메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 121, Issue 4, 2008, Pages 1195-1214

Fixing medical malpractice through health insurer enterprise liability
[No Author Info available]

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 40749090337     PISSN: 0017811X     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (6)

References (134)
  • 1
    • 40749103529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Daniel P. Kessler, Evaluating the U.S. Malpractice System and Paths to Its Reform 2 (Dec. 2006) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Harvard Law School Library).
    • Daniel P. Kessler, Evaluating the U.S. Malpractice System and Paths to Its Reform 2 (Dec. 2006) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Harvard Law School Library).
  • 2
    • 40749140490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paul C. Weiler, Reforming Medical Malpractice in a Radically Moderate - and Ethical - Fashion, 54 DEPAUL L. REV. 205, 215 (2005) ([T]here is just one paid malpractice claim for every twenty-one negligent medical injuries, and just one for every eight serious or fatal injuries.). Professor Richard Epstein provides a different take on Professor Paul Weiler's numbers, pointing out that there is no reason to believe that all, or even most, of the relatively few paid claims come from the pool of negligently injured patients, making the system not only undercompensatory but also inaccurate.
    • Paul C. Weiler, Reforming Medical Malpractice in a Radically Moderate - and Ethical - Fashion, 54 DEPAUL L. REV. 205, 215 (2005) ("[T]here is just one paid malpractice claim for every twenty-one negligent medical injuries, and just one for every eight serious or fatal injuries."). Professor Richard Epstein provides a different take on Professor Paul Weiler's numbers, pointing out that there is no reason to believe that all, or even most, of the relatively few paid claims come from the pool of negligently injured patients, making the system not only undercompensatory but also inaccurate.
  • 3
    • 77950553920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contractual Principle Versus Legislative Fixes: Coming to Closure on the Unending Travails of Medical Malpractice, 54
    • Richard A. Epstein, Contractual Principle Versus Legislative Fixes: Coming to Closure on the Unending Travails of Medical Malpractice, 54 DEPAUL L. REV. 503, 512 (2005).
    • (2005) DEPAUL L. REV , vol.503 , pp. 512
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 4
    • 14644422207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Richard E. Anderson, Effective Legal Reform and the Malpractice Insurance Crisis, 5 YALE J. HEALTH POL'Y L. & ETHICS 343 (2005);
    • See, e.g., Richard E. Anderson, Effective Legal Reform and the Malpractice Insurance Crisis, 5 YALE J. HEALTH POL'Y L. & ETHICS 343 (2005);
  • 5
    • 0038699588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The New Medical Malpractice Crisis, 348
    • describing eighteen states as in crisis
    • Michelle M. Mello, David M. Studdert & Troyen A. Brennan, The New Medical Malpractice Crisis, 348 NEW ENG. J. MED. 2281, 2281 (2003) (describing eighteen states as "in crisis");
    • (2003) NEW ENG. J. MED , vol.2281 , pp. 2281
    • Mello, M.M.1    Studdert, D.M.2    Brennan, T.A.3
  • 6
    • 40749113336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Current Medical Malpractice Crisis: The Need for Reform To Ensure a Tomorrow for Oregon's Obstetricians, 84
    • Lindsay J. Stamm, Comment, The Current Medical Malpractice Crisis: The Need for Reform To Ensure a Tomorrow for Oregon's Obstetricians, 84 OR. L. REV. 283 (2005);
    • (2005) OR. L. REV , vol.283
    • Lindsay, J.1    Stamm, C.2
  • 7
    • 3242699668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kenneth E. Thorpe, The Medical Malpractice 'Crisis': Recent Trends and the Impact of State Tort Reforms, HEALTH AFF. WEB EXCLUSIVE, Jan. 21, 2004, http://content.healthaffairs. org/cgi/reprint/hlthaff.w4.20. A Westlaw search for TI(malpractice & crisis) yielded fifty-two results in the Journals & Law Reviews database as of November 9, 2007.
    • Kenneth E. Thorpe, The Medical Malpractice 'Crisis': Recent Trends and the Impact of State Tort Reforms, HEALTH AFF. WEB EXCLUSIVE, Jan. 21, 2004, http://content.healthaffairs. org/cgi/reprint/hlthaff.w4.20. A Westlaw search for "TI(malpractice & crisis)" yielded fifty-two results in the "Journals & Law Reviews" database as of November 9, 2007.
  • 8
    • 40749154120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thorpe, supra note 3, at W4-22 to W4-24
    • Thorpe, supra note 3, at W4-22 to W4-24.
  • 9
    • 40749117806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Weiler, supra note 2
    • See, e.g., Weiler, supra note 2.
  • 10
    • 40749102270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Epstein, supra note 2
    • See, e.g., Epstein, supra note 2.
  • 11
    • 0001011413 scopus 로고
    • Enterprise Medical Liability and the Evolution of the American Health Care System, 108
    • Kenneth S. Abraham & Paul C. Weiler, Enterprise Medical Liability and the Evolution of the American Health Care System, 108 HARV. L. REV. 381 (1994).
    • (1994) HARV. L. REV , vol.381
    • Abraham, K.S.1    Weiler, P.C.2
  • 12
    • 19644384380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Defensive Medicine Among High-Risk Specialist Physicians in a Volatile Malpractice Environment, 293
    • David M. Studdert et al., Defensive Medicine Among High-Risk Specialist Physicians in a Volatile Malpractice Environment, 293 JAMA 2609, 2609 (2005).
    • (2005) JAMA , vol.2609 , pp. 2609
    • Studdert, D.M.1
  • 13
    • 40749099171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 14
    • 40749094629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2612
    • Id. at 2612.
  • 15
    • 40749098757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 16
    • 40749148249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AM. MED. ASS'N, MEDICAL LIABILITY REFORM - NOW! 8 (2006), available at http://ama-assn.org/ama1/pub/upload/mm/-1/mlrnow.pdf.
    • AM. MED. ASS'N, MEDICAL LIABILITY REFORM - NOW! 8 (2006), available at http://ama-assn.org/ama1/pub/upload/mm/-1/mlrnow.pdf.
  • 17
    • 0025422527 scopus 로고
    • Experience Rating: Does It Make Sense for Medical Malpractice Insurance?, 80
    • Frank A. Sloan, Experience Rating: Does It Make Sense for Medical Malpractice Insurance?, 80 AM. ECON. REV. 128, 128 (1990).
    • (1990) AM. ECON. REV , vol.128 , pp. 128
    • Sloan, F.A.1
  • 19
    • 40749158106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 20
    • 40749083713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 129
    • Id. at 129.
  • 21
    • 40749118659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 22
    • 40749109993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Low-dollar-value and old claims were excluded because their relevance to current risk was unclear. Id. at 128.
    • Low-dollar-value and old claims were excluded because their relevance to current risk was unclear. Id. at 128.
  • 23
    • 40749099172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 128-29
    • Id. at 128-29.
  • 24
    • 40749102681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 132
    • Id. at 132.
  • 25
    • 40749093427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 26
    • 40749126928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. The comparatively astronomical increase in claims frequency since Professor Sloan wrote in 1990 can only fortify this point.
    • Id. The comparatively astronomical increase in claims frequency since Professor Sloan wrote in 1990 can only fortify this point.
  • 27
    • 40749105887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 129-30
    • Id. at 129-30.
  • 28
    • 40749161066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 29
    • 40749140886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One could question whether physicians subject to frequent judgments ought to be forced out of business or into another practice demographic, and the answer would depend on the specificity of the court system. If malpractice judgments correctly target negligence on the part of the physician, then the answer is yes. If, however, judgments are highly correlated with other factors, such as the underlying risk of the patient, then the answer is more complicated; in that case, experience rating would remove cross-subsidization effects, which, while economically inefficient, might have equality or fairness effects that one may want to take into consideration
    • One could question whether physicians subject to frequent judgments ought to be forced out of business or into another practice demographic, and the answer would depend on the specificity of the court system. If malpractice judgments correctly target negligence on the part of the physician, then the answer is yes. If, however, judgments are highly correlated with other factors, such as the underlying risk of the patient, then the answer is more complicated; in that case, experience rating would remove cross-subsidization effects, which, while economically inefficient, might have equality or fairness effects that one may want to take into consideration.
  • 30
    • 40749097876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 401-02.
    • See Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 401-02.
  • 31
    • 40749128633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 32
    • 0034933365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • No-Fault Compensation for Medical Injuries: The Prospect for Error Prevention, 286
    • David M. Studdert & Troyen A. Brennan, No-Fault Compensation for Medical Injuries: The Prospect for Error Prevention, 286 JAMA 217, 217-18 (2001).
    • (2001) JAMA , vol.217 , pp. 217-218
    • Studdert, D.M.1    Brennan, T.A.2
  • 33
    • 40749099565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 218
    • Id. at 218.
  • 34
    • 40749157294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is a reference to the informational asymmetry problem in which healthy subscribers drop from a plan, which causes premiums to rise, which in turn causes more healthy subscribers to drop, which causes premiums to rise again, and so on
    • This is a reference to the informational asymmetry problem in which healthy subscribers drop from a plan, which causes premiums to rise, which in turn causes more healthy subscribers to drop, which causes premiums to rise again, and so on.
  • 35
    • 40749112909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 7. Under their proposal, hospitals may contract with insurers to allow insurers to finance malpractice costs. Id. at
    • Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7. Under their proposal, hospitals may contract with insurers to allow insurers to finance malpractice costs. Id. at 419.
    • supra , pp. 419
    • Abraham1    Weiler2
  • 36
    • 40749157699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 400
    • Id. at 400.
  • 37
    • 40749091810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 38
    • 40749130584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 39
    • 40749133920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 402-03. Some physicians decline to purchase any liability insurance at all, instead deciding to make themselves judgment-proof by transferring assets to relatives.
    • Id. at 402-03. Some physicians decline to purchase any liability insurance at all, instead deciding to make themselves judgment-proof by transferring assets to relatives.
  • 40
    • 40749132312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 403 n.81.
    • Id. at 403 n.81.
  • 41
    • 40749136757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 403
    • Id. at 403.
  • 42
    • 40749136463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 402. The small size is the result of the fact that insurance pools are limited to a single state and subdivided by specialty. Thus, the maximum number of physicians in a pool would be the number of specialists in the state. Competition between insurers drastically reduces that number, so the end result is that insurance pools are small when compared with the size of an average hospital
    • Id. at 402. The small size is the result of the fact that insurance pools are limited to a single state and subdivided by specialty. Thus, the maximum number of physicians in a pool would be the number of specialists in the state. Competition between insurers drastically reduces that number, so the end result is that insurance pools are small when compared with the size of an average hospital.
  • 43
    • 40749147819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 401-02
    • Id. at 401-02.
  • 46
    • 40749086947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. What this reasoning does not take into account is that enterprise liability would involve a single defendant, whereas under the current system there are multiple defendants with divergent interests. This effect cuts in both directions; however, it is likely that the strength of a unified defense would outweigh the rare cases in which there is not enough evidence to find any particular defendant liable but it is clear that one of them did something wrong, a problem that the doctrine of res ipsa loquitur attempts to mitigate. In any event, this Note does not address the problem of differential damages because it assumes that juries can adequately assess the proper damages for pain and suffering. Capping these damages would lead to suboptimal deterrence, so it should be done only for a compelling reason. A desire to maintain the status quo in terms of damage awards is not a compelling reason
    • Id. What this reasoning does not take into account is that enterprise liability would involve a single defendant, whereas under the current system there are multiple defendants with divergent interests. This effect cuts in both directions; however, it is likely that the strength of a unified defense would outweigh the rare cases in which there is not enough evidence to find any particular defendant liable but it is clear that one of them did something wrong - a problem that the doctrine of res ipsa loquitur attempts to mitigate. In any event, this Note does not address the problem of differential damages because it assumes that juries can adequately assess the proper damages for pain and suffering. Capping these damages would lead to suboptimal deterrence, so it should be done only for a compelling reason. A desire to maintain the status quo in terms of damage awards is not a compelling reason.
  • 47
    • 40749098273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 406
    • Id. at 406.
  • 48
    • 40749152043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 406 & n.92.
    • Id. at 406 & n.92.
  • 49
    • 40749133125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 410
    • Id. at 410.
  • 50
    • 40749138791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 411
    • Id. at 411.
  • 51
    • 40749134747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 411-12. The recommendations included mechanized monitors for the patients' respiration, circulation, and oxygen saturation; an alarm that sounded when vitals reached dangerous levels; and the presence of trained personnel at all times.
    • Id. at 411-12. The recommendations included mechanized monitors for the patients' respiration, circulation, and oxygen saturation; an alarm that sounded when vitals reached dangerous levels; and the presence of trained personnel at all times.
  • 52
    • 40749083320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 411 n.115.
    • Id. at 411 n.115.
  • 53
    • 40749137555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 412-13
    • Id. at 412-13.
  • 54
    • 40749109994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 410
    • Id. at 410.
  • 55
    • 0001490331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Health Plans Accountable for the Quality of Care, 31
    • Clark C. Havighurst, Making Health Plans Accountable for the Quality of Care, 31 GA. L. REV. 587, 587-88 (1997).
    • (1997) GA. L. REV , vol.587 , pp. 587-588
    • Havighurst, C.C.1
  • 56
    • 40749111198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 607
    • Id. at 607.
  • 57
    • 40749099977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 587
    • Id. at 587.
  • 58
    • 40749129457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 435. It should be noted that enterprise liability is practically a predicate for no-fault liability; without enterprise liability, no-fault liability fails to realize deterrence gains.
    • Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 435. It should be noted that enterprise liability is practically a predicate for no-fault liability; without enterprise liability, no-fault liability fails to realize deterrence gains.
  • 59
    • 40749098758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weiler, supra note 2, at 227
    • Weiler, supra note 2, at 227.
  • 60
    • 40749085809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 61
    • 40749124188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 227-28. Professor Weiler notes that the wealthy would be able to purchase disability insurance.
    • Id. at 227-28. Professor Weiler notes that the wealthy would be able to purchase disability insurance.
  • 62
    • 40749111645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 228. Without significant reforms, wage reimbursement in a no-fault regime would be regressive because the rich would not be charged more for care than the poor would be charged, even though their economic damages would be much larger. Even Professor Weiler's hospital enterprise liability system does not alleviate this problem, as hospitals have no way of charging the wealthy more for no-fault insurance. It should be noted that, though this Note does not advocate for a no-fault regime, holding the insurer exclusively liable in a no-fault matter could avoid regressive consequences, as the insurer can easily charge the wealthy more by tailoring premiums to salary or adjusting the reimbursement limit and, in this case, it would have a strong financial incentive to do so
    • Id. at 228. Without significant reforms, wage reimbursement in a no-fault regime would be regressive because the rich would not be charged more for care than the poor would be charged, even though their economic damages would be much larger. Even Professor Weiler's hospital enterprise liability system does not alleviate this problem, as hospitals have no way of charging the wealthy more for no-fault insurance. It should be noted that - though this Note does not advocate for a no-fault regime - holding the insurer exclusively liable in a no-fault matter could avoid regressive consequences, as the insurer can easily charge the wealthy more by tailoring premiums to salary or adjusting the reimbursement limit and, in this case, it would have a strong financial incentive to do so.
  • 65
    • 40749116195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Second, overall reimbursement might increase drastically. If the sixty-twenty ratio is to be believed, overall costs would rise unless the value of compensated injures rose by a factor lower than three. Given the breadth of no-fault insurance, and the significant number of negligence injuries that currently slip through the cracks, overall compensation amounts would almost assuredly rise. However, Professor Weiler points out that the additional compensation might not be a large fraction of the U.S. healthcare budget, which is over $1.4 trillion.
    • Id. Second, overall reimbursement might increase drastically. If the sixty-twenty ratio is to be believed, overall costs would rise unless the value of compensated injures rose by a factor lower than three. Given the breadth of no-fault insurance, and the significant number of negligence injuries that currently slip through the cracks, overall compensation amounts would almost assuredly rise. However, Professor Weiler points out that the additional compensation might not be a large fraction of the U.S. healthcare budget, which is over $1.4 trillion.
  • 66
    • 40749152884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 227
    • Id. at 227.
  • 67
    • 40749133123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Studdert & Brennan, supra note 27
    • See Studdert & Brennan, supra note 27.
  • 69
    • 40749153690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 70
    • 40749088237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 220
    • Id. at 220.
  • 72
    • 40749103531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id., though the increased number of claims would undoubtedly increase the statistical power.
    • id., though the increased number of claims would undoubtedly increase the statistical power.
  • 73
    • 40749150837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein, supra note 2. Professor Epstein's argument is a response to Professor Weiler's advocacy of no-fault insurance.
    • Epstein, supra note 2. Professor Epstein's argument is a response to Professor Weiler's advocacy of no-fault insurance.
  • 74
    • 40749130160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 519
    • Id. at 519.
  • 75
    • 40749109545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 520
    • Id. at 520.
  • 77
    • 40749145015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 78
    • 40749111646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 79
    • 40749154534 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. However, Professors Studdert et al. report a moderately successful outcome in an analysis of Florida's obstetric neurological injury no-fault regime, although they also note a significant number of concerns, primarily with patients' filing malpractice cases in addition to no-fault claims.
    • Id. However, Professors Studdert et al. report a moderately successful outcome in an analysis of Florida's obstetric neurological injury no-fault regime, although they also note a significant number of concerns, primarily with patients' filing malpractice cases in addition to no-fault claims.
  • 80
    • 0033945634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David M. Studdert, Lori A. Fritz & Troyen A. Brennan, The Jury Is Still In: Florida's Birth-Related Neurological Injury Compensation Plan After a Decade, 25 J. HEALTH POL. POL'Y & L. 499, 516-20 (2000).
    • See David M. Studdert, Lori A. Fritz & Troyen A. Brennan, The Jury Is Still In: Florida's Birth-Related Neurological Injury Compensation Plan After a Decade, 25 J. HEALTH POL. POL'Y & L. 499, 516-20 (2000).
  • 81
    • 40749131008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein, supra note 2, at 519
    • Epstein, supra note 2, at 519.
  • 82
    • 40749117401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 83
    • 40749126926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 520
    • Id. at 520.
  • 84
    • 40749149328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 509
    • Id. at 509.
  • 85
    • 40749137138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 508
    • Id. at 508.
  • 86
    • 40749107599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 512-13
    • Id. at 512-13.
  • 87
    • 40749101188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 513-14
    • Id. at 513-14.
  • 88
    • 0022673633 scopus 로고
    • Medical Malpractice, Imperfect Information, and the Contractual Foundation for Medical Services
    • spring, at
    • Richard Epstein, Medical Malpractice, Imperfect Information, and the Contractual Foundation for Medical Services, LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS., spring 1986, at 201, 205.
    • (1986) LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS
    • Epstein, R.1
  • 89
    • 40749140086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 207
    • Id. at 207.
  • 90
    • 40749126927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 91
    • 40749137930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 92
    • 40749103073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 209
    • Id. at 209.
  • 93
    • 40749153278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (citing PATRICIA M. DANZON, MEDICAL MALPRACTICE: THEORY, EVIDENCE, AND PUBLIC POLICY 187 (1985)).
    • Id. (citing PATRICIA M. DANZON, MEDICAL MALPRACTICE: THEORY, EVIDENCE, AND PUBLIC POLICY 187 (1985)).
  • 94
    • 40749132713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CAL. CIV. CODE § 3333.2 (West 2007).
    • CAL. CIV. CODE § 3333.2 (West 2007).
  • 96
    • 33645374345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Amanda Edwards, Recent Development, Medical Malpractice Non-Economic Damages Caps, 43 HARV. J. ON LEGIS. 213, 216-18 (2006).
    • See Amanda Edwards, Recent Development, Medical Malpractice Non-Economic Damages Caps, 43 HARV. J. ON LEGIS. 213, 216-18 (2006).
  • 97
    • 40749145464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thorpe, supra note 3, at W4-25
    • Thorpe, supra note 3, at W4-25.
  • 98
    • 40749129458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at W4-26
    • Id. at W4-26.
  • 99
    • 40749133124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mello et al., supra note 3, at 2283-84 (questioning whether the conclusion that damage caps reduce premiums is justified given that the relevant studies are based on data from earlier eras and present mixed findings).
    • See Mello et al., supra note 3, at 2283-84 (questioning whether the conclusion that damage caps reduce premiums is justified given that the relevant studies "are based on data from earlier eras and present mixed findings").
  • 100
    • 40749084163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 101
    • 40749160649 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kenneth S. Reinker & David Rosenberg, Improving Medical Malpractice Liability by Allowing Insurers To Take Charge (John M. Olin Ctr. for Law, Econ., & Bus., Harvard Law Sch., Discussion Paper No. 556, 2006), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 923424.
    • Kenneth S. Reinker & David Rosenberg, Improving Medical Malpractice Liability by Allowing Insurers To Take Charge (John M. Olin Ctr. for Law, Econ., & Bus., Harvard Law Sch., Discussion Paper No. 556, 2006), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 923424.
  • 102
    • 40749147383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 5
    • Id. at 5.
  • 103
    • 40749105886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 20
    • Id. at 20.
  • 104
    • 40749151247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 17
    • Id. at 17.
  • 105
    • 40749148666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 16-17
    • Id. at 16-17.
  • 106
    • 40749110402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It should be noted that the difference between the second and third options is that, in the case of reckless or intentional conduct on the part of the physician, the second would not cover any liability, whereas the third would cover the compensatory but not the punitive damages
    • It should be noted that the difference between the second and third options is that, in the case of reckless or intentional conduct on the part of the physician, the second would not cover any liability, whereas the third would cover the compensatory but not the punitive damages.
  • 107
    • 40749088238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Limits on noneconomic damages, for example, do not provide a reliable proxy because they remove liability altogether instead of shifting it from one regime to another
    • Limits on noneconomic damages, for example, do not provide a reliable proxy because they remove liability altogether instead of shifting it from one regime to another.
  • 108
    • 40749091416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James W. Childs, Jr., Comment, You May Be Willing, but Are You Able?: A Critical Analysis of Any Willing Provider Legislation, 27 CUMB. L. REV. 199, 199-200 (1997). Some any-willing-provider laws apply only to pharmacies.
    • James W. Childs, Jr., Comment, You May Be Willing, but Are You Able?: A Critical Analysis of "Any Willing Provider" Legislation, 27 CUMB. L. REV. 199, 199-200 (1997). Some any-willing-provider laws apply only to pharmacies.
  • 109
    • 40749162912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 200 n.3. Laws so limited make more sense than laws that apply to all health providers, as pharmaceuticals are much more of a commodity than healthcare services are.
    • Id. at 200 n.3. Laws so limited make more sense than laws that apply to all health providers, as pharmaceuticals are much more of a commodity than healthcare services are.
  • 110
    • 40749086948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 212-13
    • Id. at 212-13.
  • 111
    • 40749095755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 213
    • Id. at 213.
  • 112
    • 40749118660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 200
    • Id. at 200.
  • 113
    • 40749145858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is unclear whether a third party insurance market would even be viable in the face of a lemon stigma that would be associated with the search for supplemental coverage. Presumably, the health insurer is in possession of better information, so physicians with low coverage would be lemons and extremely expensive to insure. This would likely trigger the vicious cycle that unfortunately plagues many insurance markets where the premiums go up, causing the lower risk physicians to drop, which causes the premiums to go up, and so on. Alternatively, it might be more efficient for another company to insure the doctor. If this efficiency outweighs the benefits of placing the risk on the health insurer, then the entire regime advocated by this Note is inefficient; thus, this Note assumes that this is not the case
    • It is unclear whether a third party insurance market would even be viable in the face of a "lemon" stigma that would be associated with the search for supplemental coverage. Presumably, the health insurer is in possession of better information, so physicians with low coverage would be "lemons" and extremely expensive to insure. This would likely trigger the vicious cycle that unfortunately plagues many insurance markets where the premiums go up, causing the lower risk physicians to drop, which causes the premiums to go up, and so on. Alternatively, it might be more efficient for another company to insure the doctor. If this efficiency outweighs the benefits of placing the risk on the health insurer, then the entire regime advocated by this Note is inefficient; thus, this Note assumes that this is not the case.
  • 114
    • 40749161673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 419-20
    • Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 419-20.
  • 115
    • 40749116661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 116
    • 40749117071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra p. 1194.
    • See supra p. 1194.
  • 117
    • 40749093837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 396
    • Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 396.
  • 118
    • 40749090575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Havighurst, supra note 45, at 591
    • See Havighurst, supra note 45, at 591.
  • 119
    • 40749106751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 410
    • See Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 410.
  • 120
    • 40749142890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Studdert & Brennan, supra note 27, at 221-22
    • See Studdert & Brennan, supra note 27, at 221-22.
  • 121
    • 40749137929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Havighurst, supra note 45, at 610 ([I]n most cases MCOs will be held liable for physician negligence only if the plaintiff makes an additional factual showing - which an MCO can make more difficult by distancing itself from its physicians and prominently disavowing any agency relationship with, or any warranty concerning, providers of any kind. (footnote omitted)).
    • Havighurst, supra note 45, at 610 ("[I]n most cases MCOs will be held liable for physician negligence only if the plaintiff makes an additional factual showing - which an MCO can make more difficult by distancing itself from its physicians and prominently disavowing any agency relationship with, or any warranty concerning, providers of any kind." (footnote omitted)).
  • 122
    • 40749097029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professors Abraham & Weiler say the solution to this problem is to determine with which hospital the physician is principally affiliated, a system which is currently used in New York for supplementary physician coverage. Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 421-22. The danger of this idea is difficult to overstate. It makes physicians with principal privileges at other hospitals extremely desirable, and it could cause large hospitals to cross-subsidize small ones or eliminate multiple privilege rights altogether.
    • Professors Abraham & Weiler say the solution to this problem is to determine with which hospital the physician is principally affiliated, a system which is currently used in New York for supplementary physician coverage. Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 421-22. The danger of this idea is difficult to overstate. It makes physicians with principal privileges at other hospitals extremely desirable, and it could cause large hospitals to cross-subsidize small ones or eliminate multiple privilege rights altogether.
  • 123
    • 40749146130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra pp. 1196-97.
    • See supra pp. 1196-97.
  • 124
    • 40749109992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One interesting inquiry is whether this would have a cross-subsidization effect, with low-risk specialties, such as dermatology, subsidizing the high-risk ones like obstetrics. The answer is probably not. In a competitive market, if one insurer is underpaying dermatologists, dermatologists will likely drop that insurer and seek one with a higher reimbursement. It does, however, seem paradoxical that the health insurer can better spread risk without spreading it between different specialties. Part of the solution may lie in the fact that there could be fewer health insurers than malpractice insurers, especially when the pools are separated by state lines. For example, in 1985 the number of neurologists and neurosurgeons in Florida, a relatively large state, was only about 500, see Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 401 n.77 citing David J. Nye et al, The Causes of the Medical Malpractice Crisis: An Analysis of Claims Data and Insurance Company Finances, 76 G
    • One interesting inquiry is whether this would have a cross-subsidization effect, with low-risk specialties, such as dermatology, subsidizing the high-risk ones like obstetrics. The answer is probably not. In a competitive market, if one insurer is underpaying dermatologists, dermatologists will likely drop that insurer and seek one with a higher reimbursement. It does, however, seem paradoxical that the health insurer can better spread risk without spreading it between different specialties. Part of the solution may lie in the fact that there could be fewer health insurers than malpractice insurers, especially when the pools are separated by state lines. For example, in 1985 the number of neurologists and neurosurgeons in Florida, a relatively large state, was only about 500, see Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 401 n.77 (citing David J. Nye et al., The Causes of the Medical Malpractice Crisis: An Analysis of Claims Data and Insurance Company Finances, 76 GEO. L.J. 1495, 1532 (1988)), so pools must have been very small when divided among the individual malpractice insurers. It should be noted that Professors Abraham and Weiler believe that enterprise liability would cause some cross-subsidization between specialties and that that may be a good thing, as the cost is spread among the patient population anyway.
  • 126
    • 40749107598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hence, the risk is optimally placed on health insurers, given the government's questionable ability to respond to financial incentives
    • Hence, the risk is optimally placed on health insurers, given the government's questionable ability to respond to financial incentives.
  • 127
    • 40749093426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra p. 1199.
    • See supra p. 1199.
  • 128
    • 40749162103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 412
    • Abraham & Weiler, supra note 7, at 412.
  • 129
    • 40749133501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 406
    • Id. at 406.
  • 131
    • 40749086110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A third option is to mandate health insurance, eliminating the uninsured and this problem
    • A third option is to mandate health insurance, eliminating the uninsured and this problem.
  • 132
    • 0036172884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This would not be the case if physicians rendered inferior care to the uninsured; however, empirical research into differential treatment of patients based on HMO market penetration suggests that the ability of physicians to modify their behavior when the patient population is heterogeneous may be severely limited. Sherry Glied & Joshua Graff Zivin, How Do Doctors Behave When Some (but Not All) of Their Patients Are in Managed Care, 21 J. HEALTH ECON. 337, 352 2002, The result is only strengthened when one assumes that the majority of innovations are going to be systematic
    • This would not be the case if physicians rendered inferior care to the uninsured; however, empirical research into differential treatment of patients based on HMO market penetration suggests that "the ability of physicians to modify their behavior when the patient population is heterogeneous may be severely limited." Sherry Glied & Joshua Graff Zivin, How Do Doctors Behave When Some (but Not All) of Their Patients Are in Managed Care?, 21 J. HEALTH ECON. 337, 352 (2002). The result is only strengthened when one assumes that the majority of innovations are going to be systematic.
  • 133
    • 1542752829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jack Hadley & John Holahan, How Much Medical Care Do the Uninsured Use, and Who Pays for It?, HEALTH AFF. WEB EXCLUSIVE, Feb. 12, 2003, http://content.healthaffairs. org/cgi/reprint/hlthaff.W3.66v1 (estimating that the uninsured pay for only sixty-five percent of the care they receive).
    • See Jack Hadley & John Holahan, How Much Medical Care Do the Uninsured Use, and Who Pays for It?, HEALTH AFF. WEB EXCLUSIVE, Feb. 12, 2003, http://content.healthaffairs. org/cgi/reprint/hlthaff.W3.66v1 (estimating that the uninsured pay for only sixty-five percent of the care they receive).
  • 134
    • 40749162102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A physician's only incentive is the desire to avoid reputational damage and wasted time in litigation. Though significant, this is substantially less than the penalty for negligently killing or disabling someone.
    • A physician's only incentive is the desire to avoid reputational damage and wasted time in litigation. Though significant, this is substantially less than the penalty for negligently killing or disabling someone.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.