메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 83, Issue 1, 2008, Pages 21-69

Sustainable development and market liberalism's shotgun wedding: Emissions trading under the Kyoto protocol

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 44649087603     PISSN: 00196665     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (29)

References (457)
  • 1
    • 44649168041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ANDREW E. DESSLER & EDWARD A. PARSON, THE SCIENCE AND POLITICS OF GLOBAL CLIMATE CHANGE: A GUIDE TO THE DEBATE 8 (2006) (explaining that greenhouse gases warm the earth by absorbing infrared radiation that would otherwise escape into space).
    • See ANDREW E. DESSLER & EDWARD A. PARSON, THE SCIENCE AND POLITICS OF GLOBAL CLIMATE CHANGE: A GUIDE TO THE DEBATE 8 (2006) (explaining that greenhouse gases warm the earth by absorbing infrared radiation that would otherwise escape into space).
  • 2
    • 44649123456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, opened for signature Dec. 10, 1997, 37 I.L.M. 22 [hereinafter Kyoto Protocol].
    • See Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, opened for signature Dec. 10, 1997, 37 I.L.M. 22 [hereinafter Kyoto Protocol].
  • 3
    • 44649131773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally MICHAEL GRUBB, CHRISTIAAN VROLIJK & DUNCAN BRACK, KYOTO PROTOCOL: A GUIDE AND ASSESSMENT (1999);
    • See generally MICHAEL GRUBB, CHRISTIAAN VROLIJK & DUNCAN BRACK, KYOTO PROTOCOL: A GUIDE AND ASSESSMENT (1999);
  • 4
    • 84922957226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FARHANA YAMIN & JOANNA DEPLEDGE, THE INTERNATIONAL CLIMATE CHANGE REGIME: A GUIDE TO RULES, INSTITUTIONS, AND PROCEDURES (2004).
    • FARHANA YAMIN & JOANNA DEPLEDGE, THE INTERNATIONAL CLIMATE CHANGE REGIME: A GUIDE TO RULES, INSTITUTIONS, AND PROCEDURES (2004).
  • 5
    • 44649131764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kyoto Protocol, note 2, art. 12;
    • See Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, art. 12;
    • supra
  • 6
    • 44649153604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kevin A. Baumert, Note, Participation of Developing Countries in the International Climate Change Regime: Lessons for the Future, 38 GEO. WASH. INT'L L. REV. 365, 383 (2006) (explaining that the Clean Development Mechanism described in article 2 of the Kyoto Protocol allows companies from industrialized countries to. . . receive emission reduction credits from projects based in developing countries.).
    • Kevin A. Baumert, Note, Participation of Developing Countries in the International Climate Change Regime: Lessons for the Future, 38 GEO. WASH. INT'L L. REV. 365, 383 (2006) (explaining that the Clean Development Mechanism described in article 2 of the Kyoto Protocol allows "companies from industrialized countries to. . . receive emission reduction credits from projects based in developing countries.").
  • 7
    • 0001406009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Free Lunch or Cheap Fix?: The Emissions Trading Idea and the Climate Change Convention, 26
    • analyzing the key language in the Kyoto Protocol authorizing trading, In all likelihood, the producer can only substitute credits for some of her reductions, because the Kyoto Protocol requires that trading function as a supplement to domestic reductions. See generally
    • See generally David M. Driesen, Free Lunch or Cheap Fix?: The Emissions Trading Idea and the Climate Change Convention, 26 B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 1,27-35 (1998) (analyzing the key language in the Kyoto Protocol authorizing trading). In all likelihood, the producer can only substitute credits for some of her reductions, because the Kyoto Protocol requires that trading function as a supplement to domestic reductions.
    • (1998) B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 27-35
    • Driesen, D.M.1
  • 8
    • 44649202594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, arts. 6(1)(d), 12(3)(b), 17. For any particular producer, the extent of permissible reliance on foreign credits will depend upon domestic trading rules implementing the Kyoto Protocol's supplementarity requirement.
    • See Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, arts. 6(1)(d), 12(3)(b), 17. For any particular producer, the extent of permissible reliance on foreign credits will depend upon domestic trading rules implementing the Kyoto Protocol's "supplementarity" requirement.
  • 9
    • 44649143678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sharon Long & Giedre Kaminskaite-Salters, The EU ETS - Latest Developments and the Way Forward, 1 CARBON & CLIMATE L. REV. 64, 65 (2007) (pointing out that EU member states are required to set limits on the use of credits from the CDM to conform to the Kyoto Protocol's supplementarity requirement).
    • See Sharon Long & Giedre Kaminskaite-Salters, The EU ETS - Latest Developments and the Way Forward, 1 CARBON & CLIMATE L. REV. 64, 65 (2007) (pointing out that EU member states are required to set limits on the use of credits from the CDM to conform to the Kyoto Protocol's "supplementarity" requirement).
  • 10
    • 44649094989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally PRICEWATERHOUSECOOPERS LTD., CDM PROJECT DESIGN DOCUMENT: PROJECT FOR GHG EMISSION REDUCTION BY THERMAL OXIDATION OF HFC 23 AT HCFC 22 PLANT OF GUJARAT FLUOROCHEMICALS LIMITED (GFL), available at http://cdm.unfccc.int/ UserManagement/FileStorage/ FS_59491890 [hereinafter HFC PDD] (describing installation and operation of a thermal oxidation system to control HFC 23 emissions).
    • See generally PRICEWATERHOUSECOOPERS LTD., CDM PROJECT DESIGN DOCUMENT: PROJECT FOR GHG EMISSION REDUCTION BY THERMAL OXIDATION OF HFC 23 AT HCFC 22 PLANT OF GUJARAT FLUOROCHEMICALS LIMITED (GFL), available at http://cdm.unfccc.int/ UserManagement/FileStorage/ FS_59491890 [hereinafter HFC PDD] (describing installation and operation of a thermal oxidation system to control HFC 23 emissions).
  • 11
    • 44649152125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See National Energy Conservation Policy Act, 42 U.S.C. §15851 2006, stating that renewable energy includes solar, resources
    • See National Energy Conservation Policy Act, 42 U.S.C. §15851 (2006) (stating that renewable energy includes "solar . . . resources.");
  • 12
    • 44649088094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. EPA, STATE AND LOCAL CLIMATE CHANGE PROGRAM, CLIMATE CHANGE TECHNOLOGIES: SOLAR ENERGY 1 (2000), available at http://yosemite.epa.gov/oar/globalwarming.nsf/uniquekeylookup/shsu5bvr3a / $file/solarenergy. pdf (stating that solar energy technologies emit no greenhouse gases during operation);
    • U.S. EPA, STATE AND LOCAL CLIMATE CHANGE PROGRAM, CLIMATE CHANGE TECHNOLOGIES: SOLAR ENERGY 1 (2000), available at http://yosemite.epa.gov/oar/globalwarming.nsf/uniquekeylookup/shsu5bvr3a/ $file/solarenergy. pdf (stating that solar energy technologies emit no greenhouse gases during operation);
  • 13
    • 44649176189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CLIMATE CHANGE 1995 : ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL DIMENSIONS OF CLIMATE CHANGE 241 (James P. Bruce, H. Lee & E.F. Haites eds., 1996) (noting that renewable energy sources emit little carbon and that switching to them reduces emissions);
    • CLIMATE CHANGE 1995 : ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL DIMENSIONS OF CLIMATE CHANGE 241 (James P. Bruce, H. Lee & E.F. Haites eds., 1996) (noting that renewable energy sources emit little carbon and that switching to them reduces emissions);
  • 14
    • 33646698032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 Emissions Trading Directive and the Climate Stewardship Act, 45
    • explaining that renewable energy reduces emissions by avoiding fossil fuel combustion
    • 2 Emissions Trading Directive and the Climate Stewardship Act, 45 NAT. RESOURCES J. 865, 936 (2005) (explaining that renewable energy reduces emissions by avoiding fossil fuel combustion);
    • (2005) NAT. RESOURCES J , vol.865 , pp. 936
    • Choi, I.1
  • 15
    • 0033421923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kirsten H. Engel, The Dormant Commerce Clause Threat to Market-Based Environmental Regulation: The Case of Electricity Deregulation, 26 ECOLOGY L.Q. 243,270 n.73 (1999) (stating that renewable energy produces no carbon emissions).
    • Kirsten H. Engel, The Dormant Commerce Clause Threat to Market-Based Environmental Regulation: The Case of Electricity Deregulation, 26 ECOLOGY L.Q. 243,270 n.73 (1999) (stating that renewable energy produces no carbon emissions).
  • 16
    • 0035372339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Simone Espey, Renewable Portfolio Standard: A Means for Trade With Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources?, 29 ENERGY POL'Y 557, 558 (2001) (explaining that renewable resources are inexhaustible).
    • See generally Simone Espey, Renewable Portfolio Standard: A Means for Trade With Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources?, 29 ENERGY POL'Y 557, 558 (2001) (explaining that renewable resources are "inexhaustible").
  • 17
    • 44649197574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jolene Lin Shuwen, Assessing The Dragon's Choice: The Use of Market-Based Instruments in Chinese Environmental Policy, 16 GEO. INT'L ENVTL. L. REV. 617, 633 (2004) (emissions trading creates incentives for firms to minimize the aggregate costs of producing a given level of environmental quality);
    • See Jolene Lin Shuwen, Assessing The Dragon's Choice: The Use of Market-Based Instruments in Chinese Environmental Policy, 16 GEO. INT'L ENVTL. L. REV. 617, 633 (2004) (emissions trading creates incentives for firms to minimize the aggregate costs of producing a given level of environmental quality);
  • 18
    • 44649163683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas K. Ruppert, Water Quality Trading And Agricultural Nonpoint Source Pollution: An Analysis Of The Effectiveness And Fairness Of EPA's Policy On Water Quality Trading, 15 VILL. ENVTL. L.J. 1,4-5 (2004) (describing trading as encouraging parties with the least cost abatement options to reduce their pollutant loadings). These technological options involve choosing between reductions of two different greenhouse gases. The climate change regime employs scientific assessment of different greenhouse gases' relative contributions to global warming to create trading ratios, measuring the value of all relevant emission reductions in carbon dioxide equivalents.
    • Thomas K. Ruppert, Water Quality Trading And Agricultural Nonpoint Source Pollution: An Analysis Of The Effectiveness And Fairness Of EPA's Policy On Water Quality Trading, 15 VILL. ENVTL. L.J. 1,4-5 (2004) (describing trading as encouraging parties with the least cost abatement options to reduce their pollutant loadings). These technological options involve choosing between reductions of two different greenhouse gases. The climate change regime employs scientific assessment of different greenhouse gases' relative contributions to global warming to create trading ratios, measuring the value of all relevant emission reductions in carbon dioxide equivalents.
  • 19
    • 44649193477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See INTERGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE, WORKING GROUP I, IPCC THIRD ASSESSMENT REPORT: THE SCIENTIFIC BASIS, ch. 6.12.2 (2001), available at http://www.grida.no/ climate/ipcc_tar/wg1/248.htm;
    • See INTERGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE, WORKING GROUP I, IPCC THIRD ASSESSMENT REPORT: THE SCIENTIFIC BASIS, ch. 6.12.2 (2001), available at http://www.grida.no/ climate/ipcc_tar/wg1/248.htm;
  • 20
    • 44649201939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard B. Stewart & Jonathan B. Wiener, The Comprehensive Approach to Global Climate Policy: Issues of Design and Practicability, 9 ARIZ. J. INT'L & COMP. L. 83, 86 (1992).
    • Richard B. Stewart & Jonathan B. Wiener, The Comprehensive Approach to Global Climate Policy: Issues of Design and Practicability, 9 ARIZ. J. INT'L & COMP. L. 83, 86 (1992).
  • 21
    • 0347036769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally James Salzman & J.B. Ruhl, Currencies and the Commodification of Environmental Law, 53 STAN. L. REV. 607 (2000) (explaining that choosing a common currency for environmental benefits trades can prove problematic). For a potent greenhouse gas like HFC 23, a relatively small amount of reduction can generate a carbon benefit (i.e., reduced warming) equal to a relatively large carbon dioxide reduction. For purposes of understanding the text's hypothetical problem, the reader should assume that both technological options deliver the same amount of carbon dioxide equivalents. Also, this Article uses the term carbon in isolation to refer to carbon dioxide equivalents.
    • See generally James Salzman & J.B. Ruhl, Currencies and the Commodification of Environmental Law, 53 STAN. L. REV. 607 (2000) (explaining that choosing a common currency for environmental benefits trades can prove problematic). For a potent greenhouse gas like HFC 23, a relatively small amount of reduction can generate a carbon benefit (i.e., reduced warming) equal to a relatively large carbon dioxide reduction. For purposes of understanding the text's hypothetical problem, the reader should assume that both technological options deliver the same amount of carbon dioxide equivalents. Also, this Article uses the term carbon in isolation to refer to carbon dioxide equivalents.
  • 22
    • 44649192166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See KARAN CAPOOR & PHILIPPE AMBROSI, STATE AND TRENDS OF THE CARBON MARKET 2006 i (2006), available at http://carbonfinance.org/ docs/StateoftheCarbonMarket2006.pdf (characterizing HFC projects as the lowest-cost options and therefore becoming the first asset classes to be systematically tapped globally.);
    • See KARAN CAPOOR & PHILIPPE AMBROSI, STATE AND TRENDS OF THE CARBON MARKET 2006 i (2006), available at http://carbonfinance.org/ docs/StateoftheCarbonMarket2006.pdf (characterizing HFC projects as the "lowest-cost options" and therefore becoming the "first asset classes to be systematically tapped globally.");
  • 23
    • 33645965558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Xingshu Zhao & Axel Michaelowa, CDM Potential for Rural Transition in China Case Study: Options in Yinzhou District, Zhejiang Province, 34 ENERGY POL'Y 1867, 1876 (2006) (finding the initial cost of solar installation high, even though over the long term it is cost competitive).
    • Xingshu Zhao & Axel Michaelowa, CDM Potential for Rural Transition in China Case Study: Options in Yinzhou District, Zhejiang Province, 34 ENERGY POL'Y 1867, 1876 (2006) (finding the initial cost of solar installation high, even though over the long term it is cost competitive).
  • 24
    • 28044463169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sustainable Development and Private Global Governance, 83
    • See
    • See Douglas A. Kysar, Sustainable Development and Private Global Governance, 83 TEX. L. REV. 2109, 2116 (2005).
    • (2005) TEX. L. REV , vol.2109 , pp. 2116
    • Kysar, D.A.1
  • 25
    • 44649144420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See World Comm'n on Env't & Dev., Our Common Future: Report of the World Commission on Environment & Development, at 54, U.N. Doc A/42/427 (Aug. 4, 1987) [hereinafter BRUNDTLAND REPORT] (defining sustainable development as development meeting the current generation's needs without compromising future generations' ability to meet their own needs).
    • See World Comm'n on Env't & Dev., Our Common Future: Report of the World Commission on Environment & Development, at 54, U.N. Doc A/42/427 (Aug. 4, 1987) [hereinafter BRUNDTLAND REPORT] (defining sustainable development as development meeting the current generation's needs without compromising future generations' ability to meet their own needs).
  • 26
    • 44649181954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 3, at, explaining that the CDM encourages private sector project development to seek out the least cost reductions
    • See Baumert, supra note 3, at 384 (explaining that the CDM encourages private sector project development to seek out the least cost reductions);
    • supra , pp. 384
    • Baumert1
  • 27
    • 44649133060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. David M. Driesen, Markets Are Not Magic, ENVTL. F., Nov .-Dec. 2003, at 19 (discussing the tendency to view the free market as a magical solution to environmental problems).
    • cf. David M. Driesen, Markets Are Not Magic, ENVTL. F., Nov .-Dec. 2003, at 19 (discussing the "tendency to view the free market as a magical solution to environmental problems").
  • 28
    • 44649088075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HFC PDD, note 4, at
    • See HFC PDD, supra note 4, at 8.
    • supra , pp. 8
  • 29
    • 44649158106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer, Sept. 16, 1987, S. Treaty Doc. No. 100-10, 1522 U.N.T.S.3,26 I.L.M. 1550;
    • Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer, Sept. 16, 1987, S. Treaty Doc. No. 100-10, 1522 U.N.T.S.3,26 I.L.M. 1550;
  • 30
    • 44649128978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also MENOJ MEHROTA, POSSIBLE ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES TO ASSESSING THE BASELINE SCENARIO FOR DESTRUCTION OF HFC 23 IN THE HCFC 22 INDUSTRY 2 (noting that India has ratified the Montreal Protocol with its London and Beijing Amendments and has passed implementing regulations addressing HCFC 22).
    • see also MENOJ MEHROTA, POSSIBLE ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES TO ASSESSING THE BASELINE SCENARIO FOR DESTRUCTION OF HFC 23 IN THE HCFC 22 INDUSTRY 2 (noting that India has ratified the Montreal Protocol with its London and Beijing Amendments and has passed implementing regulations addressing HCFC 22).
  • 31
    • 44649104920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE OF THE MULTILATERAL FUND FOR THE IMPLEMENTATION OF THE MONTREAL PROTOCOL, COUNTRY PROGRAM UPDATE: INDIA 3 (2006), available at http://www.multilateralfund.org/files/49/4937.pdf (stating that HCFC 22 production has gone up in India even while India has phased out other ozone depleters).
    • But see EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE OF THE MULTILATERAL FUND FOR THE IMPLEMENTATION OF THE MONTREAL PROTOCOL, COUNTRY PROGRAM UPDATE: INDIA 3 (2006), available at http://www.multilateralfund.org/files/49/4937.pdf (stating that HCFC 22 production has gone up in India even while India has phased out other ozone depleters).
  • 32
    • 44649086078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gerard Winn, U.N. Kyoto Chief Judges Climate Change Options, REUTERS, May 30,2006, http://www.sea-user.org/news-detail. php?news_id=1607 (quoting a UN official who criticized the HFC 23 reduction project and stated that the environmental benefits must be clear for future generations.).
    • See Gerard Winn, U.N. Kyoto Chief Judges Climate Change Options, REUTERS, May 30,2006, http://www.sea-user.org/news-detail. php?news_id=1607 (quoting a UN official who criticized the HFC 23 reduction project and stated that "the environmental benefits must be clear for future generations.").
  • 33
    • 44649189624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Technology and Economic Assessment Panel, Special Report: Safeguarding the Ozone Layer and the Global Climate System: Issues Related to Hydroflurocarbons and Perfluorocarbons, at 394-396, U.N.Doc. FCCC/SBSTA/2005/L.8 (May 26, 2005), available at http://arch.rivm.nl/env/int/ipcc/ pages_media/SROC-final/ SpecialReportSROC.html (explaining that HFC-23 emission formation depends upon the HCFC-22 manufacture process, which implies that no reductions can occur once the facilities are shut);
    • See Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Technology and Economic Assessment Panel, Special Report: Safeguarding the Ozone Layer and the Global Climate System: Issues Related to Hydroflurocarbons and Perfluorocarbons, at 394-396, U.N.Doc. FCCC/SBSTA/2005/L.8 (May 26, 2005), available at http://arch.rivm.nl/env/int/ipcc/ pages_media/SROC-final/ SpecialReportSROC.html (explaining that HFC-23 emission formation depends upon the HCFC-22 manufacture process, which implies that no reductions can occur once the facilities are shut);
  • 35
    • 44649196950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. OTHMAR SCHWANK, CONCERNS ABOUT CDM PROJECTS BASED ON DECOMPOSITION OF HFC-23 EMISSIONS FROM HFC-23 EMISSIONS FROM 22 HCFC PRODUCTION SITES 4 (2004, available at http://cdm.unfccc.int/public_inputs/inputam0001/Comment_AM0001_Schwank_0 81004. pdf expressing a concern that approval of CDM credits for emissions associated with HCFC 22 production may create an incentive to delay phasing out this ozone depleting chemical, If one assumes that the carbon credits will create sufficient incentives to keep the HCFC 22 plant open, then the decision to use this option creates a continuing carbon benefit, but creates an ozone depletion cost. Either way, the net societal value of the project may be less than that associated with a project that does not involve an ozone depleting production process
    • Cf. OTHMAR SCHWANK, CONCERNS ABOUT CDM PROJECTS BASED ON DECOMPOSITION OF HFC-23 EMISSIONS FROM HFC-23 EMISSIONS FROM 22 HCFC PRODUCTION SITES 4 (2004), available at http://cdm.unfccc.int/public_inputs/inputam0001/Comment_AM0001_Schwank_081004. pdf (expressing a concern that approval of CDM credits for emissions associated with HCFC 22 production may create an incentive to delay phasing out this ozone depleting chemical). If one assumes that the carbon credits will create sufficient incentives to keep the HCFC 22 plant open, then the decision to use this option creates a continuing carbon benefit, but creates an ozone depletion cost. Either way, the net societal value of the project may be less than that associated with a project that does not involve an ozone depleting production process.
  • 36
    • 44649187276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2).
    • 2).
  • 37
    • 44649084155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RICHARD A. POSNER, CATASTROPHE: RISK AND RESPONSE 15 (2004) (explaining that breakthroughs in solar technology could help enable a substitution of solar energy for fossil fuels at reasonable cost).
    • See RICHARD A. POSNER, CATASTROPHE: RISK AND RESPONSE 15 (2004) (explaining that breakthroughs in solar technology could help enable a substitution of solar energy for fossil fuels at reasonable cost).
  • 38
    • 44649128368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • describing global warming as largely a product of fossil fuel combustion
    • See id. (describing global warming as largely a product of fossil fuel combustion);
    • See id
  • 39
    • 44649202572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard B. Stewart, Economic Incentives for Environmental Protection: Opportunities and Obstacles, in ENVIRONMENTAL LAW, THE ECONOMY, AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT 228 (Richard L. Revesz, Philippe Sands & Richard B. Stewart eds., 2000) (characterizing carbon dioxide as the most important greenhouse gas).
    • Richard B. Stewart, Economic Incentives for Environmental Protection: Opportunities and Obstacles, in ENVIRONMENTAL LAW, THE ECONOMY, AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT 228 (Richard L. Revesz, Philippe Sands & Richard B. Stewart eds., 2000) (characterizing carbon dioxide as "the most important" greenhouse gas).
  • 40
    • 44649169500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. POSNER, supra note 16, at 59 (recognizing that fossil fuel resources are finite, but arguing that they may not be finite relative to human demand because prices will rise when they become scarce).
    • Cf. POSNER, supra note 16, at 59 (recognizing that fossil fuel resources are finite, but arguing that they may not be finite relative to human demand because prices will rise when they become scarce).
  • 41
    • 44649168040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 8, at, discussing the rise of market liberalism and international interest in sustainable development
    • See Kysar, supra note 8, at 2114-18 (discussing the rise of market liberalism and international interest in sustainable development).
    • supra , pp. 2114-2118
    • Kysar1
  • 42
    • 44649112871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Barbara Ann White, Economic Efficiency and the Parameters of Fairness: A Marriage of Marketplace Morals and the Ethic of Care, 15 CORNELL J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 1, 2 (2005) (The great divide among scholars... is between those who advocate for using theories of welfare-maximization derived from the study of market forces and those who urge that fairness ... should predominate ....).
    • Cf. Barbara Ann White, Economic Efficiency and the Parameters of Fairness: A Marriage of Marketplace Morals and the Ethic of Care, 15 CORNELL J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 1, 2 (2005) ("The great divide among scholars... is between those who advocate for using theories of welfare-maximization derived from the study of market forces and those who urge that fairness ... should predominate ....").
  • 43
    • 44649144401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., WILLFRED BECKERMAN, A POVERTY OF REASON : SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH xii (2003) (an economist arguing that the sustainable development ideal is not ethically superior to the economist's goal of maximizing the sum of human welfare over future generations);
    • See, e.g., WILLFRED BECKERMAN, A POVERTY OF REASON : SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH xii (2003) (an economist arguing that the sustainable development ideal is not ethically superior to the "economist's goal of maximizing the sum of human welfare over future generations");
  • 45
    • 44649127794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GEOFFREY HEAL, VALUING THE FUTURE: ECONOMIC THEORY AND SUSTAINABILITY (1998);
    • GEOFFREY HEAL, VALUING THE FUTURE: ECONOMIC THEORY AND SUSTAINABILITY (1998);
  • 46
    • 44649168040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 8, at, describing tensions between market liberalism and sustainable development
    • Kysar, supra note 8, at 2118-47 (describing tensions between market liberalism and sustainable development).
    • supra , pp. 2118-2147
    • Kysar1
  • 47
    • 0347569385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Expanded Debate over the Future of the Regulatory State, 63
    • See
    • See Thomas O. McGarity, The Expanded Debate over the Future of the Regulatory State, 63 U. CHI. L. REV. 1463, 1492 (1996).
    • (1996) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.1463 , pp. 1492
    • McGarity, T.O.1
  • 48
    • 44649168040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 8, at, noting that neoclassical economics does support some regulation
    • See Kysar, supra note 8, at 2120 (noting that neoclassical economics does support some regulation).
    • supra , pp. 2120
    • Kysar1
  • 49
    • 26644444368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Robert W. Hahn & Robert E. Litan, Counting Regulatory Benefits and Costs: Lessons for the US and Europe, 8 J. INT'L ECON. L. 473, 481 (2005) (illustrating CBA approach to regulation);
    • See, e.g., Robert W. Hahn & Robert E. Litan, Counting Regulatory Benefits and Costs: Lessons for the US and Europe, 8 J. INT'L ECON. L. 473, 481 (2005) (illustrating CBA approach to regulation);
  • 50
    • 44649086241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McGarity, supra note 22, at 1491-97 (explaining that free marketeers favor CBA and market-based mechanisms).
    • McGarity, supra note 22, at 1491-97 (explaining that "free marketeers" favor CBA and market-based mechanisms).
  • 51
    • 44649132391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The term neoliberal describes a world view embracing broad reliance on global markets and supporting economic concepts (i.e., the view embracing market liberalism). See Kysar, supra note 8, at 2116.
    • The term neoliberal describes a world view embracing broad reliance on global markets and supporting economic concepts (i.e., the view embracing market liberalism). See Kysar, supra note 8, at 2116.
  • 52
    • 44649140269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2116 (identifying market liberalism with a neoliberal political philosophy and cultural exaltation of the market).
    • See id. at 2116 (identifying market liberalism with a "neoliberal political philosophy" and "cultural exaltation of the market").
  • 53
    • 73949116233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, note 16, at, claiming that economics is both normative and positive
    • See, e.g., POSNER, supra note 16, at 201 (claiming that economics is both normative and positive).
    • supra , pp. 201
    • POSNER1
  • 55
    • 84869670913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fairness v. Welfare, 114
    • Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Fairness v. Welfare, 114 HARV. L. REV. 961, 968 (2001).
    • (2001) HARV. L. REV , vol.961 , pp. 968
    • Kaplow, L.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 56
    • 44649134375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McGarity, supra note 22, at 1484-1513 (contrasting radical anti-interventionists opposing nearly all government regulation with other neoliberal groups that support reformed regulation).
    • See McGarity, supra note 22, at 1484-1513 (contrasting "radical anti-interventionists" opposing nearly all government regulation with other neoliberal groups that support reformed regulation).
  • 57
    • 21944456167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Societal Cost of Environmental Regulation: Beyond Administrative Cost-Benefit Analysis, 24
    • See
    • See David M. Driesen, The Societal Cost of Environmental Regulation: Beyond Administrative Cost-Benefit Analysis, 24 ECOLOGY L.Q. 545, 552-53(1997).
    • (1997) ECOLOGY L.Q , vol.545 , pp. 552-553
    • Driesen, D.M.1
  • 59
    • 44649151560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (explaining that economists support regulating and/or taxing pollution to internalize pollution's cost).
    • See id. (explaining that economists support regulating and/or taxing pollution to internalize pollution's cost).
  • 60
    • 44649132406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 577-78 (explaining the concept of an optimal, i.e., efficient, level of pollution as that where the marginal benefits of control equal the marginal costs).
    • See id. at 577-78 (explaining the concept of an optimal, i.e., efficient, level of pollution as that where the marginal benefits of control equal the marginal costs).
  • 61
    • 44649101740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DAVID M. DRIESEN, THE ECONOMIC DYNAMICS OF ENVIRONMENTAL LAW 1 (2003) (describing the economics-based regulatory reform agenda as including increased use of CBA).
    • See DAVID M. DRIESEN, THE ECONOMIC DYNAMICS OF ENVIRONMENTAL LAW 1 (2003) (describing the "economics-based regulatory reform agenda" as including increased use of CBA).
  • 62
    • 44649203226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Driesen, supra note 30, at 558 (explaining that CBA requires the comparison of pollution control costs with costs consisting of environmental and health effects).
    • See Driesen, supra note 30, at 558 (explaining that CBA requires the comparison of pollution control costs with "costs" consisting of environmental and health effects).
  • 63
    • 44649116931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David M. Driesen, Getting Our Priorities Straight: One Strand of the Regulatory Reform Debate, 31 ENVT'L L. REP. 10003, 10019 n.204 (2001).
    • See David M. Driesen, Getting Our Priorities Straight: One Strand of the Regulatory Reform Debate, 31 ENVT'L L. REP. 10003, 10019 n.204 (2001).
  • 64
    • 44649153355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 30, at, noting the difficulty of quantifying these benefits
    • See Driesen, supra note 30, at 558-59 (noting the difficulty of quantifying these benefits).
    • supra , pp. 558-559
    • Driesen1
  • 65
    • 44649141134 scopus 로고
    • BAUMOL & WALLACE E. OATES, THE THEORY OF ENVIRONMENTAL
    • See
    • See WILLIAM J. BAUMOL & WALLACE E. OATES, THE THEORY OF ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY 23 (1975);
    • (1975) POLICY , vol.23
    • WILLIAM, J.1
  • 66
    • 44649103683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Driesen, supra note 30, at 582-83
    • Driesen, supra note 30, at 582-83.
  • 67
    • 44649188349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THOMAS O. MCGARITY, REINVENTING RATIONALITY: THE ROLE OF REGULATORY ANALYSIS IN THE FEDERAL BUREAUCRACY 5 (1991) (characterizing CBA as supporting comprehensive analytical rationality).
    • See THOMAS O. MCGARITY, REINVENTING RATIONALITY: THE ROLE OF REGULATORY ANALYSIS IN THE FEDERAL BUREAUCRACY 5 (1991) (characterizing CBA as supporting "comprehensive analytical rationality").
  • 68
    • 44649117201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 1 discussing use of economic incentive measures to meet environmental goals as part of the economics-based regulatory reform agenda
    • See DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 1 (discussing use of "economic incentive" measures to meet environmental goals as part of the "economics-based regulatory reform agenda").
  • 69
    • 44649191552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Driesen, supra note 30, at 564-65 explaining the difference between allocatively efficient goal selection and selection of cost-effective means of meeting chosen goals
    • See Driesen, supra note 30, at 564-65 (explaining the difference between allocatively efficient goal selection and selection of cost-effective means of meeting chosen goals).
  • 70
    • 44649157525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David M. Driesen, What is Free Trade: The Real Issue Lurking Behind the Trade and Environment Debate, 41 VA. J. INT'L L. 279, 287-91 (2001) (describing free trade's classical origins and explaining that modern economists employ an allocative efficiency test in thinking about free trade).
    • See David M. Driesen, What is Free Trade: The Real Issue Lurking Behind the Trade and Environment Debate, 41 VA. J. INT'L L. 279, 287-91 (2001) (describing free trade's classical origins and explaining that modern economists "employ an allocative efficiency test" in thinking about free trade).
  • 71
    • 0042715443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jonathan Baert Wiener, Global Environmental Regulation: Instrument Choice in Legal Context, 108 YALE L.J. 677, 748 (1999) (explaining that widening participation in emissions trading to include developing countries reduces abatement costs).
    • See Jonathan Baert Wiener, Global Environmental Regulation: Instrument Choice in Legal Context, 108 YALE L.J. 677, 748 (1999) (explaining that widening participation in emissions trading to include developing countries reduces abatement costs).
  • 72
    • 44649163698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BRUNDTLAND REPORT, supra note 9, at 54. I have not attempted to provide a comprehensive account of sustainable development's elements here, but instead focus on the components most relevant to this Article's thesis.
    • BRUNDTLAND REPORT, supra note 9, at 54. I have not attempted to provide a comprehensive account of sustainable development's elements here, but instead focus on the components most relevant to this Article's thesis.
  • 73
    • 33748335435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally John Martin Gillroy, Adjudication Norms, Dispute Settlement Regimes and International Tribunals: The Status of Environmental Sustainability in International Jurisprudence, 42 STAN. J. INT'L L. 1, 12 (2006) (identifying eight sustainable development sub-principles).
    • See generally John Martin Gillroy, Adjudication Norms, Dispute Settlement Regimes and International Tribunals: The Status of "Environmental Sustainability" in International Jurisprudence, 42 STAN. J. INT'L L. 1, 12 (2006) (identifying eight sustainable development "sub-principles").
  • 74
    • 44649165495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MARIE-CLAIRE CORDONIER SEGGER & ASHFAQ KHALFAN, SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT LAW: PRINCIPLES, PRACTICES, AND PROSPECTS 15 (2004) (discussing sustainable development's origins as a compromise term);
    • MARIE-CLAIRE CORDONIER SEGGER & ASHFAQ KHALFAN, SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT LAW: PRINCIPLES, PRACTICES, AND PROSPECTS 15 (2004) (discussing sustainable development's origins as a " compromise" term);
  • 75
    • 44649101203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PHILIPPE SANDS, PRINCIPLES OF INTERNATIONAL ENVIRONMENTAL LAW 252 (2d ed. 2003) (stating that the term sustainable development now appears regularly in international environmental instruments).
    • PHILIPPE SANDS, PRINCIPLES OF INTERNATIONAL ENVIRONMENTAL LAW 252 (2d ed. 2003) (stating that the term sustainable development now appears regularly in international environmental instruments).
  • 76
    • 44649086862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, BECKERMAN, supra note 21, at xi;
    • See, e.g., BECKERMAN, supra note 21, at xi;
  • 77
    • 44649108725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEGGER & KHALFAN, supra note 45, at 4 (explaining that the vagueness of the sustainable development concept helped it gain universal acceptance, but creates difficulties).
    • SEGGER & KHALFAN, supra note 45, at 4 (explaining that the vagueness of the sustainable development concept helped it gain universal acceptance, but creates "difficulties").
  • 78
    • 44649097392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g, Kysar, supra note 8, at 2118
    • E.g., Kysar, supra note 8, at 2118.
  • 79
    • 44649153374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rio Declaration on Environment and Development, U.N. Conf. on Env't & Dev., principle 4, U.N. Doc. A/CONF.151/6/Rev. 1, 31 I.L.M. 874 (June 16, 1992) (stating that achievement of sustainable development requires the integration of environmental and developmental concerns);
    • See Rio Declaration on Environment and Development, U.N. Conf. on Env't & Dev., principle 4, U.N. Doc. A/CONF.151/6/Rev. 1, 31 I.L.M. 874 (June 16, 1992) (stating that achievement of sustainable development requires the integration of environmental and developmental concerns);
  • 80
    • 44649202574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John C. Dernbach, Sustainable Development: Now More than Ever, in STUMBLING TOWARD SUSTAINABILITY 51-53, 56 (John C. Dernbach ed., 2002);
    • John C. Dernbach, Sustainable Development: Now More than Ever, in STUMBLING TOWARD SUSTAINABILITY 51-53, 56 (John C. Dernbach ed., 2002);
  • 81
    • 44649148172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SANDS, supra note 45, at 263 (discussing integration of environment and development as an element of sustainable development);
    • SANDS, supra note 45, at 263 (discussing integration of environment and development as an "element" of sustainable development);
  • 82
    • 44649154858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SEGGER & KHALFAN, supra note 45, at 3 (explaining that sustainable development seeks to encourage integrated solutions to our most important problems by requiring accommodation between economic development, social justice, and environmental protection . . . . through a process requiring public participation).
    • SEGGER & KHALFAN, supra note 45, at 3 (explaining that sustainable development seeks to encourage integrated solutions to our most important problems by requiring "accommodation between economic development, social justice, and environmental protection . . . . through a process requiring public participation").
  • 83
    • 44649123455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BRUNDTLAND REPORT, supra note 9, at 22
    • BRUNDTLAND REPORT, supra note 9, at 22.
  • 85
    • 44649168040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 8, at, stating that sustainable development proponents favor collective decision making
    • Kysar, supra note 8, at 2147 (stating that sustainable development proponents favor collective decision making).
    • supra , pp. 2147
    • Kysar1
  • 86
    • 33846639563 scopus 로고
    • Reforming Environmental Law, 37
    • explaining that environmental law relies heavily upon uniform standards for industrial categories, See
    • See Bruce A. Ackerman & Richard B. Stewart, Reforming Environmental Law, 37 STAN. L. REV. 1333, 1335 (1985) (explaining that environmental law relies heavily upon uniform standards for industrial categories);
    • (1985) STAN. L. REV , vol.1333 , pp. 1335
    • Ackerman, B.A.1    Stewart, R.B.2
  • 87
    • 44649168644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • e.g, 42 U.S.C. §§ 7411(a, 7412(d, 7521 2000
    • e.g., 42 U.S.C. §§ 7411(a), 7412(d), 7521 (2000).
  • 88
    • 44649117215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see 33 U.S.C. §1312 2000
    • But see 33 U.S.C. §1312 (2000);
  • 89
    • 44649104903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David M. Driesen, Is Emissions Trading an Economic Incentive Program?: Beyond the Command and Control/Economic Incentive Dichotomy, 55 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 289,308 n.93 (1998) (arguing that commentators have exaggerated the extent of the uniform standard approach's use);
    • David M. Driesen, Is Emissions Trading an Economic Incentive Program?: Beyond the Command and Control/Economic Incentive Dichotomy, 55 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 289,308 n.93 (1998) (arguing that commentators have exaggerated the extent of the uniform standard approach's use);
  • 90
    • 44649139023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Driesen, supra note 3, at 36-37 (noting that the Kyoto Protocol does not impose uniform standards upon countries, but explaining why emissions trading increases cost effectiveness anyway).
    • Driesen, supra note 3, at 36-37 (noting that the Kyoto Protocol does not impose uniform standards upon countries, but explaining why emissions trading increases cost effectiveness anyway).
  • 91
    • 44649194266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jason S. Johnston, Tradable Pollution Permits and the Regulatory Game, in MOVING TO MARKETS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION: LESSONS FROM TWENTY YEARS OF EXPERIENCE 358 (Jody Freeman & Charles D. Kolstad eds., 2007) [hereinafter MOVING TO MARKETS] (stating that federal environmental regulations require uniform emission reductions for facilities of the same approximate age in an industry category).
    • See Jason S. Johnston, Tradable Pollution Permits and the Regulatory Game, in MOVING TO MARKETS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION: LESSONS FROM TWENTY YEARS OF EXPERIENCE 358 (Jody Freeman & Charles D. Kolstad eds., 2007) [hereinafter MOVING TO MARKETS] (stating that federal environmental regulations require uniform emission reductions for facilities of the same approximate age in an industry category).
  • 92
    • 44649188957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., id. at 353 ([C]ommand-and-control regulation has been widely decried as inefficient.).
    • E.g., id. at 353 ("[C]ommand-and-control" regulation has been "widely decried as inefficient.").
  • 93
    • 44649084154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unfortunately, regulators rarely have sufficient marginal cost information to tailor regulation to each facility's marginal control cost. Cf. EMISSIONS TRADINGFOR CLIMATE POLICY: U.S. AND EUROPEAN PERSPECTIVES at 3 (Bernd Hansjürgens ed., 2005) [hereinafter EMISSIONS TRADING] (explaining that regulators could tailor standards to each firm's marginal abatement cost, but pointing out the controversial nature of these adjustments).
    • Unfortunately, regulators rarely have sufficient marginal cost information to tailor regulation to each facility's marginal control cost. Cf. EMISSIONS TRADINGFOR CLIMATE POLICY: U.S. AND EUROPEAN PERSPECTIVES at 3 (Bernd Hansjürgens ed., 2005) [hereinafter EMISSIONS TRADING] (explaining that regulators could tailor standards to each firm's marginal abatement cost, but pointing out the controversial nature of these adjustments).
  • 94
    • 44649178446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I use the term traditional regulation to refer to performance standards, which require a particular pollution source to meet a quantitative limit for pollution outputs, and work practice standards, which dictate use of a particular technology or practice. Some writers use the term command and control regulation in the same way. Driesen, supra note 52, at 297 n.44.
    • I use the term "traditional regulation" to refer to performance standards, which require a particular pollution source to meet a quantitative limit for pollution outputs, and work practice standards, which dictate use of a particular technology or practice. Some writers use the term "command and control" regulation in the same way. Driesen, supra note 52, at 297 n.44.
  • 95
    • 44649157522 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I eschew use of this term, because it misleadingly suggests that performance standards dictate technological choices or that work practice standards dominate environmental law. See id. at 296-302.
    • I eschew use of this term, because it misleadingly suggests that performance standards dictate technological choices or that work practice standards dominate environmental law. See id. at 296-302.
  • 96
    • 0027101265 scopus 로고
    • Tradable Emission Permits and the Control of Greenhouse Gases, 28
    • See
    • See Geoffrey Bertram, Tradable Emission Permits and the Control of Greenhouse Gases, 28 J. DEV. STUD. 423, 425 (1992).
    • (1992) J. DEV. STUD , vol.423 , pp. 425
    • Bertram, G.1
  • 97
    • 44649189623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 98
    • 44649103106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 17, at, describing trading as automatically transferring resources from high-cost to low-cost sources
    • Stewart, supra note 17, at 190 (describing trading as automatically transferring resources from high-cost to low-cost sources);
    • supra , pp. 190
    • Stewart1
  • 99
    • 44649089847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Driesen, supra note 3, at 36 (illustrating trading's encouragement of cost-effective reduction shifts with a numerical example).
    • Driesen, supra note 3, at 36 (illustrating trading's encouragement of cost-effective reduction shifts with a numerical example).
  • 100
    • 44649119686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§ 7651-76510 2000
    • 42 U.S.C. §§ 7651-76510 (2000).
    • 42 U.S.C
  • 101
    • 44649101223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jacob Kreutzer, Cap and Trade: A Behavioral Analysis of the Sulfur Dioxide Emissions Market, 62 N.Y.U. ANN. SURV. AM. L. 125, 129 (2006) (calling the cap and trade program a success by any measure);
    • See Jacob Kreutzer, Cap and Trade: A Behavioral Analysis of the Sulfur Dioxide Emissions Market, 62 N.Y.U. ANN. SURV. AM. L. 125, 129 (2006) (calling the cap and trade program "a success by any measure");
  • 102
    • 44649136548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Byron Swift, Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate Standards for Regional Pollutants, 31 ENVTL. L. REP. 10330,10331-32 (2001) (explaining that the acid rain program produced early reductions and cheaper-than-expected costs).
    • Byron Swift, Command Without Control: Why Cap-and-Trade Should Replace Rate Standards for Regional Pollutants, 31 ENVTL. L. REP. 10330,10331-32 (2001) (explaining that the acid rain program produced early reductions and cheaper-than-expected costs).
  • 103
    • 44649136547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Driesen, supra note 52, at 314-17 & n. 131 (reviewing the history of trading prior to 1990).
    • See generally Driesen, supra note 52, at 314-17 & n. 131 (reviewing the history of trading prior to 1990).
  • 104
    • 44649182546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§ 7651c(e, 7651d 2000
    • 42 U.S.C. §§ 7651c(e), 7651d (2000).
    • 42 U.S.C
  • 105
    • 44649152737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §7651bb, 2000
    • 42 U.S.C. §7651b(b) (2000).
    • 42 U.S.C
  • 106
    • 58849157382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 5, at, conceding, context of a fairly critical appraisal, that the acid rain program has achieved its goals
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 890 (conceding, in the context of a fairly critical appraisal, that the acid rain program has achieved its goals);
    • supra , pp. 890
    • Choi1
  • 107
    • 44649123185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 60, at, discussing the reductions and cost savings
    • Swift, supra note 60, at 10331-32 (discussing the reductions and cost savings).
    • supra , pp. 10331-10332
    • Swift1
  • 108
    • 44649171412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 892-94 (claiming that trading has been used frequently in the United States and providing examples). While other emissions trading programs have failed because of monitoring and tracking difficulties, this Article will assume, perhaps unwisely, that the Kyoto trading programs will produce real emission reductions as planned.
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 892-94 (claiming that trading has been used frequently in the United States and providing examples). While other emissions trading programs have failed because of monitoring and tracking difficulties, this Article will assume, perhaps unwisely, that the Kyoto trading programs will produce real emission reductions as planned.
  • 110
    • 44649155525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 8-10 (explaining that carbon dioxide and water vapor are the principal greenhouse gases and that by the 1980s evidence had mounted that temperatures were warming);
    • DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 8-10 (explaining that carbon dioxide and water vapor are the principal greenhouse gases and that by the 1980s evidence had mounted that temperatures were warming);
  • 111
    • 44649103108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zachary Tyler, Massachusetts v. EPA: The D.C. Circuit's Failure to Extend the Clean Air Act to Greenhouse Gas Emissions, 36 ENVTL. L. REP. 10456, 10457 (2006) (explaining the link between fossil fuel combustion and carbon dioxide).
    • Zachary Tyler, Massachusetts v. EPA: The D.C. Circuit's Failure to Extend the Clean Air Act to Greenhouse Gas Emissions, 36 ENVTL. L. REP. 10456, 10457 (2006) (explaining the link between fossil fuel combustion and carbon dioxide).
  • 112
    • 44649139035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GERMAN ADVISORY COUNCIL ON GLOBAL CHANGE, THE FUTURE OCEANS - WARMING UP, RISING HIGH, TURNING SOUR 2 (2006) [hereinafter WBGU] (There are indications that the continental ice sheets on Greenland and in the Antarctic are beginning to disintegrate.).
    • GERMAN ADVISORY COUNCIL ON GLOBAL CHANGE, THE FUTURE OCEANS - WARMING UP, RISING HIGH, TURNING SOUR 2 (2006) [hereinafter WBGU] ("There are indications that the continental ice sheets on Greenland and in the Antarctic are beginning to disintegrate.").
  • 114
    • 44649196316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • INTERGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE, WORKING GROUP I, supra note 6, at 4 (finding that sea levels have risen by four to eight inches over the last 100 years).
    • INTERGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE, WORKING GROUP I, supra note 6, at 4 (finding that sea levels have risen by four to eight inches over the last 100 years).
  • 115
    • 44649183175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WBGU, supra note 66, at 2 (stating that both observed data and mathematical models show that global warming boosts hurricanes' destructive energy);
    • WBGU, supra note 66, at 2 (stating that both "observed data" and "mathematical models" show that global warming boosts hurricanes' "destructive energy");
  • 116
    • 23644453661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kerry Emanuel, Increasing Destructiveness of Tropical Cyclones over the Past 30 Years, 436 NATURE 686 (2005) (showing a correlation between the increased destructiveness of tropical cyclones and average mean surface temperature).
    • Kerry Emanuel, Increasing Destructiveness of Tropical Cyclones over the Past 30 Years, 436 NATURE 686 (2005) (showing a correlation between the increased destructiveness of tropical cyclones and average mean surface temperature).
  • 117
    • 44649139034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • there is [a] good basis
    • See generally, note 1, at, explaining that because the strength of tropical cyclones depends on sea surface temperatures, to expect more intense hurricanes and typhoons
    • See generally DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 83 (explaining that because the strength of tropical cyclones depends on sea surface temperatures, "there is [a] good basis" to expect more intense hurricanes and typhoons).
    • supra , pp. 83
    • DESSLER1    PARSON2
  • 118
    • 44649103105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • INTEGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE, WORKING GROUP II, Vulnerability to Climate Change and Reasons for Concern: A Synthesis, in CLIMATE CHANGE 2001: IMPACTS, ADAPTATION, AND VULNERABILITY ch. 19.3.4.1 (2001), available at http://www.grida.no/climate/ ipcc_tar/wg2/pdf/wg2TARchap19.pdf (discussing the vulnerability of Antigua, the Cook Islands, the Federated States of Micronesia, Kiribati, the Maldives, the Marshall Islands, Nevis, Tonga, and Tuvalu);
    • INTEGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE, WORKING GROUP II, Vulnerability to Climate Change and Reasons for Concern: A Synthesis, in CLIMATE CHANGE 2001: IMPACTS, ADAPTATION, AND VULNERABILITY ch. 19.3.4.1 (2001), available at http://www.grida.no/climate/ ipcc_tar/wg2/pdf/wg2TARchap19.pdf (discussing the vulnerability of Antigua, the Cook Islands, the Federated States of Micronesia, Kiribati, the Maldives, the Marshall Islands, Nevis, Tonga, and Tuvalu);
  • 119
    • 44649170791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WBGU, supra note 66, at 2 (Sea-level rise will lead to inundation of coasts and small island states ....).
    • WBGU, supra note 66, at 2 ("Sea-level rise will lead to inundation of coasts and small island states ....").
  • 120
    • 44649105555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See INTERGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE, CLIMATE CHANGE 2007: THE PHYSICAL SCIENCE BASIS: SUMMARY FOR POLICYMAKERS 7-9 (2007), available at http://www.grida.no/ (discussing links between global climate change and droughts, increased extreme weather, and sea level rise);
    • See INTERGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE, CLIMATE CHANGE 2007: THE PHYSICAL SCIENCE BASIS: SUMMARY FOR POLICYMAKERS 7-9 (2007), available at http://www.grida.no/ (discussing links between global climate change and droughts, increased extreme weather, and sea level rise);
  • 121
    • 84890638058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NICHOLAS STERN, THE ECONOMICS OF CLIMATE CHANGE: THE STERN REVIEW 74 (2007) (discussing the spread of infectious diseases);
    • NICHOLAS STERN, THE ECONOMICS OF CLIMATE CHANGE: THE STERN REVIEW 74 (2007) (discussing the spread of infectious diseases);
  • 122
    • 44649196315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert L. Glicksman, Global Climate Change and the Risks to Coastal Areas from Hurricanes and Rising Sea Levels: The Costs of Doing Nothing, 52 LOY. L. REV. 1127 (2006) (discussing violent weather events and other effects).
    • Robert L. Glicksman, Global Climate Change and the Risks to Coastal Areas from Hurricanes and Rising Sea Levels: The Costs of Doing Nothing, 52 LOY. L. REV. 1127 (2006) (discussing violent weather events and other effects).
  • 123
    • 44649101224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ELIZABETH KOLBERT, FIELD NOTES FROM A CATASTROPHE: MAN, NATURE, AND CLIMATE CHANGE 88 (2006) (reporting biologists' preliminary estimate of species extinction as between 15 percent and 37 percent);
    • ELIZABETH KOLBERT, FIELD NOTES FROM A CATASTROPHE: MAN, NATURE, AND CLIMATE CHANGE 88 (2006) (reporting biologists' preliminary estimate of species extinction as between 15 percent and 37 percent);
  • 124
    • 44649129868 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also IPCC WORKING GROUP II, supra note 69, ch. 19.2.2.2 (discussing elevational shifts in species and earlier timing of reproduction);
    • see also IPCC WORKING GROUP II, supra note 69, ch. 19.2.2.2 (discussing elevational shifts in species and earlier timing of reproduction);
  • 125
    • 44649090463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shari L. Diener, Note, Ratification of Kyoto Aside: How International Law and Market Uncertainty Obviate the Current U.S. Approach to Climate Change Emissions, 47 WM. & MARY L. REV. 2089, 2093 (2006) (discussing studies predicting devastating consequences for polar bears and certain seals).
    • Shari L. Diener, Note, Ratification of Kyoto Aside: How International Law and Market Uncertainty Obviate the Current U.S. Approach to Climate Change Emissions, 47 WM. & MARY L. REV. 2089, 2093 (2006) (discussing studies predicting "devastating consequences" for polar bears and certain seals).
  • 126
    • 44649116265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.N. Conference on Env't & Dev., New York, U.S., May 29, 1992, Framework Convention on Climate Change, U.N. Doc. A/AC.237/18 (1992), 31 I.L.M. 849 [hereinafter FCCC].
    • U.N. Conference on Env't & Dev., New York, U.S., May 29, 1992, Framework Convention on Climate Change, U.N. Doc. A/AC.237/18 (1992), 31 I.L.M. 849 [hereinafter FCCC].
  • 127
    • 0000279934 scopus 로고
    • The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change: A Commentary, 18
    • See generally
    • See generally Daniel Bodansky, The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change: A Commentary, 18 YALE J. INT'L L. 451 (1993).
    • (1993) YALE J. INT'L L , vol.451
    • Bodansky, D.1
  • 128
    • 44649084770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FCCC, note 72, art. 3, para. 4
    • FCCC, supra note 72, art. 3, para. 4.
    • supra
  • 129
    • 44649160449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 3, para. 1.
    • Id. art. 3, para. 1.
  • 130
    • 44649203239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally EDITH BROWN WEISS, IN FAIRNESS TO FUTURE GENERATIONS: INTERNATIONAL LAW, COMMON PATRIMONY, AND INTERGENERATIONAL EQUITY (1989).
    • See generally EDITH BROWN WEISS, IN FAIRNESS TO FUTURE GENERATIONS: INTERNATIONAL LAW, COMMON PATRIMONY, AND INTERGENERATIONAL EQUITY (1989).
  • 131
    • 44649171400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FCCC, note 72, art. 2
    • FCCC, supra note 72, art. 2.
    • supra
  • 132
    • 44649154857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 3, para. 3.
    • Id. art. 3, para. 3.
  • 133
    • 44649151571 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Driesen, supra note 30, at 560-61 & n.67 (pointing out that cost-benefit proponents use the word benefits to describe averted harms).
    • Cf. Driesen, supra note 30, at 560-61 & n.67 (pointing out that cost-benefit proponents use the word "benefits" to describe averted harms).
  • 134
    • 44649152744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SANDS, supra note 45, at 365-66 (linking the joint implementation provision to the Framework Convention's language on cost effectiveness);
    • See SANDS, supra note 45, at 365-66 (linking the joint implementation provision to the Framework Convention's language on cost effectiveness);
  • 135
    • 44649083546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Driesen, supra note 3, at 15-18 (explaining that the language surrounding the cost effectiveness principle seems to qualify it, but that cost effectiveness concerns have tended to dominate debates about implementation of the Climate Change Convention).
    • Driesen, supra note 3, at 15-18 (explaining that the language surrounding the cost effectiveness principle seems to qualify it, but that "cost effectiveness concerns have tended to dominate debates about implementation of the Climate Change Convention").
  • 136
    • 84958676111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 45, at, stating that the United States publicly opposed specific targets and timetables for greenhouse gas emission reductions
    • SANDS, supra note 45, at 360 (stating that the United States publicly opposed specific targets and timetables for greenhouse gas emission reductions);
    • supra , pp. 360
    • SANDS1
  • 137
    • 0030326247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also James E. Beard, Note, An Application of the Principles of Sustainability to the Problem of Global Climate Change: An Argument for Integrated Energy Services, 11 J. ENVTL. L. & LITIG. 191, 203 (1996) (discussing the U.S. effort to defeat a proposal for a twenty percent emissions cut).
    • see also James E. Beard, Note, An Application of the Principles of Sustainability to the Problem of Global Climate Change: An Argument for Integrated Energy Services, 11 J. ENVTL. L. & LITIG. 191, 203 (1996) (discussing the U.S. effort to defeat a proposal for a twenty percent emissions cut).
  • 138
    • 44649182553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Diener, supra note 71, at 2101 (attributing the inclusion of some trading provisions to U.S. pressure).
    • See Diener, supra note 71, at 2101 (attributing the inclusion of some trading provisions to "U.S. pressure").
  • 139
    • 44649106810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SANDS, supra note 45, at 365 (pointing out that the European Union and other countries supported a clear commitment to stabilizing greenhouse gas emissions at 1990 levels).
    • See SANDS, supra note 45, at 365 (pointing out that the European Union and other countries supported a clear commitment to stabilizing greenhouse gas emissions at 1990 levels).
  • 140
    • 44649170780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FCCC, note 72, art. 4, para. 2b, emphasis added
    • FCCC, supra note 72, art. 4, para. 2(b) (emphasis added);
    • supra
  • 141
    • 44649137168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see PRUE TAYLOR, AN ECOLOGICAL APPROACH TO INTERNATIONAL LAW 332 (1998) (describing this compromise as a watering down of obligations achieved through a U.S. threat to boycott the talks).
    • see PRUE TAYLOR, AN ECOLOGICAL APPROACH TO INTERNATIONAL LAW 332 (1998) (describing this compromise as a "watering down of obligations" achieved through a U.S. threat to boycott the talks).
  • 142
    • 44649118455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bodansky, supra note 72, at 515-17 (describing this clause as establishing a quasi-target).
    • See Bodansky, supra note 72, at 515-17 (describing this clause as establishing a "quasi-target").
  • 143
    • 44649190252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Driesen, supra note 3, at 28 (explaining that the joint implementation language suggests authorization of trading, but could also be interpreted as contemplating one country helping another achieve reductions without credit sales).
    • See Driesen, supra note 3, at 28 (explaining that the "joint implementation" language suggests authorization of trading, but could also be interpreted as contemplating one country helping another achieve reductions without credit sales).
  • 144
    • 44649099364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 14 (discussing the Clinton Administration's initial reluctance to accept mandatory emission reductions).
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 14 (discussing the Clinton Administration's initial reluctance to accept mandatory emission reductions).
  • 146
    • 22344445531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Axel Michaelowa & Sonja Butzengeiger, EU Emissions Trading: Navigating Between Scylla and Charybdis, 5 CLIMATE POL'Y 1, 2 (2005) (noting that the EU opposed international trading in the run-up to the Kyoto conference).
    • Axel Michaelowa & Sonja Butzengeiger, EU Emissions Trading: Navigating Between Scylla and Charybdis, 5 CLIMATE POL'Y 1, 2 (2005) (noting that the EU opposed international trading in the "run-up" to the Kyoto conference).
  • 147
    • 44649192845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joby Warrick, Gore Urges Resolution at Climate Talks with Summit in Disarray, Vice President Prods U.S. Negotiators to Bridge Gaps, WASH. POST, Dec. 8, 1998, at A1 (describing the U.S. compromise accepting a seven percent reduction target);
    • Joby Warrick, Gore Urges Resolution at Climate Talks with Summit in Disarray, Vice President Prods U.S. Negotiators to Bridge Gaps, WASH. POST, Dec. 8, 1998, at A1 (describing the U.S. compromise accepting a seven percent reduction target);
  • 148
    • 44649097381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also James H. Searles, Analysis of the Kyoto Protocol to the U.N. Framework Convention on Climate Change, 21 INT'L ENV'T REP. 131,133 (Feb. 4,1998) (stating that the United States demanded emissions trading in exchange for legally binding emissions reductions).
    • see also James H. Searles, Analysis of the Kyoto Protocol to the U.N. Framework Convention on Climate Change, 21 INT'L ENV'T REP. 131,133 (Feb. 4,1998) (stating that the United States demanded emissions trading in exchange for legally binding emissions reductions).
  • 149
    • 44649112245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, art. 3(1) (requiring industrialized countries to reduce their emissions by the amounts assigned in annex B with a view to reducing their overall emissions of such gases by at least 5 per cent below 1990 levels);
    • Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, art. 3(1) (requiring industrialized countries to reduce their emissions by the amounts assigned in annex B "with a view to reducing their overall emissions of such gases by at least 5 per cent below 1990 levels");
  • 150
    • 44649196314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Kyoto Parties End Meetings with Consensus for Avoiding 'Gap' in Post-2012 Reductions, 37 ENVTL. REP. 1154 (2006) ([The Kyoto Protocol] requires 36 industrialized countries ... to collectively reduce carbon dioxide emissions by about 5 percent below 1990 levels . . . .).
    • see also Kyoto Parties End Meetings with Consensus for Avoiding 'Gap' in Post-2012 Reductions, 37 ENVTL. REP. 1154 (2006) ("[The Kyoto Protocol] requires 36 industrialized countries ... to collectively reduce carbon dioxide emissions by about 5 percent below 1990 levels . . . .").
  • 151
    • 44649172029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See LEGAL ASPECTS OF IMPLEMENTING THE KYOTO PROTOCOL MECHANISMS: MAKING KYOTO WORK 175 (David Freestone & Charlotte Streck eds., 2005) [hereinafter KYOTO MECHANISMS] (introducing Joint Implementation, Emissions Trading, and the Clean Development Mechanism as the three market-oriented mechanisms provided for in the Kyoto Protocol);
    • See LEGAL ASPECTS OF IMPLEMENTING THE KYOTO PROTOCOL MECHANISMS: MAKING KYOTO WORK 175 (David Freestone & Charlotte Streck eds., 2005) [hereinafter KYOTO MECHANISMS] (introducing Joint Implementation, Emissions Trading, and the Clean Development Mechanism as the three "market-oriented mechanisms" provided for in the Kyoto Protocol);
  • 152
    • 44649159344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SANDS, supra note 45, at 372 (listing the flexibility mechanisms as emissions trading, joint implementation, and the [Clean Development Mechanism]);
    • SANDS, supra note 45, at 372 (listing the flexibility mechanisms as "emissions trading, joint implementation, and the [Clean Development Mechanism]");
  • 153
    • 44649187277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Stewart, supra note 17, at 238 (interpreting the Kyoto Protocol as providing four different economic incentive systems).
    • cf. Stewart, supra note 17, at 238 (interpreting the Kyoto Protocol as providing four different economic incentive systems).
  • 154
    • 44649136532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, art. 16.
    • Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, art. 16.
  • 155
    • 44649114395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 6
    • Id. art. 6.
  • 156
    • 44649126524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 12
    • Id. art. 12.
  • 157
    • 44649125238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. art. 12(2). The CDM also aims to contribute to achieving the Framework Convention's objective of avoiding dangerous climate change and assisting developed countries in complying with their emission reduction obligations.
    • Id. art. 12(2). The CDM also aims to contribute to achieving the Framework Convention's objective of avoiding dangerous climate change and assisting developed countries in complying with their emission reduction obligations.
  • 158
    • 44649193670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 159
    • 44649159362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally KYOTO MECHANISMS, supra note 90, at 71-104
    • See generally KYOTO MECHANISMS, supra note 90, at 71-104.
  • 162
    • 44649090462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 197, 202 (stating that the Executive Board reviews projects for environmental integrity).
    • Id. at 197, 202 (stating that the Executive Board reviews projects for environmental integrity).
  • 164
    • 44649105554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • George W. Bush, U.S. President, Press Conference at the White House (Mar. 29, 2001), available at
    • George W. Bush, U.S. President, Press Conference at the White House (Mar. 29, 2001), available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/news/releases/2001/03/ 20010329.html (explaining Bush's concerns about cost and the ineffectiveness of the agreement). Congress has also not been forthcoming with U.S. support for international climate change agreements.
  • 165
    • 44649199068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., S. Res. 98,105th Cong. (1997) (enacted) (disapproving of climate change agreements that do not mandate developing country emission reductions and expressing cost concerns).
    • See, e.g., S. Res. 98,105th Cong. (1997) (enacted) (disapproving of climate change agreements that do not mandate developing country emission reductions and expressing cost concerns).
  • 166
    • 44649091757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 1, at, noting that the Kyoto Protocol entered into force on February 16
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 16 (noting that the Kyoto Protocol entered into force on February 16, 2005).
    • (2005) supra , pp. 16
    • DESSLER1    PARSON2
  • 167
    • 44649172291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kirsten H. Engel, Mitigating Global Climate Change in the United States: A Regional Approach, 14 N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. 54, 55 (2005) (noting the absence of the federal government's participation in the Kyoto Protocol);
    • Kirsten H. Engel, Mitigating Global Climate Change in the United States: A Regional Approach, 14 N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. 54, 55 (2005) (noting "the absence of the federal government's participation in the Kyoto Protocol");
  • 168
    • 27844437985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Kirsten H. Engel & Scott R. Saleska, The Subglobal Regulation of the Global Commons: The Case of Climate Change, 32 ECOLOGY L.Q. 183, 186 (2005) (pointing out that the U.S. federal government has eschewed substantive regulation in favor of voluntary reduction efforts and a continuation of scientific research on climate);
    • see also Kirsten H. Engel & Scott R. Saleska, The Subglobal Regulation of the Global Commons: The Case of Climate Change, 32 ECOLOGY L.Q. 183, 186 (2005) (pointing out that the U.S. federal government has "eschewed substantive regulation in favor of voluntary reduction efforts and a continuation of scientific research on climate");
  • 169
    • 44649194281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Gary C. Bryner, Carbon Markets: Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions Through Emissions Trading, 17 TUL. ENVTL. L.J. 267, 273 (2004) (describing the Bush Administration's plan to address climate change without meeting Kyoto targets);
    • cf. Gary C. Bryner, Carbon Markets: Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions Through Emissions Trading, 17 TUL. ENVTL. L.J. 267, 273 (2004) (describing the Bush Administration's plan to address climate change without meeting Kyoto targets);
  • 170
    • 0347600411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deborah Keeth, Note, The California Climate Law: A State's Cutting Edge Efforts to Achieve Clean Air, 30 ECOLOGY L.Q. 715 (2003) (discussing California climate change law).
    • Deborah Keeth, Note, The California Climate Law: A State's Cutting Edge Efforts to Achieve Clean Air, 30 ECOLOGY L.Q. 715 (2003) (discussing California climate change law).
  • 171
    • 44649143656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 952 (stating that the European Emissions Trading Scheme will provide important lessons to the rest of the world, including the United States).
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 952 (stating that the European Emissions Trading Scheme "will provide important lessons to the rest of the world," including the United States).
  • 172
    • 44649161666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michael A. Mehling, Emissions Trading and National Allocation in the Member States - An Achilles ' Heel of European Climate Policy?, 5 Y.B. EUR. ENVTL. L. 113, 118-19 (2005) (describing emissions trading as something [1]argely adopted in response to U.S. pressure).
    • See Michael A. Mehling, Emissions Trading and National Allocation in the Member States - An Achilles ' Heel of European Climate Policy?, 5 Y.B. EUR. ENVTL. L. 113, 118-19 (2005) (describing emissions trading as something "[1]argely adopted in response" to U.S. "pressure").
  • 173
    • 44649137736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 123, 127 (describing the EU decision to adopt trading after notoriously opposing it as a remarkable shift and noting that it moved from proposal to adoption in less than four years).
    • See id. at 123, 127 (describing the EU decision to adopt trading after "notoriously" opposing it as a "remarkable shift" and noting that it moved from proposal to adoption in "less than four years").
  • 174
    • 42949113199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • O.J, L 275, EC
    • Council Directive 2003/87,2003 O.J. (L 275) (EC).
    • (2003) Council Directive , pp. 2003
  • 175
    • 44649099351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Bent O. Mortensen, The EU Emission Trading Directive, 14 EUR. ENVTL. L. REV. 275 (2004) (discussing the directive and how it helps the European Union meet Kyoto Protocol objectives);
    • See generally Bent O. Mortensen, The EU Emission Trading Directive, 14 EUR. ENVTL. L. REV. 275 (2004) (discussing the directive and how it helps the European Union meet Kyoto Protocol objectives);
  • 176
    • 22244444508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rie Watanabe & Guy Robinson, The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme, 5 CLIMATE POL'Y 10 (2005) (explaining the particulars of the scheme).
    • Rie Watanabe & Guy Robinson, The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme, 5 CLIMATE POL'Y 10 (2005) (explaining the particulars of the scheme).
  • 177
    • 44649174195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Council Directive 2004/101, pmbl., 2004 O.J. (L 338) 18 (EC) [hereinafter Linking Directive];
    • Council Directive 2004/101, pmbl., 2004 O.J. (L 338) 18 (EC) [hereinafter Linking Directive];
  • 178
    • 44649120643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Watanabe & Robinson, supra note 105, at 12-13
    • Watanabe & Robinson, supra note 105, at 12-13.
  • 179
    • 44649188348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Linking Directive, supra note 106, at 18
    • Linking Directive, supra note 106, at 18.
  • 180
    • 44649155522 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reimund Schwarze, Incentives to Adopt New Abatement Technology and US-European Regulatory Cultures, in EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 58 (likening the EU to a hesitant bride expecting a baby after the father has left).
    • Reimund Schwarze, Incentives to Adopt New Abatement Technology and US-European Regulatory Cultures, in EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 58 (likening the EU to a hesitant bride expecting a baby after the father has left).
  • 181
    • 44649185433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mehling, supra note 103, at 121-22 (describing legislation on energy efficiency, renewable energy, energy taxation, funding and promotion schemes, voluntary agreements with industry, and monitoring of greenhouse gas emissions as following in the wake of a Europe Commission decision to make climate change a priority in 1992).
    • See Mehling, supra note 103, at 121-22 (describing legislation on energy efficiency, renewable energy, energy taxation, funding and promotion schemes, voluntary agreements with industry, and monitoring of greenhouse gas emissions as following in the wake of a Europe Commission decision to make climate change a priority in 1992).
  • 182
    • 44649097996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commission of the European Communities, Commission Staff Working Document: The Share of Renewable Energy in the EU: Country Profiles: Overview of Renewable Energy Sources in the Enlarged EU, at 3, COM (2004) 366 final (May 26, 2004) (discussing the EU's target of a twelve percent share of renewable energy consumption by 2010);
    • Commission of the European Communities, Commission Staff Working Document: The Share of Renewable Energy in the EU: Country Profiles: Overview of Renewable Energy Sources in the Enlarged EU, at 3, COM (2004) 366 final (May 26, 2004) (discussing the EU's target of a twelve percent share of renewable energy consumption by 2010);
  • 183
    • 44649191562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commission of the European Communities, The Share of Renewable Energy in the EU: Commission Report in Accordance with Article 3 of Directive 2001/77/EC, Evaluation of the Effect of Legislative Instruments and Other Community Policies on the Development of the Contribution of Renewable Energy Resources in the EU and Proposals for Concrete Actions, at 12, COM (2004) 366 final (May 26, 2004) [hereinafter 2004 Commission Energy Evaluation] (discussing an indicative target of twenty-two percent renewable electricity generation by 2010 for the EU fifteen).
    • Commission of the European Communities, The Share of Renewable Energy in the EU: Commission Report in Accordance with Article 3 of Directive 2001/77/EC, Evaluation of the Effect of Legislative Instruments and Other Community Policies on the Development of the Contribution of Renewable Energy Resources in the EU and Proposals for Concrete Actions, at 12, COM (2004) 366 final (May 26, 2004) [hereinafter 2004 Commission Energy Evaluation] (discussing an "indicative target" of twenty-two percent renewable electricity generation by 2010 for the EU fifteen).
  • 184
    • 44649131152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BARRY G. RABE, RACE TO THE TOP: THE EXPANDING ROLE OF U.S. STATE RENEWABLE PORTFOLIO STANDARDS 3-4 (2006) (listing states and countries that have adopted renewable portfolio standards);
    • BARRY G. RABE, RACE TO THE TOP: THE EXPANDING ROLE OF U.S. STATE RENEWABLE PORTFOLIO STANDARDS 3-4 (2006) (listing states and countries that have adopted renewable portfolio standards);
  • 185
    • 33750194934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrew Ford, Klaus Vogstad & Hilary Flynn, Stimulating Price Patterns for Tradable Green Certificates to Promote Electricity Generation from Wind, 35 ENERGY POL'Y 91, 92-94 (2007) (describing state programs and mentioning the European countries employing similar programs);
    • Andrew Ford, Klaus Vogstad & Hilary Flynn, Stimulating Price Patterns for Tradable Green Certificates to Promote Electricity Generation from Wind, 35 ENERGY POL'Y 91, 92-94 (2007) (describing state programs and mentioning the European countries employing similar programs);
  • 186
    • 0348230429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kevin S. Golden, Senate Bill 1078: The Renewable Portfolio Standard-California Asserts its Renewable Energy Leadership, 30 ECOLOGY L.Q. 693, 699 (2003) (describing renewable energy portfolio standards as requirements that retail electricity sellers include a determined percentage of renewable energy sources in their resource portfolios);
    • Kevin S. Golden, Senate Bill 1078: The Renewable Portfolio Standard-California Asserts its Renewable Energy Leadership, 30 ECOLOGY L.Q. 693, 699 (2003) (describing renewable energy portfolio standards as requirements that "retail electricity sellers" include "a determined percentage of renewable energy sources" in their "resource portfolios");
  • 187
    • 44649143013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Commission of the European Communities, Communication from the Commission: The Support of Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources, at 4-5, COM (2005) 627 final [hereinafter Renewables Support] (listing countries employing green certificate systems, which can be a form of renewable portfolio standards);
    • see Commission of the European Communities, Communication from the Commission: The Support of Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources, at 4-5, COM (2005) 627 final [hereinafter Renewables Support] (listing countries employing green certificate systems, which can be a form of renewable portfolio standards);
  • 188
    • 44649093112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Espey, supra note 5, at 560 (explaining that the term renewable portfolio standard comes from U.S. practice, but that other countries employ different names to describe similar programs).
    • Espey, supra note 5, at 560 (explaining that the term renewable portfolio standard comes from U.S. practice, but that other countries employ different names to describe similar programs).
  • 189
    • 44649151570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally NANCY RADER& SCOTT HEMPLING, THE RENEWABLES PORTFOLIO STANDARD: A PRACTICAL GUIDE (2001) (discussing how decision makers can use renewable portfolio standards to achieve policy goals).
    • See generally NANCY RADER& SCOTT HEMPLING, THE RENEWABLES PORTFOLIO STANDARD: A PRACTICAL GUIDE (2001) (discussing how decision makers can use renewable portfolio standards to achieve policy goals).
  • 190
    • 44649178442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N.H. VAN DER LINDEN, M.A. UYTERLINDE, C. VROLIJK, L.J. NILSSON, J. KHAN, K. ÅSTRAND, K. ERICSSON & R. WISER, REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL EXPERIENCE WITH RENEWABLE ENERGY OBLIGATIONS SUPPORT MECHANISMS 49 (2005) (noting that suppliers usually purchase tradable renewable energy credits from suppliers of renewable energy in order to meet their own compliance obligations);
    • N.H. VAN DER LINDEN, M.A. UYTERLINDE, C. VROLIJK, L.J. NILSSON, J. KHAN, K. ÅSTRAND, K. ERICSSON & R. WISER, REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL EXPERIENCE WITH RENEWABLE ENERGY OBLIGATIONS SUPPORT MECHANISMS 49 (2005) (noting that suppliers usually purchase tradable renewable energy credits from suppliers of renewable energy in order to meet their own compliance obligations);
  • 191
    • 44649145020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RYAN WISER & OLE LANGNISS, THE RENEWABLES PORTFOLIO STANDARD IN TEXAS: AN EARLY ASSESSMENT 15 (2001), http://www.rff.org/Documents/RFFRPT-Renewables.pdf (stating that certificate trades may not be essential to effective design of a renewable portfolio standard);
    • RYAN WISER & OLE LANGNISS, THE RENEWABLES PORTFOLIO STANDARD IN TEXAS: AN EARLY ASSESSMENT 15 (2001), http://www.rff.org/Documents/RFFRPT-Renewables.pdf (stating that certificate trades "may not be essential to effective design" of a renewable portfolio standard);
  • 192
    • 44649161680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Engel, supra note 5, at 268 n.72 (noting that only one state, Arizona, currently uses tradable renewable power credits);
    • Engel, supra note 5, at 268 n.72 (noting that only one state, Arizona, currently uses tradable renewable power credits);
  • 193
    • 44649133716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Espey, supra note 5, at 557 (describing certificates as a means of proving compliance with a renewable portfolio standard);
    • Espey, supra note 5, at 557 (describing "certificates" as a means of proving compliance with a renewable portfolio standard);
  • 194
    • 44649083544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ford et al., supra note 111, at 94 (characterizing tradable green certificates markets as quite new);
    • Ford et al., supra note 111, at 94 (characterizing tradable green certificates markets as "quite new");
  • 195
    • 44649093733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Golden, supra note 111, at 699-700. Espey further explains that because a utility can acquire a certificate without acquiring the underlying power, the certificate system allows a utility to participate in financing renewable energy without acquiring a production facility or obtaining the renewable power.
    • Golden, supra note 111, at 699-700. Espey further explains that because a utility can acquire a certificate without acquiring the underlying power, the certificate system allows a utility to participate in financing renewable energy without acquiring a production facility or obtaining the renewable power.
  • 196
    • 44649154256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 5, at, This separation can both simplify enforcement and provide flexibility for those complying with a renewables portfolio obligation
    • Espey, supra note 5, at 560. This separation can both simplify enforcement and provide flexibility for those complying with a renewables portfolio obligation.
    • supra , pp. 560
    • Espey1
  • 197
    • 44649167432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally RADER & HEMPLING, supra note 111, at 55-71 (discussing trading's potential uses). While the green certificates have a number of advantages, the evidence suggests that the quotas themselves, not the trading, have spurred the technological development.
    • See generally RADER & HEMPLING, supra note 111, at 55-71 (discussing trading's potential uses). While the green certificates have a number of advantages, the evidence suggests that the quotas themselves, not the trading, have spurred the technological development.
  • 198
    • 44649084151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • noting that most EU member states employ feed-in tariffs, at
    • Renewables Support, supra note 111, at 4 (noting that most EU member states employ feed-in tariffs);
    • Renewables Support, supra note , vol.111 , pp. 4
  • 199
    • 44649095503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ford et al., supra note 111, at 94 n. 12;
    • Ford et al., supra note 111, at 94 n. 12;
  • 200
    • 44649128988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • discussing feed-in tariffs' use in several European countries, Feed-in tariffs constitute a subsidy and as such bear some similarity to the Federal Production Tax Credit. see also
    • see also KAREN PALMER & DALLAS BURTRAW, ELECTRICITY, RENEWABLES, AND CLIMATE CHANGE: SEARCHING FOR A COST- EFFECTIVE POLICY 8-9 (2004), http://www.rff.org/Documents/RFF- RPT-Renewables.pdf (discussing feed-in tariffs' use in several European countries). Feed-in tariffs constitute a subsidy and as such bear some similarity to the Federal Production Tax Credit.
    • (2004) POLICY , vol.8-9
    • PALMER, K.1    BURTRAW, D.2
  • 201
    • 44649115000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RENEWABLE ENERGY CERTIFICATES SYSTEM INTERNATIONAL, THE USE OF GUARANTEE OF ORIGIN 24-25 (2005), http://www.recs.org/doctree/RECS%20Intemational/ 05%20Evaluation %20Report.pdf (explaining that a fixed feed-in tariff introduces a market distortion).
    • RENEWABLE ENERGY CERTIFICATES SYSTEM INTERNATIONAL, THE USE OF GUARANTEE OF ORIGIN 24-25 (2005), http://www.recs.org/doctree/RECS%20Intemational/ 05%20Evaluation %20Report.pdf (explaining that a fixed feed-in tariff introduces a "market distortion").
  • 202
    • 84869288999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 113, at, discussing state subsidies and funded by a surcharge on electricity purchases and federal renewable energy production tax credits
    • See PALMER & BURTRAW, supra note 113, at 3 (discussing state subsidies and funded by a surcharge on electricity purchases and federal renewable energy production tax credits);
    • supra , pp. 3
    • PALMER1    BURTRAW2
  • 203
    • 44649150044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 112, at, discussing feed-in tariffs, a tendering system with government contracts for renewable power, financial incentives, and tax incentives
    • VAN DER LINDEN ET AL., supra note 112, at 11-12 (discussing feed-in tariffs, a tendering system with government contracts for renewable power, financial incentives, and tax incentives);
    • supra , pp. 11-12
    • DER LINDEN, V.A.N.1    AL, E.T.2
  • 204
    • 0037210509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lene Nielsen & Tim Jeppesen, Tradable Green Certificates in Selected European Countries-Overview and Assessment, 31 ENERGY POL'Y 3, 5 (2003) (noting that all countries planning green certificate programs except the Netherlands envisage . . . politically determined demand).
    • Lene Nielsen & Tim Jeppesen, Tradable Green Certificates in Selected European Countries-Overview and Assessment, 31 ENERGY POL'Y 3, 5 (2003) (noting that all countries planning green certificate programs except the Netherlands "envisage . . . politically determined demand").
  • 205
    • 44649135900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Wiener, supra note 43, at 706-713 (developing the distinction between price and quantity instruments with examples).
    • See generally Wiener, supra note 43, at 706-713 (developing the distinction between price and quantity instruments with examples).
  • 206
    • 44649170161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commission Proposal for a Council Directive on Passenger Car Related Taxes, at 7-8, COM (2005) 261 final (July 5, 2005), available at http://ec.europa.eu/environment/co2/pdf/ taxation_com_2005_261 .pdf.
    • Commission Proposal for a Council Directive on Passenger Car Related Taxes, at 7-8, COM (2005) 261 final (July 5, 2005), available at http://ec.europa.eu/environment/co2/pdf/ taxation_com_2005_261 .pdf.
  • 207
    • 44649154853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 896-97 (discussing green taxes in the European energy sector);
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 896-97 (discussing "green taxes" in the European energy sector);
  • 208
    • 44649189622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David M. Driesen, Economic Instruments for Sustainable Development, in ENVIRONMENTAL LAW FOR SUSTAINABILITY: A READER 295 (Stepan Wood & Benjamin J. Richardson eds., 2006) (discussing taxes touted as carbon taxes in several European countries).
    • David M. Driesen, Economic Instruments for Sustainable Development, in ENVIRONMENTAL LAW FOR SUSTAINABILITY: A READER 295 (Stepan Wood & Benjamin J. Richardson eds., 2006) (discussing taxes touted as carbon taxes in several European countries).
  • 209
    • 44649105553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Engel, supra note 101, at 54 (describing state and local government as taking the lead in addressing global climate change);
    • Engel, supra note 101, at 54 (describing state and local government as "taking the lead in addressing global climate change");
  • 210
    • 44649144418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Engel & Saleska, supra note 101, at 184-86 (stating that at least half the states have passed legislation addressing global wanning).
    • Engel & Saleska, supra note 101, at 184-86 (stating that "at least half the states" have passed legislation addressing global wanning).
  • 211
    • 44649187293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally BARRY G. RABE, STATEHOUSE AND GREENHOUSE: THE EMERGING POLITICS OF AMERICAN CLIMATE CHANGE POLICY (2004).
    • See generally BARRY G. RABE, STATEHOUSE AND GREENHOUSE: THE EMERGING POLITICS OF AMERICAN CLIMATE CHANGE POLICY (2004).
  • 212
    • 38749108733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 101, at, discussing various regional initiatives
    • Engel, supra note 101, at 65-68 (discussing various regional initiatives);
    • supra , pp. 65-68
    • Engel1
  • 213
    • 38749108733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 101, at, discussing vehicle emissions standards and renewable energy programs
    • Engel & Saleska, supra note 101, at 212-13 (discussing vehicle emissions standards and renewable energy programs).
    • supra , pp. 212-213
    • Engel1    Saleska2
  • 214
    • 44649086882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David M. Driesen, The Changing Climate for United States Law, 1 CARBON & CLIMATE L. REV. 35,36 (2007) (stating that a number of bills pending in Congress... use the emissions trading approach);
    • See David M. Driesen, The Changing Climate for United States Law, 1 CARBON & CLIMATE L. REV. 35,36 (2007) (stating that "a number of bills pending in Congress... use the emissions trading approach");
  • 215
    • 44649098706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • .see, e.g., Climate Stewardship and Innovation Act of 2007, S. 280, 110th Cong. (2007); S. 3698, 109th Cong. (2006).
    • .see, e.g., Climate Stewardship and Innovation Act of 2007, S. 280, 110th Cong. (2007); S. 3698, 109th Cong. (2006).
  • 216
    • 44649201953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CAPOOR & AMBROSI, supra note 7, at 33 stating that fifty-one percent of the projects generating transactions have involved energy efficiency or renewable energy
    • CAPOOR & AMBROSI, supra note 7, at 33 (stating that fifty-one percent of the projects generating transactions have involved energy efficiency or renewable energy).
  • 217
    • 33846924315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is the Global Carbon Market Working?, 445
    • showing that waste gas projects account for the majority of credits claimed for projects in the pipeline
    • Michael Wara, Is the Global Carbon Market Working?, 445 NATURE 595, 596 (2007) (showing that waste gas projects account for the majority of credits claimed for projects "in the pipeline");
    • (2007) NATURE , vol.595 , pp. 596
    • Wara, M.1
  • 218
    • 44649124051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Baumert, supra note 3, at 386 (noting that gas capture/destruction projects account for sixty-six percent of expected emissions reduction credits).
    • Baumert, supra note 3, at 386 (noting that "gas capture/destruction projects" account for "sixty-six percent of expected emissions reduction credits").
  • 219
    • 44649137167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robin Lancaster, Beyond All Expectation, CARBON FIN., May 2006, at 15 (stating that HFC23 reductions accounted for fifty-eight percent of the market between January 2005 and March 2006);
    • Robin Lancaster, Beyond All Expectation, CARBON FIN., May 2006, at 15 (stating that HFC23 reductions accounted for fifty-eight percent of the market volume between January 2005 and March 2006);
  • 221
    • 44649134372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joergen Fenhann, UNEP Risoe Center: CDM/JI Pipeline: Analysis and Database: CDM Pipeline Overview (July 2007), http://cdmpipeline.org/ publications/CDMpipeline.xls [hereinafter Fenhann CDM Pipeline];
    • Joergen Fenhann, UNEP Risoe Center: CDM/JI Pipeline: Analysis and Database: CDM Pipeline Overview (July 2007), http://cdmpipeline.org/ publications/CDMpipeline.xls [hereinafter Fenhann CDM Pipeline];
  • 222
    • 44649124665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also UNEP RISOE CENTER: GUIDANCE TO THE CDM/JI 1 (2006), http://cdmpipeline.org/publications/ GuidanceCDMpipeline.pdf [hereinafter CDM/JI GUIDE] (explaining that data comes from the UNFCC homepage located at http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html, and also that project design documents are also available there).
    • see also UNEP RISOE CENTER: GUIDANCE TO THE CDM/JI 1 (2006), http://cdmpipeline.org/publications/ GuidanceCDMpipeline.pdf [hereinafter CDM/JI GUIDE] (explaining that data comes from the UNFCC homepage located at http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html, and also that project design documents are also available there).
  • 223
    • 44649176187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fenhann CDM Pipeline, supra note 124, at tbl.10 (providing analysis of all CDM/JI projects in the pipeline). The other category in this chart and the subsequent JI chart denotes technologies that are not known to involve end-of-the-pipe, renewable efficiency, or energy efficiency technologies. The other category includes some projects that might be properly viewed as end-of-the-pipe projects, so that the percentage of end-of-the-pipe credits may be understated. The finding that renewables projects generate only a modest percentage of the total credits is broadly consistent with other analysts' conclusions.
    • Fenhann CDM Pipeline, supra note 124, at tbl.10 (providing analysis of all CDM/JI projects in the pipeline). The "other" category in this chart and the subsequent JI chart denotes technologies that are not known to involve end-of-the-pipe, renewable efficiency, or energy efficiency technologies. The "other" category includes some projects that might be properly viewed as end-of-the-pipe projects, so that the percentage of end-of-the-pipe credits may be understated. The finding that renewables projects generate only a modest percentage of the total credits is broadly consistent with other analysts' conclusions.
  • 224
    • 44649100602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lars Friberg, Gudrun Benecke & Miriam Schröder, KyotoPlus - Papers: The Role of the Clean Development Mechanism - Now and in the Future 11 (KyotoPlus - Escaping the Climate Trap 2006), http://www.sfbgovernance.de/ teilprojekte/projektbereich_d/d3/friberg_etal.pdf (noting that renewables have seen a recent increase only because developers are beginning to run out of viable end-of-the-pipe projects);
    • Lars Friberg, Gudrun Benecke & Miriam Schröder, KyotoPlus - Papers: The Role of the Clean Development Mechanism - Now and in the Future 11 (KyotoPlus - Escaping the Climate Trap 2006), http://www.sfbgovernance.de/ teilprojekte/projektbereich_d/d3/friberg_etal.pdf (noting that renewables have seen a recent increase only because developers are beginning to run out of viable end-of-the-pipe projects);
  • 225
    • 44649114394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • e.g., Michael Wara, Measuring the Clean Development Mechanism's Performance and Potential 23 (The Program on Energy and Sustainable Dev. at Stan. Univ., Working Paper No. 56, 2006), available at http://iis-db.stanford.edu/pubs/21211/Wara_CDM.pdf (stating that renewables have generated eighteen percent of the total credits).
    • e.g., Michael Wara, Measuring the Clean Development Mechanism's Performance and Potential 23 (The Program on Energy and Sustainable Dev. at Stan. Univ., Working Paper No. 56, 2006), available at http://iis-db.stanford.edu/pubs/21211/Wara_CDM.pdf (stating that renewables have generated eighteen percent of the total credits).
  • 226
    • 44649172290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lucy Mortimer, An unCERtain Path?, CARBON FIN., Apr. 2006, at 14, available at http://www.carbon-financeonline.com (noting that many projects may not make it through the registration process because of financial problems, methodological problems, and uncertainty about the post-2012 carbon market);
    • Lucy Mortimer, An unCERtain Path?, CARBON FIN., Apr. 2006, at 14, available at http://www.carbon-financeonline.com (noting that many projects may not make it through the registration process because of financial problems, methodological problems, and uncertainty about the post-2012 carbon market);
  • 227
    • 33947303655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ben Pearson, Market Failure: Why the Clean Development Mechanism Won't Promote Clean Development, 15 J. CLEANER PROD. 247, 248 (2007) (noting that many renewables projects may not meet the Kyoto Protocol's additionality criterion). Similarly, the smaller joint implementation mechanism pipeline's renewable energy credits constitute about nineteen percent of total projected credits.
    • Ben Pearson, Market Failure: Why the Clean Development Mechanism Won't Promote Clean Development, 15 J. CLEANER PROD. 247, 248 (2007) (noting that many renewables projects may not meet the Kyoto Protocol's "additionality" criterion). Similarly, the smaller joint implementation mechanism pipeline's renewable energy credits constitute about nineteen percent of total projected credits.
  • 228
    • 44649196960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KARAN CAPOOR & PHILIPPE AMBROSI, STATE AND TRENDS OF THE CARBON MARKET 2007 28 (2007), http://carbonfinance.org/docs/Carbon_Trends_2007-_FINAL_-_May_2.pdf;
    • KARAN CAPOOR & PHILIPPE AMBROSI, STATE AND TRENDS OF THE CARBON MARKET 2007 28 (2007), http://carbonfinance.org/docs/Carbon_Trends_2007-_FINAL_-_May_2.pdf;
  • 229
    • 44649091754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fenhann CDM Pipeline, supra note 124, at tbl.10 (showing that projected renewable energy credits will reach twenty-five percent in 2012). Furthermore, renewables project developers may face greater risks of having their projects' emission credits disapproved or reduced than developers of cheaper projects.
    • Fenhann CDM Pipeline, supra note 124, at tbl.10 (showing that projected renewable energy credits will reach twenty-five percent in 2012). Furthermore, renewables project developers may face greater risks of having their projects' emission credits disapproved or reduced than developers of cheaper projects.
  • 230
    • 44649105547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JANE ELLIS & SAMI KAMEL, OVERCOMING BARRIERS TO CLEAN DEVELOPMENT MECHANISM PROJECTS 10 (2007), http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/51/ 14/38684304.pdf;
    • JANE ELLIS & SAMI KAMEL, OVERCOMING BARRIERS TO CLEAN DEVELOPMENT MECHANISM PROJECTS 10 (2007), http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/51/ 14/38684304.pdf;
  • 231
    • 44649103705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joergen Fenhann, UNEP Risoe CDM/JI Pipeline: Analysis and Database: JI Pipeline Overview (July 2007), http://cdmpipeline.org/publications/JIpipeline. xls. Conversely, analysts expect end-ofthe-pipe control's share of future project credits to decline to about forty percent of the total.
    • Joergen Fenhann, UNEP Risoe CDM/JI Pipeline: Analysis and Database: JI Pipeline Overview (July 2007), http://cdmpipeline.org/publications/JIpipeline. xls. Conversely, analysts expect end-ofthe-pipe control's share of future project credits to decline to about forty percent of the total.
  • 232
    • 44649102426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., JIM VALLETTE, DAPHNE WYSHAM & NADIA MARTÍNEZ, A WRONG TURN FROM RIO: THE WORLD BANK'S ROAD TO CLIMATE CATASTROPHE 9-10 (2004), http://www.seen.org/ PDFs/ Wrong_turn_Rio.pdf (describing these projects and their effects).
    • E.g., JIM VALLETTE, DAPHNE WYSHAM & NADIA MARTÍNEZ, A WRONG TURN FROM RIO: THE WORLD BANK'S ROAD TO CLIMATE CATASTROPHE 9-10 (2004), http://www.seen.org/ PDFs/ Wrong_turn_Rio.pdf (describing these projects and their effects).
  • 233
    • 44649159360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contra The World Bank Carbon Finance Unit, Brazil: Plantar Sequestration and Biomass Use (2006), http://carbon finance.org/Router.cfm?Page= Projport&ProjID=9600#DocsList (suggesting that the Plantar project will lessen ecological destruction). The point here is not to determine who is right about project disputes, but simply to characterize the types of concerns that come up in public comment processes on CDM projects.
    • Contra The World Bank Carbon Finance Unit, Brazil: Plantar Sequestration and Biomass Use (2006), http://carbon finance.org/Router.cfm?Page= Projport&ProjID=9600#DocsList (suggesting that the Plantar project will lessen ecological destruction). The point here is not to determine who is right about project disputes, but simply to characterize the types of concerns that come up in public comment processes on CDM projects.
  • 234
    • 44649127813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., CDM WATCH, THE WORLD BANK AND THE CARBON MARKET: RHETORIC AND REALITY,23-25, available at http://www.cdmwatch.org/files/ World%20Bank%20paper%20final.pdf, at (describing the reasons for rejection of some CDM projects).
    • See, e.g., CDM WATCH, THE WORLD BANK AND THE CARBON MARKET: RHETORIC AND REALITY,23-25, available at http://www.cdmwatch.org/files/ World%20Bank%20paper%20final.pdf, at (describing the reasons for rejection of some CDM projects).
  • 235
    • 44649099363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David M. Driesen, Air Pollution, in STUMBLING TOWARD SUSTAINABILITY, supra note 48, at 257-61 (discussing Agenda 21's provisions favoring renewable energy and energy efficiency as part of sustainable development);
    • David M. Driesen, Air Pollution, in STUMBLING TOWARD SUSTAINABILITY, supra note 48, at 257-61 (discussing Agenda 21's provisions favoring renewable energy and energy efficiency as part of sustainable development);
  • 236
    • 44649111662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. U.N. Conference on Env't & Dev., Rio de Janerio, Brazil, June 3-14, 1992, Agenda 21, 9.9, U.N. Doc. A/CONF.151/26 (calling for a greater need to rely on renewable energy sources).
    • cf. U.N. Conference on Env't & Dev., Rio de Janerio, Brazil, June 3-14, 1992, Agenda 21, 9.9, U.N. Doc. A/CONF.151/26 (calling for a greater need to rely on renewable energy sources).
  • 237
    • 44649193491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of Credits and Quotas: Federal Tax Incentives for Renewable Resources, State Renewable Portfolio Standards, and the Evolution of Proposals fora Federal Renewable Portfolio Standard, 15
    • explaining that a federal requirement that electric utilities purchase power from renewable energy sources played an important role in expanding renewable power generation
    • James W. Moeller, Of Credits and Quotas: Federal Tax Incentives for Renewable Resources, State Renewable Portfolio Standards, and the Evolution of Proposals fora Federal Renewable Portfolio Standard, 15 FORDHAM ENVTL. L.J. 69, 73-77 (2004) (explaining that a federal requirement that electric utilities purchase power from renewable energy sources played an important role in expanding renewable power generation);
    • (2004) FORDHAM ENVTL. L.J , vol.69 , pp. 73-77
    • Moeller, J.W.1
  • 238
    • 44649170160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • e.g, VAN DER LINDEN ET AL, supra note 112, at 38 suggesting that a number of policy instruments have contributed to increased renewable energy production in Sweden
    • e.g., VAN DER LINDEN ET AL., supra note 112, at 38 (suggesting that a number of policy instruments have contributed to increased renewable energy production in Sweden).
  • 239
    • 44649139665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contra Choi, supra note 5, at 891 n.86 (claiming that the acid rain program has discouraged use of renewable energy, in spite of the establishment of reserve allowances to provide incentives to use it).
    • Contra Choi, supra note 5, at 891 n.86 (claiming that the acid rain program has discouraged use of renewable energy, in spite of the establishment of reserve allowances to provide incentives to use it).
  • 240
    • 44649092472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2004 Commission Energy Evaluation, supra note 110, at 19 (noting that wind power grew by twenty-three percent in 2003, exceeding the EU's wind target);
    • 2004 Commission Energy Evaluation, supra note 110, at 19 (noting that wind power grew by twenty-three percent in 2003, exceeding the EU's wind target);
  • 241
    • 44649188345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ford et al., supra note 111, at 92 n.4 (explaining that the Texas renewable portfolio standard produced the Texas Wind Rush, the installation often new wind projects in 2001 producing 930 megawatts of power);
    • Ford et al., supra note 111, at 92 n.4 (explaining that the Texas renewable portfolio standard produced the "Texas Wind Rush," the installation often new wind projects in 2001 producing 930 megawatts of power);
  • 242
    • 33646479340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Frederic C. Menz & Stephan Vachon, The Effectiveness of Different Policy Regimes for Promoting Wind Power: Experiences from the States, 34 ENERGY POL'Y 1786 (2006) (finding that renewable portfolio standards have stimulated increased production of wind power).
    • Frederic C. Menz & Stephan Vachon, The Effectiveness of Different Policy Regimes for Promoting Wind Power: Experiences from the States, 34 ENERGY POL'Y 1786 (2006) (finding that renewable portfolio standards have stimulated increased production of wind power).
  • 243
    • 44649148189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 110, at, finding that wind costs have fallen by fifty percent over the last fifteen years
    • 2004 Commission Energy Evaluation, supra note 110, at 19 (finding that wind costs have fallen by fifty percent over the last fifteen years);
    • 2004 Commission Energy Evaluation, supra , pp. 19
  • 244
    • 33845264801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jeffrey Greenblatt, Samir Succar, David C. Denkenberger, Robert H. Williams & Robert H. Socolow, Baseload Wind Energy: Modeling the Competition Between Gas Turbines and Compressed Air Energy Storage for Supplemental Generation, 35 ENERGY POL'Y1474,1474 (2007) (attributing a thirty percent annual increase in installed wind capacity to a twofold drop in capital costs between 1992 and 2001 and government initiatives).
    • Jeffrey Greenblatt, Samir Succar, David C. Denkenberger, Robert H. Williams & Robert H. Socolow, Baseload Wind Energy: Modeling the Competition Between Gas Turbines and Compressed Air Energy Storage for Supplemental Generation, 35 ENERGY POL'Y1474,1474 (2007) (attributing a thirty percent annual increase in installed wind capacity to a "twofold drop in capital costs between 1992 and 2001" and "government initiatives").
  • 245
    • 44649185432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2004 Commission Energy Evaluation, supra note 110, at 20-21
    • 2004 Commission Energy Evaluation, supra note 110, at 20-21.
  • 246
    • 2442661929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Emissions Trading and Technology Deployment in an Energy-Systems "Bottom-up " Model with Technology Learning, 158
    • estimating an eighty-six percent progress ratio for solar photovoltaics, representing the rate of cost decline per doubling of production, See
    • See Bernardo Barreto & Socrates Kypreos, Emissions Trading and Technology Deployment in an Energy-Systems "Bottom-up " Model with Technology Learning, 158 EUR. J. OPERATIONAL RES. 243, 246-48 (2004) (estimating an eighty-six percent progress ratio for solar photovoltaics, representing the rate of cost decline per doubling of production);
    • (2004) EUR. J. OPERATIONAL RES , vol.243 , pp. 246-248
    • Barreto, B.1    Kypreos, S.2
  • 247
    • 44649117214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mona Hymel, The United States ' Experience with Energy-Based Tax Incentives: The Evidence Supporting Tax Incentives for Renewable Energy 3-8 (Ariz. Legal Studies, Discussion Paper No. 06-21, 2006), http://www.ssrn.com/ abstract=896987 (discussing the United States' subsidies for fossil fuels and renewable energy);
    • Mona Hymel, The United States ' Experience with Energy-Based Tax Incentives: The Evidence Supporting Tax Incentives for Renewable Energy 3-8 (Ariz. Legal Studies, Discussion Paper No. 06-21, 2006), http://www.ssrn.com/ abstract=896987 (discussing the United States' subsidies for fossil fuels and renewable energy);
  • 248
    • 44649105550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bert Metz & Detlef van Vuuren, How, and at What Costs, Can Low-Level Stabilization Be Achieved? - An Overview, in AVOIDING DANGEROUS CLIMATE CHANGE 339 (Hans Joachim Schellnhuber, Wolfgang Cramer, Nebojsa Nakicenovic, Tom Wigley & Gary Yohe eds., 2006) (noting that renewable energy today represent one of the most expensive options for greenhouse gas mitigation).
    • Bert Metz & Detlef van Vuuren, How, and at What Costs, Can Low-Level Stabilization Be Achieved? - An Overview, in AVOIDING DANGEROUS CLIMATE CHANGE 339 (Hans Joachim Schellnhuber, Wolfgang Cramer, Nebojsa Nakicenovic, Tom Wigley & Gary Yohe eds., 2006) (noting that renewable energy today represent one of the most expensive options for greenhouse gas mitigation).
  • 249
    • 33745465382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Plugging Into the Future
    • discussing the fuel efficiency gains of the Toyota Prius and other hybrid vehicles, June 10, at
    • Plugging Into the Future, THE ECONOMIST, June 10, 2006, at 30 (discussing the fuel efficiency gains of the Toyota Prius and other hybrid vehicles).
    • (2006) THE ECONOMIST , pp. 30
  • 250
    • 44649091755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CAL. CODE REGS. tit. 13, § 1960.1 (2006).
    • See CAL. CODE REGS. tit. 13, § 1960.1 (2006).
  • 251
    • 44649169514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Motor Vehicles Mfrs. Ass'n v. N. Y. State Dep't of Envtl. Conservation, 17 F.3d 521, 528 (2d Cir. 1994) (describing the fleet average approach), aff'd, 79 F.2d 1298 (2d Cir. 1996).
    • See Motor Vehicles Mfrs. Ass'n v. N. Y. State Dep't of Envtl. Conservation, 17 F.3d 521, 528 (2d Cir. 1994) (describing the fleet average approach), aff'd, 79 F.2d 1298 (2d Cir. 1996).
  • 252
    • 44649090459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keeth, supra note 101, at 726-27 (explaining how manufacturers can comply with averaging requirements that relaxed the technological demands in the original program's zero emission vehicle requirement).
    • Keeth, supra note 101, at 726-27 (explaining how manufacturers can comply with averaging requirements that relaxed the technological demands in the original program's zero emission vehicle requirement).
  • 253
    • 44649167431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CAL. CODE REGS. tit. 13, § 1961.1(a)-(g) (2006).
    • CAL. CODE REGS. tit. 13, § 1961.1(a)-(g) (2006).
  • 254
    • 44649106183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keith Bradsher & David Barboza, Pollution from Chinese Coal Casts Shadow Around Globe, N. Y. TIMES, June 11, 2006, at Al (noting that vehicles sold in China must meet stricter fuel efficiency standards than those of the United States).
    • Keith Bradsher & David Barboza, Pollution from Chinese Coal Casts Shadow Around Globe, N. Y. TIMES, June 11, 2006, at Al (noting that vehicles sold in China must meet stricter fuel efficiency standards than those of the United States).
  • 255
    • 0842312315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David S. Loughran & Jonathan Kulick, Demand-Side Management and Energy Efficiency in the United States, 25 ENERGY J. 19, 34 (2004) (noting that between 1989 and 1999, utilities reported on average 180,000 MWh annual energy efficiency savings from demand-side management).
    • David S. Loughran & Jonathan Kulick, Demand-Side Management and Energy Efficiency in the United States, 25 ENERGY J. 19, 34 (2004) (noting that between 1989 and 1999, utilities reported on average 180,000 MWh annual energy efficiency savings from demand-side management).
  • 256
    • 44649109389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert R. Nordhaus & Kyle W. Danish, Assessing the Options for Designing a Mandatory U.S. Greenhouse Gas Reduction Program, 32 B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 97, 107 (2005) (noting that the Department of Energy's appliance efficiency program has saved about one-percent of total U.S. energy use).
    • Robert R. Nordhaus & Kyle W. Danish, Assessing the Options for Designing a Mandatory U.S. Greenhouse Gas Reduction Program, 32 B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 97, 107 (2005) (noting that the Department of Energy's appliance efficiency program has saved about one-percent of total U.S. energy use).
  • 257
    • 44649191564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Least-Cost Planning Imperatives for Electric Utilities and Their Regulators, 10
    • justifying such a comparison, explaining how to carry it out, and surveying state programs, See generally
    • See generally Ralph C. Cavanagh, Least-Cost Planning Imperatives for Electric Utilities and Their Regulators, 10 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 299, 300-01 (1996) (justifying such a comparison, explaining how to carry it out, and surveying state programs).
    • (1996) HARV. ENVTL. L. REV , vol.299 , pp. 300-301
    • Cavanagh, R.C.1
  • 258
    • 44649165513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 141, at, showing that generating a kWh costs more than twice as much as saving a kWh through energy efficiency
    • Loughran & Kulick, supra note 141, at 25 (showing that generating a kWh costs more than twice as much as saving a kWh through energy efficiency).
    • supra , pp. 25
    • Loughran1    Kulick2
  • 259
    • 44649157521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Choi, supra note 5, at 951 (arguing that addressing global climate change requires fundamental changes in human behavior).
    • Cf. Choi, supra note 5, at 951 (arguing that "addressing global climate change requires fundamental changes in human behavior").
  • 260
    • 44649104917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard B. Stewart, Controlling Environmental Risks Through Economic Incentives, 13 COLUM. J. ENVTL. L. 153, 155,166 (1988) noting that technology-based regulation requires installation of pollution control technology, while economic incentives encourage new
    • Richard B. Stewart, Controlling Environmental Risks Through Economic Incentives, 13 COLUM. J. ENVTL. L. 153, 155,166 (1988) (noting that technology-based regulation requires installation of "pollution control" technology, while "economic incentives" encourage "new
  • 261
    • 44649156858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • products or production technologies; e.g., Richard B. Stewart, United States Environmental Regulation: A Failing Paradigm, 15 J.L. & COM. 585, 592 (1996) (contrasting the existing technology-based system['s] emphasis on end of pipe controls with trading's encouragement of process changes and conservation).
    • products or production technologies"); e.g., Richard B. Stewart, United States Environmental Regulation: A Failing Paradigm, 15 J.L. & COM. 585, 592 (1996) (contrasting the "existing technology-based system['s]" emphasis on "end of pipe" controls with trading's encouragement of "process changes and conservation").
  • 262
    • 22244475439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 3 (suggesting that renewables policies might be justified without carbon benefits because of falling costs over time) with Jos Sijm, The Interaction Between the EU Emissions Trading Scheme and National Energy Policies, 5 CLIMATE POL'Y 79, 94 (2005) (suggesting that energy security, equity, raising fiscal resources, ancillary environmental benefits, and dynamic efficiency may justify energy policy, but that allowance trading makes it unnecessary for carbon-reduction purposes).
    • Compare Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 3 (suggesting that renewables policies might be justified without carbon benefits because of falling costs over time) with Jos Sijm, The Interaction Between the EU Emissions Trading Scheme and National Energy Policies, 5 CLIMATE POL'Y 79, 94 (2005) (suggesting that energy security, equity, "raising fiscal resources," ancillary environmental benefits, and dynamic efficiency may justify energy policy, but that allowance trading makes it unnecessary for carbon-reduction purposes).
  • 263
    • 44649188346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 75-77;
    • DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 75-77;
  • 264
    • 44649136545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David M. Driesen, Design, Trading, and Innovation, in MOVING TO MARKETS, supra note 53, at 437-38. While I frame much of my argument about spillover neglect in terms of technological innovation, market-neglected positive spillovers can arise from high quality non-innovative technology as well.
    • David M. Driesen, Design, Trading, and Innovation, in MOVING TO MARKETS, supra note 53, at 437-38. While I frame much of my argument about spillover neglect in terms of technological innovation, market-neglected positive spillovers can arise from high quality non-innovative technology as well.
  • 265
    • 44649135013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.N. Conference on Env't & Dev., Rio de Janerio, Brazil, June 3-14, 1992, Agenda 21, ¶ 9.9, U.N. Doc. A/CONF. 151.26 (Aug. 12 1992) (calling for increased use of renewable energy and energy efficiency); BRUNDTLAND REPORT, supra note 9, at 188 (stating that the development of renewable energy be given the highest priority).
    • U.N. Conference on Env't & Dev., Rio de Janerio, Brazil, June 3-14, 1992, Agenda 21, ¶ 9.9, U.N. Doc. A/CONF. 151.26 (Aug. 12 1992) (calling for increased use of renewable energy and energy efficiency); BRUNDTLAND REPORT, supra note 9, at 188 (stating that the development of renewable energy be given the "highest priority").
  • 266
    • 44649104918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Herman E. Daly, Sustainable Growth: An Impossibility Theorem, in VALUING THE EARTH 271 (Herman E. Daly & Kenneth N. Townsend eds., 1992).
    • Herman E. Daly, Sustainable Growth: An Impossibility Theorem, in VALUING THE EARTH 271 (Herman E. Daly & Kenneth N. Townsend eds., 1992).
  • 267
    • 44649148186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 267-68
    • Id. at 267-68.
  • 268
    • 44649195496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 268
    • Id. at 268.
  • 269
    • 44649097390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 89 (explaining the link between Daly's idea of reduced through-put and technological innovation).
    • See DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 89 (explaining the link between Daly's idea of reduced through-put and technological innovation).
  • 270
    • 44649178444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interview with Lewis Milford, Clean Air Group, Clean Energy Group (July 5, 2006, claiming that experts agree that the world needs significant innovation in how energy is produced to adequately address climate change, See, e.g, DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 102-06 (discussing technological options to address climate change with emphasis on options involving significant technological changes, Baumert, supra note 3, at 388 stating that effectively addressing climate change requires large-scale technological and behavioral changes
    • Interview with Lewis Milford, Clean Air Group, Clean Energy Group (July 5, 2006) (claiming that experts agree that the world needs significant innovation in how energy is produced to adequately address climate change). See, e.g., DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 102-06 (discussing technological options to address climate change with emphasis on options involving significant technological changes); Baumert, supra note 3, at 388 (stating that effectively addressing climate change requires "large-scale technological and behavioral changes").
  • 271
    • 44649158116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 155-58 (suggesting that avoiding a three degrees Celsius temperature rise may require a forty percent cut from 2010 levels by 2050 and more than a sixty percent cut by 2100);
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 155-58 (suggesting that avoiding a three degrees Celsius temperature rise may require a forty percent cut from 2010 levels by 2050 and more than a sixty percent cut by 2100);
  • 272
    • 16444372838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Slippery Slope: How Much Global Warming Constitutes "Dangerous Anthropogenic Interference," 68
    • stating that a two degrees Celsius temperature rise almost surely takes us well into the realm of dangerous climate change
    • James E. Hansen, A Slippery Slope: How Much Global Warming Constitutes "Dangerous Anthropogenic Interference," 68 CLIMATE CHANGE 269, 277 (2005) (stating that a two degrees Celsius temperature rise "almost surely takes us well into the realm of dangerous" climate change);
    • (2005) CLIMATE CHANGE , vol.269 , pp. 277
    • Hansen, J.E.1
  • 273
    • 44649170159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Malte Meinshausen, What Does a 2°C Target Mean for Greenhouse Gas Concentrations? A Brief Analysis Based on Multi-Gas Emissions Pathways and Several Climate Sensitivity Uncertainty Estimates, in AVOIDING DANGEROUS CLIMATE CHANGE, supra note 134, at 269-70 (estimating that limiting temperature rise to less than two degrees Celsius likely requires a fifty-five percent reduction below 1990 emissions levels by 2050).
    • Malte Meinshausen, What Does a 2°C Target Mean for Greenhouse Gas Concentrations? A Brief Analysis Based on Multi-Gas Emissions Pathways and Several Climate Sensitivity Uncertainty Estimates, in AVOIDING DANGEROUS CLIMATE CHANGE, supra note 134, at 269-70 (estimating that limiting temperature rise to less than two degrees Celsius likely requires a fifty-five percent reduction below 1990 emissions levels by 2050).
  • 274
    • 44649122562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bradsher & Barboza, supra note 140 explaining that Chinese coal-fired power plants will probably increase greenhouse gas emissions by five times the amount of cuts from Kyoto and that India is following suit
    • Bradsher & Barboza, supra note 140 (explaining that Chinese coal-fired power plants will probably increase greenhouse gas emissions by five times the amount of cuts from Kyoto and that India is following suit).
  • 275
    • 44649131154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James E. Hansen, Global Warming: Is There Still Time to Avoid Disastrous Human-Made Climate Change? i.e. Have We Passed a Tipping Point?, 26-29 (2006), http://www.columbia.edu /~jehl/nas_24april2006.pdf (providing maps of areas that would probably be under water if temperature increased by three degrees Celsius).
    • James E. Hansen, Global Warming: Is There Still Time to Avoid Disastrous Human-Made Climate Change? i.e. Have We Passed a Tipping Point?, 26-29 (2006), http://www.columbia.edu /~jehl/nas_24april2006.pdf (providing maps of areas that would probably be under water if temperature increased by three degrees Celsius).
  • 276
    • 44649119699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Choi, supra note 5, at 872 claiming that development of renewable energy and increased energy efficiency can move the world toward sustainable development
    • See generally Choi, supra note 5, at 872 (claiming that development of renewable energy and increased energy efficiency can move the world toward sustainable development).
  • 277
    • 44649146931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KOLBERT, supra note 71, at 168
    • KOLBERT, supra note 71, at 168.
  • 279
    • 44649141152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 16, at 123 (commenting that uncertainty lies at the core of technological innovation, because [scientific progress is unpredictable ).
    • POSNER, supra note 16, at 123 (commenting that uncertainty lies at the "core" of technological innovation, because "[scientific progress is unpredictable ").
  • 280
    • 44649097994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 123-24 explaining that third parties' ability to use information makes it difficult for inventors to keep all the value their inventions create
    • See id. at 123-24 (explaining that third parties' ability to use information makes it difficult for inventors to keep all the value their inventions create);
  • 281
    • 44649170788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gregory N. Mandel, Promoting Environmental Innovation and Intellectual Property Innovation: A New Basis for Patent Rewards, 24 TEMPLE J. ENVTL. L. & TECH. 51, 56 2006, explaining that if a person builds a better mousetrap, others may copy it
    • Gregory N. Mandel, Promoting Environmental Innovation and Intellectual Property Innovation: A New Basis for Patent Rewards, 24 TEMPLE J. ENVTL. L. & TECH. 51, 56 (2006) (explaining that if a person "builds a better mousetrap," others may copy it).
  • 282
    • 44649125851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 16, at 283 (explaining that intellectual property law allows innovators to capture some, but not all, of innovation's value).
    • POSNER, supra note 16, at 283 (explaining that intellectual property law allows innovators to capture some, but "not all," of innovation's value).
  • 283
    • 44649172287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 282-93 (explaining that both copyright and patent law create a semicommons combining private property rights and commons elements).
    • Id. at 282-93 (explaining that both copyright and patent law create a "semicommons" combining private property rights and commons elements).
  • 285
    • 44649097389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 292
    • Id. at 292.
  • 287
    • 44649180287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally, Steffen Kallbekken & Nathan Rive, Why Delaying Emissions Cuts is a Gamble, in AVOIDING DANGEROUS CLIMATE CHANGE, supra note 134, at 315 (explaining that technological change can influence pollution abatement's cost and feasibility).
    • See generally, Steffen Kallbekken & Nathan Rive, Why Delaying Emissions Cuts is a Gamble, in AVOIDING DANGEROUS CLIMATE CHANGE, supra note 134, at 315 (explaining that technological change can influence pollution abatement's cost and feasibility).
  • 288
    • 44649146306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Eban Goodstein, Prices Versus Policy: Which Path to Clean Technology, in THE LONG-TERM ECONOMICS OF CLIMATE CHANGE: BEYOND A DOUBLING OF GREENHOUSE GAS CONCENTRATIONS 225 (Darwin C. Hall & Richard B. Howarth eds., 2001) (identifying early investment in clean technology with avoidance of ongoing residual damage from carbon emissions).
    • See Eban Goodstein, Prices Versus Policy: Which Path to Clean Technology, in THE LONG-TERM ECONOMICS OF CLIMATE CHANGE: BEYOND A DOUBLING OF GREENHOUSE GAS CONCENTRATIONS 225 (Darwin C. Hall & Richard B. Howarth eds., 2001) (identifying early investment in clean technology with avoidance of "ongoing residual damage from carbon emissions").
  • 289
    • 44649161055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf Choi, supra note 5, at 951 (claiming that recent crude oil prices indicate that fossil fuels have already begun to be in short supply).
    • Cf Choi, supra note 5, at 951 (claiming that recent crude oil prices indicate that "fossil fuels have already begun to be in short supply").
  • 290
    • 44649187292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Goodstein, supra note 169, at 233 explaining in detail why earlier investment in clean technology reduces costs
    • See Goodstein, supra note 169, at 233 (explaining in detail why earlier investment in clean technology reduces costs).
  • 291
    • 0042740380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Douglas A. Kysar, Some Realism About Environmental Skepticism: The Implications of Bjorn Lomborg's The Skeptical Environmentalist for Environmental Law and Policy, 30 ECOLOGY L. Q. 223, 263 (2003) (noting incidental reductions in sulfur dioxide, nitrogen oxides, volatile organic compounds, and particulates due to efforts to reduce climate change);
    • See Douglas A. Kysar, Some Realism About Environmental Skepticism: The Implications of Bjorn Lomborg's The Skeptical Environmentalist for Environmental Law and Policy, 30 ECOLOGY L. Q. 223, 263 (2003) (noting incidental reductions in sulfur dioxide, nitrogen oxides, volatile organic compounds, and particulates due to efforts to reduce climate change);
  • 292
    • 20644436920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Luis Mundaca & Hakan Rodhe, CDM Wind-Energy Projects: Exploring Small Capacity Thresholds and Low Performances, 4 CLIMATE POL'Y 399, 405 (2005) (describing how wind energy reduces harmful sulfur dioxide emissions to zero).
    • cf. Luis Mundaca & Hakan Rodhe, CDM Wind-Energy Projects: Exploring Small Capacity Thresholds and Low Performances, 4 CLIMATE POL'Y 399, 405 (2005) (describing how wind energy reduces harmful sulfur dioxide emissions to zero).
  • 293
    • 44649093729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. U.N. Conference on Env't & Dev., Rio de Janerio, Brazil, June 3-14, 1992, Rio Declaration on Env't and Dev., princ. 1, U.N. Doc. A/CONF.151/26 (Aug. 12, 1992) (recognizing a human right to a healthy life based on the centrality of human beings to sustainable development).
    • Cf. U.N. Conference on Env't & Dev., Rio de Janerio, Brazil, June 3-14, 1992, Rio Declaration on Env't and Dev., princ. 1, U.N. Doc. A/CONF.151/26 (Aug. 12, 1992) (recognizing a human right to a healthy life based on the centrality of human beings to sustainable development).
  • 294
    • 44649196312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Palmer & Burtraw, supra note 113, at 62, providing a jump start to technology learning can yield significant future benefits
    • See Palmer & Burtraw, supra note 113, at 62 ("[providing a jump start to technology learning" can yield significant future benefits).
  • 295
    • 44649099979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See LINDA NULL & JULIA LOBUR, THE ESSENTIALS OF COMPUTER ORGANIZATION AND ARCHITECTURE 19-25 (2d ed. 2006) (explaining that the first supercomputer built with transistors cost $10 million, but that integrated circuits and then microprocessors to miniaturize transistors dropped the price and made personal computers possible);
    • See LINDA NULL & JULIA LOBUR, THE ESSENTIALS OF COMPUTER ORGANIZATION AND ARCHITECTURE 19-25 (2d ed. 2006) (explaining that the first supercomputer built with transistors cost $10 million, but that integrated circuits and then microprocessors to miniaturize transistors dropped the price and made personal computers possible);
  • 296
    • 0030328659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rudi Volti, A Century of Automobility, 37 TECH. & CULTURE 663, 667, 670 (1996) (describing cars' origins as luxury goods and the assembly line's role in reducing prices);
    • Rudi Volti, A Century of Automobility, 37 TECH. & CULTURE 663, 667, 670 (1996) (describing cars' origins as luxury goods and the assembly line's role in reducing prices);
  • 297
    • 0031231896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. DAVID A. HOUNSHELL, FROM THE AMERICAN SYSTEM TO MASS PRODUCTION, 1800-1932, 218, 241 (1984) (while Ford had experience making luxury cars, he credits observation of other production processes as the source of the idea of the assembly line to produce automobiles). See generally Sabine Messner, Endogenized Technological Learning in an Energy Systems Model, 7 J. Evolutionary Econ. 291, 293 (1997) (describing learning by doing as among the best empirically corroborated phenomena characterizing technological change in industry.).
    • cf. DAVID A. HOUNSHELL, FROM THE AMERICAN SYSTEM TO MASS PRODUCTION, 1800-1932, 218, 241 (1984) (while Ford had experience making luxury cars, he credits observation of other production processes as the source of the idea of the assembly line to produce automobiles). See generally Sabine Messner, Endogenized Technological Learning in an Energy Systems Model, 7 J. Evolutionary Econ. 291, 293 (1997) (describing "learning by doing" as "among the best empirically corroborated phenomena characterizing technological change in industry.").
  • 298
    • 44649143673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barreto & Kypreos, supra note 134, at 245-46 (learning.. .plays an important role in improving technologies' cost and performance).
    • Barreto & Kypreos, supra note 134, at 245-46 ("learning.. .plays an important role" in improving technologies' cost and performance).
  • 299
    • 33644758430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Patrick Matschoss & Heinz Welsch, International Emissions Trading and Induced Carbon-Saving Technological Change: Effects of Restricting the Trade in Carbon Rights, 33 ENVTL. & RESOURCE ECON. 169, 172 (2006) (associating learning by doing with assuming that learning comes from production).
    • See Patrick Matschoss & Heinz Welsch, International Emissions Trading and Induced Carbon-Saving Technological Change: Effects of Restricting the Trade in Carbon Rights, 33 ENVTL. & RESOURCE ECON. 169, 172 (2006) (associating learning by doing with assuming that learning comes from production).
  • 300
    • 44649140268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CHRISTOPHER HARMON, EXPERIENCE CURVES OF PHOTOVOLTAIC TECHNOLOGIES 3 (2000), available at http://www.iiasa.ac.at/Publications/Documents/IR-00-014.pdf (photovoltaic modules experienced a 20% cost decline with each doubling of installed capacity on average); Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 3 (most forms of renewable energy are undergoing a strong cost decrease);
    • See CHRISTOPHER HARMON, EXPERIENCE CURVES OF PHOTOVOLTAIC TECHNOLOGIES 3 (2000), available at http://www.iiasa.ac.at/Publications/Documents/IR-00-014.pdf (photovoltaic modules experienced a 20% cost decline with each doubling of installed capacity on average); Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 3 (most forms of renewable energy are "undergoing a strong cost decrease");
  • 301
    • 44649127167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Palmer & Burtraw, supra note 113, at 17, 51-52 explaining that the potential for learning by doing is high for renewable energy
    • Palmer & Burtraw, supra note 113, at 17, 51-52 (explaining that the potential for learning by doing is high for renewable energy).
  • 302
    • 44649159841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 83-85 (providing a numerical example to illustrate how long-term and short-term costs may diverge).
    • Cf. DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 83-85 (providing a numerical example to illustrate how long-term and short-term costs may diverge).
  • 303
    • 44649173537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Kysar, supra note 172, at 266 (stating that economic models used to estimate the costs and benefits of mitigating climate change use a mathematical discount rate ... to significantly reduce future harms' value);
    • See generally Kysar, supra note 172, at 266 (stating that economic models used to estimate the costs and benefits of mitigating climate change "use a mathematical discount rate ... to significantly reduce" future harms' value);
  • 304
    • 0033127822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Environmental Regulation, Cost-Benefit Analysis, and the Discounting of Human Lives, 99
    • Richard L. Revesz, Environmental Regulation, Cost-Benefit Analysis, and the Discounting of Human Lives, 99 COLUM. L. REV. 941 (1999);
    • (1999) COLUM. L. REV , vol.941
    • Revesz, R.L.1
  • 305
    • 44649142383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kenneth Arrow, William R. Cline, Karl-Göran Maler, Mohan Munasinghe, Rafael Squitieri & Joeseph E. Stiglitz, Intertemporal Equity, Discounting, and Economic Efficiency, in CLIMATE CHANGE 1995, supra note 5, at 125.
    • Kenneth Arrow, William R. Cline, Karl-Göran Maler, Mohan Munasinghe, Rafael Squitieri & Joeseph E. Stiglitz, Intertemporal Equity, Discounting, and Economic Efficiency, in CLIMATE CHANGE 1995, supra note 5, at 125.
  • 306
    • 44649087490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 16, at 151-52 (recognizing that application of a discount rate tends to obliterate future generations' interests in contexts like that of global warming because the discounting drastically reduces valuation of future harms).
    • POSNER, supra note 16, at 151-52 (recognizing that application of a discount rate tends to "obliterate" future generations' interests in contexts like that of global warming because the discounting drastically reduces valuation of future harms).
  • 307
    • 0347335866 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why We Should Discount The Views of Those Who Discount Discounting, 108
    • a person would prefer saving ten lives today over saving ten lives seven years from now, See
    • See John L. Donohue, Why We Should Discount The Views of Those Who Discount Discounting, 108 YALE L. J. 1901, 1905 (1999) (a person would prefer saving ten lives today over saving ten lives seven years from now).
    • (1999) YALE L. J. 1901 , pp. 1905
    • Donohue, J.L.1
  • 308
    • 44649175510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Douglas A. Kysar, Climate Change, Cultural Transformation, and Comprehensive Rationality, 31 B. C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 555, 578-85 (2004) (discussing moral issues with discounting in the climate change context); Kysar, supra note 8, at 2134 (noting that sustainable development proponents do not accept existing preferences as immutable);
    • See Douglas A. Kysar, Climate Change, Cultural Transformation, and Comprehensive Rationality, 31 B. C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 555, 578-85 (2004) (discussing moral issues with discounting in the climate change context); Kysar, supra note 8, at 2134 (noting that sustainable development proponents do not accept existing preferences as immutable);
  • 309
    • 44649127168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kysar, supra note 172, at 266-67 (questioning the moral basis for discounting human lives saved and other future benefits of climate change policies).
    • Kysar, supra note 172, at 266-67 (questioning the "moral basis" for discounting human lives saved and other future benefits of climate change policies).
  • 310
    • 7544242893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Behavioral Economic Defense of the Precautionary Principle, 97
    • defending the precautionary principle as a means of correcting for cognitive bias favoring short-term cost avoidance over long-term risk avoidance, See generally
    • See generally David A. Dana, A Behavioral Economic Defense of the Precautionary Principle, 97 Nw. U. L. REV. 1315 (2003) (defending the precautionary principle as a means of correcting for cognitive bias favoring short-term cost avoidance over long-term risk avoidance);
    • (2003) Nw. U. L. REV , vol.1315
    • Dana, D.A.1
  • 311
    • 21144481908 scopus 로고
    • The Shadow of the Future: Discount Rates, Later Generations, and the Environment, 46
    • Daniel A. Farber & Paul A. Hemmersbaugh, The Shadow of the Future: Discount Rates, Later Generations, and the Environment, 46 VAND. L. REV. 267 (1993);
    • (1993) VAND. L. REV , vol.267
    • Farber, D.A.1    Hemmersbaugh, P.A.2
  • 312
    • 44649168638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lisa Heinzerling, Discounting, 108 YALE L. J. 1911 (1999); Edith Brown Weiss, The Planetary Trust Conservation and Intergenerational Equity, 11 ECOLOGY L. Q. 495 (1984).
    • Lisa Heinzerling, Discounting, 108 YALE L. J. 1911 (1999); Edith Brown Weiss, The Planetary Trust Conservation and Intergenerational Equity, 11 ECOLOGY L. Q. 495 (1984).
  • 313
    • 24644439205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fostering the Use of Renewable Energies in the European Union: The Race Between Feed-in Tariffs and Green Certificates, 31
    • discussing these factors as aims of EU policy on renewables
    • Marc Ringel, Fostering the Use of Renewable Energies in the European Union: The Race Between Feed-in Tariffs and Green Certificates, 31 RENEWABLE ENERGY 1, 4-5 (2006) (discussing these factors as aims of EU policy on renewables).
    • (2006) RENEWABLE ENERGY , vol.1 , pp. 4-5
    • Ringel, M.1
  • 314
    • 0006916513 scopus 로고
    • Reforming Environmental Law: The Democratic Case for Market Incentives, 13
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Bruce A. Ackerman & Richard B. Stewart, Reforming Environmental Law: The Democratic Case for Market Incentives, 13 COLUM. J. ENVTL. L. 171, 183 (1988);
    • (1988) COLUM. J. ENVTL. L , vol.171 , pp. 183
    • Ackerman, B.A.1    Stewart, R.B.2
  • 315
    • 0002212026 scopus 로고
    • Incentive-Based Environmental Regulation: A New Era From an Old Idea?, 18
    • Robert W. Hahn and Robert N. Stavins, Incentive-Based Environmental Regulation: A New Era From an Old Idea?, 18 ECOLOGY L. Q. 1, 13 (1991);
    • (1991) ECOLOGY L. Q , vol.1 , pp. 13
    • Hahn, R.W.1    Stavins, R.N.2
  • 316
    • 44649154854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert N. Stavins, Policy Instruments for Climate Change: How Can National Governments Address a Global Problem?, 1997 U. CHI. LEGAL F. 293, 302-03 (1997);
    • Robert N. Stavins, Policy Instruments for Climate Change: How Can National Governments Address a Global Problem?, 1997 U. CHI. LEGAL F. 293, 302-03 (1997);
  • 317
    • 44649166793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stewart, supra note 146, at 160;
    • Stewart, supra note 146, at 160;
  • 318
    • 44649161684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stewart, supra note 17, at 19 (stating that economic incentive systems, including emissions trading, have an advantage over command and control regulation in stimulating continuing innovation).
    • Stewart, supra note 17, at 19 (stating that "economic incentive systems," including emissions trading, have an advantage over command and control regulation in stimulating "continuing innovation").
  • 319
    • 0036278682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adam B. Jaffe, Richard G. Newell & Robert N. Stavins, Environmental Policy and Technological Change, 22 ENVTL. & RESOURCE ECON. 41, 51 (2002) (economic incentives stimulate innovation by paying firms to clean up a bit more);
    • Adam B. Jaffe, Richard G. Newell & Robert N. Stavins, Environmental Policy and Technological Change, 22 ENVTL. & RESOURCE ECON. 41, 51 (2002) (economic incentives stimulate innovation by paying firms to "clean up a bit more");
  • 320
    • 0024497653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David A. Malueg, Emissions Credit Trading and the Incentive to Adopt New Pollution A batement Technology, 16 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MGMT. 52, 53-54 (1987).
    • David A. Malueg, Emissions Credit Trading and the Incentive to Adopt New Pollution A batement Technology, 16 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MGMT. 52, 53-54 (1987).
  • 321
    • 44649153355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 148, at, explaining how the traditional focus on sellers biases theory
    • Driesen, supra note 148, at 434-35 (explaining how the traditional focus on sellers biases theory).
    • supra , pp. 434-435
    • Driesen1
  • 322
    • 44649190249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barreto & Kypreos, supra note 134, at 259 finding that trading hinders the development and deployment of low carbon technology in permit buying regions
    • Barreto & Kypreos, supra note 134, at 259 (finding that trading hinders the development and deployment of low carbon technology in permit buying regions).
  • 323
    • 44649153355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 148, at, presenting and defending this analytical framework
    • Driesen, supra note 148, at 433-34 (presenting and defending this analytical framework);
    • supra , pp. 433-434
    • Driesen1
  • 324
    • 44649084148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwarze, supra note 108, at 56-57 (recognizing that a fair comparison between trading and traditional regulation requires the same standard).
    • Schwarze, supra note 108, at 56-57 (recognizing that a "fair comparison" between trading and traditional regulation requires the same standard).
  • 325
    • 22444442676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Joel F. Bruneau, A Note on Permits, Standards, and Technological Innovation, 48 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MGMT. 1192 (2004);
    • See, e.g., Joel F. Bruneau, A Note on Permits, Standards, and Technological Innovation, 48 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MGMT. 1192 (2004);
  • 326
    • 0017943104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • W. A. Magat, Pollution Control and Technological Advance: A Dynamic Model of the Firm, 5 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MGMT. 1 (1978);
    • W. A. Magat, Pollution Control and Technological Advance: A Dynamic Model of the Firm, 5 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MGMT. 1 (1978);
  • 327
    • 44649177444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Malueg, supra note 185;
    • Malueg, supra note 185;
  • 328
    • 44649172284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Juan-Pablo Montero, Market Structure and Environmental Innovation, 5 J. APPLIED ECON. 293 (2002) (trading, taxes, or traditional regulation can best encourage research and development when firms' products are strategic substitutes);
    • Juan-Pablo Montero, Market Structure and Environmental Innovation, 5 J. APPLIED ECON. 293 (2002) (trading, taxes, or traditional regulation can best encourage research and development when firms' products are strategic substitutes);
  • 329
    • 0036651510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Juan-Pablo Montero, Permits, Standards, and Technological Innovation, 44 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MGMT. 23 (2002);
    • Juan-Pablo Montero, Permits, Standards, and Technological Innovation, 44 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MGMT. 23 (2002);
  • 330
    • 44649149413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also David M. Driesen, Does Emissions Trading Encourage Innovation?, 33 ENVTL. L. REP. 10094 (2003) (arguing that trading may encourage less innovation than a comparable performance standard, but suggesting that it may change the type of innovation);
    • see also David M. Driesen, Does Emissions Trading Encourage Innovation?, 33 ENVTL. L. REP. 10094 (2003) (arguing that trading may encourage less innovation than a comparable performance standard, but suggesting that it may change the type of innovation);
  • 331
    • 33646702404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economic Dynamics of Environmental Law: Cost-Benefit Analysis, Emissions Trading, and Priority Setting, 31
    • stating that trading may have an overall negative effect on innovation
    • David M. Driesen, The Economic Dynamics of Environmental Law: Cost-Benefit Analysis, Emissions Trading, and Priority Setting, 31 B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 501, 519-20 (2004) (stating that trading may have an overall negative effect on innovation).
    • (2004) B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV , vol.501 , pp. 519-520
    • Driesen, D.M.1
  • 332
    • 20344376982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 Control, 27 L. & POL'Y 348, 370 (2005) (concluding that trading encouraged less innovation than command and control).
    • 2 Control, 27 L. & POL'Y 348, 370 (2005) (concluding that trading encouraged less innovation than command and control).
  • 333
    • 58849157382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 5, at, stating that the acid rain program has encouraged reliance on low-sulfur coal and scrubber installation
    • Choi, supra note 5, at 887 (stating that the acid rain program has encouraged reliance on low-sulfur coal and scrubber installation);
    • supra , pp. 887
    • Choi1
  • 334
    • 44649123185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 60, at, describing scrubbing and low-sulfur coals as the principle compliance means, but finding innovation in blending techniques and scrubber design
    • Swift, supra note 60, at 10332 (describing scrubbing and low-sulfur coals as the principle compliance means, but finding innovation in blending techniques and scrubber design);
    • supra , pp. 10332
    • Swift1
  • 335
    • 77950401580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 190, at, discussing reliance on wet scrubbers and low-sulfur coals
    • Taylor et al., supra note 190, at 356 (discussing reliance on wet scrubbers and low-sulfur coals);
    • supra , pp. 356
    • Taylor1
  • 336
    • 2442442123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see David Popp, Pollution Control Innovations and the Clean Air Act of 1990, 22 J. POL'Y ANALYSIS & MGMT. 641 (2003) (finding more patenting of scrubber technology under command and control than under the acid rain trading program, but finding a shift in the type of innovation encouraged under trading).
    • see David Popp, Pollution Control Innovations and the Clean Air Act of 1990, 22 J. POL'Y ANALYSIS & MGMT. 641 (2003) (finding more patenting of scrubber technology under command and control than under the acid rain trading program, but finding a shift in the type of innovation encouraged under trading).
  • 337
    • 44649178085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 71
    • DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 71.
  • 338
    • 44649179695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 339
    • 44649186684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Driesen, supra note 52, at 336 (noting that spatial flexibility makes it easier to deploy a well understood control method).
    • See Driesen, supra note 52, at 336 (noting that spatial flexibility makes it easier "to deploy a well understood control method").
  • 340
    • 44649177430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In reality, marginal control costs usually rise as a facility increases reductions. Thus, this example is oversimplified. But this simplification does not influence the results. Even if the low cost facility incurs higher costs for the reductions sold to Buyer than for the reductions made to merely achieve compliance, these extra reductions must still cost substantially less than the cost of routine compliance at Buyer's firm to make trading worthwhile. Indeed, the example in some ways understates the depth of the weakness of global trading in stimulating expensive innovation. One would expect trading to lower the marginal control costs of a large group of buyers, which might constitute about half of the participants in a trading program. And it would systematically lower the costs, and hence the price points innovators must meet, to the level of the cheapest reductions available anywhere within the universe of sources eligible to generate credits. In a global market, that universe is
    • In reality, marginal control costs usually rise as a facility increases reductions. Thus, this example is oversimplified. But this simplification does not influence the results. Even if the low cost facility incurs higher costs for the reductions sold to Buyer than for the reductions made to merely achieve compliance, these extra reductions must still cost substantially less than the cost of routine compliance at Buyer's firm to make trading worthwhile. Indeed, the example in some ways understates the depth of the weakness of global trading in stimulating expensive innovation. One would expect trading to lower the marginal control costs of a large group of buyers, which might constitute about half of the participants in a trading program. And it would systematically lower the costs, and hence the price points innovators must meet, to the level of the cheapest reductions available anywhere within the universe of sources eligible to generate credits. In a global market, that universe is likely to be large and the opportunities for cheap routine reductions enormous.
  • 341
    • 44649189616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Matschoss & Welsch, supra note 176, at 173 (referring to this hypothesis as the assumption of induced factor-saving technological change).
    • Cf. Matschoss & Welsch, supra note 176, at 173 (referring to this hypothesis as the assumption of "induced factor-saving technological change").
  • 342
    • 44649161049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Paolo Bertoldi, Silvia Rezessy, Ole Langniss & Monique Voogt, White, Green & Brown Certificates: How to Make the Most of Them at 11 (2005), http://sunbird.jrc.it/energy efficiency/pdf/publications/ ECEEE%202005%20paper%207%20203%20final.pdf(stating that the ETS will probably do little to encourage renewable energy because renewables may have higher marginal abatement costs than other carbon mitigation options).
    • See Paolo Bertoldi, Silvia Rezessy, Ole Langniss & Monique Voogt, White, Green & Brown Certificates: How to Make the Most of Them at 11 (2005), http://sunbird.jrc.it/energy efficiency/pdf/publications/ ECEEE%202005%20paper%207%20203%20final.pdf(stating that the ETS will probably do little to encourage renewable energy because "renewables may have higher marginal abatement costs" than other carbon mitigation options).
  • 343
    • 44649150042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 103 (pointing out that solar power is already cost competitive in some niche applications).
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 103 (pointing out that solar power is "already cost competitive in some niche applications").
  • 344
    • 44649128976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fenhann CDM Pipeline, note 124 buyers and investors favor projects requiring the least investment
    • See Fenhann CDM Pipeline, supra note 124 (buyers and investors favor projects requiring the least investment).
    • supra
  • 345
    • 44649159832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ellis & Kamel, supra note 126, at 13-15 (stating that renewable energy projects typically have relatively high abatement costs and industrial gas projects have low costs); Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 3 (predicting that the EU emissions trading will not induce development of technologies that currently have high... costs, such as renewable energy, because of low allowance prices). See generally CAPOOR & AMBROSI, supra note 7, at 9 (discussing the lack of an internationally recognized price index and the tendency to keep prices and contract structures confidential).
    • See Ellis & Kamel, supra note 126, at 13-15 (stating that renewable energy projects typically have relatively high abatement costs and industrial gas projects have low costs); Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 3 (predicting that the "EU emissions trading will not induce development of technologies that currently have high... costs," such as renewable energy, because of low allowance prices). See generally CAPOOR & AMBROSI, supra note 7, at 9 (discussing the lack of an internationally recognized price index and the tendency to keep prices and contract structures confidential).
  • 346
    • 44649123454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ellis & Butzengeiger, supra note 126, at 13
    • See Ellis & Butzengeiger, supra note 126, at 13.
  • 347
    • 44649150028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See White, note 20, at, noting that firms make decisions to maximize profits, It is also possible that in some locations renewable energy proves extremely cost effective
    • See White, supra note 20, at 65 (noting that firms make decisions to maximize profits). It is also possible that in some locations renewable energy proves extremely cost effective.
    • supra , pp. 65
  • 348
    • 44649134367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pearson, supra note 126, at 15 (suggesting that some buyers will pay a premium for renewables credits for public relations reasons).
    • See Pearson, supra note 126, at 15 (suggesting that "some buyers" will pay a premium for renewables credits for public relations reasons).
  • 349
    • 44649117213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Gold Standard, http://www.cdmgoldstandard.org/ (webpage of gold standard certifying organization).
    • The Gold Standard, http://www.cdmgoldstandard.org/ (webpage of "gold standard" certifying organization).
  • 350
    • 13544273514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Douglas Kysar, Preferences for Processes: The Process/Product Distinction and the Regulation of Consumer Choice, 118 HARV. L. REV. 525, 529 (2004) (explaining that information about how goods are produced can influence consumer choice);
    • Douglas Kysar, Preferences for Processes: The Process/Product Distinction and the Regulation of Consumer Choice, 118 HARV. L. REV. 525, 529 (2004) (explaining that information about how goods are produced can influence consumer choice);
  • 351
    • 44649170783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kysar, supra note 8, at 2156 (identifying infusing public policy elements into markets as an important phenomenon that has attracted little attention);
    • Kysar, supra note 8, at 2156 (identifying "infusing public policy elements into markets" as an important phenomenon that has attracted little attention);
  • 352
    • 20444452901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Iain MacGill, Hugh Outhred & Karel Nolles, Some Design Lessons from Market-Based Greenhouse Gas Regulation in the Restructured Australian Electricity Industry, 34 ENERGY POL'Y 11, 17 (2006) (demonstrating that markets have discounted credits for renewable energy produced by burning native forest waste in response to NGO opposition); The Gold Standard, supra note 204 (describing the NGO's strategy of persuading stakeholders that gold standard credits offer greater value and less risk than credits reflecting projects that NGOs have not specifically endorsed).
    • see Iain MacGill, Hugh Outhred & Karel Nolles, Some Design Lessons from Market-Based Greenhouse Gas Regulation in the Restructured Australian Electricity Industry, 34 ENERGY POL'Y 11, 17 (2006) (demonstrating that markets have discounted credits for renewable energy produced by burning native forest waste in response to NGO opposition); The Gold Standard, supra note 204 (describing the NGO's strategy of persuading stakeholders that gold standard credits offer greater value and less risk than credits reflecting projects that NGOs have not specifically endorsed).
  • 353
    • 30744455795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Pedro Linares, Francisco Javier Santos, Mariano Ventosa & Luis Lapiedra, Impacts of the European Emissions Trading Scheme Directive and Permit Assignment Methods on the Spanish Electricity Sector, 27 ENERGY J. 79, 88, 91 (2006) (forecasting switches to natural gas combined cycles but no other new technology, because the permit price is not high enough).
    • See, e.g., Pedro Linares, Francisco Javier Santos, Mariano Ventosa & Luis Lapiedra, Impacts of the European Emissions Trading Scheme Directive and Permit Assignment Methods on the Spanish Electricity Sector, 27 ENERGY J. 79, 88, 91 (2006) (forecasting switches to natural gas combined cycles but no other "new" technology, because "the permit price is not high enough").
  • 354
    • 44649187721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nicholas A. Ashford & George R. Heaton, Jr., Regulation and Technological Innovation in the Chemical Industry, 46 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 109, 139-140 (1983);
    • Nicholas A. Ashford & George R. Heaton, Jr., Regulation and Technological Innovation in the Chemical Industry, 46 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 109, 139-140 (1983);
  • 355
    • 44649149412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwarze, supra note 108, at 57-58 (stating that demanding traditional regulation produces strong incentives for innovation);
    • Schwarze, supra note 108, at 57-58 (stating that demanding traditional regulation produces strong incentives for innovation);
  • 356
    • 44649106807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 52-53 (discussing cases where traditional regulation has encouraged innovation); OFFICE OF TECHNOLOGY ASSESSMENT, U.S. CONGRESS, GAUGING CONTROL TECHNOLOGY AND REGULATORY IMPACTS IN OCCUPATIONAL SAFETY AND HEALTH: AN APPRAISAL OF OSHA's ANALYTICAL APPROACH, 89-90 (1995);
    • see DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 52-53 (discussing cases where traditional regulation has encouraged innovation); OFFICE OF TECHNOLOGY ASSESSMENT, U.S. CONGRESS, GAUGING CONTROL TECHNOLOGY AND REGULATORY IMPACTS IN OCCUPATIONAL SAFETY AND HEALTH: AN APPRAISAL OF OSHA's ANALYTICAL APPROACH, 89-90 (1995);
  • 357
    • 0038085013 scopus 로고
    • Using Regulation to Change the Market for Innovation, 9
    • Nicholas A. Ashford, Christine Ayers & Robert F. Stone, Using Regulation to Change the Market for Innovation, 9 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 419, 440-41 (1985);
    • (1985) HARV. ENVTL. L. REV , vol.419 , pp. 440-441
    • Ashford, N.A.1    Ayers, C.2    Stone, R.F.3
  • 358
    • 44649168637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kurt Strasser, Cleaner Technology, Pollution Prevention and Environmental Regulation, 9 FORDHAM ENVTL. L. REV. 1, 28-32 (1997).
    • Kurt Strasser, Cleaner Technology, Pollution Prevention and Environmental Regulation, 9 FORDHAM ENVTL. L. REV. 1, 28-32 (1997).
  • 359
    • 0037411680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The failure of emissions trading to stimulate projects that increase energy efficiency stems from the peculiarities of the Kyoto trading design rather than a general failure of trading to encourage cost effectiveness. See Bertoldi et al, supra note 197, at 11 (pointing out that enduse energy efficiency provides low-cost carbon reduction, The Kyoto parties' decision to allow trades with sources whose emissions remain uncapped threatens the program's integrity because it creates a potential to give up reductions from regulated sources in exchange for positive changes that would happen even without a trading program. See Sandra Greiner & Axel Michaelowa, Defining Investment Additionality for CDM Projects-Practical Approaches, 31 ENERGY POL'Y 1007, 1007 2003, linking the lack of targets for reductions in developing countries to potential problems with CDM's integrity, In order to avoid this danger, the Kyoto Protocol requires that
    • The failure of emissions trading to stimulate projects that increase energy efficiency stems from the peculiarities of the Kyoto trading design rather than a general failure of trading to encourage cost effectiveness. See Bertoldi et al., supra note 197, at 11 (pointing out that enduse energy efficiency provides "low-cost" carbon reduction.) The Kyoto parties' decision to allow trades with sources whose emissions remain uncapped threatens the program's integrity because it creates a potential to give up reductions from regulated sources in exchange for positive changes that would happen even without a trading program. See Sandra Greiner & Axel Michaelowa, Defining Investment Additionality for CDM Projects-Practical Approaches, 31 ENERGY POL'Y 1007, 1007 (2003) (linking the lack of targets for reductions in developing countries to potential problems with CDM's integrity). In order to avoid this danger, the Kyoto Protocol requires that credit only be granted for projects yielding " additional" emission reductions. Kyoto Protocol, supra note 2, art. 12(5)(c); Framework Convention on Climate Change: Conference of the Parties, October 19-November 10, 2001, Marrakesh Accords, Annex 17/CP.7 43. U.N. Doc FCCC/CP/2001/13/Add.1 (Jan. 21, 2002);
  • 360
    • 44649119067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see KYOTO MECHANISMS, supra note 90, at 193 (explaining that certification of credits for energy efficiency projects that would have been used anyway would lead to increased emissions). Because many energy efficiency projects are economically attractive on their own, they have difficulty satisfying this criterion.
    • see KYOTO MECHANISMS, supra note 90, at 193 (explaining that certification of credits for energy efficiency projects that would have been used anyway would lead to increased emissions). Because many energy efficiency projects are economically attractive on their own, they have difficulty satisfying this criterion.
  • 361
    • 44649150932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See KYOTO MECHANISMS, supra note 90, at 193 (using introduction of improved energy efficiency technologies that would have become widely used anyway as the example of an additionality problem);
    • See KYOTO MECHANISMS, supra note 90, at 193 (using introduction of "improved energy efficiency technologies that would have become widely used" anyway as the example of an additionality problem);
  • 362
    • 44649199064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • K. Umamaheswaran & Axel Michaelowa, Additionality and Sustainable Development Issues Regarding CDMProjects in Energy Efficiency Sector, HWWA Discussion Paper 346, 2, http://www.hwwa.de (characterizing additionality analysis of energy efficiency projects as cursory). The Kyoto Protocol's language suggests a project additionality test-that the project produce real additional reductions-but the regime has included to some degree a financial additionality test that requires that the credit purchases are essential to making the project happen.
    • K. Umamaheswaran & Axel Michaelowa, Additionality and Sustainable Development Issues Regarding CDMProjects in Energy Efficiency Sector, HWWA Discussion Paper 346, 2, http://www.hwwa.de (characterizing additionality analysis of energy efficiency projects as "cursory"). The Kyoto Protocol's language suggests a "project additionality test"-that the project produce real additional reductions-but the regime has included to some degree a "financial additionality test" that requires that the credit purchases are essential to making the project happen.
  • 363
    • 33645144577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michael Dutschke & Axel Michaelowa, Development Assistance and CDM - How to Interpret Financial Additionality, ' 11 ENVT. & DEV. ECON. 235 (2006) (discussing an interpretive issue with regard to financial additionality's relationship to foreign aid);
    • See Michael Dutschke & Axel Michaelowa, Development Assistance and CDM - How to Interpret Financial Additionality, ' 11 ENVT. & DEV. ECON. 235 (2006) (discussing an interpretive issue with regard to financial additionality's relationship to foreign aid);
  • 364
    • 44649122560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fenhann CDM Pipeline, supra note 124, at 22-23 (quoting an EU program elaborating additionality testing as acknowledging a general recognition that only projects that would not have taken place without the purchase of credits meet additionality criteria);
    • Fenhann CDM Pipeline, supra note 124, at 22-23 (quoting an EU program elaborating additionality testing as acknowledging a general recognition that only projects that would not have taken place without the purchase of credits meet additionality criteria);
  • 365
    • 44649093725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • noting that the CDM Executive Board has required evidence that CDM revenue was considered at the design stage for prompt start projects, A design that only allowed trades with sources subject to caps might well encourage energy efficiency, supra, at
    • Umamaheswaran & Michaelowa, supra, at 22 (noting that the CDM Executive Board has required evidence that CDM revenue was considered at the design stage for "prompt start projects"). A design that only allowed trades with sources subject to caps might well encourage energy efficiency.
    • Umamaheswaran1    Michaelowa2
  • 366
    • 44649164293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert N. Stavins, Implications of the US Experience With Market-Based Environmental Strategies for Future Climate Policy, in EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 66-67 (recognizing that programs allowing an unregulated source to generate credits require review lest credits be given for reductions that would have taken place in any event).
    • See Robert N. Stavins, Implications of the US Experience With Market-Based Environmental Strategies for Future Climate Policy, in EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 66-67 (recognizing that programs allowing "an unregulated source" to generate credits require review lest credits be given for reductions "that would have taken place in any event").
  • 367
    • 44649127795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Our entrepreneur may consider the value of receiving a longer stream of direct carbon benefits from the solar project than the HFC project would generate. She may sharply discount the value of future carbon reductions even though their value to future generations might be nearly as high as the early reductions. The parties to Kyoto have not yet agreed to targets beyond 2012, which lessens incentives to think about long-term streams of reductions. Even if she considers long-term benefits that she can realize profits from, there remains no reason for her to consider spillovers like the value of her technological contribution to other suppliers' future development of solar energy
    • Our entrepreneur may consider the value of receiving a longer stream of direct carbon benefits from the solar project than the HFC project would generate. She may sharply discount the value of future carbon reductions even though their value to future generations might be nearly as high as the early reductions. The parties to Kyoto have not yet agreed to targets beyond 2012, which lessens incentives to think about long-term streams of reductions. Even if she considers long-term benefits that she can realize profits from, there remains no reason for her to consider spillovers like the value of her technological contribution to other suppliers' future development of solar energy.
  • 368
    • 44649086223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 170-71 (explaining that emissions trading exploits cheap opportunities to deploy presently available technology, but it undermines the incentives to develop the new technologies that may reduce long-term costs);
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 170-71 (explaining that emissions trading exploits "cheap opportunities" to deploy "presently available" technology, but it undermines the incentives to develop the new technologies that may reduce long-term costs);
  • 369
    • 44649156855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PALMER & BURTRAW, supra note 113, at 59 (explaining that the most cost effective way to encourage renewable energy employs a carbon trading design that is more costly than a standard design);
    • PALMER & BURTRAW, supra note 113, at 59 (explaining that the most cost effective way to encourage renewable energy employs a carbon trading design that is more costly than a standard design);
  • 370
    • 44649192178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwarze, supra note 108, at 53 recognizing a general tradeoff between the goal of stimulating new technology and the goal of dynamic efficiency
    • Schwarze, supra note 108, at 53 (recognizing "a general tradeoff between the goal of stimulating new technology and the goal of dynamic efficiency").
  • 371
    • 44649177441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stavins, supra note 208, at 71-72 (stating that little is known empirically about the impact of these instruments on technological change and that there is... no policy panacea).
    • Stavins, supra note 208, at 71-72 (stating that "little is known empirically about the impact of these instruments on technological change" and that "there is... no policy panacea").
  • 372
    • 44649117836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Additional approaches to possible innovation exist. See DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 151-61, 183-201;
    • Additional approaches to possible innovation exist. See DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 151-61, 183-201;
  • 373
    • 44649108121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David M. Driesen, Sustainable Development and Air Quality: The Need to Replace Basic Technologies with Cleaner Alternatives, 32 ENVTL. L. REP. 10277, 10285-90 (2002) (discussing various alternatives).
    • David M. Driesen, Sustainable Development and Air Quality: The Need to Replace Basic Technologies with Cleaner Alternatives, 32 ENVTL. L. REP. 10277, 10285-90 (2002) (discussing various alternatives).
  • 374
    • 44649167424 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Richard B. Stewart, Regulation, Innovation, and Administrative Law: A Conceptual Framework, 69 CAL. L. REV. 1256, 1260-61 (1981) (concluding that innovation is needed just to keep environmental problems from getting worse as economic growth continues).
    • See Richard B. Stewart, Regulation, Innovation, and Administrative Law: A Conceptual Framework, 69 CAL. L. REV. 1256, 1260-61 (1981) (concluding that innovation is needed just to keep environmental problems from getting worse as economic growth continues).
  • 375
    • 44649202586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Choi, supra note 5, at 934 n.308 (calling renewable portfolio standards [t]he most effective policy tool for increasing renewable energy's market share).
    • Choi, supra note 5, at 934 n.308 (calling renewable portfolio standards "[t]he most effective policy tool" for increasing renewable energy's market share).
  • 376
    • 44649200935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Mandel, supra note 162, at 64-69 proposing a patent rewards system for environmental technology
    • See, e.g., Mandel, supra note 162, at 64-69 (proposing a "patent rewards system" for environmental technology).
  • 377
    • 44649165507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 151-161
    • See DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 151-161.
  • 380
    • 44649192860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EMISSIONS TRADING AND BUSINESS 46-49 (Ralf Antes, Bernd Hansjürgens & Peter Letmathe eds., 2006) (discussing the effects of auctioning allowances, providing free allowances to new entrants, and preserving allowances for owners of closed plants on innovation);
    • EMISSIONS TRADING AND BUSINESS 46-49 (Ralf Antes, Bernd Hansjürgens & Peter Letmathe eds., 2006) (discussing the effects of auctioning allowances, providing free allowances to new entrants, and preserving allowances for owners of closed plants on innovation);
  • 381
    • 31544443926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Modular Environmental Regulation, 54
    • characterizing careful attention to design as crucial
    • Jody Freeman & Daniel A. Farber, Modular Environmental Regulation, 54 DUKE L.J. 795, 836 (2005) (characterizing "careful attention to design" as "crucial");
    • (2005) DUKE L.J , vol.795 , pp. 836
    • Freeman, J.1    Farber, D.A.2
  • 382
    • 38849210229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see, note 205, at, explaining that absent appropriate design, poor quality credits can crowd out high quality credits
    • see MacGill et al., supra note 205, at 23 (explaining that absent appropriate design, poor quality credits can crowd out high quality credits);
    • supra , pp. 23
    • MacGill1
  • 383
    • 44649181935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see, e.g., PALMER & BURTRAW, supra note 113, at 25 (advocating the allocation of carbon allowances based on output, which favors renewable energy providers with the opportunity to sell all of their allowances);
    • see, e.g., PALMER & BURTRAW, supra note 113, at 25 (advocating the allocation of carbon allowances based on output, which favors renewable energy providers with the opportunity to sell all of their allowances);
  • 384
    • 33845244127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Atle Midttun & Kristian Gautesen, Feed in or Certificates, Competition or Complementarity? Combining a Static Efficiency and a Dynamic Innovation Perspective on the Greening of the Energy Industry, 35 ENERGY POL'Y 1419, 1420 (2007) (green certificate systems with free competition between all renewable technologies will not support the broader technological development necessary to further subsequent generations of renewable technology).
    • Atle Midttun & Kristian Gautesen, Feed in or Certificates, Competition or Complementarity? Combining a Static Efficiency and a Dynamic Innovation Perspective on the Greening of the Energy Industry, 35 ENERGY POL'Y 1419, 1420 (2007) (green certificate systems "with free competition between all renewable technologies" will not support "the broader technological development necessary to further subsequent generations of renewable technology").
  • 385
    • 44649120623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See James MacKintosh, The Car Industry Needs Carbon Trading, FIN. TIMES, July 3, 2006, at 17 (suggesting that a broader trading scheme would allow car manufacturers to avoid manufacturing hybrid vehicles and vehicles using biofuels).
    • See James MacKintosh, The Car Industry Needs Carbon Trading, FIN. TIMES, July 3, 2006, at 17 (suggesting that a broader trading scheme would allow car manufacturers to avoid manufacturing hybrid vehicles and vehicles using biofuels).
  • 386
    • 44649190233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CALIFORNIA ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY AIR RESOURCES BOARD, STAFF REPORT: INITIAL STATEMENT OF REASONS FOR PROPOSED RULEMAKING, PUBLIC HEARING TO CONSIDER ADOPTION OF REGULATIONS TO CONTROL GREENHOUSE GAS EMISSIONS FROM MOTOR VEHICLES vii (2004) (prohibiting use of credits from non-vehicle measures or for measures outside of California to avoid diluting carbon reduction regulations' technology-forcing effect).
    • See CALIFORNIA ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY AIR RESOURCES BOARD, STAFF REPORT: INITIAL STATEMENT OF REASONS FOR PROPOSED RULEMAKING, PUBLIC HEARING TO CONSIDER ADOPTION OF REGULATIONS TO CONTROL GREENHOUSE GAS EMISSIONS FROM MOTOR VEHICLES vii (2004) (prohibiting use of credits from non-vehicle measures or for measures outside of California to avoid diluting carbon reduction regulations' technology-forcing effect).
  • 387
    • 44649181936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 937 (recommending a cap on credits from foreign countries to address deterrence of long-term technological improvements);
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 937 (recommending a cap on credits from foreign countries to address "deterrence of long-term technological improvements");
  • 388
    • 44649112244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Matschoss & Welsch, supra note 176, at 170 noting that a number of writers have argued that placing limits on trades increases incentives for technological innovation
    • Matschoss & Welsch, supra note 176, at 170 (noting that a number of writers have argued that placing limits on trades increases incentives for technological innovation).
  • 389
    • 44649153355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 34, at, explaining principles of regulatory design and making illustrative reform recommendations
    • DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 183-201 (explaining principles of regulatory design and making illustrative reform recommendations);
    • supra , pp. 183-201
    • DRIESEN1
  • 390
    • 44649096149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael Grubb, Carlo Carraro & John Schellnhuber, Technological Change for Atmospheric Stabilization: Introductory Overview to the Innovation Modeling Comparison Project, 2 7 ENERGY J.1, 14 (2006) (highlighting the need for clear signals through long-term targets and characterizing the policy implications of considering innovation as far more subtle than questions of choosing between trading and traditional regulation). The acid rain program sought to encourage renewable energy by setting aside allowances for renewable energy. 42 U.S.C. § 7651c(f)-(g) (2007). But this feature had little effect.
    • Michael Grubb, Carlo Carraro & John Schellnhuber, Technological Change for Atmospheric Stabilization: Introductory Overview to the Innovation Modeling Comparison Project, 2 7 ENERGY J.1, 14 (2006) (highlighting the need for clear signals through long-term targets and characterizing the policy implications of considering innovation as "far more subtle" than questions of choosing between trading and traditional regulation). The acid rain program sought to encourage renewable energy by setting aside allowances for renewable energy. 42 U.S.C. § 7651c(f)-(g) (2007). But this feature had little effect.
  • 391
    • 44649188958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 891 n.86. We need more research about designing trading programs to encourage innovation. Cf. id. at 936-37 (opining that [d]irect allocations of allowances to renewable energy sources would function as a much more powerful tool for accelerating the commercial development of renewable energy technologies).
    • See Choi, supra note 5, at 891 n.86. We need more research about designing trading programs to encourage innovation. Cf. id. at 936-37 (opining that "[d]irect allocations of allowances to renewable energy sources would function as a much more powerful tool for accelerating the commercial development of renewable energy technologies").
  • 392
    • 22244437600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael Grubb, Christian Azar & U. Martin Persson, Allowance Allocation in the European Emissions Trading Scheme: A Commentary, 5 CLIMATE POL'Y 127, 127 (2005) (describing the allocation of allowances as the most... important step for any emissions trading system).
    • Michael Grubb, Christian Azar & U. Martin Persson, Allowance Allocation in the European Emissions Trading Scheme: A Commentary, 5 CLIMATE POL'Y 127, 127 (2005) (describing the "allocation of allowances" as "the most... important step" for "any emissions trading system").
  • 393
    • 44649147538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (allowance allocation determines the total emissions reductions and the magnitude of incentives for change); see, e.g., Choi, supra note 5, at 902-03 (describing California's RECLAIM program as a failure because the South Coast Air Quality Management District set the cap too high).
    • Id. (allowance allocation determines the total emissions reductions and the magnitude of incentives for change); see, e.g., Choi, supra note 5, at 902-03 (describing California's RECLAIM program as a "failure" because the South Coast Air Quality Management District set the cap too high).
  • 394
    • 44649129853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Grubb et al, supra note 224
    • See Grubb et al., supra note 224.
  • 395
    • 44649148173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 131 -32 (finding the allocations in phase one inconsistent with a serious effort to meet Kyoto targets and unlikely to encourage innovation); Gaming Gases; Emissions Trading
    • because of overallocation of allowances and other design features the EU Emissions Trading Scheme failed to boost alternatives, See, June 10, at
    • See id. at 131 -32 (finding the allocations in phase one inconsistent with a serious effort to meet Kyoto targets and unlikely to encourage innovation); Gaming Gases; Emissions Trading, THE ECONOMIST, June 10, 2006, at 69 (because of overallocation of allowances and other design features the EU Emissions Trading Scheme "failed to boost alternatives").
    • (2006) THE ECONOMIST , pp. 69
  • 396
    • 44649110003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PALMER & BURTRAW, supra note 113, at 31 explaining that the stringency of a renewable portfolio standard affects the prospects of different classes of renewable energy
    • See PALMER & BURTRAW, supra note 113, at 31 (explaining that the stringency of a renewable portfolio standard affects the prospects of different classes of renewable energy).
  • 397
    • 44649153355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 34, at, explaining the link between stringency and innovation
    • DRIESEN, supra note 34, at 197 (explaining the link between stringency and innovation).
    • supra , pp. 197
    • DRIESEN1
  • 398
    • 44649095489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 4 (describing cap-and-trade systems as representing a transition to market-based instruments which rely totally on market forces to create the necessary ... incentives).
    • See, e.g., EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 4 (describing "cap-and-trade systems" as representing "a transition to market-based instruments which rely totally on market forces to create the necessary ... incentives").
  • 399
    • 84928268710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas Sterner & Henrik Hammar, Designing Instruments for Climate Policy, in EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 17, 18.
    • Thomas Sterner & Henrik Hammar, Designing Instruments for Climate Policy, in EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 17, 18.
  • 400
    • 44649150924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 15 (explaining that many European countries wanted less flexibility to use foreign emissions reduction credits than the U.S., Russia, Japan, and Canada wanted). Cf. Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 2-3 (the EU opposed trading in the run-up to Kyoto but embraced it afterwards).
    • See DESSLER & PARSON, supra note 1, at 15 (explaining that many European countries wanted less flexibility to use foreign emissions reduction credits than the U.S., Russia, Japan, and Canada wanted). Cf. Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 2-3 (the EU opposed trading in the run-up to Kyoto but embraced it afterwards).
  • 401
    • 44649196952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Envtl. Def. Fund v. EPA, 489 F.2d 1247 (D.C. Cir. 1973) (upholding a ban on DDT).
    • See, e.g., Envtl. Def. Fund v. EPA, 489 F.2d 1247 (D.C. Cir. 1973) (upholding a ban on DDT).
  • 402
    • 0039591541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I am providing general thinking about the political economy of trading, not a comprehensive empirical analysis of the particulars of Kyoto's political economy. Emissions trading did prove essential to the Kyoto Protocol's entry into force, but not sufficient. It became necessary to grant extra allowances to Russia to obtain ratification, thereby potentially coupling trading with weaker limits. This suggests that once countries treat costs as critical, trading alone may not be sufficient to get them on board, but rather laxity may be necessary. David M. Driesen, Choosing Environmental Instruments in a Transnational Context, 27 ECOLOGY L.Q. 1, 47 (2000) (raising the possibility of relaxing stringency to buy assent to a regulatory regime).
    • I am providing general thinking about the political economy of trading, not a comprehensive empirical analysis of the particulars of Kyoto's political economy. Emissions trading did prove essential to the Kyoto Protocol's entry into force, but not sufficient. It became necessary to grant extra allowances to Russia to obtain ratification, thereby potentially coupling trading with weaker limits. This suggests that once countries treat costs as critical, trading alone may not be sufficient to get them on board, but rather laxity may be necessary. David M. Driesen, Choosing Environmental Instruments in a Transnational Context, 27 ECOLOGY L.Q. 1, 47 (2000) (raising the possibility of relaxing stringency to buy assent to a regulatory regime).
  • 403
    • 44649088730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 1-2 explaining that the EU supported stringent absolute emissions targets for industrialized countries and opposed international trading for a long time
    • See Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 1-2 (explaining that the EU supported "stringent absolute emissions targets for industrialized countries" and opposed international trading for a long time).
  • 404
    • 44649186050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dan M. Kahan, Paul Slovic, Donald Braman & John Ciastil, Fear of Democracy: A Cultural Evaluation of Sunstein on Risk, 119 HARV. L. REV. 1071, 1072 (2005) (book review) (finding that cultural worldviews influence risk perception). Professor Kahan and his coauthors explain that egalitarians tend to favor environmental regulation and that individualists tend to trust markets and react skeptically to environmental risks. Id. at 1083-84. Their empirical research confirms previous research finding that the egalitarians are more concerned about global warming and other environmental hazards than the individualists. Id. at 1086;
    • Dan M. Kahan, Paul Slovic, Donald Braman & John Ciastil, Fear of Democracy: A Cultural Evaluation of Sunstein on Risk, 119 HARV. L. REV. 1071, 1072 (2005) (book review) (finding that "cultural worldviews" influence risk perception). Professor Kahan and his coauthors explain that "egalitarians" tend to favor environmental regulation and that "individualists" tend to trust markets and react skeptically to environmental risks. Id. at 1083-84. Their empirical research confirms previous research finding that the egalitarians are more concerned about global warming and other environmental hazards than the individualists. Id. at 1086;
  • 405
    • 44649179687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Cass Sunstein, Misfearing: A Reply, 119 HARV. L. REV. 1110, 1111 (2005) (agreeing that cultural cognition influences risk perception, but arguing that it's hardly undemocratic to ignore the misperceptions).
    • cf. Cass Sunstein, Misfearing: A Reply, 119 HARV. L. REV. 1110, 1111 (2005) (agreeing that cultural cognition influences risk perception, but arguing that it's "hardly undemocratic" to ignore the misperceptions).
  • 406
    • 44649187279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Driesen, supra note 234, at 49 (pointing out that the availability of lower cost abatement options in foreign countries will only affect the stringency of limits for a trading program if the government considers those cost savings); cf. Deiner, supra note 71, at 2117 (explaining that states reducing greenhouse gas emissions report that doing so creates new jobs, develops new technologies, and lowers energy costs).
    • Driesen, supra note 234, at 49 (pointing out that the availability of lower cost abatement options in foreign countries will only affect the stringency of limits for a trading program if the government considers those cost savings); cf. Deiner, supra note 71, at 2117 (explaining that states reducing greenhouse gas emissions report that doing so creates new jobs, develops new technologies, and lowers energy costs).
  • 407
    • 44649190232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Terry Barker, Haoran Pan, Jonathan Köhler, Rachel Warren & Sarah Winne, Avoiding Dangerous Climate Change by Inducing Technological Progress; Scenarios Using a Large-Scale Econometric Model, in AVOIDING DANGEROUS CLIMATE CHANGE supra note 134, at 362-64 (discussing the wide divergence of results in economic models assessing the costs of climate change abatement);
    • See Terry Barker, Haoran Pan, Jonathan Köhler, Rachel Warren & Sarah Winne, Avoiding Dangerous Climate Change by Inducing Technological Progress; Scenarios Using a Large-Scale Econometric Model, in AVOIDING DANGEROUS CLIMATE CHANGE supra note 134, at 362-64 (discussing the wide divergence of results in economic models assessing the costs of climate change abatement);
  • 408
    • 44649100594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kahan et al., supra note 236, at 1088 (explaining that cultural world views influence perceptions of both the costs and benefits of dangerous activities). Professor Kahan argues that differences among experts reflect their divergent world views. Id. at 1092-1094. He also argues that experts may screen arguments and evidence to protect their status and beliefs. Id. at 1094. This suggests that economists may neglect learning by doing in economic modeling because recognizing the importance of something difficult to quantify threatens their status, but others may create numbers because their world views favor doing something about global warming.
    • Kahan et al., supra note 236, at 1088 (explaining that cultural world views influence perceptions of both the costs and benefits of dangerous activities). Professor Kahan argues that differences among experts reflect their divergent world views. Id. at 1092-1094. He also argues that experts may "screen arguments and evidence" to protect their status and beliefs. Id. at 1094. This suggests that economists may neglect learning by doing in economic modeling because recognizing the importance of something difficult to quantify threatens their status, but others may create numbers because their world views favor doing something about global warming.
  • 409
    • 85137623988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Polluters 'Profits and Political Response: Direct Control Versus Taxes, 65
    • explaining why polluters may prefer regulations to taxes, See
    • See James M. Buchanan & Gordon Tullock, Polluters 'Profits and Political Response: Direct Control Versus Taxes, 65 AM. ECON. REV. 139, 141-142 (explaining why polluters may prefer regulations to taxes);
    • AM. ECON. REV , vol.139 , pp. 141-142
    • Buchanan, J.M.1    Tullock, G.2
  • 410
    • 0347776234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nathaniel O. Keohane, Richard R. Revesz & Robert N. Stavins, The Choice of Regulatory Instruments in Environmental Policy, 22 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 313, 348-51 (1998) (explaining that polluters must pay taxes on residual emissions, but need not pay for those emissions under trading).
    • Nathaniel O. Keohane, Richard R. Revesz & Robert N. Stavins, The Choice of Regulatory Instruments in Environmental Policy, 22 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 313, 348-51 (1998) (explaining that polluters must pay taxes on residual emissions, but need not pay for those emissions under trading).
  • 411
    • 44649104904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 5 (explaining how lobbying in the EU led to goals in phase one that provided little departure from business-as-usual levels of carbon emissions).
    • See Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 5 (explaining how lobbying in the EU led to goals in phase one that provided little departure from "business-as-usual" levels of carbon emissions).
  • 412
    • 44649128980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Grubb et al., supra note 224, at 132-33 (describing industry lobbying's contribution to the EU's over allocation of phase one emissions allowances);
    • See Grubb et al., supra note 224, at 132-33 (describing industry lobbying's contribution to the EU's over allocation of phase one emissions allowances);
  • 413
    • 44649132393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 3 (pointing out that German industry lobbied against the EU emissions trading directive and that the chemical and aluminum industries lobbied, successfully, for their exclusion from the scheme);
    • Michaelowa & Butzengeiger, supra note 87, at 3 (pointing out that German industry lobbied against the EU emissions trading directive and that the chemical and aluminum industries lobbied, successfully, for their exclusion from the scheme);
  • 414
    • 44649142376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • France Haggles over Banking Rules as Second NAP Set to Miss Deadline, POINT CARBON (June 15, 2006), available at http://www.pointcarbon.com/ articlel6056-868.html?articleID= 16056&categoryID= (mentioning a French industry's advocacy of a high phase two cap).
    • France Haggles over Banking Rules as Second NAP Set to Miss Deadline, POINT CARBON (June 15, 2006), available at http://www.pointcarbon.com/ articlel6056-868.html?articleID= 16056&categoryID= (mentioning a French industry's advocacy of a high phase two cap).
  • 415
    • 44649135669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Choi, supra note 5, at 950 (attributing the U.S. failure to implement Kyoto to an economic way of thinking, which stresses short-term costs rather than long-term benefits).
    • See, e.g., Choi, supra note 5, at 950 (attributing the U.S. failure to implement Kyoto to "an economic way of thinking," which stresses "short-term costs rather than long-term benefits").
  • 416
    • 44649152115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Driesen, supra note 234, at 47 (explaining that no economic reason exists for a polluter to agree to emissions trading, unless government is willing to impose a more costly alternative).
    • See Driesen, supra note 234, at 47 (explaining that no economic reason exists for a polluter to agree to emissions trading, unless government is willing to impose a more costly alternative).
  • 417
    • 44649086863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Driesen, supra note 52, at 293;
    • Driesen, supra note 52, at 293;
  • 418
    • 44649145000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Samuel P. Hays, The Future of Environmental Regulation, 15 J.L. & COM. 549, 565-66 (1996) (characterizing traditional standards as the most significant market force in environmental protection).
    • see Samuel P. Hays, The Future of Environmental Regulation, 15 J.L. & COM. 549, 565-66 (1996) (characterizing traditional standards as the most significant "market force" in environmental protection).
  • 419
    • 44649112873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Driesen, supra note 52, at 336
    • See Driesen, supra note 52, at 336.
  • 420
    • 84922571440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 52, at, linking trading to a system that provides for democratic goal setting
    • See Ackerman & Stewart, supra note 52, at 1352-59 (linking trading to a system that provides for democratic goal setting);
    • supra , pp. 1352-1359
    • Ackerman1    Stewart2
  • 421
    • 0001292466 scopus 로고
    • Where Did All the Markets Go? An Analysis of EPA 's Emissions Trading Program, 6
    • monitoring and enforcement issues play a critical role in trading program design
    • Robert W. Hahn & Gordon L. Hester, Where Did All the Markets Go? An Analysis of EPA 's Emissions Trading Program, 6 YALE J. ON REG. 109, 111 (1989) (monitoring and enforcement issues play a critical role in trading program design).
    • (1989) YALE J. ON REG , vol.109 , pp. 111
    • Hahn, R.W.1    Hester, G.L.2
  • 422
    • 44649127156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ruth Greenspan Bell, Choosing Environmental Policy Instruments in the Real World, in OECD GLOBAL FORUM ON SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT: EMISSIONS TRADING 10 (2003) (arguing that emissions trading may not work well in countries lacking the capabilities to define and implement complex systems);
    • See, e.g., Ruth Greenspan Bell, Choosing Environmental Policy Instruments in the Real World, in OECD GLOBAL FORUM ON SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT: EMISSIONS TRADING 10 (2003) (arguing that emissions trading may not work well in countries lacking the capabilities to define and implement complex systems);
  • 423
    • 44649150923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Driesen, supra note 10, at 22 discussing the collapse of a New Jersey emissions trading program because of efforts to delegate monitoring to a private agency
    • Driesen, supra note 10, at 22 (discussing the collapse of a New Jersey emissions trading program because of efforts to delegate monitoring to a private agency).
  • 424
    • 2442491022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Haripriya Gundimeda, How Sustainable is the Sustainable Development Objective of CDM in Developing Countries Like India, 6 FOREST POL'Y & ECON. 329, 333 (2004) (explaining that project developers are likely to overlook micro level issues that determine whether afforestation and conservation projects for credit harm or help the poor).
    • See, e.g., Haripriya Gundimeda, How Sustainable is the Sustainable Development Objective of CDM in Developing Countries Like India, 6 FOREST POL'Y & ECON. 329, 333 (2004) (explaining that project developers are likely to overlook micro level issues that determine whether afforestation and conservation projects for credit harm or help the poor).
  • 425
    • 44649165496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert N. Stavins, Implications of the US Experience with Market-Based Environmental Strategies for Future Climate Change Policy, in EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 66 (referring to government approval of individual trades as transaction costs);
    • Robert N. Stavins, Implications of the US Experience with Market-Based Environmental Strategies for Future Climate Change Policy, in EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 66 (referring to government approval of individual trades as transaction costs);
  • 426
    • 44649164880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David M. Driesen & Shubha Ghosh, The Functions of Transaction Costs: Rethinking Transaction Cost Minimization in a World of Friction, 47 ARIZONA L. REV. 61, 79-82 (2005) (reviewing transaction cost minimization's role in emissions trading).
    • David M. Driesen & Shubha Ghosh, The Functions of Transaction Costs: Rethinking Transaction Cost Minimization in a World of Friction, 47 ARIZONA L. REV. 61, 79-82 (2005) (reviewing transaction cost minimization's role in emissions trading).
  • 427
    • 44649101204 scopus 로고
    • Risk and Design, 19
    • explaining that externalities arise when A and B mistransact with respect to C, whose interest they do not take into account, See
    • See James E. Krier, Risk and Design, 19 J. LEGAL STUD. 781, 782 (1990) (explaining that externalities arise when A and B "mistransact" with respect to C, whose interest they do not take into account).
    • (1990) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.781 , pp. 782
    • Krier, J.E.1
  • 428
    • 21144438737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michael S. Barr, Credit Where it Counts: The Community Reinvestment Act and its Critics, 80 N.Y.U. L. REV. 513, 602 (2005) (arguing that transaction costs generated by public involvement in Community Reinvestment Act processes should be weighed against the benefits of civic engagement);
    • See Michael S. Barr, Credit Where it Counts: The Community Reinvestment Act and its Critics, 80 N.Y.U. L. REV. 513, 602 (2005) (arguing that transaction costs generated by public involvement in Community Reinvestment Act processes should be weighed against the benefits of "civic engagement");
  • 429
    • 44649137158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Driesen & Ghosh, supra note 247, at 92-98 (discussing the tension between the impetus to reduce transaction costs to encourage trading and the need to preserve effective government oversight to protect environmental quality from poor quality trades);
    • Driesen & Ghosh, supra note 247, at 92-98 (discussing the tension between the impetus to reduce transaction costs to encourage trading and the need to preserve effective government oversight to protect environmental quality from poor quality trades);
  • 430
    • 44649163040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • accord Stavins, supra note 206, at 66 (the negative effects of transaction costs should be balanced against any anticipated benefits due to required government approval).
    • accord Stavins, supra note 206, at 66 (the negative effects of transaction costs "should be balanced against any anticipated benefits due to required government approval").
  • 432
    • 44649138378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John D. Graham & Jonathan Baert Wiener, Confronting Risk Tradeoffs, in RISK VERSUS RISK: TRADEOFFS IN PROTECTING HEALTH AND THE ENVIRONMENT 1 (John D. Graham & Jonathan Baert Wiener eds., 1995);
    • John D. Graham & Jonathan Baert Wiener, Confronting Risk Tradeoffs, in RISK VERSUS RISK: TRADEOFFS IN PROTECTING HEALTH AND THE ENVIRONMENT 1 (John D. Graham & Jonathan Baert Wiener eds., 1995);
  • 433
    • 21344496311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Randall Lutter & John F. Monall III, Health-Health Analysis: A New Way to Evaluate Health and Safety Regulation, 8 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 43 (1994); Cass Sunstein, HealthHealth Tradeoffs, 63 U. CHI. L. REV. 1533 (1996);
    • Randall Lutter & John F. Monall III, Health-Health Analysis: A New Way to Evaluate Health and Safety Regulation, 8 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 43 (1994); Cass Sunstein, HealthHealth Tradeoffs, 63 U. CHI. L. REV. 1533 (1996);
  • 435
    • 44649106165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kysar, supra note 172, at 258-59 defining risk-risk analysis as focusing decision-makers on the secondary ancillary harms that come from regulating a chosen harm
    • See Kysar, supra note 172, at 258-59 (defining "risk-risk analysis" as focusing decision-makers on the secondary ancillary harms that come from regulating a chosen harm).
  • 436
    • 0036766170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Biases of Risk Tradeoff Analysis: Towards Parity in Environmental andHealth-and-Safety Regulation, 69
    • faulting risk tradeoff analysis's neglect of ancillary benefits, See
    • See Samuel J. Rascoff & Richard L. Revesz, The Biases of Risk Tradeoff Analysis: Towards Parity in Environmental andHealth-and-Safety Regulation, 69 U. CHI. L. REV. 1763, 1766 (2002) (faulting risk tradeoff analysis's neglect of "ancillary benefits").
    • (2002) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.1763 , pp. 1766
    • Rascoff, S.J.1    Revesz, R.L.2
  • 437
    • 33746219700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David M. Driesen, Trading and Its Limits, 14 PENN ST. ENVTL. L. REV. 169, 173 (2006) (leaving the choice of technologies to regulated parties leaves the government with no timely means of evaluating risk/risk tradeoffs).
    • See David M. Driesen, Trading and Its Limits, 14 PENN ST. ENVTL. L. REV. 169, 173 (2006) (leaving the choice of technologies to regulated parties leaves the government with "no timely means of evaluating risk/risk tradeoffs").
  • 438
    • 44649193478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Driesen, supra note 234, at 49-50 (government must consider data of polluters' abatement costs if it wishes to consider cost in setting a cap for a tradable permit program).
    • Driesen, supra note 234, at 49-50 (government must consider data of polluters' abatement costs if it wishes to consider cost in setting a cap for a tradable permit program).
  • 439
    • 44649173521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Wiener, supra note 43, at 775 (suggesting that only technology-based regulation depends upon agency consideration of abatement costs).
    • Cf. Wiener, supra note 43, at 775 (suggesting that only "technology-based regulation" depends upon agency consideration of abatement costs).
  • 440
    • 44649187715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kysar, supra note 172, at 268 (noting that analysts expected acid rain permits to cost $1,500 a ton, but that they have traded for as little as $66.05 a ton).
    • See Kysar, supra note 172, at 268 (noting that analysts expected acid rain permits to cost $1,500 a ton, but that they have traded for as little as $66.05 a ton).
  • 441
    • 44649137157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Driesen, supra note 255, at 173 (pointing out that CBA is more likely to be wrong when a trading approach is used than when it is not used, because it is difficult to predict the magnitude of the trading program's cost savings).
    • See Driesen, supra note 255, at 173 (pointing out that CBA is more likely to be wrong when a trading approach is used than when it is not used, because it is difficult to predict the magnitude of the trading program's cost savings).
  • 442
    • 44649128979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 3 (stating that once government allocates allowances its action is limited to supervising the market, monitoring adequately, and applying sanctions in the case of non-compliance).
    • See EMISSIONS TRADING, supra note 55, at 3 (stating that once government allocates allowances its "action is limited to supervising the market, monitoring adequately, and applying sanctions in the case of non-compliance").
  • 443
    • 44649088726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SEGGER & KHALFAN, supra note 45, at 4 (noting that sustainable development's inclusiveness helped it guide diverse local, national, and international communities).
    • See SEGGER & KHALFAN, supra note 45, at 4 (noting that sustainable development's "inclusiveness" helped it guide diverse local, national, and international communities).
  • 444
    • 44649097380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (explaining that sustainable development does not function as a scientific blueprint for decision-makers and that this has caused difficulties in recent years);
    • See id. (explaining that sustainable development does not function as a "scientific blueprint" for decision-makers and that this has caused "difficulties" in recent years);
  • 445
    • 44649172028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. White, supra note 20, at 27-39 (explaining sources of great indeterminacy in efficiency determinations).
    • cf. White, supra note 20, at 27-39 (explaining sources of great indeterminacy in efficiency determinations).
  • 446
    • 0040766062 scopus 로고
    • Economics, Environment, and the Limits of Legal Control, 9
    • See
    • See Richard B. Stewart, Economics, Environment, and the Limits of Legal Control, 9 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 1, 6 (1985).
    • (1985) HARV. ENVTL. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 6
    • Stewart, R.B.1
  • 447
    • 44649148791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Richard B. Stewart, A New Generation of Environmental Regulation?, 29 CAP. U. L. REV. 21, 94 (2001) (command systems limit... the quantity of residuals that each actormay generate).
    • See Richard B. Stewart, A New Generation of Environmental Regulation?, 29 CAP. U. L. REV. 21, 94 (2001) ("command systems limit... the quantity of residuals that each actormay generate").
  • 448
    • 44649107462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Swift, supra note 60, at 10336-37 (explaining that traditional regulations have accommodated different base technologies for power generation, instead of encouraging shifts to cleaner fuels and boiler designs).
    • See Swift, supra note 60, at 10336-37 (explaining that traditional regulations have accommodated different base technologies for power generation, instead of encouraging shifts to cleaner fuels and boiler designs).
  • 449
    • 44649196951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 16, at 160 (referring to government's well known inability to pick technological winners).
    • POSNER, supra note 16, at 160 (referring to government's "well known" inability to pick "technological winners").
  • 450
    • 44649183160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Kysar, supra note 8, at 2147-48 (detailing a host of reasons to be skeptical of government's ability).
    • See generally Kysar, supra note 8, at 2147-48 (detailing a host of reasons to be skeptical of government's ability).
  • 452
    • 44649104284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JAMES M. BUCHANAN & GORDON TULLOCK, THE CALCULUS OF CONSENT: LOGICAL
    • JAMES M. BUCHANAN & GORDON TULLOCK, THE CALCULUS OF CONSENT: LOGICAL FOUNDATIONS OF CONSTITUTIONAL DEMOCRACY (1962). Cf. JERRY L. MASHAW, GREED, CHAOS, AND GOVERNANCE: USING PUBLIC CHOICE TO IMPROVE PUBLIC LAW (1997);
  • 454
    • 65349114217 scopus 로고
    • The Jurisprudence of Public Choice, 65
    • Daniel A. Farber & Philip E. Frickey, The Jurisprudence of Public Choice, 65 TEX. L. REV. 873 (1987);
    • (1987) TEX. L. REV , vol.873
    • Farber, D.A.1    Frickey, P.E.2
  • 455
    • 44649200303 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mark Kelman, On Democracy-Bashing: A Skeptical Look at the Theoretical and Empirical Practices of the Public Choice Movement, 74 VA. L. REV. (1988).
    • Mark Kelman, On Democracy-Bashing: A Skeptical Look at the Theoretical and "Empirical " Practices of the Public Choice Movement, 74 VA. L. REV. (1988).
  • 456
    • 44649146295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JIM VALLETTE & STEVE KRETZMANN, THE ENERGY TUG-OF-WAR: THE WINNERS AND LOSERS OF WORLD BANK FOSSIL FUEL FINANCE 2 (2004) (chiding the World Bank for funding projects benefiting Northern fossil fuel corporations).
    • See, e.g., JIM VALLETTE & STEVE KRETZMANN, THE ENERGY TUG-OF-WAR: THE WINNERS AND LOSERS OF WORLD BANK FOSSIL FUEL FINANCE 2 (2004) (chiding the World Bank for funding projects benefiting "Northern fossil fuel corporations").
  • 457
    • 33745254225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Irreversible and Catastrophic, 91
    • stating that public resistance to paying now to reduce future risks fits standard claims about discounting, See
    • See Cass Sunstein, Irreversible and Catastrophic, 91 CORNELL L. REV. 841, 864 (2006) (stating that public resistance to paying now to reduce future risks fits standard claims about discounting).
    • (2006) CORNELL L. REV , vol.841 , pp. 864
    • Sunstein, C.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.