메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 32, Issue 2, 2008, Pages 433-502

Beyond cost-benefit analysis: A pragmatic reorientation

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS; ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS; ENVIRONMENTAL LEGISLATION; ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY; ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION; PARADIGM SHIFT; POLICY IMPLEMENTATION;

EID: 50349092537     PISSN: 01478257     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (53)

References (508)
  • 1
    • 33947506300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James Farr et al., The Policy Scientist of Democracy: The Discipline of Harold D. Lasswell, 100 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 579, 582 (2006) ([T]he policy scientist was (to be) a practitioner of a kind of science that took the lawyer's or doctor's practice as its model, putting the methods and findings of a general science to work in solving real-world problems.).
    • James Farr et al., The Policy Scientist of Democracy: The Discipline of Harold D. Lasswell, 100 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 579, 582 (2006) ("[T]he policy scientist was (to be) a practitioner of a kind of science that took the lawyer's or doctor's practice as its model, putting the methods and findings of a general science to work in solving real-world problems.").
  • 2
    • 50349091220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FRANK FISCHER, REFRAMING PUBLIC POLICY 3
    • FRANK FISCHER, REFRAMING PUBLIC POLICY 3 (2003);
    • (2003)
  • 3
    • 0001213635 scopus 로고
    • Contextual Orientation in Policy Analysis: The Contribution of Harold D. Lasswell, 18 POL'Y
    • see also
    • see also Douglas Torgerson, Contextual Orientation in Policy Analysis: The Contribution of Harold D. Lasswell, 18 POL'Y SCI. 241, 251 (1985).
    • (1985) SCI , vol.241 , pp. 251
    • Torgerson, D.1
  • 4
    • 50349097719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Harold D. Lasswell, The Policy Orientation, in THE POLICY SCIENCES 3, 10 (Daniel Lerner & Harold D. Lasswell eds., 1951) (internal quotation marks omitted). Lasswell apparently referred to the new field using the plural policy sciences to highlight the interdisciplinary nature of his proposal.
    • E.g., Harold D. Lasswell, The Policy Orientation, in THE POLICY SCIENCES 3, 10 (Daniel Lerner & Harold D. Lasswell eds., 1951) (internal quotation marks omitted). Lasswell apparently referred to the new field using the plural "policy sciences" to highlight the interdisciplinary nature of his proposal.
  • 5
    • 50349093168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Torgerson, supra note 2, at 242 n.4.
    • Torgerson, supra note 2, at 242 n.4.
  • 6
    • 50349099926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lasswell's own work is admittedly not easy to follow, given his penchant for continually repackaging his concepts inside ever changing neologisms, and for their lack of clarity on several key points. See Farr et al., supra note 1, at 583. Still, the failure to follow Lasswell's ideas is traceable to many more significant factors than his obscurantism - or so we argue here.
    • Lasswell's own work is admittedly not easy to follow, given his penchant for continually repackaging his concepts inside ever changing neologisms, and for their lack of clarity on several key points. See Farr et al., supra note 1, at 583. Still, the failure to follow Lasswell's ideas is traceable to many more significant factors than his obscurantism - or so we argue here.
  • 7
    • 0039479003 scopus 로고
    • Policy Sciences and the Economic Approach in a "Post-Positivist" Era, 20 POL'Y
    • William Ascher, Editorial, Policy Sciences and the Economic Approach in a "Post-Positivist" Era, 20 POL'Y SCI. 3, 4 (1987).
    • (1987) SCI , vol.3 , pp. 4
    • William Ascher, E.1
  • 8
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 246 and accompanying text
    • See infra note 246 and accompanying text.
    • See infra
  • 9
    • 50349098430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See EDWARD A. PURCELL, JR., THE CRISIS OF DEMOCRATIC THEORY 6-12 (1973);
    • See EDWARD A. PURCELL, JR., THE CRISIS OF DEMOCRATIC THEORY 6-12 (1973);
  • 10
    • 50349091684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also RICHARD HOFSTADTER, THE AGE OF REFORM 148-62 (1955).
    • see also RICHARD HOFSTADTER, THE AGE OF REFORM 148-62 (1955).
  • 11
    • 50349095247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Progressives assumed that once the society knew, really knew, the facts and figures of social disorganization, corrective action would inevitably follow as enlightened citizens [rose] up to demand and ensure action. Carol H. Weiss, Ideology, Interests, and Information: The Basis of Policy Positions, in ETHICS, THE SOCIAL SCIENCES AND POLICY ANALYSIS 213, 214 (Daniel Callahan & Bruce Jennings eds., 1983).
    • Progressives assumed that "once the society knew, really knew, the facts and figures of social disorganization, corrective action would inevitably follow" as enlightened citizens "[rose] up to demand and ensure action." Carol H. Weiss, Ideology, Interests, and Information: The Basis of Policy Positions, in ETHICS, THE SOCIAL SCIENCES AND POLICY ANALYSIS 213, 214 (Daniel Callahan & Bruce Jennings eds., 1983).
  • 12
    • 50349088373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 215
    • Id. at 215.
  • 13
    • 50349102836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see infra Part II.D (discussing the demise of the assumption that science could trump political concerns).
    • But see infra Part II.D (discussing the demise of the assumption that science could trump political concerns).
  • 15
    • 50349094373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 408
    • Id. at 408.
  • 16
    • 50349102617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ELLIOT A. ROSEN, HOOVER, ROOSEVELT, AND THE BRAINS TRUST 329-61 (1977).
    • ELLIOT A. ROSEN, HOOVER, ROOSEVELT, AND THE BRAINS TRUST 329-61 (1977).
  • 17
    • 50349087151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PETER DELEON, ADVICE AND CONSENT: THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE POLICY SCIENCES 57 (1988);
    • PETER DELEON, ADVICE AND CONSENT: THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE POLICY SCIENCES 57 (1988);
  • 19
    • 50349088487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HAROLD LASSWELL, A PRE-VIEW OF POLICY SCIENCES xiii, 4 (1971);
    • See HAROLD LASSWELL, A PRE-VIEW OF POLICY SCIENCES xiii, 4 (1971);
  • 21
    • 50349092291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lasswell argued that a new field was necessary because traditional disciplines did not pay sufficient attention to the fundamental problems of man in society. Lasswell, supra note 3, at 8.
    • Lasswell argued that a new field was necessary because traditional disciplines did not pay sufficient attention to "the fundamental problems of man in society." Lasswell, supra note 3, at 8.
  • 22
    • 50349096798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DELEON, supra note 13, at 29 (Lasswell and others were interested in both knowledge of and in the policy process).
    • DELEON, supra note 13, at 29 (Lasswell and others were interested in both "knowledge of and in the policy process").
  • 23
    • 50349088915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 8
    • Id. at 8.
  • 24
    • 50349088250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lasswell, supra note 3, at 14
    • Lasswell, supra note 3, at 14.
  • 25
    • 50349086826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 2-3 and accompanying text; see also LASSWELL, supra note 14, at 3-4.
    • See supra notes 2-3 and accompanying text; see also LASSWELL, supra note 14, at 3-4.
  • 26
    • 50349089439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • According to Dror, The main test of policy science is better policy making, which produces better policies; these, in turn, are defined as policies which provide increased achievement of goals that are preferred after careful consideration. DROR, supra note 14, at 51.
    • According to Dror, "The main test of policy science is better policy making, which produces better policies; these, in turn, are defined as policies which provide increased achievement of goals that are preferred after careful consideration." DROR, supra note 14, at 51.
  • 27
    • 50349089327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PETER DELEON, DEMOCRACY AND THE POLICY SCIENCES 7 (1997).
    • PETER DELEON, DEMOCRACY AND THE POLICY SCIENCES 7 (1997).
  • 28
    • 50349085409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Exec. Order No. 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193 (Feb. 17, 1981). The current order is Exec. Order No. 12,866, 58 Fed. Reg. 51,735 (Sept. 30, 1993), as amended by Exec. Order No. 13,258, 67 Fed. Reg. 9385 (Feb. 26, 2002) and Exec. Order No. 13,422, 72 Fed. Reg. 2763 (Jan. 18, 2007).
    • See, e.g., Exec. Order No. 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193 (Feb. 17, 1981). The current order is Exec. Order No. 12,866, 58 Fed. Reg. 51,735 (Sept. 30, 1993), as amended by Exec. Order No. 13,258, 67 Fed. Reg. 9385 (Feb. 26, 2002) and Exec. Order No. 13,422, 72 Fed. Reg. 2763 (Jan. 18, 2007).
  • 29
    • 50349088244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THOMAS O. MCGARITY, REINVENTING RATIONALITY: THE ROLE OF REGULATORY ANALYSIS IN THE FEDERAL BUREAUCRACY 6 (1991) (discussing the role of program offices in the context of rulemaking).
    • See THOMAS O. MCGARITY, REINVENTING RATIONALITY: THE ROLE OF REGULATORY ANALYSIS IN THE FEDERAL BUREAUCRACY 6 (1991) (discussing the role of "program offices" in the context of rulemaking).
  • 30
    • 50349090386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DELEON, supra note 19, at 98 (The 'day to day' policy sciences (especially under the rubric of policy analysis) have ... adopted an expertise, whatever the discipline, based on positivism, 'instrumental rationality,' ... and technocracy.).
    • See DELEON, supra note 19, at 98 ("The 'day to day' policy sciences (especially under the rubric of policy analysis) have ... adopted an expertise, whatever the discipline, based on positivism, 'instrumental rationality,' ... and technocracy.").
  • 31
    • 0032440304 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Max Neiman & Stephen J. Stambough, Rational Choice Theory and the Evaluation of Public Policy, 26 POL. STUDIES J. 449, 450 (1998).
    • Max Neiman & Stephen J. Stambough, Rational Choice Theory and the Evaluation of Public Policy, 26 POL. STUDIES J. 449, 450 (1998).
  • 32
    • 50349094143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PURCELL, supra note 7, at 15
    • PURCELL, supra note 7, at 15.
  • 33
    • 50349086822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Systems analysts and operations researchers did some of the first work and they were followed by analysts trained as economists. DELEON , supra note 13, at 23-24.
    • Systems analysts and operations researchers did some of the first work and they were followed by analysts trained as economists. DELEON , supra note 13, at 23-24.
  • 34
    • 50349085513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FISCHER, supra note 2, at 118
    • See FISCHER, supra note 2, at 118.
  • 36
    • 50349099473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GIANDOMENICO MAJONE, EVIDENCE, ARGUMENT AND PERSUASION IN THE POLICY PROCESS 34-35 (1989) (same).
    • GIANDOMENICO MAJONE, EVIDENCE, ARGUMENT AND PERSUASION IN THE POLICY PROCESS 34-35 (1989) (same).
  • 37
    • 50349083217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PURCELL, supra note 7, at 22 (A fact existed and could be observed, and it was the social scientist's function to separate the verifiable, objective facts from the confused and subjectively colored interpretations that men habitually gave them.).
    • PURCELL, supra note 7, at 22 ("A fact existed and could be observed, and it was the social scientist's function to separate the verifiable, objective facts from the confused and subjectively colored interpretations that men habitually gave them.").
  • 38
    • 50349102182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 35
    • Id. at 35.
  • 39
    • 50349091426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 40
    • 50349093600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DAVID C. PARIS & JAMES F. REYNOLDS, THE LOGIC OF POLICY INQUIRY 22 (1983).
    • DAVID C. PARIS & JAMES F. REYNOLDS, THE LOGIC OF POLICY INQUIRY 22 (1983).
  • 41
    • 50349084672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PURCELL, supra note 7, at 25-28
    • PURCELL, supra note 7, at 25-28.
  • 42
    • 50349086030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 43
    • 50349101338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 44
    • 50349091349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 46
    • 50349083538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 13, at, discussing Popper
    • SCHNEIDER & INGRAM, supra note 13, at 30 (discussing Popper).
    • supra , pp. 30
    • SCHNEIDER1    INGRAM2
  • 47
    • 50349096229 scopus 로고
    • The Action Intellectuals
    • June 16, at
    • Theodore H. White, The Action Intellectuals, LIFE, June 16, 1967, at 43;
    • (1967) LIFE , pp. 43
    • White, T.H.1
  • 48
    • 50349096454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also FISCHER, supra note 2, at 6 (the policy community became professionally consumed devising new programs for President Johnson's Great Society).
    • see also FISCHER, supra note 2, at 6 (the policy community became "professionally consumed" devising new programs for President Johnson's Great Society).
  • 49
    • 50349094372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 7
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 7.
  • 50
    • 50349085214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weiss, supra note 8, at 216 (evaluations indicated only fitful success in solving social problems);
    • Weiss, supra note 8, at 216 (evaluations indicated only "fitful success in solving social problems");
  • 51
    • 50349083007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also FISCHER, supra note 2, at 7 (there was far less to show for these programs than the Johnson administration and its supporters had promised).
    • see also FISCHER, supra note 2, at 7 ("there was far less to show for these programs than the Johnson administration and its supporters had promised").
  • 52
    • 50349091430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JEFFREY L. PRESSMAN & AARON B. WILDAVKSY, IMPLEMENTATION (1973) (demonstrating how policy implementation remains intertwined with the political process after a law is enacted and how the political process can distort the original policy goals of the legislation).
    • JEFFREY L. PRESSMAN & AARON B. WILDAVKSY, IMPLEMENTATION (1973) (demonstrating how policy implementation remains intertwined with the political process after a law is enacted and how the political process can distort the original policy goals of the legislation).
  • 53
    • 50349092968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Giandomenico Majone & Aaron Wildavsky, Implementation as Evolution, in IMPLEMENTATION (Jeffrey Pressman & Aaron Wildavsky eds., 1984) (proposing that the content of policy evolves as interest groups seek to influence the outcome and that the outcome is influenced by negotiations between interested parties).
    • Giandomenico Majone & Aaron Wildavsky, Implementation as Evolution, in IMPLEMENTATION (Jeffrey Pressman & Aaron Wildavsky eds., 1984) (proposing that the content of policy evolves as interest groups seek to influence the outcome and that the outcome is influenced by negotiations between interested parties).
  • 54
    • 50349103496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 9
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 9.
  • 55
    • 50349092515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The defense community was at the forefront of the development of analytical techniques for guiding management and policy dating back to statistical analysis of bombing by the Air Force in World War II. Id.
    • "The defense community was at the forefront of the development of analytical techniques for guiding management and policy" dating back to statistical analysis of bombing by the Air Force in World War II. Id.
  • 56
    • 50349098322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 57
    • 50349083329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DAVID HALBERSTAM, THE BEST AND THE BRIGHTEST (1972) (documenting how prointerventionist officials pushed faulty analyses and suppressed assessments that contradicted these assessments);
    • DAVID HALBERSTAM, THE BEST AND THE BRIGHTEST (1972) (documenting how prointerventionist officials pushed faulty analyses and suppressed assessments that contradicted these assessments);
  • 58
    • 50349086612 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NEIL SHEEHAN, A BRIGHT SHINING LIE: JOHN PAUL VANN AND AMERICA IN VIETNAM (1988) (illustrating the self-deceiving illusions of the American military and civilian bureaucracy).
    • NEIL SHEEHAN, A BRIGHT SHINING LIE: JOHN PAUL VANN AND AMERICA IN VIETNAM (1988) (illustrating the self-deceiving illusions of the American military and civilian bureaucracy).
  • 59
    • 50349092623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 10
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 10.
  • 60
    • 50349088805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DELEON, supra note 13, at 70
    • DELEON, supra note 13, at 70.
  • 61
    • 34250132197 scopus 로고
    • Among the Energy Tribes: A Cultural Framework for the Analysis and Design of Energy Policy, 17 POL'Y
    • See
    • See Michael Thompson, Among the Energy Tribes: A Cultural Framework for the Analysis and Design of Energy Policy, 17 POL'Y SCI. 321, 321 (1984).
    • (1984) SCI , vol.321 , pp. 321
    • Thompson, M.1
  • 62
    • 50349091348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When we refer to political assumptions, we mean this in the broad sense employed by Thompson, who describes energy experts as disagreeing because they embrace alternative assumptions about the nature of the world, about the nature of man, and about the nature of the relationship between man and the world, all of which are socially constructed. Id. at 328.
    • When we refer to political assumptions, we mean this in the broad sense employed by Thompson, who describes energy experts as disagreeing because they embrace "alternative assumptions about the nature of the world, about the nature of man, and about the nature of the relationship between man and the world," all of which are "socially constructed." Id. at 328.
  • 63
    • 0020219690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alternative assumptions may map onto partisan political distinctions such as between Republicans and Democrats, but that is not a subject we explore here. Policies toward risk, a primary concern in crafting environmental, health and safety rules, exhibit similar sets of alternative assumptions. Indeed, it was in thinking about risk policy that Thompson and others first developed the hypothesis that political culture shapes how any individual approaches a policy question. See Michael Thompson & Aaron Wildavsky, A Proposal to Create a Cultural Theory of Risk, in THE RISK ANALYSIS CONTROVERSY: AN INSTITUTIONAL PERSPECTIVE 146 Howard C. Kunreuther & Eryl V. Ley eds, 1982
    • Alternative assumptions may map onto partisan political distinctions such as between Republicans and Democrats, but that is not a subject we explore here. Policies toward risk - a primary concern in crafting environmental, health and safety rules - exhibit similar sets of alternative assumptions. Indeed, it was in thinking about risk policy that Thompson and others first developed the hypothesis that "political culture" shapes how any individual approaches a policy question. See Michael Thompson & Aaron Wildavsky, A Proposal to Create a Cultural Theory of Risk, in THE RISK ANALYSIS CONTROVERSY: AN INSTITUTIONAL PERSPECTIVE 146 (Howard C. Kunreuther & Eryl V. Ley eds., 1982).
  • 64
    • 50349083750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 10;
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 10;
  • 65
    • 50349103166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see, e.g., Martin Rein, Value-Critical Policy Analysis, in ETHICS, THE SOCIAL SCIENCES AND POLICY ANALYSIS, supra note 8, at 83.
    • see, e.g., Martin Rein, Value-Critical Policy Analysis, in ETHICS, THE SOCIAL SCIENCES AND POLICY ANALYSIS, supra note 8, at 83.
  • 66
    • 50349085317 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A similar reassessment occurred in political science. See, e.g., IAN SHAPIRO, THE FLIGHT FROM REALITY IN THE HUMAN SCIENCES (2005);
    • A similar reassessment occurred in political science. See, e.g., IAN SHAPIRO, THE FLIGHT FROM REALITY IN THE HUMAN SCIENCES (2005);
  • 67
    • 50349089740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DONALD R. GREEN & IAN SHAPIRO, PATHOLOGIES OF RATIONAL CHOICE: A CRITIQUE OF APPLICATIONS IN POLITICAL SCIENCE (1994);
    • DONALD R. GREEN & IAN SHAPIRO, PATHOLOGIES OF RATIONAL CHOICE: A CRITIQUE OF APPLICATIONS IN POLITICAL SCIENCE (1994);
  • 69
    • 50349093074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STEPHEN KELMAN, MAKING PUBLIC POLICY: A HOPEFUL VIEW OF AMERICAN GOVERNMENT (1987);
    • STEPHEN KELMAN, MAKING PUBLIC POLICY: A HOPEFUL VIEW OF AMERICAN GOVERNMENT (1987);
  • 71
    • 50349089633 scopus 로고
    • Politics, Policy, and Public Choice: A Critique and a Proposal, 19
    • Lawrence A. Schaff & Helen M. Ingram, Politics, Policy, and Public Choice: A Critique and a Proposal, 19 POLITY 613 (1986).
    • (1986) POLITY , vol.613
    • Schaff, L.A.1    Ingram, H.M.2
  • 72
    • 50349083330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Donald Green and Ian Shapiro, for example, have found that public choice analyses using empirical analysis, economic assumptions and rational choice methodologies have been largely unable to explain key political events. GREEN & SHAPIRO, supra, at 6.
    • Donald Green and Ian Shapiro, for example, have found that public choice analyses using empirical analysis, economic assumptions and rational choice methodologies have been largely unable to explain key political events. GREEN & SHAPIRO, supra, at 6.
  • 73
    • 50349084164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, the theory predicts that, rationally, no one will vote because it is so improbable that any one person's vote will decide an election. Since the costs of voting outweigh the extremely negligible benefits, a rational person will stay at home. The reality, however, is that millions of persons do vote. Id. at 50-52.
    • For example, the theory predicts that, rationally, no one will vote because it is so improbable that any one person's vote will decide an election. Since the costs of voting outweigh the extremely negligible benefits, a rational person will stay at home. The reality, however, is that millions of persons do vote. Id. at 50-52.
  • 74
    • 50349085826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shapiro therefore calls for a political science discipline that employs diverse methodologies, such as history and psychology, as well as economic theory, to build explanations that fit the facts on the ground. Shapiro and other like-minded scholars have joined the Perestroika movement in political science to object to the hegemonic role that rational choice methodologies have taken on in research, publication and teaching. The movement seeks greater plurality in the field. See Catarina Kinnvall, Not Here, Not Now: The Absence of a European Perestroika Movement, in PERESTROIKA: THE RAUCOUS REBELLION IN POLITICAL SCIENCE 21 (Kristen Renwick Monroe ed., 2005) (describing the movement).
    • Shapiro therefore calls for a political science discipline that employs diverse methodologies, such as history and psychology, as well as economic theory, to build explanations that fit the facts on the ground. Shapiro and other like-minded scholars have joined the "Perestroika" movement in political science to object to the hegemonic role that rational choice methodologies have taken on in research, publication and teaching. The movement seeks greater plurality in the field. See Catarina Kinnvall, Not Here, Not Now: The Absence of a European Perestroika Movement, in PERESTROIKA: THE RAUCOUS REBELLION IN POLITICAL SCIENCE 21 (Kristen Renwick Monroe ed., 2005) (describing the movement).
  • 75
    • 50349086823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • THOMAS KUHN, THE STRUCTURE OF SCIENTIFIC REVOLUTIONS (1970);
    • THOMAS KUHN, THE STRUCTURE OF SCIENTIFIC REVOLUTIONS (1970);
  • 77
    • 50349098843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 124
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 124.
  • 78
    • 50349085418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 79
    • 50349091547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.;
    • Id.;
  • 80
    • 50349098016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see LARRY LAUDAN, SCIENCE & RELATIVISM: SOME KEY CONTROVERSIES IN THE POLICY OF SCIENCE 64-65 (1990) (describing the post-empiricist realist position).
    • see LARRY LAUDAN, SCIENCE & RELATIVISM: SOME KEY CONTROVERSIES IN THE POLICY OF SCIENCE 64-65 (1990) (describing the post-empiricist realist position).
  • 81
    • 50349083008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See LAUDAN, supra note 52, at 67
    • See LAUDAN, supra note 52, at 67.
  • 82
    • 50349091855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DEBORAH STONE, POLICY PARADOX: THE ART OF POLITICAL DECISIONMAKING 9 (1997).
    • DEBORAH STONE, POLICY PARADOX: THE ART OF POLITICAL DECISIONMAKING 9 (1997).
  • 83
    • 50349095244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Post-empiricists argue there is also a deeper ideological problem: the belief that science is nonideological and neutral is profoundly ideological and political. Robert Bellah explains, I believe it is not fortuitous that so many of the 'useful' technologies, practices, and concepts ... turn out to be manipulative instruments in the hands of political and economic power. It is precisely a science that imagines itself uninvolved in society, that sees itself as operating under no ethical norm other than the pursuit of knowledge, that will produce instruments of manipulation for anyone who can afford to put them into practice. Robert A. Bellah, Social Science as Practical Reason, in ETHICS, THE SOCIAL SCIENCES AND POLICY ANALYSIS, supra note 8 at 37, 41.
    • Post-empiricists argue there is also a deeper ideological problem: the belief that science is nonideological and neutral is profoundly ideological and political. Robert Bellah explains, "I believe it is not fortuitous that so many of the 'useful' technologies, practices, and concepts ... turn out to be manipulative instruments in the hands of political and economic power. It is precisely a science that imagines itself uninvolved in society, that sees itself as operating under no ethical norm other than the pursuit of knowledge, that will produce instruments of manipulation for anyone who can afford to put them into practice." Robert A. Bellah, Social Science as Practical Reason, in ETHICS, THE SOCIAL SCIENCES AND POLICY ANALYSIS, supra note 8 at 37, 41.
  • 84
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 210 and accompanying text
    • See infra note 210 and accompanying text.
    • See infra
  • 85
    • 50349088704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STONE, supra note 54, at 10
    • STONE, supra note 54, at 10.
  • 86
    • 50349098216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 12
    • Id. at 12.
  • 87
    • 50349101117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 131
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 131.
  • 88
    • 84983874631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Marie Danziger, Policy Analysis Postmodernized: Some Political and Pedagogical Ramifications, 23 POL'Y STUD. J. 435, 445-47 (1995).
    • See Marie Danziger, Policy Analysis Postmodernized: Some Political and Pedagogical Ramifications, 23 POL'Y STUD. J. 435, 445-47 (1995).
  • 89
    • 50349096230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 130-31
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 130-31.
  • 90
    • 0009324682 scopus 로고
    • Law As Practical Reason, 62
    • defining practical reason as individuals' capacity to take intentional actions based on reasons for action which are linked to social norms
    • Steven J. Burton, Law As Practical Reason, 62 S. CAL. L. REV. 747, 747 (1989) (defining "practical reason" as individuals' capacity to take intentional actions based on reasons for action which are linked to social norms);
    • (1989) S. CAL. L. REV , vol.747 , pp. 747
    • Burton, S.J.1
  • 91
    • 50349085417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also note 55, at, explaining practical reason
    • see also Bellah, supra note 55, at 54-64 (explaining practical reason);
    • supra , pp. 54-64
    • Bellah1
  • 92
    • 50349085515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SCHNEIDER & INGRAM, supra note 13, at 57-58 (same). For additional discussion of practical reason, see infra notes 231-238 and accompanying text.
    • SCHNEIDER & INGRAM, supra note 13, at 57-58 (same). For additional discussion of "practical reason," see infra notes 231-238 and accompanying text.
  • 93
    • 84927034398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Frank Fischer, Beyond Empiricism: Policy Analysis as Deliberative Practice, in DELIBERATIVE POLICY ANALYSIS: UNDERSTANDING GOVERNMENTS IN THE NETWORK SOCIETY 209, 218 (Maarten Hajer & Hendrik Wagenaar eds., 2003).
    • Frank Fischer, Beyond Empiricism: Policy Analysis as Deliberative Practice, in DELIBERATIVE POLICY ANALYSIS: UNDERSTANDING GOVERNMENTS IN THE NETWORK SOCIETY 209, 218 (Maarten Hajer & Hendrik Wagenaar eds., 2003).
  • 94
    • 50349095367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 95
    • 50349097092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Fischer explains: Through the processes of deliberation and debate, a consensus emerges among particular researchers concerning what will be taken as a valid explanation .... [I]t is the practical judgment of the community of researchers and not the data themselves that establishes the accepted explanation. Such practical judgments, rather than supposed reliance on proof unto itself, provides the mechanism for not only identifying the incompetent charlatan, but investigating the more subtle errors in our sophisticated approximations of reality.
    • Id. Fischer explains: Through the processes of deliberation and debate, a consensus emerges among particular researchers concerning what will be taken as a valid explanation .... [I]t is the practical judgment of the community of researchers and not the data themselves that establishes the accepted explanation. Such practical judgments, rather than supposed reliance on proof unto itself, provides the mechanism for not only identifying the incompetent charlatan, but investigating the more subtle errors in our sophisticated approximations of reality.
  • 96
    • 50349086323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 220-21
    • Id. at 220-21.
  • 97
    • 50349083538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 13, at, listing examples
    • See SCHNEIDER & INGRAM, supra note 13, at 52 (listing examples).
    • supra , pp. 52
    • SCHNEIDER1    INGRAM2
  • 98
    • 84895687862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., MICHAEL M. HARMON, PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION'S FINAL EXAM: A PRAGMATIST RESTRUCTURING OF THE PROFESSION AND THE DISCIPLINE (2006);
    • See, e.g., MICHAEL M. HARMON, PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION'S FINAL EXAM: A PRAGMATIST RESTRUCTURING OF THE PROFESSION AND THE DISCIPLINE (2006);
  • 99
    • 50349094486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JOHN FORESTER, CRITICAL THEORY, PUBLIC POLICY AND PLANNING PRACTICE: TOWARD A CRITICAL PRAGMATISM (1993);
    • JOHN FORESTER, CRITICAL THEORY, PUBLIC POLICY AND PLANNING PRACTICE: TOWARD A CRITICAL PRAGMATISM (1993);
  • 100
    • 50349098845 scopus 로고
    • CRITICAL THEORY AND PUBLIC LIFE John Forester ed
    • CRITICAL THEORY AND PUBLIC LIFE (John Forester ed., 1985);
    • (1985)
  • 101
    • 50349100022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBERT P. DENHARDT, THEORIES OF PUBLIC ORGANIZATION (1984).
    • ROBERT P. DENHARDT, THEORIES OF PUBLIC ORGANIZATION (1984).
  • 102
    • 85040874151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JOHN S. DRYZEK, RATIONAL ECOLOGY: ENVIRONMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY (1987).
    • See, e.g., JOHN S. DRYZEK, RATIONAL ECOLOGY: ENVIRONMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY (1987).
  • 103
    • 50349090593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, STONE, supra note 54;
    • See, e.g., STONE, supra note 54;
  • 104
    • 50349093939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JOHN GAVENTA, POWER AND POWERLESSNESS (1980).
    • JOHN GAVENTA, POWER AND POWERLESSNESS (1980).
  • 105
    • 50349086229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, FISCHER, supra note 2;
    • See, e.g., FISCHER, supra note 2;
  • 106
    • 50349083844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DELEON, supra note 13;
    • DELEON, supra note 13;
  • 107
    • 50349099370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SCHNEIDER & INGRAM, supra note 13;
    • SCHNEIDER & INGRAM, supra note 13;
  • 108
    • 50349094699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MAJONE, supra note 27;
    • MAJONE, supra note 27;
  • 109
    • 50349097415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weiss, supra note 8;
    • Weiss, supra note 8;
  • 110
    • 50349086721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fischer, supra note 63;
    • Fischer, supra note 63;
  • 111
    • 50349089638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSTMODERN PUBLIC POLICY
    • HUGH T. MILLER, POSTMODERN PUBLIC POLICY (2002);
    • (2002)
    • MILLER, H.T.1
  • 112
    • 50349090390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WILLIAM DUNN, PUBLIC POLICY ANALYSIS: AN INTRODUCTION (1981);
    • WILLIAM DUNN, PUBLIC POLICY ANALYSIS: AN INTRODUCTION (1981);
  • 113
    • 50349089223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • THE ARGUMENTATIVE TURN IN POLICY ANALYSIS (Frank Fischer & John Forester eds., 1993);
    • THE ARGUMENTATIVE TURN IN POLICY ANALYSIS (Frank Fischer & John Forester eds., 1993);
  • 114
    • 50349089960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • M.E. HAWKESWORTH, THEORETICAL ISSUES IN POLICY ANALYSIS (1988);
    • M.E. HAWKESWORTH, THEORETICAL ISSUES IN POLICY ANALYSIS (1988);
  • 118
    • 50349097198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DELEON, supra note 19, at 111-14
    • DELEON, supra note 19, at 111-14.
  • 119
    • 50349099155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Torgerson, supra note 2, at 242-43
    • See, e.g., Torgerson, supra note 2, at 242-43.
  • 120
    • 50349092624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One of the primary defenses of CBA against its critics is the charge that any other way of approaching policy problems is irrational, subjective, or subject to the vagaries of politics. We defend our pragmatic approach against charges of irrationality below. See infra Part IV.A
    • One of the primary defenses of CBA against its critics is the charge that any other way of approaching policy problems is irrational, subjective, or subject to the "vagaries" of politics. We defend our pragmatic approach against charges of irrationality below. See infra Part IV.A.
  • 121
    • 50349101440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Nixon, Ford, and Carter Administrations mandated a regulatory analysis process that was less comprehensive than the current process and involved an interagency review of an agency's analysis. President Ford required the use of CBA, but President Carter did not. See MCGARITY, supra note 21, at 18 (Nixon and Ford administration); Exec. Order No. 12,044, 43 Fed. Reg. 12,661 (Mar. 23, 1978) (Carter Administration).
    • The Nixon, Ford, and Carter Administrations mandated a regulatory analysis process that was less comprehensive than the current process and involved an interagency review of an agency's analysis. President Ford required the use of CBA, but President Carter did not. See MCGARITY, supra note 21, at 18 (Nixon and Ford administration); Exec. Order No. 12,044, 43 Fed. Reg. 12,661 (Mar. 23, 1978) (Carter Administration).
  • 122
    • 50349087832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President Reagan ordered agencies to prepare a comprehensive RIA, to use CBA, and to submit the RIA to OIRA for oversight. Exec. Order No. 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193 (Feb. 17, 1981).
    • President Reagan ordered agencies to prepare a comprehensive RIA, to use CBA, and to submit the RIA to OIRA for oversight. Exec. Order No. 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193 (Feb. 17, 1981).
  • 123
    • 50349083223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The first Bush Administration left the Reagan approach largely intact. MCGARITY, supra note 21, at 18.
    • The first Bush Administration left the Reagan approach largely intact. MCGARITY, supra note 21, at 18.
  • 124
    • 50349092967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President Clinton adopted a similar process, and, unlike President Carter, mandated the use of CBA. Exec. Order No. 12,866, 58 Fed. Reg. 51,735 (Sept. 30, 1993).
    • President Clinton adopted a similar process, and, unlike President Carter, mandated the use of CBA. Exec. Order No. 12,866, 58 Fed. Reg. 51,735 (Sept. 30, 1993).
  • 125
    • 50349089849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President Bush initially adopted the Clinton order without significant changes, although he later extended the requirement of assessing costs and benefits to significant agency guidance documents. Exec. Order No. 13,422, 72 Fed. Reg. 2763 (Jan. 18, 2007).
    • President Bush initially adopted the Clinton order without significant changes, although he later extended the requirement of assessing costs and benefits to significant agency guidance documents. Exec. Order No. 13,422, 72 Fed. Reg. 2763 (Jan. 18, 2007).
  • 127
    • 50349093499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCGARITY, supra note 21, at 10-11;
    • MCGARITY, supra note 21, at 10-11;
  • 128
    • 0001514870 scopus 로고
    • Policymaking Paradigms in Administrative Law, 95
    • Colin S. Diver, Policymaking Paradigms in Administrative Law, 95 HARV. L. REV. 393, 396-99 (1981).
    • (1981) HARV. L. REV , vol.393 , pp. 396-399
    • Diver, C.S.1
  • 129
    • 50349088595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCGARITY, supra note 21, at 6
    • MCGARITY, supra note 21, at 6.
  • 130
    • 50349102387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 7
    • Id. at 7.
  • 131
    • 50349089745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exec. Order No. 12,866, 58 Fed. Reg. 51,735-36, (Sept. 30, 1993).
    • Exec. Order No. 12,866, 58 Fed. Reg. 51,735-36, (Sept. 30, 1993).
  • 132
    • 50349098955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCGARITY, supra note 21, at xiv
    • MCGARITY, supra note 21, at xiv.
  • 133
    • 50349089744 scopus 로고
    • A Review of the Record, 10
    • John F. Morrall III, A Review of the Record, 10 REGULATION 25 (1986).
    • (1986) REGULATION , vol.25
    • Morrall III, J.F.1
  • 134
    • 50349084163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert W. Hahn, Regulatory Reform: What Do the Government's Numbers Tell Us?, in RISKS, COSTS, AND LIVES SAVED: GETTING BETTER RESULTS FROM REGULATION 208, 239 (Robert W. Hahn ed., 1996).
    • Robert W. Hahn, Regulatory Reform: What Do the Government's Numbers Tell Us?, in RISKS, COSTS, AND LIVES SAVED: GETTING BETTER RESULTS FROM REGULATION 208, 239 (Robert W. Hahn ed., 1996).
  • 136
    • 0039623483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulatory Costs of Mythic Proportions, 107
    • documenting citations of Morrall
    • Lisa Heinzerling, Regulatory Costs of Mythic Proportions, 107 YALE L.J. 1981, 1994-95 (1998) (documenting citations of Morrall).
    • (1998) YALE L.J. 1981 , pp. 1994-1995
    • Heinzerling, L.1
  • 137
    • 50349085213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., ROBERT W. CRANDALL, CHRISOPHER DEMUTH, ROBERT H. HAHN, ROBERT E. LITAN, PIETRO S. NIVOLA, & PAUL R. PORTNOY, AN AGENDA FOR FEDERAL REGULATORY REFORM (1997).
    • See, e.g., ROBERT W. CRANDALL, CHRISOPHER DEMUTH, ROBERT H. HAHN, ROBERT E. LITAN, PIETRO S. NIVOLA, & PAUL R. PORTNOY, AN AGENDA FOR FEDERAL REGULATORY REFORM (1997).
  • 138
    • 50349087941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Unbearable Lightness of Regulatory Costs, 33
    • discussing claim of statistical murder by Graham and others, See
    • See Frank Ackerman, The Unbearable Lightness of Regulatory Costs, 33 FORDHAM URB. L.J. 1071, 1075 (2006) (discussing claim of "statistical murder" by Graham and others).
    • (2006) FORDHAM URB. L.J , vol.1071 , pp. 1075
    • Ackerman, F.1
  • 139
    • 50349097833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Flood Control Act of 1936, 49 Stat. 1570;
    • Flood Control Act of 1936, 49 Stat. 1570;
  • 140
    • 84902945595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see RICHARD N. L. ANDREWS, MANAGING THE ENVIRONMENT, MANAGING OURSELVES: A HISTORY OF AMERICAN ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY 166 (2006);
    • see RICHARD N. L. ANDREWS, MANAGING THE ENVIRONMENT, MANAGING OURSELVES: A HISTORY OF AMERICAN ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY 166 (2006);
  • 142
    • 50349085105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Whether the 1936 Act's cost-benefit requirement accomplished its goal is debatable. See infra note 155 and accompanying text.
    • Whether the 1936 Act's cost-benefit requirement accomplished its goal is debatable. See infra note 155 and accompanying text.
  • 143
    • 44849109014 scopus 로고
    • White House Review of Agency Rulemaking, 99
    • regulation tends to be excessively cautious forcing investments in risk reduction far in excess of the value that individuals place on avoiding the risks involved, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Christopher C. DeMuth & Douglas H. Ginsburg, White House Review of Agency Rulemaking, 99 HARV. L. REV. 1075, 1080 (1986) ("regulation tends to be excessively cautious (forcing investments in risk reduction far in excess of the value that individuals place on avoiding the risks involved)").
    • (1986) HARV. L. REV , vol.1075 , pp. 1080
    • DeMuth, C.C.1    Ginsburg, D.H.2
  • 144
    • 0013065921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mathew D. Adler & Eric A. Posner, Rethinking Cost-Benefit Analysis, 109 YALE L.J. 165, 170 (1999) (describing this change as a breakthrough). Pareto proposed as a principle of evaluation that a project should be undertaken if it makes at least one person better off and no one worse off. This criterion is difficult to satisfy because almost every government project has winners and losers and compensating the losers is usually not feasible. Kaldor and Hicks proposed that a project should be undertaken if the beneficiaries are enriched sufficiently that they could compensate those who are hurt by the project even though no compensation is actually paid.
    • See Mathew D. Adler & Eric A. Posner, Rethinking Cost-Benefit Analysis, 109 YALE L.J. 165, 170 (1999) (describing this change as a breakthrough). Pareto proposed as a principle of evaluation that a project should be undertaken if it makes at least one person better off and no one worse off. This criterion is difficult to satisfy because almost every government project has winners and losers and compensating the losers is usually not feasible. Kaldor and Hicks proposed that a project should be undertaken if the beneficiaries are enriched sufficiently that they could compensate those who are hurt by the project even though no compensation is actually paid.
  • 145
    • 23844520081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Defense of Absolutes: Combating the Politics of Power in Environmental Law, 90
    • describing this theoretical switch, See
    • See Amy Sinden, In Defense of Absolutes: Combating the Politics of Power in Environmental Law, 90 IOWA L. REV. 1405, 1413-16 (2005) (describing this theoretical switch).
    • (2005) IOWA L. REV , vol.1405 , pp. 1413-1416
    • Sinden, A.1
  • 146
    • 50349097511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.J. MISHAN, COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS 298-309 (1976);
    • E.J. MISHAN, COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS 298-309 (1976);
  • 147
    • 37749042019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 132 and accompanying text discussing the use of WTP in regulatory impact analysis
    • see infra note 132 and accompanying text (discussing the use of WTP in regulatory impact analysis).
    • see infra
  • 148
    • 50349094481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STEPHEN BREYER, BREAKING THE VICIOUS CIRCLE: TOWARD EFFECTIVE RISK REGULATION (1993);
    • STEPHEN BREYER, BREAKING THE VICIOUS CIRCLE: TOWARD EFFECTIVE RISK REGULATION (1993);
  • 149
    • 0347107211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cognition and Cost-Benefit Analysis, 29
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Cognition and Cost-Benefit Analysis, 29 J. LEGAL STUD. 1059 (2000).
    • (2000) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.1059
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 150
    • 50349102283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Christopher H. Schroeder, The Story of American Trucking: The Blockbuster That Misfired, in ENVIRONMENTAL LAW STORIES 321, 331-40 (2005) (explaining how economic efficiency provided the framework for business interests seeking deregulation);
    • See Christopher H. Schroeder, The Story of American Trucking: The Blockbuster That Misfired, in ENVIRONMENTAL LAW STORIES 321, 331-40 (2005) (explaining how economic efficiency provided the framework for business interests seeking deregulation);
  • 151
    • 50349084673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sidney A. Shapiro, Administrative Law After the Counter-Reformation: Restoring Faith in Pragmatic Government, 48 KAN. L. REV. 689, 697-706 (2000) (same).
    • Sidney A. Shapiro, Administrative Law After the Counter-Reformation: Restoring Faith in Pragmatic Government, 48 KAN. L. REV. 689, 697-706 (2000) (same).
  • 152
    • 50349089117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCGARITY, supra note 21, at 4
    • MCGARITY, supra note 21, at 4.
  • 153
    • 50349100896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exec. Order No. 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193, 13,196 (Feb. 17, 1981).
    • Exec. Order No. 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193, 13,196 (Feb. 17, 1981).
  • 154
    • 50349100684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David M. Driesen, Is Cost-Benefit Neutral?, 77 COLORADO L. REV. 335, 355 (2006) (citing case studies reaching this conclusion).
    • See David M. Driesen, Is Cost-Benefit Neutral?, 77 COLORADO L. REV. 335, 355 (2006) (citing case studies reaching this conclusion).
  • 155
    • 50349099597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Richard D. Morgenstern & Marc K. Landy, Economic Analysis: Benefits, Costs, and Implications, in ECONOMIC ANALYSIS AT EPA 458 (Richard D. Morgenstern ed., 1997).
    • See, e.g., Richard D. Morgenstern & Marc K. Landy, Economic Analysis: Benefits, Costs, and Implications, in ECONOMIC ANALYSIS AT EPA 458 (Richard D. Morgenstern ed., 1997).
  • 156
    • 50349101906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 97, at, disputing claims that OIRA seeks stronger regulation
    • Driesen, supra note 97, at 354-64 (disputing claims that OIRA seeks stronger regulation).
    • supra , pp. 354-364
    • Driesen1
  • 157
    • 50349084882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Driesen looked at twenty-five rules that a GAO study found had been significantly affected by OMB between June 2001 and July 2002. In twenty-four of the twenty-five rules, OMB's recommended changes would have reduced regulatory protections, while the remaining case was neutral. Id. at 365
    • Driesen looked at twenty-five rules that a GAO study found had been significantly affected by OMB between June 2001 and July 2002. In twenty-four of the twenty-five rules, OMB's recommended changes would have reduced regulatory protections, while the remaining case was neutral. Id. at 365.
  • 158
    • 33750070312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bressman and Vandenbergh studied the impact of OMB review by interviewing top political officials at EPA during the first Bush and Clinton administrations. Lisa Schultz Bressman & Michael P. Vandenbergh, Inside the Administrative State: A Critical Look at the Practice of Presidential Control, 105 MICH. L. REV. 47, 49 2006
    • Bressman and Vandenbergh studied the impact of OMB review by interviewing top political officials at EPA during the first Bush and Clinton administrations. Lisa Schultz Bressman & Michael P. Vandenbergh, Inside the Administrative State: A Critical Look at the Practice of Presidential Control, 105 MICH. L. REV. 47, 49 (2006).
  • 159
    • 50349088370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • They found that OIRA regularly skews rulemaking in a deregulatory direction, id. at 50,
    • They found that OIRA "regularly skews rulemaking in a deregulatory direction," id. at 50,
  • 160
    • 50349092749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and concluded that OIRA may be using cost-benefit analysis to impose its own normative preference for deregulation. Id. at 75.
    • and concluded that OIRA "may be using cost-benefit analysis to impose its own normative preference for deregulation." Id. at 75.
  • 161
    • 0041328726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Croley found that politically controversial rules are usually changed in the White House review process, which he thinks contradicts the claim that OMB review is purely technocratic. Steven Croley, White House Review of Agency Rulemaking: An Empirical Investigation, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 821, 877 2003, If OIRA review is indeed primarily technocratic, then political controversy should not be the dominant engine prompting changes in submitted rules, On the other hand, he found no statistical correlation between whether a rule was changed or approved by OIRA without change and written submissions by various types of interest groups. He also found that the type of interest group that attended a meeting with OIRA officials did not predict whether OIRA would change the rule or accept it as is. Croley suggests these results create doubt that the White House regularly uses the review process to deliver benefits to powerful interests. Id. at 858-60
    • Croley found that politically controversial rules are usually changed in the White House review process, which he thinks contradicts the claim that OMB review is purely technocratic. Steven Croley, White House Review of Agency Rulemaking: An Empirical Investigation, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 821, 877 (2003) ("If OIRA review is indeed primarily technocratic, then political controversy should not be the dominant engine prompting changes in submitted rules."). On the other hand, he found no statistical correlation between whether a rule was changed or approved by OIRA without change and written submissions by various types of interest groups. He also found that the type of interest group that attended a meeting with OIRA officials did not predict whether OIRA would change the rule or accept it as is. Croley suggests these results create doubt that the White House regularly uses the review process to deliver benefits to powerful interests. Id. at 858-60.
  • 162
    • 33751251369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Centralized Oversight of the Regulatory State, 106
    • OIRA's denials notwithstanding, there is substantial evidence that emphasizing the cost side of the cost-benefit ledger remains a pervasive and entrenched feature of OIRA review, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Nicholas Bagley & Richard L. Revesz, Centralized Oversight of the Regulatory State, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 1260 (2006) ("OIRA's denials notwithstanding, there is substantial evidence that emphasizing the cost side of the cost-benefit ledger remains a pervasive and entrenched feature of OIRA review.");
    • (2006) COLUM. L. REV , vol.1260
    • Bagley, N.1    Revesz, R.L.2
  • 163
    • 84866243104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statutory Interpretation in the Era of OIRA, 33
    • describing unidirectional nature of OIRA review
    • Lisa Heinzerling, Statutory Interpretation in the Era of OIRA, 33 FORDHAM URB. L.J. 1097, 1100 (2006) (describing "unidirectional nature" of OIRA review).
    • (2006) FORDHAM URB. L.J , vol.1097 , pp. 1100
    • Heinzerling, L.1
  • 164
    • 50349088911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Supporters justify White House review on the basis of public choice theory, which predicts that self-interested administrators will seek to maximize the significance of their agency and the size of its budget. DENNIS C. MUELLER, PUBLIC CHOICE II 250-57 (1989).
    • Supporters justify White House review on the basis of public choice theory, which predicts that self-interested administrators will seek to maximize the significance of their agency and the size of its budget. DENNIS C. MUELLER, PUBLIC CHOICE II 250-57 (1989).
  • 165
    • 50349086228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This means an agency charged with the responsibility of protecting people or the environment will inevitably attempt to spend too much on its goals. See, e.g, DeMuth & Ginsberg, supra note 90, at 1081
    • This means an agency charged with the responsibility of protecting people or the environment will inevitably attempt to spend too much on its goals. See, e.g., DeMuth & Ginsberg, supra note 90, at 1081.
  • 166
    • 50349091549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • White House review by an office with no program responsibilities and answerable to the President responds to this tendency because the office is more likely than any agency to take a broad viewpoint of the value of a proposed regulation. Id. at 1081-82
    • White House review by an office with no program responsibilities and answerable to the President responds to this tendency because the office is more likely than any agency to take a broad viewpoint of the value of a proposed regulation. Id. at 1081-82.
  • 167
    • 50349097087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 85, at, analyzing Morrall
    • See Heinzerling, supra note 85, at 1983-86 (analyzing Morrall);
    • supra , pp. 1983-1986
    • Heinzerling1
  • 168
    • 0346074703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grading the Government, 70
    • analyzing Hahn
    • Richard W. Parker, Grading the Government, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 1345 (2003) (analyzing Hahn);
    • (2003) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.1345
    • Parker, R.W.1
  • 169
    • 85007306001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Five-Hundred Life-Saving Interventions and Their Misuse in the Debate Over Regulatory Reform, 13
    • analyzing Graham
    • Lisa Heinzerling, Five-Hundred Life-Saving Interventions and Their Misuse in the Debate Over Regulatory Reform, 13 RISK 151 (2002) (analyzing Graham);
    • (2002) RISK , vol.151
    • Heinzerling, L.1
  • 170
    • 50349103276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also SIDNEY A. SHAPIRO & ROBERT L. GLICKSMAN, RISK REGULATION AT RISK: RESTORING A PRAGMATIC APPROACH 80-91 (2003) (summarizing Heinzerling's critiques of Morrall and Graham and offering additional criticism).
    • see also SIDNEY A. SHAPIRO & ROBERT L. GLICKSMAN, RISK REGULATION AT RISK: RESTORING A PRAGMATIC APPROACH 80-91 (2003) (summarizing Heinzerling's critiques of Morrall and Graham and offering additional criticism).
  • 171
    • 50349096036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bagley & Revesz, supra note 103, at 1262
    • Bagley & Revesz, supra note 103, at 1262.
  • 172
    • 50349093601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1284-87.
  • 173
    • 50349098321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Parker, supra note 105, at 1417 (Retrospective studies, though difficult, are indispensable tools for capturing the impact of waivers, variances, and other uses of official discretion; detecting errant predictions of costs and benefits; identifying important sources of estimation error; calibrating ex ante estimates; and, most of all, identifying needed changes to rules.).
    • See Parker, supra note 105, at 1417 ("Retrospective studies, though difficult, are indispensable tools for capturing the impact of waivers, variances, and other uses of official discretion; detecting errant predictions of costs and benefits; identifying important sources of estimation error; calibrating ex ante estimates; and, most of all, identifying needed changes to rules.").
  • 174
    • 0347966089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Counting the Cost of Health, Safety, and Environmental Regulation, 80
    • explaining why retrospective studies are difficult, See
    • See Thomas O. McGarity & Ruth Ruttenberg, Counting the Cost of Health, Safety, and Environmental Regulation, 80 TEX. L. REV. 1997, 2039 (2002) (explaining why retrospective studies are difficult).
    • (2002) TEX. L. REV. 1997 , pp. 2039
    • McGarity, T.O.1    Ruttenberg, R.2
  • 175
    • 50349089634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an RIA, agencies normally have to rely on regulated entities for estimates of regulatory costs, and these entities have an incentive to overstate compliance costs. SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 106.
    • For an RIA, agencies normally have to rely on regulated entities for estimates of regulatory costs, and these entities have an incentive to overstate compliance costs. SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 106.
  • 176
    • 50349097515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Estimates of regulatory compliance costs costs may also be too high because forecasters fail to anticipate competitive pressures that will cause firms to find less expensive methods of compliance and because there can be less compliance with a regulation than an agency estimates, Id. at 108
    • Estimates of regulatory compliance costs costs may also be too high because forecasters fail to anticipate competitive pressures that will cause firms to find less expensive methods of compliance and because there can be less compliance with a regulation than an agency estimates, Id. at 108.
  • 177
    • 50349101564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although there is limited retrospective evidence, what evidence exists indicates that estimates of regulatory costs range from too high to much too high. Id. at 106-07 (describing the studies and their findings that costs are overestimated);
    • Although there is limited retrospective evidence, what evidence exists indicates that estimates of regulatory costs range from too high to much too high. Id. at 106-07 (describing the studies and their findings that costs are overestimated);
  • 178
    • 50349091854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FRANK ACKERMAN & LISA HEINZERLING, PRICELESS: ON KNOWING THE PRICE OF EVERYTHING AND THE VALUE OF NOTHING 37-39 (2004) (same);
    • FRANK ACKERMAN & LISA HEINZERLING, PRICELESS: ON KNOWING THE PRICE OF EVERYTHING AND THE VALUE OF NOTHING 37-39 (2004) (same);
  • 179
    • 50349093073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McGarity & Ruttenberg, supra note 109, at 2042-44 same
    • McGarity & Ruttenberg, supra note 109, at 2042-44 (same).
  • 180
    • 50349094042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The imprecision of CBA also permits the White House to object to any regulation it finds politically objectionable
    • The imprecision of CBA also permits the White House to object to any regulation it finds politically objectionable.
  • 181
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 110 and accompanying text;
    • See supra note 110 and accompanying text;
    • See supra
  • 182
    • 0036663582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professor Sunstein's Fuzzy Math, 90
    • Thomas O. McGarity, Professor Sunstein's Fuzzy Math, 90 GEO. L.J. 2341, 2344 (2002).
    • (2002) GEO. L.J , vol.2341 , pp. 2344
    • McGarity, T.O.1
  • 183
    • 50349090389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 94-95;
    • See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 94-95;
  • 184
    • 50349102071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sinden, supra note 91, at 1425;
    • Sinden, supra note 91, at 1425;
  • 185
    • 79955706302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It Might Have Been: Risk Precaution and Opportunity Costs, 22
    • Douglas A. Kysar, It Might Have Been: Risk Precaution and Opportunity Costs, 22 J. LAND USE & ENVTL. L. 1, 15 (2006);
    • (2006) J. LAND USE & ENVTL. L , vol.1 , pp. 15
    • Kysar, D.A.1
  • 186
    • 50349088249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McGarity, supra note 112, at 2344
    • McGarity, supra note 112, at 2344.
  • 187
    • 50349101905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 105, at 94, Most risk assessments are subject to uncertainty, but the degree of uncertainty varies. The evaluation of safety risks, for example, may be more accurate than the evaluation of cancer risks because there is better evidence about cause and relationships between risk and injuries and about the size of the exposed population
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 94, Most risk assessments are subject to uncertainty, but the degree of uncertainty varies. The evaluation of safety risks, for example, may be more accurate than the evaluation of cancer risks because there is better evidence about cause and relationships between risk and injuries and about the size of the exposed population. Id.
    • Id
    • SHAPIRO1    GLICKSMAN2
  • 188
    • 0036663573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Arithmetic of Arsenic, 90
    • Cass R. Sunstein, The Arithmetic of Arsenic, 90 GEO. L.J. 2255, 2258 (2002).
    • (2002) GEO. L.J , vol.2255 , pp. 2258
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 189
    • 50349099369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2302
    • Id. at 2302.
  • 190
    • 36749003272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of Salmon, the Sound, and the Shifting Sands of Environmental Law - A National Perspective, 82
    • Holly Doremus, Of Salmon, the Sound, and the Shifting Sands of Environmental Law - A National Perspective, 82 WASH. L. REV. 547, 564 (2007);
    • (2007) WASH. L. REV , vol.547 , pp. 564
    • Doremus, H.1
  • 191
    • 50349098215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also McGarity, supra note 112, at 2366 (At the end of the day, one is left with a pressing need to know why a person of Professor Sunstein's obvious intelligence and even disposition would conclude that all of this occasionally incomprehensible, but frequently preposterous and always manipulable number spinning, could possibly lead to better decisionmaking in the real world.).
    • see also McGarity, supra note 112, at 2366 ("At the end of the day, one is left with a pressing need to know why a person of Professor Sunstein's obvious intelligence and even disposition would conclude that all of this occasionally incomprehensible, but frequently preposterous and always manipulable number spinning, could possibly lead to better decisionmaking in the real world.").
  • 192
    • 1842783710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two such analyses are Delphi and Monte Carlo. When analysts use Delphi analysis, they gather subjective assessments of unknown risks from a survey of experts in the relevant field. The goal is to use Bayesian probability theory to find a point of convergence among the responses, thereby generating a basis for calculating expected outcomes. David E. Adelman, Scientific Activism and Restraint: The Interplay of Statistics, Judgment, and Procedure in Environmental Law, 79 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 497, 567-82 (2004).
    • Two such analyses are "Delphi" and "Monte Carlo." When analysts use Delphi analysis, they gather subjective assessments of unknown risks from a survey of experts in the relevant field. The goal is to use Bayesian probability theory to find a point of convergence among the responses, thereby generating a basis for calculating expected outcomes. David E. Adelman, Scientific Activism and Restraint: The Interplay of Statistics, Judgment, and Procedure in Environmental Law, 79 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 497, 567-82 (2004).
  • 193
    • 50349090485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although the expert responses are subjective, the assumption is that objective results independent of the original estimates will be produced as more data are collected. Id. at 573
    • Although the expert responses are subjective, the assumption is that objective results independent of the original estimates will be produced as more data are collected. Id. at 573.
  • 194
    • 50349097610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The technique, however, has limited power to harmonize divergent opinions about human and environmental risks, which magnifies the significance of an expert's starting distribution. As a result, [s]cientists' subjectively derived prior distributions are ... bound to influence greatly, if not determine, the outcome of Bayesian assessments in fields like environmental science where data are often very limited. Id. at 577.
    • The technique, however, has limited power to harmonize divergent opinions about human and environmental risks, which magnifies the significance of an expert's starting distribution. As a result, "[s]cientists' subjectively derived prior distributions are ... bound to influence greatly, if not determine, the outcome of Bayesian assessments in fields like environmental science where data are often very limited." Id. at 577.
  • 195
    • 50349084369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Monte Carlo analysis generates hypothetical distributions of unknown probabilities. These techniques study the effects of policy proposals under thousands of different states of the world with the goal of locating policy prescriptions that predominate over a wide range of possible conditions. See Susan R. Poulter, Monte Carlo Procedures in Environmental Risk Assessment, Science, Policy and Legal Issues, 9 RISK 7 1998, describing and explaining these simulations, As Douglas Kysar notes, however, these techniques depend, on the specification of certain assumptions about the theoretical nature of unknown probabilities, When applied to systems that behave, instead, according to the laws of complexity, such assumptions can lead to dramatically erroneous policy advice, despite the great technological sophistication of the Monte Carlo procedure
    • Monte Carlo analysis generates hypothetical distributions of unknown probabilities. These techniques study the effects of policy proposals under thousands of different states of the world with the goal of locating policy prescriptions that predominate over a wide range of possible conditions. See Susan R. Poulter, Monte Carlo Procedures in Environmental Risk Assessment - Science, Policy and Legal Issues, 9 RISK 7 (1998) (describing and explaining these simulations). As Douglas Kysar notes, however, these "techniques depend ... on the specification of certain assumptions about the theoretical nature of unknown probabilities .... When applied to systems that behave, instead, according to the laws of complexity, such assumptions can lead to dramatically erroneous policy advice, despite the great technological sophistication of the Monte Carlo procedure."
  • 196
    • 50349101015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kysar, supra note 113, at 20
    • Kysar, supra note 113, at 20.
  • 197
    • 50349091345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 207
    • ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 207.
  • 198
    • 50349089222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 199
    • 50349093938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 98
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 98.
  • 201
    • 50349083535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 99-100 (discussing that workers lack sufficiently accurate information about risks to bargain for appropriate risk premiums, and many workers, especially minority workers, lack sufficient bargaining power to obtain fully compensating risk premiums or even any premiums at all);
    • See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 99-100 (discussing that workers lack sufficiently accurate information about risks to bargain for appropriate risk premiums, and many workers, especially minority workers, lack sufficient bargaining power to obtain fully compensating risk premiums or even any premiums at all);
  • 202
    • 50349098954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 77-78 (same);
    • ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 77-78 (same);
  • 203
    • 50349088914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Kysar, supra note 113, at 30-31 (Thus, what the CBA analyst regards as choice (and hence preference ... ), may actually capture in part the analyst's inclination to treat pre-existing power relations in employment markets as normatively privileged,).
    • see also Kysar, supra note 113, at 30-31 ("Thus, what the CBA analyst regards as choice (and hence preference ... ), may actually capture in part the analyst's inclination to treat pre-existing power relations in employment markets as normatively privileged,").
  • 204
    • 0041412752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Value of a Statistical Life: A Critical Review of Market Estimates Throughout the World, 27
    • most hedonic labor market studies focus on the risk of accidental death or accidental injury, See
    • See W. Kip Viscusi & Joseph E. Aldy, The Value of a Statistical Life: A Critical Review of Market Estimates Throughout the World, 27 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 5, 22 (2003) ("most hedonic labor market studies focus on the risk of accidental death or accidental injury").
    • (2003) J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY , vol.5 , pp. 22
    • Kip Viscusi, W.1    Aldy, J.E.2
  • 205
    • 50349090067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 102
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 102.
  • 206
    • 50349093832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., George Tolley, Donald Kenkel & Robert Fabian, State-of-the-Art Health Values, in VALUING HEALTH FOR POLICY: AN ECONOMIC APPROACH 323, 340-41 (George Tolley et al. eds., 1994);
    • See, e.g., George Tolley, Donald Kenkel & Robert Fabian, State-of-the-Art Health Values, in VALUING HEALTH FOR POLICY: AN ECONOMIC APPROACH 323, 340-41 (George Tolley et al. eds., 1994);
  • 207
    • 21144464090 scopus 로고
    • An Empirical Investigation into the Effect of Psychological Perceptions on the Willingness-to-Pay to Reduce Risk, 6
    • see also
    • see also Ian Savage, An Empirical Investigation into the Effect of Psychological Perceptions on the Willingness-to-Pay to Reduce Risk, 6 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 75, 85 (1993).
    • (1993) J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY , vol.75 , pp. 85
    • Savage, I.1
  • 208
    • 0033127822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard L. Revesz, Environmental Regulation, Cost-Benefit Analysis and the Discounting of Human Lives, 99 COLUM. L. REV. 941, 971 (1999). Analysts have sought to overcome contextual problems by the use of contingent evaluation, but this methodology also lacks accuracy.
    • Richard L. Revesz, Environmental Regulation, Cost-Benefit Analysis and the Discounting of Human Lives, 99 COLUM. L. REV. 941, 971 (1999). Analysts have sought to overcome contextual problems by the use of contingent evaluation, but this methodology also lacks accuracy.
  • 209
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 135-137 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 135-137 and accompanying text.
    • See infra
  • 210
    • 50349094483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 78
    • ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 78.
  • 211
    • 50349102616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 78-79
    • Id. at 78-79.
  • 212
    • 50349092393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 59;
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 59;
  • 213
    • 50349097718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sinden, supra note 91, at 1424-25
    • Sinden, supra note 91, at 1424-25.
  • 214
    • 0002797884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Homo Economicus and Homo Politicus: Interpretation and Aggregation of Environmental Values, 42
    • See
    • See Karine Nyborg, Homo Economicus and Homo Politicus: Interpretation and Aggregation of Environmental Values, 42 J. ECON. BEHAV. & ORG. 305, 306 (2000).
    • (2000) J. ECON. BEHAV. & ORG , vol.305 , pp. 306
    • Nyborg, K.1
  • 215
    • 50349091963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As noted, analysts rely on wage premiums to estimate the amount that individuals are willing to pay to prevent a premature death. See supra note 121 and accompanying text.
    • As noted, analysts rely on wage premiums to estimate the amount that individuals are willing to pay to prevent a premature death. See supra note 121 and accompanying text.
  • 216
    • 50349084370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When a worker moves to a safer job, he or she gives up the wage premium. This indicates that the person is willing to pay in terms of foregone compensation the amount of the wage premium to avoid the risk. SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 98.
    • When a worker moves to a safer job, he or she gives up the wage premium. This indicates that the person is "willing to pay" in terms of foregone compensation the amount of the wage premium to avoid the risk. SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 98.
  • 217
    • 50349088485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 97-98;
    • Id. at 97-98;
  • 218
    • 50349102178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sinden, supra note 91, at 1426-27
    • Sinden, supra note 91, at 1426-27.
  • 219
    • 50349101114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moreover, as discussed in the next section, economics lacks any neutral principle to justify the use of WTP to monetize regulatory benefits. See infra note 146 and accompanying text.
    • Moreover, as discussed in the next section, economics lacks any neutral principle to justify the use of WTP to monetize regulatory benefits. See infra note 146 and accompanying text.
  • 220
    • 0036197997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is There a Kink in Consumers' Threshold Value for Cost-Effectiveness in Health Care?, 11
    • The two measures might also differ if the value of the asset an individual was being asked to purchase or sell was sufficiently large to generate a wealth effect. The magnitude of the observed discrepancy between the measures in experimental situations is, however, too large to be explained by wealth effects. See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Bernie J. O'Brien et al., Is There a Kink in Consumers' Threshold Value for Cost-Effectiveness in Health Care?, 11 HEALTH ECON. 175 (2002). The two measures might also differ if the value of the asset an individual was being asked to purchase or sell was sufficiently large to generate a wealth effect. The magnitude of the observed discrepancy between the measures in experimental situations is, however, too large to be explained by wealth effects.
    • (2002) HEALTH ECON , vol.175
    • O'Brien, B.J.1
  • 221
    • 50349090183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 104
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 104.
  • 222
    • 50349100113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Canyon, which is some evidence of its "use" value, this approach fails to account for the fact that many people value protection of the Grand Canyon even though they have no plans to visit the area,
    • For example, while there is market evidence of how much money people spend to visit the
    • For example, while there is market evidence of how much money people spend to visit the Grand Canyon, which is some evidence of its "use" value, this approach fails to account for the fact that many people value protection of the Grand Canyon even though they have no plans to visit the area, which is its nonuse" or "existence" value. Id.
    • Id
    • Grand1
  • 224
    • 50349084777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sinden, supra note 91, at 1429-30 same
    • Sinden, supra note 91, at 1429-30 (same).
  • 225
    • 50349100793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This problem is not avoided by asking questions of a representative pool of persons who have different amounts of wealth. If regulatory benefits were measured by WTS, rather than WTP, the regulatory benefits would be greater. See supra note 133 and accompanying text
    • This problem is not avoided by asking questions of a representative pool of persons who have different amounts of wealth. If regulatory benefits were measured by WTS, rather than WTP, the regulatory benefits would be greater. See supra note 133 and accompanying text.
  • 226
    • 50349097514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., STEVEN E. RHODES, THE ECONOMIST'S VIEW OF THE WORLD: GOVERNMENT, MARKETS & PUBLIC POLICY 135 (1985) (noting that a fairly wide variation in results is still precise enough to suggest skepticism about the OSHA standards costing tens or hundreds of millions of dollars per death averted ...).
    • See, e.g., STEVEN E. RHODES, THE ECONOMIST'S VIEW OF THE WORLD: GOVERNMENT, MARKETS & PUBLIC POLICY 135 (1985) (noting that a "fairly wide variation in results is still precise enough to suggest skepticism about the OSHA standards costing tens or hundreds of millions of dollars per death averted ...").
  • 227
    • 84886336150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 105 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 105 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 228
    • 0036663635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Praise of Numbers: A Reply, 90
    • Cass Sunstein, In Praise of Numbers: A Reply, 90 GEO. L.J. 2379, 2384 (2002).
    • (2002) GEO. L.J , vol.2379 , pp. 2384
    • Sunstein, C.1
  • 229
    • 50349100897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CBA critics note that this means CBA fails its own test since the benefits of CBA do not justify the considerable costs. See, e.g, Robert Verchick, The Case Against Cost-Benefit Analysis, 32 ECOLOGY L.Q. 349, 369-77 2005
    • CBA critics note that this means CBA fails its own test since the benefits of CBA do not justify the considerable costs. See, e.g., Robert Verchick, The Case Against Cost-Benefit Analysis, 32 ECOLOGY L.Q. 349, 369-77 (2005)
  • 231
    • 50349097089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 218 (Washington think tanks render precise, hostile, quantitative judgments which ... guarantee that environmental policies and regulations will fail cost-benefit tests.).
    • See, e.g., ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 218 ("Washington think tanks render precise, hostile, quantitative judgments which ... guarantee that environmental policies and regulations will fail cost-benefit tests.").
  • 232
    • 34247624860 scopus 로고
    • Science or Trans-Science, 10
    • Alvin Weinberg, Science or Trans-Science, 10 MINERVA 209 (1972).
    • (1972) MINERVA , vol.209
    • Weinberg, A.1
  • 233
    • 44149118939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 105, at, describing and explaining the divergent approaches to discount rates
    • See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 113-15 (describing and explaining the divergent approaches to discount rates).
    • supra , pp. 113-115
    • SHAPIRO1    GLICKSMAN2
  • 234
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 92 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 92 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 235
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 134 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 134 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 236
    • 50349084275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weinberg, supra note 143
    • Weinberg, supra note 143.
  • 237
    • 50349087146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Catherine A. O'Neill, Alternative Approaches to Regulatory Impact Analysis: Clean Air Mercury Rule (Jan. 31, 2008 draft), in ALTERNATIVES TO REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS (Lisa Heinzerling et al. eds.), at Part II (forthcoming) (tentatively titled) (reviewing different cost-benefit studies of regulating mercury emissions from coal-fired power plants and discussing how different inferential bridges change the net benefits by orders of magnitude) (on file with the Harvard Environmental Law Review).
    • See Catherine A. O'Neill, Alternative Approaches to Regulatory Impact Analysis: Clean Air Mercury Rule (Jan. 31, 2008 draft), in ALTERNATIVES TO REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS (Lisa Heinzerling et al. eds.), at Part II (forthcoming) (tentatively titled) (reviewing different cost-benefit studies of regulating mercury emissions from coal-fired power plants and discussing how different inferential bridges change the net benefits by orders of magnitude) (on file with the Harvard Environmental Law Review).
  • 238
    • 50349095811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sunstein, supra note 115, at 2290
    • Sunstein, supra note 115, at 2290.
  • 239
    • 50349096347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hahn, supra note 83, at 218
    • Hahn, supra note 83, at 218.
  • 240
    • 50349089635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parker, supra note 105, at 1382-83
    • Parker, supra note 105, at 1382-83.
  • 241
    • 50349096452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • He also assigned a zero-value to benefits that were quantified and monetized if they did not fall into a select category of benefits that he included within his study. Id
    • He also assigned a zero-value to benefits that were quantified and monetized if they did not fall into a select category of benefits that he included within his study. Id.
  • 242
    • 4444369690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economic Analysis of Regulation: A Response to the Critics, 71
    • Robert W. Hahn, The Economic Analysis of Regulation: A Response to the Critics, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 1021 (2004).
    • (2004) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.1021
    • Hahn, R.W.1
  • 243
    • 0347286684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulation and Information Disclosure: Parallel Universes and Beyond, 25
    • William F. Pederson, Regulation and Information Disclosure: Parallel Universes and Beyond, 25 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 151, 202-03 (2001).
    • (2001) HARV. ENVTL. L. REV , vol.151 , pp. 202-203
    • Pederson, W.F.1
  • 244
    • 50349089221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Lawrence Tribe, Trial by Mathematics: Precision and Ritual in the Legal Process, 84 HARV. L. REV. 1329, 1362 (1971) (Readily quantifiable factors are easier to process - and hence more likely to be recognized and then reflected in the outcome - than are factors that resist ready quantification.).
    • Cf. Lawrence Tribe, Trial by Mathematics: Precision and Ritual in the Legal Process, 84 HARV. L. REV. 1329, 1362 (1971) ("Readily quantifiable factors are easier to process - and hence more likely to be recognized and then reflected in the outcome - than are factors that resist ready quantification.").
  • 245
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 156-57 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 156-57 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 246
    • 50349092394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.E.
    • See supra Part II.E.
  • 247
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 54 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 54 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 248
    • 0346703224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Cost-Benefit State, 50
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Thomas O. McGarity, A Cost-Benefit State, 50 ADMIN. L. REV. 7, 72-73 (1998).
    • (1998) ADMIN. L. REV , vol.7 , pp. 72-73
    • McGarity, T.O.1
  • 249
    • 52049115057 scopus 로고
    • Rights Against Risk, 86
    • See
    • See Christopher H. Schroeder, Rights Against Risk, 86 COLUM. L. REV. 495, 508 (1986).
    • (1986) COLUM. L. REV , vol.495 , pp. 508
    • Schroeder, C.H.1
  • 250
    • 50349085411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As Lisa Heinzerling explains, [d]eciding to allow one person to harm, even kill, another person on the basis of how much it costs the person doing the harm to refrain from doing it denies the person harmed a right against harm. It makes the person's freedom from harm, indeed her life, contingent upon the financial profile of the life-threatening activity. Lisa Heinzerling, The Rights of Statistical People, 24 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 189, 189 (2000).
    • As Lisa Heinzerling explains, "[d]eciding to allow one person to harm, even kill, another person on the basis of how much it costs the person doing the harm to refrain from doing it denies the person harmed a right against harm. It makes the person's freedom from harm, indeed her life, contingent upon the financial profile of the life-threatening activity." Lisa Heinzerling, The Rights of Statistical People, 24 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 189, 189 (2000).
  • 251
    • 50349085320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 130 (supporters of impact analysis typically oppose regulation at least in its current design and seek to educate agencies and the public about the potentially deleterious effects of risk regulation on economic development and other important considerations).
    • See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 130 (supporters of impact analysis typically oppose regulation at least in its current design and seek to educate agencies and the public about "the potentially deleterious effects of risk regulation on economic development and other important considerations).
  • 252
    • 84885215480 scopus 로고
    • Reinventing the Regulatory State, 62
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Richard H. Pildes & Cass R. Sunstein, Reinventing the Regulatory State, 62 U. CHI. L. REV. 1, 74 (1995).
    • (1995) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 74
    • Pildes, R.H.1    Sunstein, C.R.2
  • 253
    • 50349091109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Thomas O. McGarity & Sidney A. Shapiro, OSHA's Critics and Regulatory Reform, 31 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 587, 631-33 (1996) (identifying conflict between CBA and decisionmaking criterion in the Occupational Safety and Health Act).
    • See Thomas O. McGarity & Sidney A. Shapiro, OSHA's Critics and Regulatory Reform, 31 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 587, 631-33 (1996) (identifying conflict between CBA and decisionmaking criterion in the Occupational Safety and Health Act).
  • 254
    • 50349089741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HARMON, supra note 67, at 55
    • HARMON, supra note 67, at 55.
  • 255
    • 50349095813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 50-53 and accompanying text (noting that some post-empiricists consider empirical results as a mixture of empiricism and social construction, while others deny that empiricism can identify reality in light of its social construction).
    • See supra notes 50-53 and accompanying text (noting that some post-empiricists consider empirical results as a mixture of empiricism and social construction, while others deny that empiricism can identify reality in light of its social construction).
  • 256
    • 50349099276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DEIRDRE N. MCCLOSKEY, THE RHETORIC OF ECONOMICS xix-xxi (2d ed. 1998).
    • DEIRDRE N. MCCLOSKEY, THE RHETORIC OF ECONOMICS xix-xxi (2d ed. 1998).
  • 257
    • 50349102069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 147
    • Id. at 147.
  • 258
    • 50349096453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 259
    • 50349087504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 260
    • 50349088035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV.A.1.
    • See infra Part IV.A.1.
  • 261
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 88 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 88 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 262
    • 50349092966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PORTER, supra note 88, at 155-62
    • See PORTER, supra note 88, at 155-62.
  • 263
    • 50349086132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 162
    • Id. at 162.
  • 264
    • 50349101116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oral Testimony of Carol M. Browner, Administrator, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency before the Subcommittee on Energy and Environment of the Committee on Science U.S. House of Representatives, May 21, 1997, available at http://yosemite.epa.gov/opa/admpress.nsf/ 7a69cfa127d8396585257359004l0226/ f59da70ee33f70d28525701a0052e3c7!OpenDocument.
    • Oral Testimony of Carol M. Browner, Administrator, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency before the Subcommittee on Energy and Environment of the Committee on Science U.S. House of Representatives, May 21, 1997, available at http://yosemite.epa.gov/opa/admpress.nsf/ 7a69cfa127d8396585257359004l0226/ f59da70ee33f70d28525701a0052e3c7!OpenDocument.
  • 265
    • 50349096569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wendy Wagner, The Science Charade in Toxic Risk Regulation, 95 COLUM. L. REV. 1613, 1640-44 (1995) (discussing the use of science to deflect criticism of policy decisions).
    • See Wendy Wagner, The Science Charade in Toxic Risk Regulation, 95 COLUM. L. REV. 1613, 1640-44 (1995) (discussing the use of science to deflect criticism of policy decisions).
  • 266
    • 50349083430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A conversation with one of the co-authors (Schroeder) in the fall of 1980.
    • A conversation with one of the co-authors (Schroeder) in the fall of 1980.
  • 267
    • 50349084675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally PORTER, supra note 88, at 89-90 describing how abandoning of reliance on expert judgment in the name of public standards and objective rules, is] never a voluntary affair, but emerge[s] always from a sense of intense pressure or bitter rivlary. Thus, as consumer interests and others who stand outside the traditional iron-triangles seek more public accountability for agency decisions, rigorous quantification is demanded, because subjective discretion has become suspect. Mechanical objectivity serves as an alternative to personal trust
    • See generally PORTER, supra note 88, at 89-90 (describing how abandoning of "reliance on expert judgment in the name of public standards and objective rules ... [is] never a voluntary affair, but emerge[s] always from a sense of intense pressure or bitter rivlary." Thus, as consumer interests and others who stand outside the traditional iron-triangles seek more public accountability for agency decisions, "rigorous quantification is demanded ... because subjective discretion has become suspect. Mechanical objectivity serves as an alternative to personal trust.").
  • 268
    • 50349094041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shapiro, supra note 94, at 695
    • Shapiro, supra note 94, at 695.
  • 269
    • 50349084567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indus. Union Dep't, AFL-CIO v. Am. Petroleum Inst., 448 U.S. 607, 639-40 (1980) (Only after the Secretary has made the threshold determination that [a significant] risk exists with respect to a toxic substance is the Secretary authorized to regulate under the statute).
    • Indus. Union Dep't, AFL-CIO v. Am. Petroleum Inst., 448 U.S. 607, 639-40 (1980) ("Only after the Secretary has made the threshold determination that [a significant] risk exists with respect to a toxic substance" is the Secretary authorized to regulate under the statute).
  • 270
    • 50349089121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 655
    • Id. at 655.
  • 271
    • 50349083843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 272
    • 0035037619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., John F. Martonik et al., The History of OSHA's Asbestos Rulemakings and Some Distinctive Approaches That They Introduced for Regulating Occupational Exposure to Toxic Substances, 62 AM. INDUS. HYGIENE ASS'N J. 208, 213 (2001) (observing that quantitative assessment of risk was the result of the Supreme Court's benzene decision requiring OSHA to perform such an analysis when appropriate data are available).
    • See, e.g., John F. Martonik et al., The History of OSHA's Asbestos Rulemakings and Some Distinctive Approaches That They Introduced for Regulating Occupational Exposure to Toxic Substances, 62 AM. INDUS. HYGIENE ASS'N J. 208, 213 (2001) (observing that "quantitative assessment of risk was the result of the Supreme Court's benzene decision requiring OSHA to perform such an analysis when appropriate data are available").
  • 273
    • 50349096568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ZYGMUNT J.B. PLATER ET AL., ENVIRONMENTAL LAW AND POLICY: NATURE, LAW, AND SOCIETY 400 (3d ed. 2004) (identifying as an underlying theme of environmental law the penetration of an iron triangle of private construction and industrial interests, government agencies that service the industry, and congressional delegations that want to attract particular public expenditures into their backyards).
    • See ZYGMUNT J.B. PLATER ET AL., ENVIRONMENTAL LAW AND POLICY: NATURE, LAW, AND SOCIETY 400 (3d ed. 2004) (identifying as an underlying theme of environmental law the penetration of an iron triangle of "private construction and industrial interests, government agencies that service the industry, and congressional delegations that want to attract particular public expenditures into their backyards").
  • 274
    • 50349101016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.A.3 (discussion of regulatory relief).
    • See supra Part III.A.3 (discussion of regulatory relief).
  • 275
    • 50349101669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.B.1.
    • See supra Part III.B.1.
  • 276
    • 50349083221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In one analysis of CBA, Richard Andrews notes the use of ... requirements [such as CBA] as a weapon for oversight and control of regulatory decisions by the president. Richard N. L. Andrews, Economics and Environmental Decisions, Past and Present Analysis, in ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY UNDER REAGAN'S EXECUTIVE ORDER: THE ROLE OF COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS 43, 45 (V. Kerry Smith ed., 1984).
    • In one analysis of CBA, Richard Andrews notes "the use of ... requirements [such as CBA] as a weapon for oversight and control of regulatory decisions by the president." Richard N. L. Andrews, Economics and Environmental Decisions, Past and Present Analysis, in ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY UNDER REAGAN'S EXECUTIVE ORDER: THE ROLE OF COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS 43, 45 (V. Kerry Smith ed., 1984).
  • 277
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 25 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 25 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 278
    • 0035998097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert W. Hahn & Cass R. Sunstein, A New Executive Order for Improving Federal Regulation? Deeper and Wider Cost-Benefit Analysis, 150 U. PA. L. REV. 1489, 1497 n.34 (2002) (comparing OIRA's small staff of about fifty and the large number of regulations it reviews).
    • See Robert W. Hahn & Cass R. Sunstein, A New Executive Order for Improving Federal Regulation? Deeper and Wider Cost-Benefit Analysis, 150 U. PA. L. REV. 1489, 1497 n.34 (2002) (comparing OIRA's small staff of about fifty and the large number of regulations it reviews).
  • 279
    • 50349096669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exec. Order 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193 (Feb. 17, 1981).
    • Exec. Order 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193 (Feb. 17, 1981).
  • 280
    • 50349099476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 75
    • See supra note 75.
  • 281
    • 50349090069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.E.
    • See supra Part II.E.
  • 282
    • 50349096227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Theodore M. Porter, Objectivity as Standardization: The Rhetoric of Impersonality in Measurement, Statistics, and Cost-Benefit Analysis, in RETHINKING OBJECTIVITY 197, 197 (Allan Megill ed., 1994).
    • Theodore M. Porter, Objectivity as Standardization: The Rhetoric of Impersonality in Measurement, Statistics, and Cost-Benefit Analysis, in RETHINKING OBJECTIVITY 197, 197 (Allan Megill ed., 1994).
  • 283
    • 50349093603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 210 (citation omitted).
    • Id. at 210 (citation omitted).
  • 284
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 88-89 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 88-89 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 285
    • 50349103062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ollie Houck, for one, has described the Army Corps of Engineers as a federal agency housed within the United States Army that worked directly for the United States Congress. It is described in the literature as an 'iron triangle,' composed of your local congressmen, your local Corps, and your local shippers, real estate developers and other beneficiaries who contributed generously to these same congressmen, and received generously in return. Oliver Houck, Can We Save New Orleans?, 19 TUL. ENVTL. L.J. 1, 13 (2006).
    • Ollie Houck, for one, has described the Army Corps of Engineers as "a federal agency housed within the United States Army that worked directly for the United States Congress. It is described in the literature as an 'iron triangle,' composed of your local congressmen, your local Corps, and your local shippers, real estate developers and other beneficiaries who contributed generously to these same congressmen, and received generously in return." Oliver Houck, Can We Save New Orleans?, 19 TUL. ENVTL. L.J. 1, 13 (2006).
  • 286
    • 50349096346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Theodore Porter is a little more positive. PORTER, supra note 88, at 155 (When, now more rarely, really disgraceful projects were authorized [after the 1936 Act], a modest standard of decorum was maintained. Official economic analyses helped to cut off debate and bargaining in Congress.).
    • Theodore Porter is a little more positive. PORTER, supra note 88, at 155 ("When, now more rarely, really disgraceful projects were authorized [after the 1936 Act], a modest standard of decorum was maintained. Official economic analyses helped to cut off debate and bargaining in Congress.").
  • 287
    • 50349103497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JOHN R. HIBBING & ELIZABETH THEISS-MORSE, CONGRESS AS PUBLIC ENEMY 147 (1995) (A surprising number of people, it seems, dislike being exposed to processes endemic to democratic government. People profess a devotion to democracy in the abstract but have little or no appreciation for what a practicing democracy invariably brings with it.... People do not wish to see uncertainty, conflicting opinions, long debate, competing interests, confusion, bargaining, and compromised, imperfect solutions. They want government to do its job quietly and efficiently, sans conflict and sans fuss.).
    • See JOHN R. HIBBING & ELIZABETH THEISS-MORSE, CONGRESS AS PUBLIC ENEMY 147 (1995) ("A surprising number of people, it seems, dislike being exposed to processes endemic to democratic government. People profess a devotion to democracy in the abstract but have little or no appreciation for what a practicing democracy invariably brings with it.... People do not wish to see uncertainty, conflicting opinions, long debate, competing interests, confusion, bargaining, and compromised, imperfect solutions. They want government to do its job quietly and efficiently, sans conflict and sans fuss.").
  • 288
    • 34547814457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 150-152 and accompanying text
    • See, e.g., supra notes 150-152 and accompanying text.
    • See, e.g., supra
  • 289
    • 50349096796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clear Consensus, Ambiguous Commitment, 98
    • See
    • See Christopher H. Schroeder, Clear Consensus, Ambiguous Commitment, 98 MICH. L. REV. 1876, 1912-13 (2000).
    • (2000) MICH. L. REV. 1876 , pp. 1912-1913
    • Schroeder, C.H.1
  • 290
    • 50349083219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Straight Talk memorandum written by Frank Luntz, a prominent Republican strategist, urges candidates to [s]tay away from 'risk assessment,' 'cost-benefit analysis,' and the other traditional environmental terminology used by industry and corporations and to [p]ut the costs of regulations in human terms, emphasizing job losses and changes in lifestyle. Memorandum from Frank Luntz, The Luntz Research Cos. 131, 139-40 (2002), excerpt available at http://www2.bc.edu/~plater/Newpublicsite06/suppmats /02.6.pdf.
    • The "Straight Talk" memorandum written by Frank Luntz, a prominent Republican strategist, urges candidates to "[s]tay away from 'risk assessment,' 'cost-benefit analysis,' and the other traditional environmental terminology used by industry and corporations" and to "[p]ut the costs of regulations in human terms," emphasizing job losses and changes in lifestyle. Memorandum from Frank Luntz, The Luntz Research Cos. 131, 139-40 (2002), excerpt available at http://www2.bc.edu/~plater/Newpublicsite06/suppmats /02.6.pdf.
  • 291
    • 50349099922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.F.
    • See supra Part II.F.
  • 292
    • 50349093390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The use of pragmatism to design a regulatory analysis methodology is hardly a new idea. Philosophical pragmatism, as originally conceived by John Dewey, William James, and others, became the dominant mode of social analysis in the early decades of the twentieth century. SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at xi.
    • The use of pragmatism to design a regulatory analysis methodology is hardly a new idea. Philosophical pragmatism, as originally conceived by John Dewey, William James, and others, became the dominant mode of social analysis in the early decades of the twentieth century. SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at xi.
  • 293
    • 50349083536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although pragmatism was eclipsed by the turn in the social sciences toward positivism, it has enjoyed a strong comeback, including as a basis for designing and implementing environmental, health, and safety policy. See, e.g, SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105;
    • Although pragmatism was eclipsed by the turn in the social sciences toward positivism, it has enjoyed a strong comeback, including as a basis for designing and implementing environmental, health, and safety policy. See, e.g., SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105;
  • 295
    • 50349084776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ENVIRONMENTAL PRAGMATISM Andrew Light & Eric Katz eds
    • ENVIRONMENTAL PRAGMATISM (Andrew Light & Eric Katz eds., 1996);
    • (1996)
  • 296
    • 0038184001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prophets, Priests, and Pragmatists, 87
    • Christopher H. Schroeder, Prophets, Priests, and Pragmatists, 87 MINN. L. REV. 1065 (2003).
    • (2003) MINN. L. REV , vol.1065
    • Schroeder, C.H.1
  • 297
    • 50349101562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PRAGMATISM: A READER, at xiv (Louis Menand ed., 1997).
    • PRAGMATISM: A READER, at xiv (Louis Menand ed., 1997).
  • 298
    • 50349091218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 15
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 15.
  • 299
    • 50349094920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 16
    • Id. at 16.
  • 300
    • 50349103167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 16-17
    • Id. at 16-17.
  • 301
    • 50349098633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.B.
    • See supra Part III.B.
  • 302
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 138, 140 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 138, 140 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 303
    • 50349086321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.A.1.
    • See supra Part III.A.1.
  • 304
    • 50349096130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rhetoric, Pragmatism and the Interdisciplinary Turn in Legal Criticism - A Study of Altruistic Judicial Argument, 46 AM
    • Gene R. Shreve, Rhetoric, Pragmatism and the Interdisciplinary Turn in Legal Criticism - A Study of Altruistic Judicial Argument, 46 AM. J. Comp. L. 41, 58 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Comp , vol.50 , Issue.41 , pp. 58
    • Shreve, G.R.1
  • 305
    • 50349094252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Parts II.D and II.E.
    • See supra Parts II.D and II.E.
  • 306
    • 50349092850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Morris Dickstein, Introduction: Pragmatism Then and Now, in THE REVIVAL OF PRAGMATISM: NEW ESSAYS ON SOCIAL THOUGHT, LAW, AND CULTURE 1, 5 (Morris Dickstein ed., 1999) (explaining that pragmatists reject concepts such as truth because truth is provisional, grounded in history and experience, not fixed in the nature of things);
    • See Morris Dickstein, Introduction: Pragmatism Then and Now, in THE REVIVAL OF PRAGMATISM: NEW ESSAYS ON SOCIAL THOUGHT, LAW, AND CULTURE 1, 5 (Morris Dickstein ed., 1999) (explaining that pragmatists reject concepts such as "truth" because "truth is provisional, grounded in history and experience, not fixed in the nature of things");
  • 307
    • 84935413351 scopus 로고
    • Can Nihilism Be Pragmatic?, 100
    • John Stick, Can Nihilism Be Pragmatic?, 100 HARV. L. REV. 332, 340 (1986).
    • (1986) HARV. L. REV , vol.332 , pp. 340
    • Stick, J.1
  • 308
    • 50349091852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dewey would not have denied that science advances deep human interests when it is able to provide better explanations of how the world works and what consequences various actions might have. See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 16-17 (describing Dewey's views on science);
    • Dewey would not have denied that science advances deep human interests when it is able to provide better explanations of how the world works and what consequences various actions might have. See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 16-17 (describing Dewey's views on science);
  • 309
    • 0348202120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Feathers or Gold?: A Civic Economics for Environmental Law, 25
    • explaining that pragmatism endorses the scientific method as a means of identifying useful insights from many perspectives, see also
    • see also Robert R.M. Verchick, Feathers or Gold?: A Civic Economics for Environmental Law, 25 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 95, 127 (2001) (explaining that pragmatism "endorses the scientific method as a means of identifying useful insights from many perspectives").
    • (2001) HARV. ENVTL. L. REV , vol.95 , pp. 127
    • Verchick, R.R.M.1
  • 310
    • 50349100683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lasswell proposed the field of policy sciences because he did not believe that the social sciences were focused on the social problems that democracy was trying to resolve. See supra note 18 and accompanying text.
    • Lasswell proposed the field of policy sciences because he did not believe that the social sciences were focused on the social problems that democracy was trying to resolve. See supra note 18 and accompanying text.
  • 311
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 246 and accompanying text
    • See infra note 246 and accompanying text.
    • See infra
  • 312
    • 50349091853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO, supra note 48, at 28
    • SHAPIRO, supra note 48, at 28.
  • 313
    • 50349097302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, CIRCULAR A-4, Sept. 17, 2003, http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/circulars/a004/a-4.pdf.
    • OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, CIRCULAR A-4, Sept. 17, 2003, http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/circulars/a004/a-4.pdf.
  • 314
    • 50349099367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see supra Part III.B.1.
    • But see supra Part III.B.1.
  • 315
    • 50349097513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV.C.
    • See infra Part IV.C.
  • 316
    • 50349098521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 21
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 21.
  • 317
    • 50349100117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g, FISCHER, supra note 2, at 191-98;
    • E.g., FISCHER, supra note 2, at 191-98;
  • 318
    • 50349098320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DUNN, supra note 70, at 20-23;
    • DUNN, supra note 70, at 20-23;
  • 319
    • 0345709179 scopus 로고
    • Justifying Policy Arguments: Criteria for Practical Discourse, 13 EVALUATION & POL
    • William N. Dunn, Justifying Policy Arguments: Criteria for Practical Discourse, 13 EVALUATION & POL. PLAN. 221 (1990).
    • (1990) PLAN , vol.221
    • Dunn, W.N.1
  • 320
    • 50349101439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These analysts rely on the work of Stephen Toulmin. See STEPHEN TOULMIN, THE USES OF ARGUMENT (1958);
    • These analysts rely on the work of Stephen Toulmin. See STEPHEN TOULMIN, THE USES OF ARGUMENT (1958);
  • 321
    • 50349095812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also STEPHEN TOULMIN, RICHARD RIEKE & ALLAN JANIK, AN INTRODUCTION TO REASONING (2d ed. 1984).
    • see also STEPHEN TOULMIN, RICHARD RIEKE & ALLAN JANIK, AN INTRODUCTION TO REASONING (2d ed. 1984).
  • 322
    • 50349089120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MAJONE, supra note 27, at 46-47
    • MAJONE, supra note 27, at 46-47.
  • 323
    • 50349094590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Majone's work taps into a literature on rhetoric dating back to Aristotle that defines rationality not in instrumental terms, but as the ability to provide acceptable reasons for one's choices and actions. Id. at 23.
    • Majone's work taps into a literature on rhetoric dating back to Aristotle that "defines rationality not in instrumental terms, but as the ability to provide acceptable reasons for one's choices and actions." Id. at 23.
  • 324
    • 50349103170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 47
    • Id. at 47.
  • 325
    • 50349091021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 326
    • 50349086029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 327
    • 50349093710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 67
    • Id. at 67.
  • 328
    • 50349091219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 133;
    • FISCHER, supra note 2, at 133;
  • 329
    • 50349088594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MAJONE, supra note 27, at 42-46;
    • MAJONE, supra note 27, at 42-46;
  • 330
    • 50349088913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DUNN, supra note 70, at 2-3;
    • DUNN, supra note 70, at 2-3;
  • 331
    • 50349094698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 209 (stating that the development of an alternative to CBA begins with the recognition that there is no formula).
    • see also ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 209 (stating that the development of an alternative to CBA "begins with the recognition that there is no formula").
  • 332
    • 50349102385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MAJONE, supra note 27, at 48-49
    • MAJONE, supra note 27, at 48-49.
  • 333
    • 50349083748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 49
    • Id. at 49.
  • 334
    • 50349085415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass'n v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29 (1983).
    • Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass'n v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29 (1983).
  • 335
    • 50349091965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 43 (internal quotation omitted).
    • Id. at 43 (internal quotation omitted).
  • 336
    • 50349085825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 62 and accompanying text (describing practical reason in post-empiricist policy analysis).
    • See supra note 62 and accompanying text (describing "practical reason" in post-empiricist policy analysis).
  • 337
    • 50349083429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837 (1984).
    • Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837 (1984).
  • 338
    • 0347710456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law as Craft, 54
    • Brett G. Scharffs, Law as Craft, 54 VAND. L. REV. 2245, 2247-50 (2001).
    • (2001) VAND. L. REV , vol.2245 , pp. 2247-2250
    • Scharffs, B.G.1
  • 339
    • 50349103386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jews, Truth and Critical Race Theory, 93
    • book review
    • Edward L. Rubin, Jews, Truth and Critical Race Theory, 93 Nw. U. L. REV. 525, 540 (1999) (book review).
    • (1999) Nw. U. L. REV , vol.525 , pp. 540
    • Rubin, E.L.1
  • 340
    • 50349098129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Burton, supra note 62, at 789-90
    • Burton, supra note 62, at 789-90.
  • 341
    • 50349091429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scharffs, supra note 231, at 2247;
    • Scharffs, supra note 231, at 2247;
  • 342
    • 50349086416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Edward L. Rubin, The Practice and Discourse of Legal Scholarship, 86 MICH. L. REV. 1835, 1878 (1988) ([The practical reason movement] is characterized by its vision of the law as an embedded social practice, whose provisions are supported by a complex set of norms, traditions, and pragmatic compromises that lack overarching justifications, but can be evaluated by judgment or intuition.).
    • Edward L. Rubin, The Practice and Discourse of Legal Scholarship, 86 MICH. L. REV. 1835, 1878 (1988) ("[The practical reason movement] is characterized by its vision of the law as an embedded social practice, whose provisions are supported by a complex set of norms, traditions, and pragmatic compromises that lack overarching justifications, but can be evaluated by judgment or intuition.").
  • 343
    • 50349102734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scharffs, supra note 231, at 2266
    • Scharffs, supra note 231, at 2266.
  • 344
    • 50349092397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rubin, supra note 234, at 1878
    • Rubin, supra note 234, at 1878.
  • 345
    • 50349095029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Burton, supra note 62, at 789-90
    • Burton, supra note 62, at 789-90.
  • 346
    • 50349084368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • THOMAS BENDER, INTELLECT AND PUBLIC LIFE: ESSAYS ON THE SOCIAL HISTORY OF ACADEMIC INTELLECTUALS IN THE UNITED STATES 137 (1993).
    • THOMAS BENDER, INTELLECT AND PUBLIC LIFE: ESSAYS ON THE SOCIAL HISTORY OF ACADEMIC INTELLECTUALS IN THE UNITED STATES 137 (1993).
  • 347
    • 50349085623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (emphasis added).
    • Id. (emphasis added).
  • 348
    • 50349090388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As noted earlier, Dewey regarded the state as analogous to a scientific society in that both were critical communities of inquiry, except that citizens were the ultimate community of inquiry regarding social and policy issues. See supra note 203 and accompanying text. For Dewey, politics in public constituted a proper source of values, purposes, and social knowledge in a democracy. BENDER, supra note 238, at 137.
    • As noted earlier, Dewey regarded the state as analogous to a scientific society in that both were critical communities of inquiry, except that citizens were the ultimate community of inquiry regarding social and policy issues. See supra note 203 and accompanying text. "For Dewey, politics in public constituted a proper source of values, purposes, and social knowledge in a democracy." BENDER, supra note 238, at 137.
  • 349
    • 50349100020 scopus 로고
    • Law as Rhetoric, Rhetoric as Law: The Arts of Cultural and Communal Life, 52
    • James Boyd White, Law as Rhetoric, Rhetoric as Law: The Arts of Cultural and Communal Life, 52 U. CHI. L. REV. 684, 701 (1985).
    • (1985) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.684 , pp. 701
    • Boyd White, J.1
  • 350
    • 50349086227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DELEON, supra note 13, at 113
    • DELEON, supra note 13, at 113.
  • 351
    • 50349102508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 31-40
    • See SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 31-40.
  • 352
    • 50349099368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 33
    • Id. at 33.
  • 353
    • 50349100334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 6
    • Id. at 6.
  • 354
    • 84894689913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 7411(b)(1)A, 2000
    • 42 U.S.C. § 7411(b)(1)(A) (2000).
    • 42 U.S.C
  • 355
    • 50349097414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 40
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 40.
  • 356
    • 50349101342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 51-52.
    • See id. at 51-52.
  • 357
    • 50349093711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This does not mean that costs are ignored. As explained later in this Part, Congress sometimes requires consideration of costs, but with the goal of ensuring that regulation is not overly disruptive or unreasonable
    • This does not mean that costs are ignored. As explained later in this Part, Congress sometimes requires consideration of costs, but with the goal of ensuring that regulation is not overly disruptive or unreasonable.
  • 358
    • 50349099924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As Doug Kysar explains: Lives lost under the do the best you can heuristic and other precautionary approaches are not viewed as efficient tradeoffs, accepted in exchange for whatever utility has been gained. Instead, they are viewed as tragic, regrettable consequences of human fallibility and finitude - a moral remainder that provides enduring motivation for surviving members of society to seek ways of doing better in the future. In contrast, because it aspires to comprehensive rationality, CBA must invariably round this moral remainder to zero. In the process, it must also fail to encourage an appropriate degree of collective self-awareness regarding the deep normativity of risk regulation.
    • As Doug Kysar explains: Lives lost under the "do the best you can" heuristic and other precautionary approaches are not viewed as efficient "tradeoffs," accepted in exchange for whatever utility has been gained. Instead, they are viewed as tragic, regrettable consequences of human fallibility and finitude - a "moral remainder" that provides enduring motivation for surviving members of society to seek ways of doing better in the future. In contrast, because it aspires to comprehensive rationality, CBA must invariably round this moral remainder to zero. In the process, it must also fail to encourage an appropriate degree of collective self-awareness regarding the deep normativity of risk regulation.
  • 359
    • 50349086941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kysar, supra note 113, at 41
    • Kysar, supra note 113, at 41.
  • 360
    • 50349085211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An agency will consider scientific evidence that measures the extent to which a substance or technology is harmful to individuals or the environment in order to decide whether it can meet the evidentiary burden established by the applicable risk trigger. Although this risk assessment is based on scientific evidence, it is not precise because information about the risks being studied is usually limited. See supra notes 113-114 and accompanying text
    • An agency will consider scientific evidence that measures the extent to which a substance or technology is harmful to individuals or the environment in order to decide whether it can meet the evidentiary burden established by the applicable risk trigger. Although this risk assessment is based on scientific evidence, it is not precise because information about the risks being studied is usually limited. See supra notes 113-114 and accompanying text.
  • 361
    • 77954531515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OMB and the Politicization of Risk Assessment, 37
    • See
    • See Sidney A. Shapiro, OMB and the Politicization of Risk Assessment, 37 ENVTL. L. 1083, 1089 (2007).
    • (2007) ENVTL. L , vol.1083 , pp. 1089
    • Shapiro, S.A.1
  • 362
    • 50349090695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 363
    • 50349101228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 95
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 95.
  • 364
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 220 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 220 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 365
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 224 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 224 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 366
    • 50349092289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EPA has explained the weight of the evidence approach in the context of carcinogen risk assessment as follows: Judgment about the weight of evidence involves considerations of the quality and adequacy of data and consistency of responses induced by the agent in question. The weight of evidence judgment requires combined input of relevant disciplines. Initial views of one kind of evidence may change significantly when other information is brought to the interpretation. For example, a positive animal carcinogenicity finding may be diminished by other key data; a weak association in epidemiologic studies may be bolstered by consideration of other key data and animal findings. Factors typically considered are illustrated in figures below. Generally, no single weighing factor on either side determines the overall weight. The factors are not scored mechanically by adding pluses and minuses; they are judged in combination. Proposed Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment, 61 Fed. Reg. 17,96
    • EPA has explained the weight of the evidence approach in the context of carcinogen risk assessment as follows: Judgment about the weight of evidence involves considerations of the quality and adequacy of data and consistency of responses induced by the agent in question. The weight of evidence judgment requires combined input of relevant disciplines. Initial views of one kind of evidence may change significantly when other information is brought to the interpretation. For example, a positive animal carcinogenicity finding may be diminished by other key data; a weak association in epidemiologic studies may be bolstered by consideration of other key data and animal findings. Factors typically considered are illustrated in figures below. Generally, no single weighing factor on either side determines the overall weight. The factors are not scored mechanically by adding pluses and minuses; they are judged in combination. Proposed Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment, 61 Fed. Reg. 17,960, 17,981 (Apr. 23, 1996).
  • 367
    • 33044499382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Prospect of "Daubertizing" Judicial Review of Risk Assessment, 66
    • Thomas O. McGarity, On the Prospect of "Daubertizing" Judicial Review of Risk Assessment, 66 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 155, 165 (2003).
    • (2003) LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS , vol.155 , pp. 165
    • McGarity, T.O.1
  • 368
    • 50349101961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 369
    • 50349100567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 370
    • 50349103169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This flaw arises from the fact that CBA is methodology-driven rather than problem-driven. See supra note 214 and accompanying text
    • This flaw arises from the fact that CBA is methodology-driven rather than problem-driven. See supra note 214 and accompanying text.
  • 371
    • 84886336150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 113-114 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 113-114 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 372
    • 50349093497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 32-33 listing statutes that use a constrained balancing standard
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 32-33 (listing statutes that use a "constrained balancing" standard).
  • 373
    • 50349085210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 37
    • Id. at 37.
  • 374
    • 50349093602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. § 655(b)(5) (20W) (emphasis added).
    • U.S.C. § 655(b)(5) (20W) (emphasis added).
  • 375
    • 50349094917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OCCUPATIONAL SAFETY AND HEALTH LAw 458-62 (Randy S. Rabinowitz ed., 2d ed. 2002).
    • OCCUPATIONAL SAFETY AND HEALTH LAw 458-62 (Randy S. Rabinowitz ed., 2d ed. 2002).
  • 376
    • 50349097090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 377
    • 50349102281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Am. Textile Mfg. Inst. v. Donovan (Cotton Dust Case), 452 U.S. 490, 509 (1981).
    • Am. Textile Mfg. Inst. v. Donovan (Cotton Dust Case), 452 U.S. 490, 509 (1981).
  • 378
    • 50349087148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 52
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 52.
  • 379
    • 50349098214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In some statutes, Congress goes further and forces regulated entities to develop more effective technologies than are currently in use. Id.
    • In some statutes, Congress goes further and forces regulated entities to develop more effective technologies than are currently in use. Id.
  • 380
    • 50349087377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 32
    • Id. at 32.
  • 381
    • 50349087719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 39
    • Id. at 39.
  • 382
    • 50349088803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. § 136a(d)(1)(C) (2000).
    • U.S.C. § 136a(d)(1)(C) (2000).
  • 384
    • 50349086615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 39
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 39.
  • 385
    • 50349101964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 43-44
    • Id. at 43-44.
  • 387
    • 50349087501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.13.2.
    • See supra Part III.13.2.
  • 388
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 154 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 154 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 389
    • 50349090893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part IV.13.3.
    • See supra Part IV.13.3.
  • 390
    • 50349085000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.B.2.
    • See supra Part III.B.2.
  • 391
    • 50349086718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 35-36 (noting that, for example, EPA can authorize the sale of food adulterated by a pesticide if, with reasonable certainty, no harm will result from exposure to the pesticide).
    • SHAPIRO & GLICKSMAN, supra note 105, at 35-36 (noting that, for example, EPA can authorize the sale of food adulterated by a pesticide if, with reasonable certainty, no harm will result from exposure to the pesticide).
  • 392
    • 50349094805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 36 (noting the example that Congress has adopted a series of prohibitions on the production and use of chemicals harmful to the strategic ozone layer to be phased in over time).
    • Id. at 36 (noting the example that Congress has adopted a series of prohibitions on the production and use of chemicals harmful to the strategic ozone layer to be phased in over time).
  • 393
    • 50349085104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part V.B (illustrating in arsenic case study how a pragmatic RIA differs from a CBA-centered RIA when a statute requires the use of CBA).
    • See infra Part V.B (illustrating in arsenic case study how a pragmatic RIA differs from a CBA-centered RIA when a statute requires the use of CBA).
  • 394
    • 50349094142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 210-23
    • ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 210-23.
  • 395
    • 50349094806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 208-09
    • Id. at 208-09.
  • 396
    • 50349095245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11
    • Id. at 11.
  • 397
    • 50349101962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10-11, 208-23.
    • Id. at 10-11, 208-23.
  • 398
    • 50349090068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 212-13
    • Id. at 212-13.
  • 399
    • 50349084566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 215 (In advocating a holistic approach to weighing costs and benefits, we have been talking about bow elected representatives and the public should think about health and environmental problems - not about how broad policies should be implemented.).
    • See id. at 215 ("In advocating a holistic approach to weighing costs and benefits, we have been talking about bow elected representatives and the public should think about health and environmental problems - not about how broad policies should be implemented.").
  • 400
    • 41149142066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributing the Costs of Environmental, Health, and Safety Protection: The Feasibility Principle, Cost-Benefit Analysis, and Regulatory Reform, 32
    • David M. Driesen, Distributing the Costs of Environmental, Health, and Safety Protection: The Feasibility Principle, Cost-Benefit Analysis, and Regulatory Reform, 32 B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 1, 3 (2005).
    • (2005) B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 3
    • Driesen, D.M.1
  • 401
    • 50349092748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 402
    • 27644495342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standards of Performance for New and Existing Stationary Sources: Electric Utility Steam Generating Units, 70 Fed. Reg. 28,606 (May 18, 2005) (codified at 40 C.F.R pts. 60, 72, and 75).
    • Standards of Performance for New and Existing Stationary Sources: Electric Utility Steam Generating Units, 70 Fed. Reg. 28,606 (May 18, 2005) (codified at 40 C.F.R pts. 60, 72, and 75).
  • 403
    • 50349093709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lisa Heinzerling & Rena I. Steinzor, A Perfect Storm: Mercury and the Bush Administration, 34 ENVTL. L. REP. 10,297, 10,307-10 (2004) (contending that EPA lacks legal authority for its cap and trade rule).
    • See Lisa Heinzerling & Rena I. Steinzor, A Perfect Storm: Mercury and the Bush Administration, 34 ENVTL. L. REP. 10,297, 10,307-10 (2004) (contending that EPA lacks legal authority for its cap and trade rule).
  • 404
    • 50349101904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Jersey v. EPA, 517 F.3d 574 (D.C. Cir. 2009) (holding that because EPA had not followed procedures prescribed in section 112(c)(9) for delisting electric generating units (EGUs) from the list of categories subject to section 112's standards for mercury, EPA's decision to regulate mercury emissions from EGUs exclusively under section III was erroneous).
    • New Jersey v. EPA, 517 F.3d 574 (D.C. Cir. 2009) (holding that because EPA had not followed procedures prescribed in section 112(c)(9) for delisting electric generating units ("EGUs") from the list of categories subject to section 112's standards for mercury, EPA's decision to regulate mercury emissions from EGUs exclusively under section III was erroneous).
  • 405
    • 50349096668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Catherine O'Neill, No Mud Pies: Risk Avoidance as Risk Regulation, 31 VT. L. REV. 273, 280 (2006) (comparing mercury reductions expected under a maximum achievable control technology standard and under EPA's final rule).
    • See Catherine O'Neill, No Mud Pies: Risk Avoidance as Risk Regulation, 31 VT. L. REV. 273, 280 (2006) (comparing mercury reductions expected under a maximum achievable control technology standard and under EPA's final rule).
  • 406
    • 50349093290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. § 7412(n)(1)(A) (2000).
    • U.S.C. § 7412(n)(1)(A) (2000).
  • 407
    • 50349095482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By comparison, Congress made the initial decision regarding the risk trigger for other sources of mercury pollution by listing mercury as a hazardous air pollutant subject to regulation, Id. § 7412(b)(1).
    • By comparison, Congress made the initial decision regarding the risk trigger for other sources of mercury pollution by listing mercury as a hazardous air pollutant subject to regulation, Id. § 7412(b)(1).
  • 408
    • 50349086025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EPA, MERCURY STUDY REPORT TO CONGRESS, EPA 452-R-97-003, 0-4 (1997), available at http://www.epa.gov/ttn/oarpg/t3/reports/ volume1.pdf.
    • EPA, MERCURY STUDY REPORT TO CONGRESS, EPA 452-R-97-003, 0-4 (1997), available at http://www.epa.gov/ttn/oarpg/t3/reports/ volume1.pdf.
  • 409
    • 50349092965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NAT'L RESEARCH COUNCIL, NAT'L ACAD. OF SCIS., TOXICOLOGICAL EFFECTS OF METHYL MERCURY 4 (2000), available at http:/ /books.nap.edu/openbook/0309071402/html/index.html.
    • NAT'L RESEARCH COUNCIL, NAT'L ACAD. OF SCIS., TOXICOLOGICAL EFFECTS OF METHYL MERCURY 4 (2000), available at http:/ /books.nap.edu/openbook/0309071402/html/index.html.
  • 410
    • 50349093707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulatory Finding on Emissions of Hazardous Air Pollutants from Electric Utility Steam-Generating Units, 65 Fed. Reg. 79,825, 79,825 Dec. 20, 2000
    • Regulatory Finding on Emissions of Hazardous Air Pollutants from Electric Utility Steam-Generating Units, 65 Fed. Reg. 79,825, 79,825 (Dec. 20, 2000).
  • 411
    • 50349102835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Heinzerling & Steinzor, supra note 292, at 10,298, 10,300
    • See Heinzerling & Steinzor, supra note 292, at 10,298, 10,300.
  • 412
    • 50349090484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 10,298-99.
    • See id. at 10,298-99.
  • 413
    • 50349092084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EPA, AMERICA'S CHILDREN AND THE ENVIRONMENT 59 (2003), available at http://www.epa.gov/opeedweb/children/ace_2003.pdf.
    • EPA, AMERICA'S CHILDREN AND THE ENVIRONMENT 59 (2003), available at http://www.epa.gov/opeedweb/children/ace_2003.pdf.
  • 414
    • 50349085622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Heinzerling & Steinzor, supra note 292, at 10,300
    • Heinzerling & Steinzor, supra note 292, at 10,300.
  • 415
    • 41249102876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See
    • § 7412(d)2, 2000
    • See 42 U.S.C. § 7412(d)(2) (2000).
    • 42 U.S.C
  • 416
    • 50349102939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Perfect Storm: Mercury and the Bush Adminsitration, Part II, 34
    • Lisa Heinzerling & Rena I. Steinzor, A Perfect Storm: Mercury and the Bush Adminsitration, Part II, 34 ENVTL. L. REP. 10,485, 10,488 (2004).
    • (2004) ENVTL. L. REP , vol.10 , Issue.485 , pp. 10-488
    • Heinzerling, L.1    Steinzor, R.I.2
  • 417
    • 50349100116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Proposed National Emission Standards for Hazardous Air Pollutants; and, in the Alternative, Proposed Standards of Performance for New and Existing Stationary Sources: Electric Utility Steam Generating Units; Proposed Rule, 69 Fed. Reg. 4652 (Jan. 30, 2004).
    • Proposed National Emission Standards for Hazardous Air Pollutants; and, in the Alternative, Proposed Standards of Performance for New and Existing Stationary Sources: Electric Utility Steam Generating Units; Proposed Rule, 69 Fed. Reg. 4652 (Jan. 30, 2004).
  • 418
    • 25144438708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Revision of December 2000 Regulatory Finding on the Emissions of Hazardous Air Pollutants From Electric Utility Steam Generating Units and the Removal of Coal- and Oil-Fired Electric Utility Steam Generating Units From the Section 112(c) List, 70 Fed. Reg. 15,994 (Mar. 29, 2005).
    • Revision of December 2000 Regulatory Finding on the Emissions of Hazardous Air Pollutants From Electric Utility Steam Generating Units and the Removal of Coal- and Oil-Fired Electric Utility Steam Generating Units From the Section 112(c) List, 70 Fed. Reg. 15,994 (Mar. 29, 2005).
  • 419
    • 50349085719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Heinzerling & Steinzor, supra note 304, at 10,489
    • Heinzerling & Steinzor, supra note 304, at 10,489.
  • 420
    • 50349096906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OFFICE OF AIR QUALITY PLANNING & STANDARDS, EPA, EPA-452 /R-05-003, REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS OF THE FINAL CLEAN AIR MERCURY RULE (2005), available at http://www.epa.gov/ttn/ecas /regdata/RIAs/mercury_ria_final.pdf [hereinafter MERCURY RIA].
    • OFFICE OF AIR QUALITY PLANNING & STANDARDS, EPA, EPA-452 /R-05-003, REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS OF THE FINAL CLEAN AIR MERCURY RULE (2005), available at http://www.epa.gov/ttn/ecas /regdata/RIAs/mercury_ria_final.pdf [hereinafter MERCURY RIA].
  • 421
    • 50349101226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10-11
    • Id. at 10-11.
  • 422
    • 50349099475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10-11
    • Id. at 10-11.
  • 423
    • 50349095363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10-3
    • Id. at 10-3.
  • 424
    • 50349094807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10-47
    • Id. at 10-47.
  • 426
    • 27644495342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standards of Performance for New and Existing Stationary Sources: Electric Utility Steam Generating Units, 70 Fed. Reg. 28,606, 28,642 (May 18, 2005).
    • Standards of Performance for New and Existing Stationary Sources: Electric Utility Steam Generating Units, 70 Fed. Reg. 28,606, 28,642 (May 18, 2005).
  • 427
    • 50349093936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 428
    • 50349100228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part IV.C.1.b.
    • See supra Part IV.C.1.b).
  • 429
    • 50349098738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • require the maximum degree of reduction in emissions
    • EPA must from new and existing sources, subject to adjustment based on cost and other factors listed in the statute. 42 U.S.C. § 7412(d)(2, 2000, For new sources, however, the maximum degree of reduction, that is deemed achievable, shall not be less stringent than the emission control that is achieved in practice by the best controlled similar source. Id. § 7412(d)3
    • EPA must "require the maximum degree of reduction in emissions" from new and existing sources, subject to adjustment based on cost and other factors listed in the statute. 42 U.S.C. § 7412(d)(2) (2000). For new sources, however, "the maximum degree of reduction ... that is deemed achievable ... shall not be less stringent than the emission control that is achieved in practice by the best controlled similar source." Id. § 7412(d)(3).
  • 430
    • 50349086613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For existing sources, the MACT can be less stringent than the MACT for new sources, but it cannot be less stringent, and can be more stringent, than the average emission limitation achieved by the best performing [twelve] percent of the existing sources if there are thirty sources or more or the average emission limitation achieved by the best performing [five] sources if there are fewer than thirty sources. Id. § 7412(d)(3)(A)-(B).
    • For existing sources, the MACT can be less stringent than the MACT for new sources, but it cannot be less stringent, and can be more stringent, than "the average emission limitation achieved by the best performing [twelve] percent of the existing sources" if there are thirty sources or more or "the average emission limitation achieved by the best performing [five] sources" if there are fewer than thirty sources. Id. § 7412(d)(3)(A)-(B).
  • 431
    • 50349103060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, GAO-05-216, CLEAN AIR ACT: EMERGING MERCURY CONTROL TECHNOLOGIES HAVE SHOWN PROMISING RESULTS, BUT DATA ON LONG-TERM PERFORMANCE ARE LIMITED 10-11 (2005) [hereinafter U.S. GAO].
    • See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, GAO-05-216, CLEAN AIR ACT: EMERGING MERCURY CONTROL TECHNOLOGIES HAVE SHOWN PROMISING RESULTS, BUT DATA ON LONG-TERM PERFORMANCE ARE LIMITED 10-11 (2005) [hereinafter U.S. GAO].
  • 432
    • 27644495342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standards of Performance for New and Existing Stationary Sources: Electric Utility Steam Generating Units, 70 Fed. Reg. 28,606, 28,614-15 (May 18, 2005).
    • Standards of Performance for New and Existing Stationary Sources: Electric Utility Steam Generating Units, 70 Fed. Reg. 28,606, 28,614-15 (May 18, 2005).
  • 433
    • 50349090294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. GAO, supra note 318, at 3-4, 16
    • U.S. GAO, supra note 318, at 3-4, 16.
  • 434
    • 50349096905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GAO also indicated that experts believed that the costs of achieving reductions in this range would fall over time as a market for new technologies emerged. Id. at 27
    • GAO also indicated that experts believed that the costs of achieving reductions in this range would fall over time as a market for new technologies emerged. Id. at 27.
  • 435
    • 50349089536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At the same time, GAO noted that data on the long-term performance of mercury controls are limited because the use of mercury reduction technology was a new development and most tests have lasted less than three months. See id. at 4
    • At the same time, GAO noted that data on the long-term performance of mercury controls are limited because the use of mercury reduction technology was a new development and most tests have lasted less than three months. See id. at 4.
  • 436
    • 50349089537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GAO concluded that available data show promising results, but noted that when power plants could rely on these technologies to achieve significant mercury reductions - such as by 2008 or later - involves professional judgment. Id. at 28.
    • GAO concluded that "available data show promising results," but noted that "when power plants could rely on these technologies to achieve significant mercury reductions - such as by 2008 or later - involves professional judgment." Id. at 28.
  • 437
    • 42049106034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mercury, Risk and Justice, 30
    • Catherine A. O'Neill, Mercury, Risk and Justice, 30 ENVTL. L. REP. 11,070 (2004).
    • (2004) ENVTL. L. REP , vol.11 , pp. 070
    • O'Neill, C.A.1
  • 438
    • 50349088804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11,093
    • Id. at 11,093.
  • 439
    • 50349084565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11,115
    • Id. at 11,115.
  • 440
    • 50349096037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11,110
    • Id. at 11,110.
  • 441
    • 50349086499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11,112-13.
    • Id. at 11,112-13.
  • 442
    • 50349085413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carl F. Cranor, Risk Assessment, Susceptible Subpopulations, and Environmental Justice, in THE LAW OF ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE 307, 328 (Michael B. Gerrard ed., 1999) (Cost-benefit analysis and its philosophic ancestor, utilitarianism, compared with environmental justice are simply two different and incompatible views for addressing the problems of guiding exposures to toxic substances.);
    • Carl F. Cranor, Risk Assessment, Susceptible Subpopulations, and Environmental Justice, in THE LAW OF ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE 307, 328 (Michael B. Gerrard ed., 1999) ("Cost-benefit analysis and its philosophic ancestor, utilitarianism, compared with environmental justice are simply two different and incompatible views for addressing the problems of guiding exposures to toxic substances.");
  • 443
    • 50349093167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • O'Neill, supra note 290, at 346-47 (Rather than undertake a sober discussion whether we as a society can support these consequences - whether we can tolerate a particular instance of distributive injustice, a particular affront to human dignity or cultural integrity - decisions made by means of cost-benefit analysis are made without reference to who is affected and without reference to what is at stake from their perspective.).
    • O'Neill, supra note 290, at 346-47 ("Rather than undertake a sober discussion whether we as a society can support these consequences - whether we can tolerate a particular instance of distributive injustice, a particular affront to human dignity or cultural integrity - decisions made by means of cost-benefit analysis are made without reference to who is affected and without reference to what is at stake from their perspective.").
  • 444
    • 84937276351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congress, Constitutional Moments, and the Cost-Benefit State, 48
    • proposing that CBA be modified to take into account whether the risk is equitably distributed or concentrated on identifiable, innocent, or traditionally disadvantaged victims, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Cass R. Sunstein, Congress, Constitutional Moments, and the Cost-Benefit State, 48 STAN. L. REV. 247, 293 (1996) (proposing that CBA be modified to take into account "whether the risk is equitably distributed or concentrated on identifiable, innocent, or traditionally disadvantaged victims").
    • (1996) STAN. L. REV , vol.247 , pp. 293
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 445
    • 50349083220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MERCURY RIA, supra note 308, at 10-130
    • MERCURY RIA, supra note 308, at 10-130.
  • 446
    • 50349099275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10-134
    • Id. at 10-134.
  • 447
    • 50349089331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 448
    • 50349098953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10-134 n.29.
    • Id. at 10-134 n.29.
  • 449
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 314-315 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 314-315 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 450
    • 84886336150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 316-320 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 316-320 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 451
    • 50349087503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RENA I. STEINZOR, MOTHER EARTH AND UNCLE SAM 122 (2008) (No one but an experienced team of economists with weeks of free time on their hands could possibly hope to evaluate these or any of the other assumptions made in the Regulatory Impact Analysis.).
    • See RENA I. STEINZOR, MOTHER EARTH AND UNCLE SAM 122 (2008) ("No one but an experienced team of economists with weeks of free time on their hands could possibly hope to evaluate these or any of the other assumptions made in the Regulatory Impact Analysis.").
  • 452
    • 50349103385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, EPA fails to discuss or justify the particular methodology it adopted to measure benefits, even though this choice had the impact of reducing the amount of benefits as compared to other potential methodological choices. See O'Neill, Clean Air Mercury Rule, supra note 148, at 34 (EPA here dazzles with detail, but never engages the question begged by their approach, namely, is it appropriate to consider exposures from the narrowly circumscribed universe of 'recreationally caught freshwater fish,' when there are clearly other sources of exposure ... from mercury emitted by U.S. utilities ....).
    • For example, EPA fails to discuss or justify the particular methodology it adopted to measure benefits, even though this choice had the impact of reducing the amount of benefits as compared to other potential methodological choices. See O'Neill, Clean Air Mercury Rule, supra note 148, at 34 ("EPA here dazzles with detail, but never engages the question begged by their approach, namely, is it appropriate to consider exposures from the narrowly circumscribed universe of 'recreationally caught freshwater fish,' when there are clearly other sources of exposure ... from mercury emitted by U.S. utilities ....").
  • 453
    • 50349089847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Notice of Proposed Rulemaking; National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring, 65 Fed. Reg. 38,888, 38,888 (June 22, 2000). The unit ppb is used to measure the concentration of contaminants in water and air and stands for one part per billion. One ppb is equal to a microgram per liter (μg/liter).
    • See Notice of Proposed Rulemaking; National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring, 65 Fed. Reg. 38,888, 38,888 (June 22, 2000). The unit "ppb" is used to measure the concentration of contaminants in water and air and stands for one part per billion. One "ppb" is equal to a microgram per liter (μg/liter).
  • 454
    • 50349102180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Final Rule: National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring, 66 Fed. Reg. 6976, 6976 (Jan. 22, 2001) [hereinafter Final Arsenic Rule].
    • Final Rule: National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring, 66 Fed. Reg. 6976, 6976 (Jan. 22, 2001) [hereinafter Final Arsenic Rule].
  • 455
    • 50349093498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Delay of Effective Date. National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring, 66 Fed. Reg. 16,134, 16,134 (Mar. 23, 2001) (sixty day delay);
    • Delay of Effective Date. National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring, 66 Fed. Reg. 16,134, 16,134 (Mar. 23, 2001) (sixty day delay);
  • 456
    • 50349088246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Delay of Effective Date: National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring, 66 Fed. Reg. 28,342, 28,342 (May 22, 2001) (nine month delay).
    • Delay of Effective Date: National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring, 66 Fed. Reg. 28,342, 28,342 (May 22, 2001) (nine month delay).
  • 457
    • 50349089118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Notice of Proposed Rulemaking: National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring, 66 Fed. Reg. 37,617, 37,617 (July 19, 2001).
    • Notice of Proposed Rulemaking: National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring, 66 Fed. Reg. 37,617, 37,617 (July 19, 2001).
  • 458
    • 50349087827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at, 22 describing planned review process
    • See id. at 37,621-22 (describing planned review process);
    • See id , pp. 37-621
  • 459
    • 50349102068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EPA, Arsenic in Drinking Water: Rule-Making History (Sept. 13, 2006), http://epa.gov/safewater/arsenic/history.html (referring to these peer reviews) (on file with the Harvard Environmental Law Review).
    • EPA, Arsenic in Drinking Water: Rule-Making History (Sept. 13, 2006), http://epa.gov/safewater/arsenic/history.html (referring to these peer reviews) (on file with the Harvard Environmental Law Review).
  • 460
    • 50349098632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 68 Fed. Reg. 14,502
    • Minor Clarification of National Primary Drinking Water Regulation for Arsenic, Mar. 23
    • Minor Clarification of National Primary Drinking Water Regulation for Arsenic, 68 Fed. Reg. 14,502, 14,503 (Mar. 23, 2003).
    • (2003) , vol.14 , pp. 503
  • 461
    • 50349096794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A longer description of the arsenic regulations and RIA can be found in ROBERT V. PERCIVAL ET AL., ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION: LAW, SCIENCE, AND POLICY 253-62 (5th ed. 2006).
    • A longer description of the arsenic regulations and RIA can be found in ROBERT V. PERCIVAL ET AL., ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION: LAW, SCIENCE, AND POLICY 253-62 (5th ed. 2006).
  • 462
    • 50349089330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. §§ 300f to 300j-26 (2000).
    • U.S.C. §§ 300f to 300j-26 (2000).
  • 467
    • 50349099705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EPA may also depart from the feasible MCL if setting a particular standard would have deleterious effects on achieving other drinking water standards. Id. §300g-1(b)5
    • EPA may also depart from the feasible MCL if setting a particular standard would have deleterious effects on achieving other drinking water standards. Id. §300g-1(b)(5).
  • 468
    • 50349088703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Final Arsenic Rule, supra note 337, at 7022
    • Final Arsenic Rule, supra note 337, at 7022.
  • 469
    • 50349090184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 470
    • 50349101963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 471
    • 50349092179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ABT ASSOCS., EPA 815-R-00-013, PROPOSED ARSENIC IN DRINKING WATER RULE REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS (2000) (prepared for U.S. EPA, Office of Ground Water and Drinking Water), available at http:// www.epa.gov/safewater/arsenic/pdfs/prop_ria.pdf;
    • ABT ASSOCS., EPA 815-R-00-013, PROPOSED ARSENIC IN DRINKING WATER RULE REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS (2000) (prepared for U.S. EPA, Office of Ground Water and Drinking Water), available at http:// www.epa.gov/safewater/arsenic/pdfs/prop_ria.pdf;
  • 472
    • 50349083427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ABT ASSOCS., EPA 815-R-00-026, FINAL ARSENIC IN DRINKING WATER RULE REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS (2000) (prepared for U.S. EPA, Office of Ground Water and Drinking Water), available at http://www.epa.gov/safewater/arsenic/pdfs/econ_analysis.pdf [hereinafter ABT ASSOCS., FINAL RIA].
    • ABT ASSOCS., EPA 815-R-00-026, FINAL ARSENIC IN DRINKING WATER RULE REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS (2000) (prepared for U.S. EPA, Office of Ground Water and Drinking Water), available at http://www.epa.gov/safewater/arsenic/pdfs/econ_analysis.pdf [hereinafter ABT ASSOCS., FINAL RIA].
  • 473
    • 50349093391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ABT ASSOCS, FINAL RIA, supra note 349, at 1-4
    • ABT ASSOCS., FINAL RIA, supra note 349, at 1-4.
  • 474
    • 50349095135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 475
    • 50349101528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 1-6. Economists are divided concerning what constitutes the appropriate discount rate
    • note 144 and accompanying text
    • Id. at 1-6. Economists are divided concerning what constitutes the appropriate discount rate. See supra note 144 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 476
    • 50349094918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ABT ASSOCS, FINAL RIA, supra note 349 at 5-11 to 5-14
    • ABT ASSOCS., FINAL RIA, supra note 349 at 5-11 to 5-14.
  • 477
    • 50349096226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The analysis used a Monte Carlo simulation, Id. at 5-11;
    • The analysis used a Monte Carlo simulation, Id. at 5-11;
  • 478
    • 33846582209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 118 discussing this technique and its limitations
    • see also supra note 118 (discussing this technique and its limitations).
    • see also supra
  • 479
    • 50349095366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ABT ASSOCS, FINAL RIA, supra note 349, at 5-23
    • ABT ASSOCS., FINAL RIA, supra note 349, at 5-23.
  • 480
    • 50349089743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 5-24
    • Id. at 5-24.
  • 481
    • 50349088912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.B.2;
    • See supra Part III.B.2;
  • 482
    • 0036663570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Markets for Arsenic, 90
    • identifying problems with the monetization process used in the Arsenic RIA, see also
    • see also Lisa Heinzerling, Markets for Arsenic, 90 GEO. L.J. 2311 (2002) (identifying problems with the monetization process used in the Arsenic RIA).
    • (2002) GEO. L.J , vol.2311
    • Heinzerling, L.1
  • 483
    • 50349090483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ABT ASSOCS, FINAL RIA, supra note 349, at 5-23
    • ABT ASSOCS., FINAL RIA, supra note 349, at 5-23.
  • 484
    • 50349098952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 5-24
    • Id. at 5-24.
  • 485
    • 50349093937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The data were based on a more than ten-year-old survey done at a Greensboro, N.C. shopping mall. ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 96.
    • The data were based on a more than ten-year-old survey done at a Greensboro, N.C. shopping mall. ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 96.
  • 486
    • 50349090799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As a sensitivity analysis, the RIA did compare the medical costs of treating non-fatal bladder cancer. The numbers are not comparable ($178,405 in medical expenses versus $607,162 for WTP to avoid chronic bronchitis, ABT. ASSOCS., FINAL RIA, supra note 349, at 5-24), but the RIA again contains no additional discussion of the implications of this disparity.
    • As a sensitivity analysis, the RIA did compare the medical costs of treating non-fatal bladder cancer. The numbers are not comparable ($178,405 in medical expenses versus $607,162 for WTP to avoid chronic bronchitis, ABT. ASSOCS., FINAL RIA, supra note 349, at 5-24), but the RIA again contains no additional discussion of the implications of this disparity.
  • 487
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 136 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 136 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 488
    • 84922571440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 110, at, discussing defects of the study
    • See ACKERMAN & HEINZERLING, supra note 110, at 96 (discussing defects of the study).
    • supra , pp. 96
    • ACKERMAN1    HEINZERLING2
  • 489
    • 50349098951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 97
    • Id. at 97.
  • 490
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 345 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 345 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 491
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 88-89 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 88-89 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 492
    • 50349093288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even outside the health and safety area, where one might suppose the use of CBA as a monitoring device would be more tractable, its record is not stellar. The installation of CBA at the Army Corps turned out to provide a layer of defense against subsequent attacks, while at the same time not greatly limiting the Corps' ability to select questionable projects. See supra note 194.
    • Even outside the health and safety area, where one might suppose the use of CBA as a monitoring device would be more tractable, its record is not stellar. The installation of CBA at the Army Corps turned out to provide a layer of defense against subsequent attacks, while at the same time not greatly limiting the Corps' ability to select questionable projects. See supra note 194.
  • 493
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 197 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 197 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 494
    • 50349086719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EDWARD M. GRAMLICH, BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS OF GOVERNMENT PROGRAMS 1-2 (1981) (quoting Franklin).
    • EDWARD M. GRAMLICH, BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS OF GOVERNMENT PROGRAMS 1-2 (1981) (quoting Franklin).
  • 495
    • 50349094484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The very idea of modeling presupposes some technique for simplifying the complexities of reality. The results of the model are then interpreted to have some meaning for the reality it seeks to model. We have argued throughout this paper that the manner in which CBA achieves simplification ignores critical features of reality, claims accuracy when that is not available, and is vulnerable to manipulation. See supra Parts III.B.2-III.B.3, IV.C.2. These problems are sufficiently severe so that RIA ought to employ alternative means of recognizing and analyzing the pros and cons of health and safety decisions.
    • The very idea of modeling presupposes some technique for simplifying the complexities of reality. The results of the model are then interpreted to have some meaning for the reality it seeks to model. We have argued throughout this paper that the manner in which CBA achieves simplification ignores critical features of reality, claims accuracy when that is not available, and is vulnerable to manipulation. See supra Parts III.B.2-III.B.3, IV.C.2. These problems are sufficiently severe so that RIA ought to employ alternative means of recognizing and analyzing the pros and cons of health and safety decisions.
  • 496
    • 50349087830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EPA, UNFINISHED BUSINESS: A COMPARATIVE ASSESSMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL PROBLEMS (1987).
    • EPA, UNFINISHED BUSINESS: A COMPARATIVE ASSESSMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL PROBLEMS (1987).
  • 497
    • 50349087611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., MICHAEL C. MUNGER, ANALYZING POLICY 6-14 (2000) (explaining the use of the criteria-alternatives matrix or CAM, and providing examples).
    • See, e.g., MICHAEL C. MUNGER, ANALYZING POLICY 6-14 (2000) (explaining the use of the "criteria-alternatives matrix" or CAM, and providing examples).
  • 498
    • 50349103061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alternatives are the columns, criteria the rows, and each cell contains a measure or evaluation of that row's criteria for the column's alternative. Id. at 9.
    • Alternatives are the columns, criteria the rows, and each cell contains a measure or evaluation of that row's criteria for the column's alternative. Id. at 9.
  • 499
    • 50349100452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This kind of matrix is useful to guide policy makers in identifying trade-offs and highlighting the importance of values. Id. at 28 n.5
    • This kind of matrix is useful "to guide policy makers in identifying trade-offs and highlighting the importance of values." Id. at 28 n.5.
  • 500
    • 50349088034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Bagley & Revesz, supra note 103, at 1312-29;
    • See, e.g, Bagley & Revesz, supra note 103, at 1312-29;
  • 501
    • 0010109852 scopus 로고
    • Political Oversight and the Deterioration of Regulatory Policy, 46
    • Sidney A. Shapiro, Political Oversight and the Deterioration of Regulatory Policy, 46 ADMIN. L. REV. 1, 30-32 (1994).
    • (1994) ADMIN. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 30-32
    • Shapiro, S.A.1
  • 502
    • 50349098634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bagley & Revesz, supra note 103, at 1307-10
    • See Bagley & Revesz, supra note 103, at 1307-10.
  • 503
    • 50349089535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • IORA has a professional staff of about [forty] persons. PETER L. STRAUSS, TODD D. RAKOFF & CYNTHIA R. FARINA, ADMINISTRATIVE LAW: CASES AND COMMENTS 615 (rev. 10th ed. 2003).
    • IORA has "a professional staff of about [forty]" persons. PETER L. STRAUSS, TODD D. RAKOFF & CYNTHIA R. FARINA, ADMINISTRATIVE LAW: CASES AND COMMENTS 615 (rev. 10th ed. 2003).
  • 504
    • 50349086027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Parts III.B.1-III.B.2.
    • See supra Parts III.B.1-III.B.2.
  • 505
    • 50349101341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shapiro, supra note 370, at 31
    • Shapiro, supra note 370, at 31.
  • 506
    • 0347664773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential Administration, 114
    • See
    • See Elena Kagan, Presidential Administration, 114 HARV. L. REV. 2245, 2309-16 (2001).
    • (2001) HARV. L. REV , vol.2245 , pp. 2309-2316
    • Kagan, E.1
  • 507
    • 50349093289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bressman & Vandenbergh, supra note 101, at 66
    • Bressman & Vandenbergh, supra note 101, at 66.
  • 508
    • 50349099052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Thomas O. McGarity, Media-Quality, Technology, and Cost-Benefit Balancing Strategies for Health and Environmental Regulation, 46 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 159 (1983) (identifying six factors that agencies use for evaluating decisions, including political feasibility).
    • See, e.g., Thomas O. McGarity, Media-Quality, Technology, and Cost-Benefit Balancing Strategies for Health and Environmental Regulation, 46 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 159 (1983) (identifying six factors that agencies use for evaluating decisions, including political feasibility).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.