Century’, MAS, 9, 4, 1975, p. 508.
    • (1975) MAS , vol.9 , Issue.4 , pp. 508
    • Stokes, E.1
  • 112
    • 79958920119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indian Reality and British Conceptions: The Agrarian Scene in South Vizagapatnam in the 18th and 19th Centuries
    • in Peter Robb, ed., New Delhi, 161, 132–33
    • Benedicte Hjejle, ‘Indian Reality and British Conceptions: The Agrarian Scene in South Vizagapatnam in the 18th and 19th Centuries’, in Peter Robb, ed., Meanings of Agriculture, New Delhi, 1996, p.159, 161, 132–33.
    • (1996) Meanings of Agriculture , pp. 159
    • Hjejle, B.1
  • 114
    • 84971951664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also, ‘… under all methods of revenue assessment [of the Mughal administration] there was some provision for relief in the case of bad harvests’
    • See also Habib, Agrarian System, pp. 249–56: ‘… under all methods of revenue assessment [of the Mughal administration] there was some provision for relief in the case of bad harvests’.
    • Agrarian System , pp. 249-256
    • Habib1
  • 115
    • 84997938195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recovery from Adversity in Eighteenth Century India: Re-thinking “village”, “peasants” and Politics in Pre-Modern Kingdoms
    • For the Marathas, see
    • For the Marathas, see Stewart Gordon, ‘Recovery from Adversity in Eighteenth Century India: Re-thinking “village”, “peasants” and Politics in Pre-Modern Kingdoms’ in idem, Marathas, p. 102.
    • Marathas , pp. 102
    • Gordon, S.1
  • 116
    • 11244350631 scopus 로고
    • In the district of Nanchilnadu (Tamil Nadu), the remission given by local lords, apart from enabling the peasantry to overcome bad harvests, was also directed at reproducing the political power structure of ‘personal dominance and deference’ between tenants and landlords. See, New Delhi
    • In the district of Nanchilnadu (Tamil Nadu), the remission given by local lords, apart from enabling the peasantry to overcome bad harvests, was also directed at reproducing the political power structure of ‘personal dominance and deference’ between tenants and landlords. See M.S.S. Pandian, The Political Economy of Agrarian Change: Nanchilnadu, 1880–1939, New Delhi, 1990, pp. 64–68.
    • (1990) The Political Economy of Agrarian Change: Nanchilnadu, 1880–1939 , pp. 64-68
    • Pandian, M.S.S.1
  • 117
    • 79958913109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the description of the Mughal provincial administration in
    • See the description of the Mughal provincial administration in Siddiqi, Land Revenue Administration.
    • Land Revenue Administration
    • Siddiqi1
  • 119
    • 79958922487 scopus 로고
    • Property in Land, Land Market and Tenancy Relations in the Colonial Period: A Review of Theoretical Categories and Study of a Zamindari District
    • Sakti Padhi describes the village headman as a ‘Janus-like entity’ who was simultaneously the representative of the state and the embodiment of the collective interests of the village. See, in K.N. Raj, Sumit Guha and Sakti Padhi, eds, Delhi
    • Sakti Padhi describes the village headman as a ‘Janus-like entity’ who was simultaneously the representative of the state and the embodiment of the collective interests of the village. See Sen, ‘Property in Land, Land Market and Tenancy Relations in the Colonial Period: A Review of Theoretical Categories and Study of a Zamindari District’, in K.N. Raj, Sumit Guha and Sakti Padhi, eds, Essays on the Commercialisation of Agriculture, Delhi, 1985, pp. 10–11.
    • (1985) Essays on the Commercialisation of Agriculture , pp. 10-11
    • Sen1
  • 120
    • 60549091717 scopus 로고
    • Letter of the Collector of Cuttack to the Board of Revenue on 17 November 1808, Acc. No. 10, Revenue Records. Quoted in, Delhi
    • Letter of the Collector of Cuttack to the Board of Revenue on 17 November 1808, Acc. No. 10, Revenue Records. Quoted in K.C. Jena, Socio-Economic Condition of Orissa, Delhi, 1978, p. 12.
    • (1978) Socio-Economic Condition of Orissa , pp. 12
    • Jena, K.C.1
  • 121
    • 79958876374 scopus 로고
    • Peasants and British Rule in Orissa
    • By 1837, these middle tenure holders or sub-proprietary tenure holders were collecting barely one-fourth of the annual revenue in the erstwhile Mughalbandi. See, 8–9 Aug–Sep
    • By 1837, these middle tenure holders or sub-proprietary tenure holders were collecting barely one-fourth of the annual revenue in the erstwhile Mughalbandi. See Pradipto Chaudhuri, ‘Peasants and British Rule in Orissa’, Social Scientist, 19, 8–9 Aug–Sep 1991, p. 30.
    • (1991) Social Scientist , vol.19 , pp. 30
    • Chaudhuri, P.1
  • 122
    • 84998027948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Minute
    • Appendix
    • Stirling, ‘Minute’, Appendix, p. xlv.
    • Stirling1
  • 123
    • 79958866122 scopus 로고
    • Society and Economy in the Deccan, 1818–1850
    • Sumit Guha's study of the Deccan is illuminating in this regard. He notes that the colonial regime by turning land into a ‘divisible saleable and qualitatively differentiated factor of production’, effectively ended up separating land from office and property from privilege. Consequently, instead of strengthening the previous elites with new privileges, the colonial regime ‘penetrated and disjointed’ a variety of local institutions, wherein, the ‘patil's office ceased to be that of a village manager and became merely the lowest rung of the administrative ladder and hereditary officials ceased to be magnates and gradually were reduced to landlords only.’, in Burton Stein, ed., New Delhi
    • Sumit Guha's study of the Deccan is illuminating in this regard. He notes that the colonial regime by turning land into a ‘divisible saleable and qualitatively differentiated factor of production’, effectively ended up separating land from office and property from privilege. Consequently, instead of strengthening the previous elites with new privileges, the colonial regime ‘penetrated and disjointed’ a variety of local institutions, wherein, the ‘patil's office ceased to be that of a village manager and became merely the lowest rung of the administrative ladder and hereditary officials ceased to be magnates and gradually were reduced to landlords only.’ Sumit Guha, ‘Society and Economy in the Deccan, 1818–1850’, in Burton Stein, ed., The Making of Agrarian Policy in India, New Delhi, 1992, pp. 187–214.
    • (1992) The Making of Agrarian Policy in India , pp. 187-214
    • Guha, S.1
  • 124
    • 79958912023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Productive power in Agriculture: A Survey of Work on the Local History of British India
    • David Ludden noted that, whereas the pre-British zamindars had been founts of patronage and authority for the provision of public goods, the new landlords instituted by the decree of 1793 became the ‘focal point for the local accumulation of capital in cash and kind’, in Desai, et al., eds
    • David Ludden noted that, whereas the pre-British zamindars had been founts of patronage and authority for the provision of public goods, the new landlords instituted by the decree of 1793 became the ‘focal point for the local accumulation of capital in cash and kind’. David Ludden, ‘Productive power in Agriculture: A Survey of Work on the Local History of British India’, in Desai, et al., eds, Agrarian Power, pp. 64–65.
    • Agrarian Power , pp. 64-65
    • Ludden, D.1
  • 125
    • 84920036731 scopus 로고
    • From Raja to Landlord: the Oudh Ta'allqdar 1850–1870
    • Thomas Metcalf's essay on the Oudh ta'allqdar concludes similarly that the ta'allqdar, following British rule, was transformed from being a ruler of men (a petty raja) to a landlord, and was hence bound to those beneath him only by ‘ties of rent and revenue.’ Such a ta'allqdar consequently found it expedient to seek tangible gains by increasing cash rentals and exploiting his powers as landlord, in Robert Frykenberg, ed., New Delhi
    • Thomas Metcalf's essay on the Oudh ta'allqdar concludes similarly that the ta'allqdar, following British rule, was transformed from being a ruler of men (a petty raja) to a landlord, and was hence bound to those beneath him only by ‘ties of rent and revenue.’ Such a ta'allqdar consequently found it expedient to seek tangible gains by increasing cash rentals and exploiting his powers as landlord. Thomas R. Metcalf, ‘From Raja to Landlord: the Oudh Ta'allqdar 1850–1870’, in Robert Frykenberg, ed., Land Control and Social Structure in Indian History, New Delhi, 1979, p. 137.
    • (1979) Land Control and Social Structure in Indian History , pp. 137
    • Metcalf, T.R.1
  • 126
    • 84972625559 scopus 로고
    • The Evolution of Land Relations in Eastern India Under British Rule
    • In Bengal, Amit Bhaduri has argued, the introduction of the zamindari system initiated, among many other changes, the commercialization of sub-tenurial rights. This led to a proliferation of intermediaries below the zamindar and choked off investment in land, there being no viable mechanism for sharing the costs and benefits between the zamindar and his innumerable tenants
    • In Bengal, Amit Bhaduri has argued, the introduction of the zamindari system initiated, among many other changes, the commercialization of sub-tenurial rights. This led to a proliferation of intermediaries below the zamindar and choked off investment in land, there being no viable mechanism for sharing the costs and benefits between the zamindar and his innumerable tenants. Amit Bhaduri, ‘The Evolution of Land Relations in Eastern India Under British Rule’, IESHR, 12, 1, 1976, p. 48.
    • (1976) IESHR , vol.12 , Issue.1 , pp. 48
    • Bhaduri, A.1
  • 127
    • 84997885378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See especially clause 5 and 6
    • Maddox, Final Report, Vol. II, p. 596. See especially clause 5 and 6.
    • Final Report , vol.2 , pp. 596
    • Maddox1
  • 129
    • 84998175695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 28–29
    • Ewer's Report, p. 33, 28–29.
    • Ewer's Report , pp. 33
  • 131
    • 84998105089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Clause 12, in
    • See Clause 12, in Maddox, Final Report, Vol. I, p. 163.
    • Final Report , vol.1 , pp. 163
    • Maddox1
  • 132
    • 0003830029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a survey of the ‘Indo-Islamic’ intelligence and surveillance systems operative in pre-colonial India, see, Cambridge, In the Rajput courts in the eighteenth century, according to Bayly, revenue farmers established their own information networks and particular rapport with village accountants and revenue overseers in order to ensure the success of their collection strategies. These magnates, in turn inevitably sought to choke information flows to the rulers about the actual revenue potential in the region. See especially, p. 31
    • For a survey of the ‘Indo-Islamic’ intelligence and surveillance systems operative in pre-colonial India, see C.A. Bayly, Empire and Information: Intelligence Gathering and Social Communication in India, 1780–1870, Cambridge, 1996, pp. 10–55. In the Rajput courts in the eighteenth century, according to Bayly, revenue farmers established their own information networks and particular rapport with village accountants and revenue overseers in order to ensure the success of their collection strategies. These magnates, in turn inevitably sought to choke information flows to the rulers about the actual revenue potential in the region. See especially, p. 31.
    • (1996) Empire and Information: Intelligence Gathering and Social Communication in India, 1780–1870 , pp. 10-55
    • Bayly, C.A.1
  • 133
    • 79958988618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maratha Revenue Administration
    • Usha Ray, ‘Maratha Revenue Administration’, p. 62.
    • Ray, U.1
  • 136
    • 84998038357 scopus 로고
    • London, In the next twenty-two years (1830–52), a total of £91,889 was remitted, while the figure for the next fifteen years (1852–67) was £397,088. Hunter calculated the average annual sum remitted for 1852–67 at roughly £26,472 per annum, which, by his estimate, approximated nearly 16 per cent of the total annual land tax of that period
    • W.W. Hunter, Orissa or the Vicissitudes of an Indian Province Under Native and British Rule, Vol. II, London, 1872, p. 181. In the next twenty-two years (1830–52), a total of £91,889 was remitted, while the figure for the next fifteen years (1852–67) was £397,088. Hunter calculated the average annual sum remitted for 1852–67 at roughly £26,472 per annum, which, by his estimate, approximated nearly 16 per cent of the total annual land tax of that period.
    • (1872) Orissa or the Vicissitudes of an Indian Province Under Native and British Rule , vol.2 , pp. 181
    • Hunter, W.W.1
  • 138
    • 79958987742 scopus 로고
    • Calcutta, Cotton based this observation on his study of the early papers of the Company's administration in the Orissa delta
    • Arthur Cotton, Report on the Mahanuddy River, Calcutta, 1858, p. 8. Cotton based this observation on his study of the early papers of the Company's administration in the Orissa delta.
    • (1858) Report on the Mahanuddy River , pp. 8
    • Cotton, A.1
  • 139
    • 84997856022 scopus 로고
    • Trower to Stirling, 26 November 1818, Bengal Revenue Consultations, 13 May 1819, quoted in, Cuttack, Amli was the local era of Orissa, it began from the twelfth day of the second half of the lunar month of Bhadra, between 27 August and 26 September of the English year. The British authorities calculated the era from the middle of September. Amli era 1211, for example, was equivalent to the English year September 1803 to September 1804
    • Trower to Stirling, 26 November 1818, Bengal Revenue Consultations, 13 May 1819, quoted in B.C. Ray, Foundations of British Orissa, Cuttack, 1960, p. 168. Amli was the local era of Orissa, it began from the twelfth day of the second half of the lunar month of Bhadra, between 27 August and 26 September of the English year. The British authorities calculated the era from the middle of September. Amli era 1211, for example, was equivalent to the English year September 1803 to September 1804.
    • (1960) Foundations of British Orissa , pp. 168
    • Ray, B.C.1
  • 140
    • 84972707349 scopus 로고
    • A Permanent Settlement for the Ceded and Conquered Provinces: Revenue Administration in North India, 1801–1833
    • The East India Company went through a financial crisis in the early decades of the nineteenth century. The fourth Mysore war (1789–99), the second Maratha war (1803–5) and the task of administering the new territorial acquisitions in the Carnatic, Awadh and the Central Provinces, severely strained the Company's internal organization and finances. This period, therefore, witnessed an attempt by the EIC to ‘extract the maximum of India's resources with the minimum effort …’. See, 6, 6–7, 12
    • The East India Company went through a financial crisis in the early decades of the nineteenth century. The fourth Mysore war (1789–99), the second Maratha war (1803–5) and the task of administering the new territorial acquisitions in the Carnatic, Awadh and the Central Provinces, severely strained the Company's internal organization and finances. This period, therefore, witnessed an attempt by the EIC to ‘extract the maximum of India's resources with the minimum effort …’. See Michael Mann, ‘A Permanent Settlement for the Ceded and Conquered Provinces: Revenue Administration in North India, 1801–1833’, IESHR, 32, 2, 1995, pp. 250–67, 6, 6–7, 12.
    • (1995) IESHR , vol.32 , Issue.2 , pp. 250-267
    • Mann, M.1
  • 142
    • 79958879358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recovery from Adversity
    • Gordon, ‘Recovery from Adversity’, pp. 102–3.
    • Gordon1
  • 143
    • 79959030375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Slow Conquest
    • Gordon, ‘The Slow Conquest’, pp. 46–47.
    • Gordon1
  • 144
    • 79955255018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The British principle of ‘non-interference’ or rather, lack of administrative penetration in the early period of their rule in the Doab districts of north India had a debilitating effect on rural credit and on implementing a remission policy. While taqqavi loans were increasingly siphoned off as ‘emoluments’ by the lower levels of the ‘native officials’, remissions could not be effectively directed at providing genuine relief. See, unpublished Ph.D. thesis, Department of History, School of Oriental and African Studies, London
    • The British principle of ‘non-interference’ or rather, lack of administrative penetration in the early period of their rule in the Doab districts of north India had a debilitating effect on rural credit and on implementing a remission policy. While taqqavi loans were increasingly siphoned off as ‘emoluments’ by the lower levels of the ‘native officials’, remissions could not be effectively directed at providing genuine relief. See Sanjay Sharma, ‘Famine State and Society in North India, c. 1800–1840’, unpublished Ph.D. thesis, Department of History, School of Oriental and African Studies, London, 1996, pp. 144–50.
    • (1996) Famine State and Society in North India, c. 1800–1840 , pp. 144-150
    • Sharma, S.1
  • 145
    • 79958891263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Deltaic Rivers of the Bengal Presidency: The Political Economy of Flood Control in Colonial Orissa
    • See, unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, Centre for Historical Studies, Jawaharlal Nehru University
    • See Rohan D'Souza, ‘The Deltaic Rivers of the Bengal Presidency: The Political Economy of Flood Control in Colonial Orissa’, unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, Centre for Historical Studies, Jawaharlal Nehru University, 1998, pp. 1–24.
    • (1998) , pp. 1-24
    • D'Souza, R.1
  • 149
    • 37749019460 scopus 로고
    • London (reprint)
    • Karl Marx, Capital, Vol. I, London (reprint), 1990, p. 931.
    • (1990) Capital , vol.1 , pp. 931
    • Marx, K.1
  • 150
    • 0004078265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I have here not dealt with the specific aspect of the manner in which capitalist rents reinforce the monetary valuation of nature. See, New York
    • I have here not dealt with the specific aspect of the manner in which capitalist rents reinforce the monetary valuation of nature. See Paul Burkett, Marx and Nature: A Red and Green Perspective, New York, 1999, pp. 90–98.
    • (1999) Marx and Nature: A Red and Green Perspective , pp. 90-98
    • Burkett, P.1
  • 151
    • 79958994135 scopus 로고
    • Also see, London
    • Also see Karl Marx, Capital, Vol. III, London, 1991, pp. 751–950
    • (1991) Capital , vol.3 , pp. 751-950
    • Marx, K.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.