메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 40, Issue 3, 2008, Pages 313-329

Survival of the fittest? Cabinet duration in postcommunist Europe

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 44649200129     PISSN: 00104159     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.5129/001041508X12911362383075     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (52)

References (70)
  • 1
    • 0003162328 scopus 로고
    • Presidential or Parliamentary Democracy: Does It Make a Difference?
    • See, Juan Linz and Arturo Valenzuela, eds, Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press
    • See Juan Linz, "Presidential or Parliamentary Democracy: Does It Make a Difference?," in Juan Linz and Arturo Valenzuela, eds., Failure of Presidential Democracy (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994);
    • (1994) Failure of Presidential Democracy
    • Linz, J.1
  • 4
    • 84935845328 scopus 로고
    • The Process of Cabinet Dissolution: An Exponential Model of Duration and Stability in Western Democracies
    • Eric C. Browne, John P. Frendreis, and Dennis W. Gleiber, "The Process of Cabinet Dissolution: An Exponential Model of Duration and Stability in Western Democracies," American Journal of Political Science, 30 (1986), 628-50;
    • (1986) American Journal of Political Science , vol.30 , pp. 628-650
    • Browne, E.C.1    Frendreis, J.P.2    Gleiber, D.W.3
  • 11
    • 84925908397 scopus 로고
    • The Stability and Survival of Governments in Western Democracies
    • D. Sanders and V. Herman, "The Stability and Survival of Governments in Western Democracies," Acta Politica, 26 (1977), 346-77.
    • (1977) Acta Politica , vol.26 , pp. 346-377
    • Sanders, D.1    Herman, V.2
  • 13
    • 84965943789 scopus 로고
    • The Durability of Coalition Governments in Parliamentary Democracies
    • Paul Warwick, "The Durability of Coalition Governments in Parliamentary Democracies," Comparative Political Studies, 11 (1979), 465-98.
    • (1979) Comparative Political Studies , vol.11 , pp. 465-498
    • Warwick, P.1
  • 14
    • 8644269524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Following the events approach, a coalition is considered terminated if (1) there were elections, (2) the prime minister voluntarily resigned, (3) the prime minister died, (4) dissention within government occurred (5) parliamentary support dropped or (6) the head of state intervened. Ferdinand Müller-Rommel, Katia Fettelschoss, and Philipp Harfst, Party Government in Central European Democracies: A Data Collection (1990-2003), European Journal of Political Research, 43 (2005), 869-94.
    • Following the events approach, a coalition is considered terminated if (1) there were elections, (2) the prime minister voluntarily resigned, (3) the prime minister died, (4) dissention within government occurred (5) parliamentary support dropped or (6) the head of state intervened. Ferdinand Müller-Rommel, Katia Fettelschoss, and Philipp Harfst, "Party Government in Central European Democracies: A Data Collection (1990-2003)," European Journal of Political Research, 43 (2005), 869-94.
  • 20
    • 85036906310 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • King, Alt, Barnes, and Laver
    • King, Alt, Barnes, and Laver.
  • 21
    • 85036944650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henderson and Robinson
    • Henderson and Robinson.
  • 22
    • 85036923027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid.
  • 23
    • 85036942688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blondel and Müller-Rommel
    • Blondel and Müller-Rommel.
  • 25
    • 27744510921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • on the substantial electoral volatility, see Margit Tavits, The Development of Stable Support: Electoral Dynamics in Post-Communist Europe, American Political Science Review, 65 (2005), 283-98;
    • on the substantial electoral volatility, see Margit Tavits, "The Development of Stable Support: Electoral Dynamics in Post-Communist Europe," American Political Science Review, 65 (2005), 283-98;
  • 26
    • 85036909925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • on weak party system institutionalization, see Scott Mainwaring and Mariano Torcal, Party System Institutionalization and Party System Theory after the Third Wave of Democracy, Working Paper #319 (2005);
    • on weak party system institutionalization, see Scott Mainwaring and Mariano Torcal, "Party System Institutionalization and Party System Theory after the Third Wave of Democracy," Working Paper #319 (2005);
  • 27
    • 0033034258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Electoral Systems and the Number of Parties in Postcommunist States
    • for fractionalized parties, see
    • for fractionalized parties, see Robert Moser, "Electoral Systems and the Number of Parties in Postcommunist States," World Politics (1999), 359-84;
    • (1999) World Politics , pp. 359-384
    • Moser, R.1
  • 29
    • 85036928822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blondel and Müller-Rommel
    • Blondel and Müller-Rommel.
  • 30
    • 85036938948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taylor and Herman
    • Taylor and Herman.
  • 33
    • 85036920574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lowell, pp. 73-74
    • Lowell, pp. 73-74.
  • 35
    • 84976104285 scopus 로고
    • Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism, and Multipartism
    • George Tsebelis, "Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism, and Multipartism," British Journal of Political Science, 25 (1995), 289-325.
    • (1995) British Journal of Political Science , vol.25 , pp. 289-325
    • Tsebelis, G.1
  • 37
    • 84976913342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sanders and Herman; Kaare Strom, Minority Governments in Parliamentary Democracies: The Rationality of Nonwinning Cabinet Solutions, Comparative Political Studies, 17 (1984), 199-227;
    • Sanders and Herman; Kaare Strom, "Minority Governments in Parliamentary Democracies: The Rationality of Nonwinning Cabinet Solutions," Comparative Political Studies, 17 (1984), 199-227;
  • 39
    • 85036929178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strom, p. 199
    • Strom, p. 199.
  • 41
    • 85036944371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taylor and Herman
    • Taylor and Herman.
  • 43
    • 85036923015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., p. 1101.
    • Dodd1
  • 44
    • 85036906863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blondel and Müller-Rommel
    • Blondel and Müller-Rommel.
  • 46
    • 85036936338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blondel and Müller-Rommel
    • Blondel and Müller-Rommel.
  • 47
    • 85036950895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henderson and Robinson, p. 256.
    • Henderson and Robinson, p. 256.
  • 48
    • 84938051914 scopus 로고
    • The Mass Public and Macroeconomic Performance: The Dynamics of Public Opinion toward Unemployment and Inflation
    • Douglas A. Hibbs, "The Mass Public and Macroeconomic Performance: The Dynamics of Public Opinion toward Unemployment and Inflation," American Journal of Political Science, 23 (1979), 705-31.
    • (1979) American Journal of Political Science , vol.23 , pp. 705-731
    • Hibbs, D.A.1
  • 49
    • 84972477449 scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy and the Durability of European Coalition Cabinets: New Variations on a Game-Theoretic Perspective
    • John D. Robertson, "The Political Economy and the Durability of European Coalition Cabinets: New Variations on a Game-Theoretic Perspective," Journal of Politics, 45 (1983), 932-57;
    • (1983) Journal of Politics , vol.45 , pp. 932-957
    • Robertson, J.D.1
  • 50
    • 84935036012 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Political-Economic Accounting of the Endurance of Cabinet Administrations: An Empirical Assessment of Eight European Democracies
    • John D. Robertson, "Toward a Political-Economic Accounting of the Endurance of Cabinet Administrations: An Empirical Assessment of Eight European Democracies," American Journal of Political Science, 28 (1984), 693-709.
    • (1984) American Journal of Political Science , vol.28 , pp. 693-709
    • Robertson, J.D.1
  • 51
    • 85036924221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robertson, The Political Economy and the Durability of European Coalition Cabinets; Robertson, Toward a Political-Economic Accounting of the Endurance of Cabinet Administrations.
    • Robertson, "The Political Economy and the Durability of European Coalition Cabinets"; Robertson, "Toward a Political-Economic Accounting of the Endurance of Cabinet Administrations."
  • 52
    • 0034002530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Government Competence, Economic Performance and Endogenous Election Dates
    • Harvey D. Palmer and Guy D. Whitten, "Government Competence, Economic Performance and Endogenous Election Dates," Electoral Studies, 19 (2000), 413-26.
    • (2000) Electoral Studies , vol.19 , pp. 413-426
    • Palmer, H.D.1    Whitten, G.D.2
  • 54
    • 84888712512 scopus 로고
    • A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context
    • G. Bingham Powell and Guy D. Whitten, "A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context," American Journal of Political Science, 37 (1993), 391-414.
    • (1993) American Journal of Political Science , vol.37 , pp. 391-414
    • Bingham Powell, G.1    Whitten, G.D.2
  • 55
    • 85036924190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blondel and Müller-Rommel
    • Blondel and Müller-Rommel.
  • 56
    • 85036952371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Müller-Rommel, Fettelschoss, and Harfst
    • Müller-Rommel, Fettelschoss, and Harfst.
  • 58
    • 84949792766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • th party.
    • th party.
  • 59
    • 85036935865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Single party government (one party holds the majority in parliament and all government seats, minimal winning coalition (all parties in government are necessary to form a majority government, surplus coalition (coalition governments that exceed the minimal winning criteria, single party minority government (the party in government does not possess the majority of seats in parliament, multiparty minority government (the parties in government do not possess the majority of seats in parliament, and caretaker government temporary cabinet, Müller-Rommel, Fettelschoss, and Harfst
    • Single party government (one party holds the majority in parliament and all government seats); minimal winning coalition (all parties in government are necessary to form a majority government); surplus coalition (coalition governments that exceed the minimal winning criteria); single party minority government (the party in government does not possess the majority of seats in parliament); multiparty minority government (the parties in government do not possess the majority of seats in parliament); and caretaker government (temporary cabinet). Müller-Rommel, Fettelschoss, and Harfst.
  • 60
    • 85036910351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • World Bank, World Development Indicators (2003); International Labour Office, Yearbook of Labour Statistics (various years).
    • World Bank, World Development Indicators (2003); International Labour Office, Yearbook of Labour Statistics (various years).
  • 61
    • 85036926682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The International Labour Office provides the monthly consumer price index for all ten states in the sample since the transition. The monthly inflation rate is created as the percentage change in CPI from one month to the next. Other states have available data from the following dates: Poland monthly 1/1999-12/2003; Hungary, quarterly 2/1992-11/2003; Czech Republic, monthly 1/1993-12/2003; Slovakia, monthly 1/1993-12/2003; Slovenia, quarterly 5/1997-11/2003; Bulgaria, monthly 3/1992-12/1994 and quarterly 3/2000-12/2003; Romania, monthly 2/1992-12/2003; Estonia, quarterly 2/1997-11/1998 and monthly 1/1999-12/2003; Latvia, monthly 7/1993-12/2003; Lithuania, monthly 1/1994-12/2003.
    • The International Labour Office provides the monthly consumer price index for all ten states in the sample since the transition. The monthly inflation rate is created as the percentage change in CPI from one month to the next. Other states have available data from the following dates: Poland monthly 1/1999-12/2003; Hungary, quarterly 2/1992-11/2003; Czech Republic, monthly 1/1993-12/2003; Slovakia, monthly 1/1993-12/2003; Slovenia, quarterly 5/1997-11/2003; Bulgaria, monthly 3/1992-12/1994 and quarterly 3/2000-12/2003; Romania, monthly 2/1992-12/2003; Estonia, quarterly 2/1997-11/1998 and monthly 1/1999-12/2003; Latvia, monthly 7/1993-12/2003; Lithuania, monthly 1/1994-12/2003.
  • 62
    • 85036950601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The change in unemployment rate from one year to the next is divided by twelve months and then added to each subsequent month's value, creating a linear interpolation
    • The change in unemployment rate from one year to the next is divided by twelve months and then added to each subsequent month's value, creating a linear interpolation.
  • 63
    • 85036922245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Duration modeling provides two principal benefits of handling these probabilities of failure within a duration analysis framework rather than using OLS. First, the OLS estimation technique does not effectively deal with those observations that have yet to experience the event. OLS either excludes the cases that are not completed or treats those observations as having occurred. Both of these approaches are incorrect. Duration analysis produces a better alternative to OLS by treating the observations at the end of the sample as still containing valuable information about the underlying hazard rate. The other principal advantage to using duration analysis is that OLS is unable to deal with the naturally occurring time dependence of a process like government removal. See Christopher Zorn, Modeling Duration Dependence, Political Analysis, 8 2000, 367-80
    • Duration modeling provides two principal benefits of handling these probabilities of failure within a duration analysis framework rather than using OLS. First, the OLS estimation technique does not effectively deal with those observations that have yet to experience the event. OLS either excludes the cases that are not completed or treats those observations as having occurred. Both of these approaches are incorrect. Duration analysis produces a better alternative to OLS by treating the observations at the end of the sample as still containing valuable information about the underlying hazard rate. The other principal advantage to using duration analysis is that OLS is unable to deal with the naturally occurring time dependence of a process like government removal. See Christopher Zorn, "Modeling Duration Dependence," Political Analysis, 8 (2000), 367-80.
  • 64
    • 0031287543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is assumed that the assumption that the probability of removal from office at time t is a function of a list of covariates and of whether that government was in office at time t-1. This assumption leads to the natural conclusion that any omitted variables will lead to autocorrelation, which OLS can not deal with satisfactorily. Alternatively, logit analyses fail because an indicator variable cannot capture the variability in duration time a state spends prior to adoption, precisely the effect we are trying to understand. Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier and Bradford M. Jones, Time Is of the Essence: Event History Models in Political Science, American Journal of Political Science, 41 October 1997, 336-83. This approach causes inefficient estimates with large variances
    • It is assumed that the assumption that the probability of removal from office at time t is a function of a list of covariates and of whether that government was in office at time t-1. This assumption leads to the natural conclusion that any omitted variables will lead to autocorrelation, which OLS can not deal with satisfactorily. Alternatively, logit analyses fail because "an indicator variable cannot capture the variability in duration time a state spends prior to adoption - precisely the effect we are trying to understand." Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier and Bradford M. Jones, "Time Is of the Essence: Event History Models in Political Science," American Journal of Political Science, 41 (October 1997), 336-83. This approach causes inefficient estimates with large variances.
  • 65
    • 84924509217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Specifying the incorrect distribution will cause the inferences regarding the relationship between the covariates and the duration time [to] be misleading since covariate estimates can be sensitive to the distribution function specified. Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier and Bradford S. Jones, Event History Modeling: A Guide for Social Scientists (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004) p. 21.
    • Specifying the incorrect distribution will cause the inferences "regarding the relationship between the covariates and the duration time [to] be misleading since covariate estimates can be sensitive to the distribution function specified." Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier and Bradford S. Jones, Event History Modeling: A Guide for Social Scientists (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004) p. 21.
  • 66
    • 85036942025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The first model is estimated with a number of different specifications of the underlying hazard rate, including the Gompertz, exponential, Weibull, log logistic, and generalized Gamma. The Weibull estimation has both the largest log likelihood and the smallest Akaike Information Criterion (AIC, Further, the parameters from the Gamma model make it possible to test various distributions. The κ parameter is significant at the .000 level, which implies that the null hypothesis that κ= 0 (which is the test of the lognormal distribution) can be rejected. Additional Wald tests show that the null hypothesis that κ=1 (Weibull distribution) can not be rejected but the null hypothesis σ=1 can be rejected. A chi square test of the sigma parameter shows that the null hypothesis σ=1 (with a chi square of 110.92, with one degree of freedom and a p-value of .000) can be rejected. This rules out the exponential model since the null hypothesis κ=1 can not be rejected
    • The first model is estimated with a number of different specifications of the underlying hazard rate, including the Gompertz, exponential, Weibull, log logistic, and generalized Gamma. The Weibull estimation has both the largest log likelihood and the smallest Akaike Information Criterion (AIC). Further, the parameters from the Gamma model make it possible to test various distributions. The κ parameter is significant at the .000 level, which implies that the null hypothesis that κ= 0 (which is the test of the lognormal distribution) can be rejected. Additional Wald tests show that the null hypothesis that κ=1 (Weibull distribution) can not be rejected but the null hypothesis σ=1 can be rejected. A chi square test of the sigma parameter shows that the null hypothesis σ=1 (with a chi square of 110.92, with one degree of freedom and a p-value of .000) can be rejected. This rules out the exponential model since the null hypothesis κ=1 can not be rejected but the null hypothesis σ=1 can be rejected. The Wald test that the κ and σ parameters are equal is also rejected implying that the Gamma distribution is not effective.
  • 67
    • 85036953378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The single party variable includes single party majority goverments; the surplus coalition variable only includes surplus coalitions; the minority variable includes both single party minorities and multiple party minorities; and the caretaker goverment includes only caretaker goverments
    • The single party variable includes single party majority goverments; the surplus coalition variable only includes surplus coalitions; the minority variable includes both single party minorities and multiple party minorities; and the caretaker goverment includes only caretaker goverments.
  • 69
    • 85036930079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Logging the inflation rate removes the unit root and makes the series stationary
    • Logging the inflation rate removes the unit root and makes the series stationary.
  • 70
    • 85036929546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the lack of mass partisanship, see Colton; on electoral volatility, see Tavits; on weak party system institutionalization, see Mainwaring and Torcal; on fractionalized parties, see Moser; on parties without crystallized ideological programs, see Kitschelt, Mansfeldova, Markowski, and Toka
    • On the lack of mass partisanship, see Colton; on electoral volatility, see Tavits; on weak party system institutionalization, see Mainwaring and Torcal; on fractionalized parties, see Moser; on parties without crystallized ideological programs, see Kitschelt, Mansfeldova, Markowski, and Toka.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.