메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 60, Issue 2, 2007, Pages 633-655

Controlling family shareholders in developing countries: Anchoring relational exchange

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 38749128425     PISSN: 00389765     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (64)

References (87)
  • 1
    • 33646419798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Controlling Shareholders and Corporate Governance: Complicating the Comparative Taxonomy, 119
    • surveys this development
    • Ronald J. Gilson, Controlling Shareholders and Corporate Governance: Complicating the Comparative Taxonomy, 119 HARV. L. REV. 1641 (2006), surveys this development.
    • (2006) HARV. L. REV , vol.1641
    • Gilson, R.J.1
  • 2
    • 38749116641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Governance Reforms in Continental Europe, 21
    • describing recent reforms in European controlling shareholder systems, See
    • See Luca Enriques & Paolo Volpin, Corporate Governance Reforms in Continental Europe, 21 J. ECON. PERSP. 117 (2007) (describing recent reforms in European controlling shareholder systems).
    • (2007) J. ECON. PERSP , vol.117
    • Enriques, L.1    Volpin, P.2
  • 3
    • 0000200532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stijn Claessens, Simeon Djankov, Joseph P. H. Fan & Larry H.P. Lang, Disentangling the Incentive and Entrenchment Effects of Large Shareholdings, 57 J. FIN. 2741, 2748, 2750 tbl.II (2002);
    • See Stijn Claessens, Simeon Djankov, Joseph P. H. Fan & Larry H.P. Lang, Disentangling the Incentive and Entrenchment Effects of Large Shareholdings, 57 J. FIN. 2741, 2748, 2750 tbl.II (2002);
  • 4
    • 0042829594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stijn Claessens, Simeon Djankov & Larry H.P. Lang, The Separation of Ownership and Control in East Asian Corporations, 58 J. FIN. ECON. 81, 92 & tbl.3, 93 (2000).
    • Stijn Claessens, Simeon Djankov & Larry H.P. Lang, The Separation of Ownership and Control in East Asian Corporations, 58 J. FIN. ECON. 81, 92 & tbl.3, 93 (2000).
  • 5
    • 0006761611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Ownership Around the World, 54
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes & Andrei Shleifer, Corporate Ownership Around the World, 54 J. FIN. 471 (1999);
    • (1999) J. FIN , vol.471
    • Rafael La Porta, F.L.-D.1    Shleifer, A.2
  • 7
    • 0003170891 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer & Robert Vishny, Investor Protection and Corporate Governance, 58 J. FIN. ECON. 3 (2000);
    • Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer & Robert Vishny, Investor Protection and Corporate Governance, 58 J. FIN. ECON. 3 (2000);
  • 8
    • 0001503097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal Determinants of External Finance, 52
    • Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer & Robert W. Vishny, Legal Determinants of External Finance, 52 J. FIN. 1131 (1997).
    • (1997) J. FIN , vol.1131
    • Rafael La Porta, F.L.-D.1    Shleifer, A.2    Vishny, R.W.3
  • 9
    • 38749104722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gilson, supra note 1, at 1649
    • See Gilson, supra note 1, at 1649.
  • 10
    • 1842445955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Benefits of Control: An International Comparison, 59
    • measuring differences by relative prices in control transactions, See
    • See Alexander Dyck & Luigi Zingales, Private Benefits of Control: An International Comparison, 59 J. FIN. 537 (2004) (measuring differences by relative prices in control transactions);
    • (2004) J. FIN , vol.537
    • Dyck, A.1    Zingales, L.2
  • 11
    • 0012533256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tatiana Nenova, The Value of Corporate Voting Rights and Control: A Cross-Country Analysis, 68 J. FIN. ECON. 325 (2003) (measuring relative differences in stock exchange trading prices). The price difference between controlling and non-controlling shares, however measured, is dramatically smaller in countries with good shareholder protection.
    • Tatiana Nenova, The Value of Corporate Voting Rights and Control: A Cross-Country Analysis, 68 J. FIN. ECON. 325 (2003) (measuring relative differences in stock exchange trading prices). The price difference between controlling and non-controlling shares, however measured, is dramatically smaller in countries with good shareholder protection.
  • 12
    • 38749124399 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I should be clear at the outset that my shorthand terms poor or bad commercial law encompass two different sources of failure: substantively bad law regardless of the quality of enforcement and substantively good law but with poor enforcement. Thus, a wonderful civil code that is not effectively enforced would fall within my terms
    • I should be clear at the outset that my shorthand terms "poor" or "bad" commercial law encompass two different sources of failure: substantively bad law regardless of the quality of enforcement and substantively good law but with poor enforcement. Thus, a wonderful civil code that is not effectively enforced would fall within my terms.
  • 13
    • 38749090203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., STEPHEN A. ROSS, RANDOLPH W. WESTERFIELD & JEFFREY JAFFE, CORPORATE FINANCE 407-09 (7th ed. 2005).
    • See, e.g., STEPHEN A. ROSS, RANDOLPH W. WESTERFIELD & JEFFREY JAFFE, CORPORATE FINANCE 407-09 (7th ed. 2005).
  • 14
    • 38749088361 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gilson, supra note 1, at 1651-52
    • Gilson, supra note 1, at 1651-52.
  • 15
    • 0142059676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John Shuhe Li states, In catching-up economies, there is generally no rule-based [formal enforcement] governance; hence relation-based governance is the only available mechanism to enforce agreements. John Shuhe Li, Relation-Based Versus Rule-Based Governance: An Explanation of the East Asian Miracle and Asian Crisis, 11 REV. INT'L ECON. 651, 658 (2003).
    • John Shuhe Li states, "In catching-up economies, there is generally no rule-based [formal enforcement] governance; hence relation-based governance is the only available mechanism to enforce agreements." John Shuhe Li, Relation-Based Versus Rule-Based Governance: An Explanation of the East Asian Miracle and Asian Crisis, 11 REV. INT'L ECON. 651, 658 (2003).
  • 16
    • 0001457802 scopus 로고
    • The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance, 89
    • See generally
    • See generally Benjamin Klein & Keith B. Leffler, The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance, 89 J. POL. ECON. 615 (1981);
    • (1981) J. POL. ECON , vol.615
    • Klein, B.1    Leffler, K.B.2
  • 17
    • 0002963088 scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements, 53
    • L.G. Telser, A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements, 53 J. BUS. 27 (1980).
    • (1980) J. BUS , vol.27
    • Telser, L.G.1
  • 18
    • 38749095931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interesting recent work has sought to link elements of corporate governance other than shareholder distribution to conditions in the product market. See, e.g, K.J. Martijn Cremers, Vinay B. Nair & Urs Peyer, Weak Shareholder Rights: A Product Market Rationale (Yale Int'l Ctr. for Fin, Working Paper No. 06-29, 2006, available at, discussing the relation between strength of shareholder rights and character of product market competition);
    • Interesting recent work has sought to link elements of corporate governance other than shareholder distribution to conditions in the product market. See, e.g., K.J. Martijn Cremers, Vinay B. Nair & Urs Peyer, Weak Shareholder Rights: A Product Market Rationale (Yale Int'l Ctr. for Fin., Working Paper No. 06-29, 2006), available at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=890570 (discussing the relation between strength of shareholder rights and character of product market competition);
  • 19
    • 38749120283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maria Guadalupe & Francisco Pérez-González, The Impact of Product Market Competition on Private Benefits of Control (Feb. 2006) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract= 890814 (discussing the impact of product market competition on private benefit extraction).
    • Maria Guadalupe & Francisco Pérez-González, The Impact of Product Market Competition on Private Benefits of Control (Feb. 2006) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract= 890814 (discussing the impact of product market competition on private benefit extraction).
  • 20
    • 38749090961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is a very interesting literature addressing the institutions necessary to support trade that is both formally sophisticated and historically grounded. The work of Avner Greif on the organization of the Maghribi traders and of Avner Greif, Paul Milgrom, and Barry Weingast on medieval European trade are examples of this work. See Avner Greif, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders, Coalition, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 525 1993, hereinafter Greif, Maghribi Traders' Coalition];
    • There is a very interesting literature addressing the institutions necessary to support trade that is both formally sophisticated and historically grounded. The work of Avner Greif on the organization of the Maghribi traders and of Avner Greif, Paul Milgrom, and Barry Weingast on medieval European trade are examples of this work. See Avner Greif, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders ' Coalition, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 525 (1993) [hereinafter Greif, Maghribi Traders' Coalition];
  • 21
    • 84863355400 scopus 로고
    • Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild, 102
    • Avner Greif, Paul Milgrom & Barry R. Weingast, Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild, 102 J. POL. ECON. 745 (1994).
    • (1994) J. POL. ECON , vol.745
    • Greif, A.1    Milgrom, P.2    Weingast, B.R.3
  • 22
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying note 47
    • See infra text accompanying note 47.
    • See infra
  • 23
    • 38749120638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Here I anticipate ongoing work with Curtis Milhaupt. See infra text accompanying note 54.
    • Here I anticipate ongoing work with Curtis Milhaupt. See infra text accompanying note 54.
  • 24
    • 38749084935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., AVINASH K. DIXIT, LAWLESSNESS AND ECONOMICS: ALTERNATIVE MODES OF GOVERNANCE 16-17 (2004).
    • See, e.g., AVINASH K. DIXIT, LAWLESSNESS AND ECONOMICS: ALTERNATIVE MODES OF GOVERNANCE 16-17 (2004).
  • 25
    • 38749144423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is the folk theorem of non-cooperative game theory. See, e.g, id. at 61; Drew Fudenberg & Eric Maskin, The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting or with Incomplete Information, 54 ECONOMETRICA 533 1986
    • This is the "folk theorem" of non-cooperative game theory. See, e.g., id. at 61; Drew Fudenberg & Eric Maskin, The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting or with Incomplete Information, 54 ECONOMETRICA 533 (1986).
  • 26
    • 0142139116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I develop similar conditions to reputation-based contracting in the venture capital market in Ronald J. Gilson, Engineering a Venture Capital Market: Lessons from the American Experience, 55 STAN. L. REV. 1067, 1086-87 2003
    • I develop similar conditions to reputation-based contracting in the venture capital market in Ronald J. Gilson, Engineering a Venture Capital Market: Lessons from the American Experience, 55 STAN. L. REV. 1067, 1086-87 (2003).
  • 27
    • 38749087976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Douglass North states the conditions in terms of the barriers they present: exchange is difficult to sustain when the game is not repeated (or there is an end game), when information on the other players is lacking, and when there are large numbers of players. DOUGLASS C. NORTH, INSTITUTIONS, INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 12 (1990). The discussion in the text assumes the condition that MacLeod and Malcomson specify as necessary before the game is worth the candle: The fundamental requirement for an implicit contract to be self-enforcing is that there exist sufficient economic surplus from continuing it over what the parties can jointly get if it is terminated.
    • Douglass North states the conditions in terms of the barriers they present: exchange "is difficult to sustain when the game is not repeated (or there is an end game), when information on the other players is lacking, and when there are large numbers of players." DOUGLASS C. NORTH, INSTITUTIONS, INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 12 (1990). The discussion in the text assumes the condition that MacLeod and Malcomson specify as necessary before the game is worth the candle: "The fundamental requirement for an implicit contract to be self-enforcing is that there exist sufficient economic surplus from continuing it over what the parties can jointly get if it is terminated."
  • 28
    • 38749099496 scopus 로고
    • Implicit Contracts, Incentive Compatibility, and Involuntary Unemployment, 57
    • W. Bentley MacLeod & James M. Malcomson, Implicit Contracts, Incentive Compatibility, and Involuntary Unemployment, 57 ECONOMETRICA 447, 448 (1989).
    • (1989) ECONOMETRICA , vol.447 , pp. 448
    • Bentley MacLeod, W.1    Malcomson, J.M.2
  • 29
    • 38749085319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DIXIT, supra note 14, at 67-71
    • DIXIT, supra note 14, at 67-71.
  • 30
    • 38749138520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cultural beliefs and behavioral norms coordinate expectations and provide a shared understanding of the meaning of various actions. Avner Greif, Commitment, Coercion, and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange, in HANDBOOK OF NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS 727, 762 (Claude Menard & Mary M. Shirley eds., 2005);
    • "Cultural beliefs and behavioral norms coordinate expectations and provide a shared understanding of the meaning of various actions." Avner Greif, Commitment, Coercion, and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange, in HANDBOOK OF NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS 727, 762 (Claude Menard & Mary M. Shirley eds., 2005);
  • 31
    • 38749149212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Markus Mobius & Adam Szeidl, Trust and Social Collateral (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 13126, 2007) (modeling a decrease in trust among trading partners in a reputation market as the heterogeneity of potential trading partners increases).
    • see Markus Mobius & Adam Szeidl, Trust and Social Collateral (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 13126, 2007) (modeling a decrease in trust among trading partners in a reputation market as the heterogeneity of potential trading partners increases).
  • 32
    • 38749091741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DIXIT, supra note 14, at 70
    • DIXIT, supra note 14, at 70.
  • 33
    • 11244292154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This account assumes that misbehavior is punished only by individuals-the injured trading partner and those who learn of the misbehavior-who decline to trade with the misbehaving trader. However, reputation markets can develop institutions that facilitate the market's operation by collectivizing information acquisition and sharing, and expanding the breadth of responsive sanctions. See Greif, supra note 18, at 733-34 (discussing [o]rganic, multilateral reputation institutions, Barak D. Richman, Firms, Courts, and Reputation Mechanisms: Towards a Positive Theory of Private Ordering, 104 COLUM. L. REV. 2328, 2338-50 2004, contrasting the circumstances that underlie the choice of enforcing a contract through firms, courts, or private organizations, Because of the path dependency of institutional characteristics in particular jurisdictions, an account of their development requires a rich historical context
    • This account assumes that misbehavior is punished only by individuals-the injured trading partner and those who learn of the misbehavior-who decline to trade with the misbehaving trader. However, reputation markets can develop institutions that facilitate the market's operation by collectivizing information acquisition and sharing, and expanding the breadth of responsive sanctions. See Greif, supra note 18, at 733-34 (discussing "[o]rganic, multilateral reputation institutions"); Barak D. Richman, Firms, Courts, and Reputation Mechanisms: Towards a Positive Theory of Private Ordering, 104 COLUM. L. REV. 2328, 2338-50 (2004) (contrasting the circumstances that underlie the choice of enforcing a contract through firms, courts, or private organizations). Because of the path dependency of institutional characteristics in particular jurisdictions, an account of their development requires a rich historical context.
  • 35
    • 38749126818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David M. Kreps, Corporate Culture and Economic Theory, in PERSPECTIVES ON POSITIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY 90 (James E. Alt & Kenneth A. Shepsle eds., 1990).
    • David M. Kreps, Corporate Culture and Economic Theory, in PERSPECTIVES ON POSITIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY 90 (James E. Alt & Kenneth A. Shepsle eds., 1990).
  • 36
    • 38749154305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A rollback cascade occurs when a potential trading partner knows that the party will not perform in the final round, so it will anticipate that behavior and not perform in the next-to-last round, which will be anticipated by the first party, and so on back to nonperformance in the current round
    • A rollback cascade occurs when a potential trading partner knows that the party will not perform in the final round, so it will anticipate that behavior and not perform in the next-to-last round, which will be anticipated by the first party, and so on back to nonperformance in the current round.
  • 37
    • 38749134897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kreps, supra note 21, at 111
    • Kreps, supra note 21, at 111.
  • 38
    • 38749138897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 108-10. Other techniques also can be used to bond future reputation, such as making observable investments in assets that will be valuable only if the corporation is successful.
    • Id. at 108-10. Other techniques also can be used to bond future reputation, such as making observable investments in assets that will be valuable only if the corporation is successful.
  • 39
    • 38749152085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Klein & Leffler, supra note 9
    • See Klein & Leffler, supra note 9.
  • 40
    • 38749138164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, all strategies require confronting the time preferences of the corporation's short-lived decision makers. Between Corporate Governance and Shareholder Wealth (European Corporate Governance Inst., Finance Working Paper No. 145/2007, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=954169 (finding that U.S. firms, on average, have better corporate governance than comparable foreign firms).
    • However, all strategies require confronting the time preferences of the corporation's short-lived decision makers. Between Corporate Governance and Shareholder Wealth (European Corporate Governance Inst., Finance Working Paper No. 145/2007, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=954169 (finding that U.S. firms, on average, have better corporate governance than comparable foreign firms).
  • 41
    • 38749089833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare LUCIAN BEBCHUK & JESSE FRIED, PAY WITHOUT PERFORMANCE: THE UNFULFILLED PROMISE OF EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION (2004) (criticizing the design of U.S. executive compensation),
    • Compare LUCIAN BEBCHUK & JESSE FRIED, PAY WITHOUT PERFORMANCE: THE UNFULFILLED PROMISE OF EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION (2004) (criticizing the design of U.S. executive compensation),
  • 42
    • 38749119040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • with Bengt Holmstrom, Pay Without Performance and the Managerial Power Hypothesis: A Comment, 30 J. CORP. L. 703 (2005) (assessing criticisms and defenses),
    • with Bengt Holmstrom, Pay Without Performance and the Managerial Power Hypothesis: A Comment, 30 J. CORP. L. 703 (2005) (assessing criticisms and defenses),
  • 43
    • 0036599979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Explaining Executive Compensation: Managerial Power Versus the Perceived Cost of Stock Options, 69
    • rebutting criticism, and
    • and Kevin J. Murphy, Explaining Executive Compensation: Managerial Power Versus the Perceived Cost of Stock Options, 69 U. CHI. L. REV. 847 (2002) (rebutting criticism).
    • (2002) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.847
    • Murphy, K.J.1
  • 44
    • 38749110412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cultural values concerning the importance of family and the trade-off between intrafamily loyalty and individual self interest will differ among countries. See Gilson, supra note 1, at 1673 (noting the cultural value of family control in Asia). Once the commitment to maximizing family wealth, as opposed to that of individual family members, breaks down-whether through cultural change as a result of modernization or because of what I have called the gravity of generations,
    • Cultural values concerning the importance of family and the trade-off between intrafamily loyalty and individual self interest will differ among countries. See Gilson, supra note 1, at 1673 (noting the cultural value of family control in Asia). Once the commitment to maximizing family wealth, as opposed to that of individual family members, breaks down-whether through cultural change as a result of modernization or because of what I have called the "gravity of generations,"
  • 45
    • 38749131254 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 1668 - then inside conflict over distributional issues will result in decreased commitment to reputation and reduced productivity generally. This, in turn, will undermine the support family ownership provides to reputation-based product market exchanges. Müller and Wärneryd argue that public ownership responds to such internal distributional competition by forcing inside managers to unite against the outside owners' demand for resources. While Müller and Wärneryd do not have family ownership in mind, the intuition seems applicable: dysfunctional family ownership leads to a public offering. Their model, however, assumes that the public's investors have the power through legal rules to assert themselves, a circumstance that is likely not present in developing countries.
    • id. at 1668 - then inside conflict over distributional issues will result in decreased commitment to reputation and reduced productivity generally. This, in turn, will undermine the support family ownership provides to reputation-based product market exchanges. Müller and Wärneryd argue that public ownership responds to such internal distributional competition by forcing inside managers to unite against the outside owners' demand for resources. While Müller and Wärneryd do not have family ownership in mind, the intuition seems applicable: dysfunctional family ownership leads to a public offering. Their model, however, assumes that the public's investors have the power through legal rules to assert themselves, a circumstance that is likely not present in developing countries.
  • 46
    • 0035623334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inside Versus Outside Ownership: A Political Theory of the Firm, 32
    • Holger M. Müller & Karl Wärneryd, Inside Versus Outside Ownership: A Political Theory of the Firm, 32 RAND J. ECON. 527 (2001).
    • (2001) RAND J. ECON , vol.527
    • Müller, H.M.1    Wärneryd, K.2
  • 47
    • 38749141416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shattered Dynasty
    • detailing how internal conflicts within the Pritzker family led to the breakup of the family fortune, For a striking example of the disintegration of intrafamily loyalty within a very successful U.S. family-controlled business, see, May, at
    • For a striking example of the disintegration of intrafamily loyalty within a very successful U.S. family-controlled business, see Suzanna Andrews, Shattered Dynasty, VANITY FAIR, May 2003, at 182 (detailing how internal conflicts within the Pritzker family led to the breakup of the family fortune).
    • (2003) VANITY FAIR , pp. 182
    • Andrews, S.1
  • 48
    • 38749121760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steven Tadelis develops a model of reputation formation that, in contrast to Kreps's focus on moral hazard (one party cheating in a future round, is based on adverse selection (future buyers are uncertain about whether future owners will be talented or trustworthy, Steven Tadelis, What's in a Name? Reputation as a Tradeable Asset, 89 AM. ECON. REV. 548 1999, Tadelis's model assumes that shifts in ownership of a business are not observable by customers of the business-hence the adverse selection problem that drives the model. Family ownership, by making ownership shifts to nonfamily transparent to future clients, therefore reduces the barriers to the operation of a reputation market in an adverse selection-driven model, just as it does in Kreps's moral hazard approach. To be fair, Tadelis does briefly consider the possibility that family ownership might address the adverse selection problem, but dismisses the fact of family ownership as providing to
    • Steven Tadelis develops a model of reputation formation that, in contrast to Kreps's focus on moral hazard (one party cheating in a future round), is based on adverse selection (future buyers are uncertain about whether future owners will be talented or trustworthy). Steven Tadelis, What's in a Name? Reputation as a Tradeable Asset, 89 AM. ECON. REV. 548 (1999). Tadelis's model assumes that shifts in ownership of a business are not observable by customers of the business-hence the adverse selection problem that drives the model. Family ownership, by making ownership shifts to nonfamily transparent to future clients, therefore reduces the barriers to the operation of a reputation market in an adverse selection-driven model, just as it does in Kreps's moral hazard approach. To be fair, Tadelis does briefly consider the possibility that family ownership might address the adverse selection problem, but dismisses the fact of family ownership as providing too little information to support a separation between good and bad service providers: "Clearly, businesses that have signs claiming that they have been owned by the same family for 75 years convey little information about the quality of the current owner, let alone of the key employees."
  • 49
    • 38749091357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 560. In settings where family ownership powerfully predicts individual family member preferences for business success, Tadelis dismisses the impact of family ownership too quickly
    • There is some empirical evidence that supports this inference
    • Id. at 560. In settings where family ownership powerfully predicts individual family member preferences for business success, Tadelis dismisses the impact of family ownership too quickly. His point might be better understood as a prediction of regression to the mean in talent as control shifts from the business's founder to her heirs. There is some empirical evidence that supports this inference.
    • His point might be better understood as a prediction of regression to the mean in talent as control shifts from the business's founder to her heirs
  • 50
    • 76849091874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 1, at, reviewing studies
    • See Gilson, supra note 1, at 1668-69 (reviewing studies).
    • supra , pp. 1668-1669
    • Gilson1
  • 51
    • 0000859784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is Group Affiliation Profitable in Emerging Markets? An Analysis of Diversified Indian Business Groups, 55
    • explaining the advantages of an internal capital market in emerging market jurisdictions, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Tarun Khanna & Krishna Palepu, Is Group Affiliation Profitable in Emerging Markets? An Analysis of Diversified Indian Business Groups, 55 J. FIN. 867 (2000) (explaining the advantages of an internal capital market in emerging market jurisdictions).
    • (2000) J. FIN , vol.867
    • Khanna, T.1    Palepu, K.2
  • 52
    • 38749118284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., RONALD J. GILSON & BERNARD S. BLACK, THE LAW AND FINANCE OF CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS 332-57 (2d ed. 1995) (reviewing explanations for conglomerate acquisitions).
    • See, e.g., RONALD J. GILSON & BERNARD S. BLACK, THE LAW AND FINANCE OF CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS 332-57 (2d ed. 1995) (reviewing explanations for conglomerate acquisitions).
  • 53
    • 1442357045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A number of explanations have been advanced for why a controlling shareholder would want to establish public minority shareholders, whether in an initial public offering or in a spin-out public sale of a minority interest in a previously wholly owned subsidiary. These include the evaluative information provided by the pricing of an efficient stock market and the availability of publicly traded shares as an incentive compensation vehicle. See Ronald J. Gilson & Jeffrey N. Gordon, Controlling Controlling Shareholders, 152 U. PA. L. REV. 785, 791 (2003, summarizing benefits to a controlling shareholder from having a publicly traded minority);
    • A number of explanations have been advanced for why a controlling shareholder would want to establish public minority shareholders, whether in an initial public offering or in a spin-out public sale of a minority interest in a previously wholly owned subsidiary. These include the evaluative information provided by the pricing of an efficient stock market and the availability of publicly traded shares as an incentive compensation vehicle. See Ronald J. Gilson & Jeffrey N. Gordon, Controlling Controlling Shareholders, 152 U. PA. L. REV. 785, 791 (2003) (summarizing benefits to a controlling shareholder from having a publicly traded minority);
  • 54
    • 0038923638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Katherine Schipper & Abbie Smith, A Comparison of Equity Carve-Outs and Seasoned Equity Offerings: Share Price Effects and Corporate Restructuring, 15 J. FIN. ECON. 153, 182 (1986) (explaining the information effect of a minority carve-out). Such information-based explanations, however, require an efficient stock market, a condition that is not consistent with poor shareholder protection law.
    • Katherine Schipper & Abbie Smith, A Comparison of Equity Carve-Outs and Seasoned Equity Offerings: Share Price Effects and Corporate Restructuring, 15 J. FIN. ECON. 153, 182 (1986) (explaining the information effect of a minority carve-out). Such information-based explanations, however, require an efficient stock market, a condition that is not consistent with poor shareholder protection law.
  • 55
    • 29244470826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Heitor Almeida & Daniel Wolfenzon, Should Business Groups Be Dismantled? The Equilibrium Costs of Efficient Internal Capital Markets, 79 J. FIN. ECON. 99, 116 (2006), provide a good example. In Almeida and Wolfenzon's model, the extent to which the controlling shareholder can divert assets is expressed as a pledgeability parameter; the model then yields different results depending on the extent to which returns can be effectively committed to minority investors. However, the institutional structures that allow an effective commitment not to divert more than a particular value of the parameter are not discussed.
    • Heitor Almeida & Daniel Wolfenzon, Should Business Groups Be Dismantled? The Equilibrium Costs of Efficient Internal Capital Markets, 79 J. FIN. ECON. 99, 116 (2006), provide a good example. In Almeida and Wolfenzon's model, the extent to which the controlling shareholder can divert assets is expressed as a "pledgeability" parameter; the model then yields different results depending on the extent to which returns can be effectively committed to minority investors. However, the institutional structures that allow an effective commitment not to divert more than a particular value of the parameter are not discussed.
  • 56
    • 0036791023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrei Shleifer & Daniel Wolfenzon, Investor Protection and Equity Markets, 66 J. FIN. ECON. 3, 14 (2002), use a similar modeling technique to parametize the level of diversion.
    • Andrei Shleifer & Daniel Wolfenzon, Investor Protection and Equity Markets, 66 J. FIN. ECON. 3, 14 (2002), use a similar modeling technique to parametize the level of diversion.
  • 57
    • 38749148825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., RICHARD A. BREALEY, STEWART C. MYERS & FRANKLIN ALLEN, PRINCIPLES OF CORPORATE FINANCE 490-93 (8th ed. 2006);
    • See, e.g., RICHARD A. BREALEY, STEWART C. MYERS & FRANKLIN ALLEN, PRINCIPLES OF CORPORATE FINANCE 490-93 (8th ed. 2006);
  • 58
    • 38749147283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STEPHEN A. ROSS ET AL, supra note 7, at 450-53
    • STEPHEN A. ROSS ET AL., supra note 7, at 450-53.
  • 59
    • 76849091874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 1, at, addresses possible reforms to improve these adverse selection problems
    • Gilson, supra note 1, at 1674-78, addresses possible reforms to improve these adverse selection problems.
    • supra , pp. 1674-1678
    • Gilson1
  • 60
    • 38749152470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 18, at, describing self enforcement among traders
    • See Greif, supra note 18, at 732-35 (describing self enforcement among traders);
    • supra , pp. 732-735
    • Greif1
  • 61
    • 44849120257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 20, at, describing private ordering systems
    • Richman, supra note 20, at 2338-48 (describing private ordering systems).
    • supra , pp. 2338-2348
    • Richman1
  • 62
    • 38749083064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Dyck & Zingales, supra note 5, at 582-86 (treating newspapers as a corporate governance constraint). Luca Enriques has pointed out that the role of the financial press may be limited to a handful of developed countries where there is a widespread confidence in the newspapers' journalistic integrity. Absent that confidence, they cannot play the contemplated shaming role. E-mail from Luca Enriques, Professor of Law, University of Bologna, and Commissioner, Commissione Nazionale per le Societa e la Borsa (CONSOB) (Nov. 24, 2006) (on file with author).
    • See Dyck & Zingales, supra note 5, at 582-86 (treating newspapers as a corporate governance constraint). Luca Enriques has pointed out that the role of the financial press may be limited to a handful of developed countries where there is a widespread confidence in the newspapers' journalistic integrity. Absent that confidence, they cannot play the contemplated "shaming" role. E-mail from Luca Enriques, Professor of Law, University of Bologna, and Commissioner, Commissione Nazionale per le Societa e la Borsa (CONSOB) (Nov. 24, 2006) (on file with author).
  • 63
    • 38749150991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I recognize that I am at this point glossing over a serious problem-why is a controlling shareholder's treatment of minority shareholders more observable than the quality of the products or services it provides? Or, setting the bar at a realistically lower level, is the controlling shareholder's treatment of minority shareholders sufficiently observable that it adds something to the customer's assessment of the corporation's reputation based only on the products or services it provides? I will return to this concern after describing the product market explanation for minority shareholders in family-controlled corporations. See infra pp. 651-52
    • I recognize that I am at this point glossing over a serious problem-why is a controlling shareholder's treatment of minority shareholders more observable than the quality of the products or services it provides? Or, setting the bar at a realistically lower level, is the controlling shareholder's treatment of minority shareholders sufficiently observable that it adds something to the customer's assessment of the corporation's reputation based only on the products or services it provides? I will return to this concern after describing the product market explanation for minority shareholders in family-controlled corporations. See infra pp. 651-52.
  • 64
    • 38749119792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Klein & Leffler, supra note 9
    • Klein & Leffler, supra note 9.
  • 65
    • 38749148496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The joke concerns a physicist, a chemist, and an economist stranded on a desert island with a can of food and no obvious way to open it. After the physicist and chemist suggest complex and unrealistic ways to open the can based on their specialties, the economist, expressing disdain for the inelegance of his companions' efforts, offers his solution: assume a can opener.
    • The joke concerns a physicist, a chemist, and an economist stranded on a desert island with a can of food and no obvious way to open it. After the physicist and chemist suggest complex and unrealistic ways to open the can based on their specialties, the economist, expressing disdain for the inelegance of his companions' efforts, offers his solution: assume a can opener.
  • 66
    • 38749101368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The enforcement of a Japanese main bank's obligation to undertake a rescue of its clients has been said to operate in this informal way. While a main bank had no formal legal obligation to undertake a rescue, the Ministry of Finance had to approve applications to open new bank branches, a decision that was left entirely in the Ministry of Finance's discretion. The failure to discharge the informal rescue obligation would be punished by the denial of branch applications. See Masahiko Aoki, Hugh Patrick & Paul Sheard, The Japanese Main Bank System: An Introductory Overview, in THE JAPANESE MAIN BANK SYSTEM 3, 31-32 (Masahiko Aoki & Hugh Patrick eds., 1994).
    • The enforcement of a Japanese main bank's obligation to undertake a rescue of its clients has been said to operate in this informal way. While a main bank had no formal legal obligation to undertake a rescue, the Ministry of Finance had to approve applications to open new bank branches, a decision that was left entirely in the Ministry of Finance's discretion. The failure to discharge the informal rescue obligation would be punished by the denial of branch applications. See Masahiko Aoki, Hugh Patrick & Paul Sheard, The Japanese Main Bank System: An Introductory Overview, in THE JAPANESE MAIN BANK SYSTEM 3, 31-32 (Masahiko Aoki & Hugh Patrick eds., 1994).
  • 67
    • 38749130122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DIXIT, supra note 14, at 82;
    • See DIXIT, supra note 14, at 82;
  • 68
    • 38749102395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Li, supra note 9, at 651
    • Li, supra note 9, at 651.
  • 69
    • 38749112594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Both DIXIT, supra note 14, at 80-82
    • Both DIXIT, supra note 14, at 80-82,
  • 70
    • 38749095548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Li, supra note 9, at 659-60, stress this point. Douglass North has stated that the inability of societies to develop effective, low-cost enforcement of contracts is the most important source of both historical stagnation and contemporary underdevelopment in the Third World.
    • and Li, supra note 9, at 659-60, stress this point. Douglass North has stated that "the inability of societies to develop effective, low-cost enforcement of contracts is the most important source of both historical stagnation and contemporary underdevelopment in the Third World."
  • 71
    • 38749105846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NORTH, supra note 16, at 54
    • NORTH, supra note 16, at 54.
  • 72
    • 38749083849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DIXIT, supra note 14, at 80
    • DIXIT, supra note 14, at 80.
  • 73
    • 38749150654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, in a system with good commercial law, contractual commitments like warranties can provide new entrants a substitute for difficult-to-acquire reputation. When KIA, a Korean automobile manufacturer, entered the U.S. market, it offered a substantially longer warranty than its established competitors. See Micheline Maynard, Things Are Looking up for South Korea's Carmakers, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 7, 2001, at F1.
    • For example, in a system with good commercial law, contractual commitments like warranties can provide new entrants a substitute for difficult-to-acquire reputation. When KIA, a Korean automobile manufacturer, entered the U.S. market, it offered a substantially longer warranty than its established competitors. See Micheline Maynard, Things Are Looking up for South Korea's Carmakers, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 7, 2001, at F1.
  • 74
    • 38749084568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MANCUR OLSON, THE RISE AND DECLINE OF NATIONS, 167-70 (1982). Almeida and Wolfenzon, supra note 33, make the same point about conglomerates in developing countries. Once conglomerates become a large enough part of the economy, they may impose a negative externality by causing the overall capital market to operate inefficiently because of a kind of crowding phenomenon, even if the conglomerates' internal capital markets operate efficiently. In this setting, government intervention may be necessary to reduce the conglomerates' role.
    • MANCUR OLSON, THE RISE AND DECLINE OF NATIONS, 167-70 (1982). Almeida and Wolfenzon, supra note 33, make the same point about conglomerates in developing countries. Once conglomerates become a large enough part of the economy, they may impose a negative externality by causing the overall capital market to operate inefficiently because of a kind of crowding phenomenon, even if the conglomerates' internal capital markets operate efficiently. In this setting, government intervention may be necessary to reduce the conglomerates' role.
  • 75
    • 0003077523 scopus 로고
    • Complementarities and Systems: Understanding Japanese Economic Organization, 9
    • Paul Milgrom & John Roberts, Complementarities and Systems: Understanding Japanese Economic Organization, 9 ESTUDIOS ECONÓMICOS 3, 12 (1994).
    • (1994) ESTUDIOS ECONÓMICOS , vol.3 , pp. 12
    • Milgrom, P.1    Roberts, J.2
  • 76
    • 38749135870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 77
    • 38749086505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Li, supra note 9, at 669
    • Li, supra note 9, at 669.
  • 78
    • 38749151570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent scholarship suggests that in some countries causation may run in the opposite direction. Julian Franks, Colin Mayer and Stefano Rossi, Spending Less Time with Family: The Decline of Family Ownership in the UK, in THE HISTORY OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AROUND THE WORLD: FAMILY BUSINESS GROUPS TO PROFESSIONAL MANAGERS Randall Morck ed, 2005, argue that U.K. shareholding patterns arose from informal relations of trust and confidence that encouraged equity investment by investors geographically proximate to the issuer. Here the influence is from product market to capital market. This diversity in actual history among jurisdictions is consistent with Avner Greifs conclusion that the structure of reputation markets in individual countries will be path dependent: Cultural beliefs and behavioral norms coordinate expectations and provide a shared understanding of the meaning of various
    • Recent scholarship suggests that in some countries causation may run in the opposite direction. Julian Franks, Colin Mayer and Stefano Rossi, Spending Less Time with Family: The Decline of Family Ownership in the UK, in THE HISTORY OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AROUND THE WORLD: FAMILY BUSINESS GROUPS TO PROFESSIONAL MANAGERS (Randall Morck ed., 2005), argue that U.K. shareholding patterns arose from informal relations of trust and confidence that encouraged equity investment by investors geographically proximate to the issuer. Here the influence is from product market to capital market. This diversity in actual history among jurisdictions is consistent with Avner Greifs conclusion that the structure of reputation markets in individual countries will be path dependent: "Cultural beliefs and behavioral norms coordinate expectations and provide a shared understanding of the meaning of various actions. Ceteris paribus, initial social structures and cultural features therefore influence which, among the many possible organic [reputation market structures] will emerge . . . ."
  • 79
    • 38749154304 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Greif, supra note 18, at 762
    • Greif, supra note 18, at 762.
  • 80
    • 38749137778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • discussing path dependency of corporate governance institutions, See, at
    • See Gilson, Corporate Governance and Economic Efficiency, supra note 25 at 329-34 (discussing path dependency of corporate governance institutions);
    • Corporate Governance and Economic Efficiency, supra note , vol.25 , pp. 329-334
    • Gilson1
  • 81
    • 38749132884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gilson, Globalizing Corporate Governance, supra note 25 same
    • Gilson, Globalizing Corporate Governance, supra note 25 (same).
  • 82
    • 38749124771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kenneth W. Dam, Legal Institutions, Legal Origins, and Governance (Chicago Working Paper Series, John M. Olin Law & Econ. Working Paper No. 303, 2006), available at http://ssra.com/abstract= 932694 (surveying literature).
    • See Kenneth W. Dam, Legal Institutions, Legal Origins, and Governance (Chicago Working Paper Series, John M. Olin Law & Econ. Working Paper No. 303, 2006), available at http://ssra.com/abstract= 932694 (surveying literature).
  • 83
    • 11044236290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Avner Greif and David Laitin provide an analytic road map for developing a dynamic account of system change, noting that a game-theoretic account explains an equilibrium, not what causes a system to shift to a new equilibrium. Avner Greif & David D. Laitin, A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change, 98 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 633 2004, A shift resulting from changed external conditions is easy enough to explain-the rules of the game have changed. The harder question is to explain how systems change as a result of internal forces. Given the equilibrium analysis, e]ndongenous institutional change appears, then, to be a contradiction in terms
    • Avner Greif and David Laitin provide an analytic road map for developing a dynamic account of system change, noting that a game-theoretic account explains an equilibrium, not what causes a system to shift to a new equilibrium. Avner Greif & David D. Laitin, A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change, 98 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 633 (2004). A shift resulting from changed external conditions is easy enough to explain-the rules of the game have changed. The harder question is to explain how systems change as a result of internal forces. Given the equilibrium analysis, "[e]ndongenous institutional change appears, then, to be a contradiction in terms."
  • 84
    • 38749128755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 633
    • Id. at 633.
  • 85
    • 0034439031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Dani Rodrik, Institutions for High-Quality Growth: What They Are and How to Acquire Them, STUD. COMP. INT'L DEV., Sept. 2000, at 3, 16-20 (2000) (finding that, in sample of countries, authoritarian regimes are associated with more volatility in economic growth).
    • See Dani Rodrik, Institutions for High-Quality Growth: What They Are and How to Acquire Them, STUD. COMP. INT'L DEV., Sept. 2000, at 3, 16-20 (2000) (finding that, in sample of countries, authoritarian regimes are associated with more volatility in economic growth).
  • 86
    • 38749112959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fareed Zakaria makes a related claim that explains the development of democratic government rather than economic development. He argues that the success of democracy is a function of per capita GDP. In his view, the first step toward representative government is economic development, which may require a dictator, but which also then creates the middle class that will bring the dictator down. FAREED ZAKARIA, THE FUTURE OF FREEDOM 69-73 2003
    • Fareed Zakaria makes a related claim that explains the development of democratic government rather than economic development. He argues that the success of democracy is a function of per capita GDP. In his view, the first step toward representative government is economic development, which may require a dictator, but which also then creates the middle class that will bring the dictator down. FAREED ZAKARIA, THE FUTURE OF FREEDOM 69-73 (2003).
  • 87
    • 38749088359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Played through the model in Greif and Laitin, supra note 52, this would be an example of an equilibrium whose circumstances undermine its stability.
    • Played through the model in Greif and Laitin, supra note 52, this would be an example of an equilibrium whose circumstances undermine its stability.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.